0% found this document useful (0 votes)
96 views61 pages

Income and Substitution Effects

Changes in prices and income can influence consumer demand through substitution and income effects. The substitution effect occurs when a price change alters consumption while holding utility constant. The income effect happens when a price change shifts the budget constraint, changing real income and allowing movement to a new indifference curve. For normal goods, the effects reinforce each other, but for inferior goods they work in opposition, making the overall impact uncertain.

Uploaded by

Suraj Shinde
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
96 views61 pages

Income and Substitution Effects

Changes in prices and income can influence consumer demand through substitution and income effects. The substitution effect occurs when a price change alters consumption while holding utility constant. The income effect happens when a price change shifts the budget constraint, changing real income and allowing movement to a new indifference curve. For normal goods, the effects reinforce each other, but for inferior goods they work in opposition, making the overall impact uncertain.

Uploaded by

Suraj Shinde
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 61

Chapter 5

INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION


EFFECTS

1
Objectives
• How will changes in prices and income
influence influence consumer’s optimal
choices?
– We will look at partial derivatives

2
Demand Functions (review)
• We have already seen how to obtain consumer’s optimal choice
• Consumer’s optimal choice was computed Max consumer’s utility
subject to the budget constraint
• After solving this problem, we obtained that optimal choices depend on
prices of all goods and income.
• We usually call the formula for the optimal choice: the demand function
• For example, in the case of the Complements utility function , we
obtained that the demand function (optimal choice) is:

I I
x*  y* 
px  0.25 py 4 p x  py
3
Demand Functions
• If we work with a generic utility function (we do
not know its mathematical formula), then we
express the demand function as:

x* = x(px,py,I)

y* = y(px,py,I)
•We will keep assuming that prices and income is
exogenous, that is:
–the individual has no control over these
parameters 4
Simple property of demand functions
• If we were to double all prices and
income, the optimal quantities demanded
will not change
– Notice that the budget constraint does not
change (the slope does not change, the
crossing with the axis do not change either)

xi* = di(px,py,I) = di(2px,2py,2I)

5
Changes in Income
• Since px/py does not change, the MRS
will stay constant
• An increase in income will cause the
budget constraint out in a parallel
fashion (MRS stays constant)

6
What is a Normal Good?
• A good xi for which xi/I  0 over some
range of income is a normal good in that
range

7
Normal goods
• If both x and y increase as income rises,
x and y are normal goods

Quantity of y
As income rises, the individual chooses
to consume more x and y

C
B

A U3
U2
U1
Quantity of x
8
What is an inferior Good?

• A good xi for which xi/I < 0 over some


range of income is an inferior good in
that range

9
Inferior good
• If x decreases as income rises, x is an
inferior good
As income rises, the individual chooses
to consume less x and more y
Quantity of y

B U3

U2
A
U1
Quantity of x
10
Changes in a Good’s Price
• A change in the price of a good alters the
slope of the budget constraint (px/py)
– Consequently, it changes the MRS at the
consumer’s utility-maximizing choices
• When a price changes, we can decompose
consumer’s reaction in two effects:
– substitution effect
– income effect

11
Substitution and Income effects
• Even if the individual remained on the same
indifference curve when the price changes,
his optimal choice will change because the
MRS must equal the new price ratio
– the substitution effect
• The price change alters the individual’s real
income and therefore he must move to a
new indifference curve
– the income effect
12
Sign of substitution effect (SE)
SE is always negative, that is, if price increases, the substitution
effect makes quantity to decrease and conversely. See why:
1) Assume px decreases, so: px1< px0
2) MRS(x0,y0)= px0/ py0 & MRS(x1,y1)= px1/ py0

1 and 2 implies that:


MRS(x1,y1)<MRS(x0,y0)

As the MRS is decreasing in x, this means that x has increased,


that is: x1>x0

13
Changes in the optimal choice when a price
decreases
Quantity of y
Suppose the consumer is maximizing
utility at point A.

