Game Theory
Game Theory
strategy, Ch 13)
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=2d_dtTZQyUM
4.1 GAMING AND STRATEGIC DECISIONS
Figure 13.1
You (Y) and a competitor (C) plan to sell soft drinks on a beach.
If sunbathers are spread evenly across the beach and will walk to the closest vendor, the
two of you will locate next to each other at the center of the beach. This is the only
Nash equilibrium.
If your competitor located at point A, you would want to move until you were just to the
left, where you could capture three-fourths of all sales.
But your competitor would then want to move back to the center, and you would do the s
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
Mixed Strategies
● pure strategy Strategy in which a player makes a
specific choice or takes a specific action.
Matching Pennies
In this game, each player chooses heads or tails and the
two players reveal their coins at the same time. If the
coins match, Player A wins and receives a dollar from
Player B. If the coins do not match, Player B wins and
receives a dollar from Player A.
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
If both firms used maximin strategies, the outcome would be that Firm 1 does not
invest and Firm 2 does. A maximin strategy is conservative, but it is not profit-
maximizing.
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
Mixed Strategies
● mixed strategy Strategy in which a player makes a
random choice among two or more possible actions,
based on a set of chosen probabilities.
The Battle of the Sexes
Jim and Joan would like to spend Saturday night together
but have different tastes in entertainment. Jim would like
to go to the opera, but Joan prefers mud wrestling.
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
Tit-for-Tat Strategy
Tit-for-Tat in Practice
Since most of us do not expect to live forever, the unraveling
argument would seem to make the tit-for-tat strategy of little
value, leaving us stuck in the prisoners’ dilemma. In practice,
however, tit-for- tat can sometimes work and cooperation can
prevail.
There are two primary reasons.
Most managers don’t know how long they will be
competing with their rivals, and this also serves to
make cooperative behavior a good strategy.
My competitor might have some doubt about the
extent of my rationality.
In a repeated game, the prisoners’ dilemma can have a
cooperative
outcome.
Microeconomics (Game theory and competitive strategy,
Ch 13)
Thank
You