If the price of good x falls, the consumer


will maximize utility at point B.
B

A
U2

U1

Quantity of x
Total increase in x
14
Substitution effect when a price decreases
To isolate the substitution effect, we hold
Quantity of y utility constant but allow the
relative price of good x to change.
Purple is parallel to the new one

The substitution effect is the movement


from point A to point C

A C The individual substitutes


good x for good y
U1
because it is now
relatively cheaper
Quantity of x

Substitution effect
15
Income effect when the price decreases
Quantity of y The income effect occurs because the
individual’s “real” income changes
(hence utility changes) when
the price of good x changes
The income effect is the movement
from point C to point B
B
If x is a normal good,
A C
U2 the individual will buy
more because “real”
U1
income increased
Quantity of x

Income effect

How would the graph change if the good was inferior? 16


Subs and income effects when a price
increases
Quantity of y
An increase in the price of good x means that
the budget constraint gets steeper
The substitution effect is the
C
movement from point A to point C
A

B
The income effect is the
U1 movement from point C
to point B
U2

Quantity of x
Substitution effect
Income effect
17
How would the graph change if the good was inferior?
Price Changes for
Normal Goods
• If a good is normal, substitution and
income effects reinforce one another
– when price falls, both effects lead to a rise in
quantity demanded
– when price rises, both effects lead to a drop
in quantity demanded

18
Price Changes for
Inferior Goods
• If a good is inferior, substitution and
income effects move in opposite directions
• The combined effect is indeterminate
– when price rises, the substitution effect leads
to a drop in quantity demanded, but the
income effect is opposite
– when price falls, the substitution effect leads
to a rise in quantity demanded, but the
income effect is opposite 19
Giffen’s Paradox
• If the income effect of a price change is
strong enough, there could be a positive
relationship between price and quantity
demanded
– an increase in price leads to a drop in real
income
– since the good is inferior, a drop in income
causes quantity demanded to rise

20
A Summary
• Utility maximization implies that (for normal goods)
a fall in price leads to an increase in quantity
demanded
– the substitution effect causes more to be purchased as
the individual moves along an indifference curve
– the income effect causes more to be purchased
because the resulting rise in purchasing power allows
the individual to move to a higher indifference curve
• Obvious relation hold for a rise in price…

21
A Summary
• Utility maximization implies that (for inferior
goods) no definite prediction can be made
for changes in price
– the substitution effect and income effect move
in opposite directions
– if the income effect outweighs the substitution
effect, we have a case of Giffen’s paradox

22
Compensated Demand Functions
• This is a new concept
• It is the solution to the following problem:
– MIN PXX+ PYY
– SUBJECT TO U(X,Y)=U0
• Basically, the compensated demand functions are the solution to the Expenditure
Minimization problem that we saw in the previous chapter
• After solving this problem, we obtained that optimal choices depend on prices of all
goods and utility. We usually call the formula: the compensated demand function
• x* = xc(px,py,U),
• y* = yc(px,py,U)

23
Compensated Demand Functions
• xc(px,py,U0), and yc(px,py,U0) tell us what
quantities of x and y minimize the expenditure
required to achieve utility level U0 at current
prices px,py

• Notice that the following relation must hold:

• pxxc(px,py,U0)+ pyyc(px,py,U0)=E(px,py,U0)

– So this is another way of computing the expenditure


function !!!!
24
Compensated Demand Functions
• There are two mathematical tricks to obtain the compensated demand function
without the need to solve the problem:
– MIN PXX+ PYY
– SUBJECT TO U(X,Y)=U0
• One trick(A) (called Shephard’s Lemma) is using the derivative of the
expenditure function

• Another trick(B) is to use the marshallian demand and the expenditure function

25
Compensated Demand Functions
• Sheppard’s Lema to obtain the compensated
demand function
E ( p x , p y , u )
x
dp x
E ( p x , p y , u )
y
dp y

Intuition: a £1 increase in px raises necessary


expenditures by x pounds, because £1 must be paid
for each unit of x purchased.
26
Proof: footnote 5 in page 137
Trick (B) to obtain compensated demand
functions

x  x( p x , p y , I ), demand function
I  E ( p x , p y , U ), expenditure function
Substituing ...
x  x( p x , p y , E ( p x , p y , U ))  x( p x , p y , U )
that is, the compensated demand function
because it depends on prices and utility
27
Trick (B) to obtain compensated demand functions

• Suppose that utility is given by


utility = U(x,y) = x0.5y0.5
• The Marshallian demand functions are
x = I/2px y = I/2py
• The expenditure function is

E  2 p x0.5 p 0y.5 U  I

28
Another trick to obtain compensated demand
functions
• Substitute the expenditure function into
the Marshallian demand functions, and
find the compensated ones:

Up 0y.5 Up x0.5
x y  0.5
p x0.5 py

29
Compensated Demand
Functions
Vpy0.5 Vpx0.5
x y  0. 5
px0.5 py
• Demand now depends on utility (V) rather than
income
• Increases in px changes the amount of x
demanded, keeping utility V constant. Hence
the compensated demand function only
includes the substitution effect but not the
income effect
30
Roy’s identity

• It is the relation between marshallian demand


function and indirect utility function

V V
dpx dp y
x( px , p y , I )   ; y( px , p y , I )  
V V
dI dI
Proof of the Roy’s identity…
31
Proof of Roy’s identity
V ( px , p y , I )  u
V ( px , p y , E ( p x , p y , u ))  u
Taking derivatives wrt p x :
V px '(.)  VI '(.) E ' px  0
Using previous trick:
E
E ' px   x
dpx
Substituting:
V px '(.)  VI '(.) x  0
and solving for x, we find the Roy's identity
32
Demand curves…
• We will start to talk about demand
curves. Notice that they are not the
same that demand functions !!!!

33
The Marshallian Demand Curve
• An individual’s demand for x depends
on preferences, all prices, and income:
x* = x(px,py,I)
• It may be convenient to graph the
individual’s demand for x assuming that
income and the price of y (py) are held
constant

34
The Marshallian Demand Curve
Quantity of y As the price px
of x falls...
…quantity of x
demanded rises.
px’

px’’

px’’’

U3
U2 x
U1

x1 x2 x3 x’ x’’ x’’’
Quantity of x Quantity of x
I = px’ + py I = px’’ + py I = px’’’ + py 35
The Marshallian Demand Curve
• The Marshallian demand curve shows the
relationship between the price of a good
and the quantity of that good purchased by
an individual assuming that all other
determinants of demand are held constant
• Notice that demand curve and demand
function is not the same thing!!!

36
Shifts in the Demand Curve
• Three factors are held constant when a
demand curve is derived
– income
– prices of other goods (py)
– the individual’s preferences
• If any of these factors change, the
demand curve will shift to a new position

37
Shifts in the Demand Curve
• A movement along a given demand
curve is caused by a change in the price
of the good
– a change in quantity demanded
• A shift in the demand curve is caused by
changes in income, prices of other
goods, or preferences
– a change in demand
38
Compensated Demand Curves
• An alternative approach holds utility
constant while examining reactions to
changes in px
– the effects of the price change are
“compensated” with income so as to constrain
the individual to remain on the same
indifference curve
– reactions to price changes include only
substitution effects (utility is kept constant)
39
Marshallian Demand Curves
• The actual level of utility varies along
the demand curve
• As the price of x falls, the individual
moves to higher indifference curves
– it is assumed that nominal income is held
constant as the demand curve is derived
– this means that “real” income rises as the
price of x falls

40
Compensated Demand Curves
• A compensated (Hicksian) demand curve
shows the relationship between the price
of a good and the quantity purchased
assuming that other prices and utility are
held constant
• The compensated demand curve is a two-
dimensional representation of the
compensated demand function
x* = xc(px,py,U)
41
Compensated Demand Curves
Holding utility constant, as price falls...
Quantity of y
px
p '
slope   x
py …quantity demanded
rises.
px ' ' px’
slope  
py

px’’
px ' ' '
slope   px’’’
py

xc

U2

x’ x’’ x’’’ x’ x’’ x’’’


Quantity of x Quantity of x
42
Compensated & Uncompensated
Demand for normal goods
px
At px’’, the curves intersect because
the individual’s income is just sufficient
to attain utility level U2

px’’

xc

x’’ Quantity of x

43
Compensated & Uncompensated Demand for
normal goods
At prices above p’’x, income
px
compensation is positive because the
individual needs some help to remain
on U2
px’

px’’

xc

x’ x* Quantity of x
As we are looking at normal goods, income and substitution effects go
in the same direction, so they are reinforced. X includes both while Xc
only the substitution effect. That is what drives the relative position of44
both curves
Compensated & Uncompensated
Demand for normal goods
px

At prices below px2, income


compensation is negative to prevent an
increase in utility from a lower price
px’’

px’’’ x

xc

As we are looking at normal goods,


x*** income
x’’’ and substitution
Quantity of x effects go
in the same direction, so they are reinforced. X includes both while Xc
only the substitution effect. That is what drives the relative position of45
both curves
Compensated &
Uncompensated Demand
• For a normal good, the compensated
demand curve is less responsive to price
changes than is the uncompensated
demand curve
– the uncompensated demand curve reflects
both income and substitution effects
– the compensated demand curve reflects only
substitution effects
46
Relations to keep in mind
• Sheppard’s Lema & Roy’s identity
• V(px,py,E(px,py,Uo)) = U0

• E(px,py,V(px,py,I0)) = I0
• xc(px,py,U0)=x(px,py,I0)

47
A Mathematical Examination
of a Change in Price
• Our goal is to examine how purchases of
good x change when px changes
x/px
• Differentiation of the first-order conditions
from utility maximization can be performed
to solve for this derivative

48
A Mathematical Examination
of a Change in Price
• However, for our purpose, we will use an
indirect approach
• Remember the expenditure function
minimum expenditure = E(px,py,U)
• Then, by definition
xc (px,py,U) = x [px,py,E(px,py,U)]
– quantity demanded is equal for both demand
functions when income is exactly what is needed to
attain the required utility level 49
A Mathematical Examination
of a Change in Price
xc (px,py,U) = x[px,py,E(px,py,U)]

• We can differentiate the compensated


demand function and get
x c x x E
  
px px E px

x x c x E
  
px px E px
50
A Mathematical Examination
of a Change in Price
x x c
x E
  
px px E px

• The first term is the slope of the


compensated demand curve
– the mathematical representation of the
substitution effect

51
A Mathematical Examination
of a Change in Price
x x c
x E
  
px px E px
• The second term measures the way in
which changes in px affect the demand
for x through changes in purchasing
power
– the mathematical representation of the
income effect
52
The Slutsky Equation
• The substitution effect can be written as
x c x
substitution effect  
px px U constant

• The income effect can be written as


x E x E
income effect      
E p x I p x
E
Using trick A : x
p x
x E x
income effect     x
I p x I 53
The Slutsky Equation
• A price change can be represented by
x
 substituti on effect  income effect
px
x x x
 x
px px U constant
I

54
The Slutsky Equation
x x x
 x
px px U constant
I

• The first term is the substitution effect


– always negative as long as MRS is
diminishing
– the slope of the compensated demand curve
must be negative
55
The Slutsky Equation
x x x
 x
px px U  constant
I

• The second term is the income effect


– if x is a normal good, then x/I > 0
• the entire income effect is negative
– if x is an inferior good, then x/I < 0
• the entire income effect is positive

56
A Slutsky Decomposition
• We can demonstrate the decomposition
of a price effect using the Cobb-Douglas
example studied earlier
• The Marshallian demand function for
good x was
0 .5 I
x ( p x , py , I ) 
px

57
A Slutsky Decomposition
• The Hicksian (compensated) demand
function for good x was
Vpy0.5
x c ( px , py ,V )  0 .5
p x

• The overall effect of a price change on


the demand for x is
x  0 .5 I

px px2
58
A Slutsky Decomposition
• This total effect is the sum of the two
effects that Slutsky identified
• The substitution effect is found by
differentiating the compensated demand
function
x
c
 0.5Vpy0.5
substitution effect  
px p1x.5

59
A Slutsky Decomposition
• We can substitute in for the indirect utility
function (V)
0.5 0.5
 0.5(0.5 Ip x p y )p 0.5
y  0.25 I
substitution effect  1 .5

p x px2

60
A Slutsky Decomposition
• Calculation of the income effect is easier

x  0 . 5 I  0 .5 0.25 I
income effect   x    
I p
 x  x p p 2
x

• By adding up substitution and income


effect, we will obtain the overall effect

61

You might also like