R merton
R merton
by
Robert C. Merton
684-73
November 1973
Robert C. Merton
I. Introduction
on three items: (1) the required rate of return on riskless (in terms of
(2) the various provisions and restrictions contained in the indenture (e.g.,
maturity date, coupon rate, call terms, seniority in the event of default,
sinking fund, etc.); (3) the probability that the firm will be unable to
default).
on the term structure of interest rates (item 1), there has been no systematic
use of the term "risk" is restricted to the possible gains or losses to bond-
and does not include the gains or losses inherent to all bonds caused by
the analysis, a given term structure is assumed and hence, the price differ-
of default.
-2-
Therefore, the model is subject to direct empirical tests which they [21
performed with some success. Merton [5] clarified and extended the Black-
Scholes model. While options are highly specialized and relatively unim-
portant financial instruments, both Black and Scholes [1] and Merton [5, 6]
Section III, the model is applied to the simplest form of corporate debt,
the discount bond where no coupon payments are made, and a formula for com-
puting the risk structure of interest rates is presented. In Section IV, com-
parative statics are used to develop graphs of the risk structure, and the
ruptcy of the famous Modigliani-Miller theorem [7] is proven, and the re-
bonds.
ibilities of assets.
levels so that each investor believes that he can buy and sell as
A.3 there exists an exchange market for borrowing and lending at the
A.4 short-sales of all assets, with full use of the proceeds, is allowEEd.
A.7 the Term-Structure is "flat" and known with certainty. I.e., the
A.8 The dynamics for the value of the firm, V, through time can be
differential equation
dV = (aV - C) dt + aVdz
where
time, C is the total dollar payouts by the firm per unit time to
-4-
Many of these assumptions are not necessary for the model to obtain but are
structure rrom term structure effects on pricing. A.5 and A.8 are the critical
assumptions. Basically, A.5 requires Lhat the market for these securities
is open for trading most of time. A.8 requires that price movements
time can be written as a function of the value of the firm and time, i.e.,
dY = [a Y - C dt + Ydz (1)
Y Y Y Y
where
dY = F dV + F(dV) + F (2)
v 2 vv t
2
= [ V2 F + (V-C)F + F] dt + dVF dz, from A.8,
2 vv v t v
aY = aF 2V 2F + (V-C)FP + F + C (3.a)
y y 2 vv v t y
a Y = a F cVF (3.b)
y Y v
dz - dz (3.c)
y
Note: from (3.c) the instantaneous returns on Y and V are perfectly cor-
related.
the firm, the particular security, and riskless debt such that the aggregate
--_I
-------
-6-
(dY+C )
dx = W (dV+Cdt) W +-- + W3rdt (4)
V 2 Y
be that to avoid arbitrage profits, the expected (and realized) return on the
-r
a - (6)
y
But, from (3a) and (3b), we substitute for a and a and rewrite (6) as
Y Y
the value of the firm and time. Of course, a complete description of the
-7-
and parameters appear in (7) (and hence, affect the value of the security)
and which do not. In addition to the value of the firm and time, F depends
on the interest rate, the volatility of the firm's value (or its business
risk) as measured by the variance, the payout policy of the firm, and the
promised payout policy to the holders of the security. However, F does not
depend on the expected rate of return on the firm nor on the risk-preferences
vestors beyond the three mentioned. Thus, two investors with quite differ-
ent utility functions and different expectations for the company's future
but who agree on the volatility of the firm's value will for a given
interest rate and current firm value, agree on the value of the particular
security, F. Also all the parameters and variables except the variance
are directly observable and the variance can be reasonably estimated from
we examine the simplest case of corporate debt pricing. Suppose the corpor-
ation has two classes of claims: (1) a single, homogenous class of debt and
(2) the residual claim, equity. Suppose further that the indenture of the
bond issue contains the following provisions and restrictions: (1) the firm
calendar date T;(2) in the event this payment is not met, the bondholders
immediately take over the company (and the shareholders receive nothing):
(3) the firm cannot ssue any new senior (or of equivalent rank) claims on
the firm nor can it pay cash dividends or do share repurchase prior to the
(8) for the value of the debt, two boundary conditions and an initial con-
dition must be specified. These boundary conditions are derived from the
·--
------------'I--- --
~1111--1---------
-9-
conditions (1) and (2) and the fact that management is elected by the equity
owners and hence, must act in their best interests. On the maturity date T
(i.e., T = 0), the firm must either pay the promised payment of B to the
T, V(T)>B, the firm should pay the bondholders because the value of equity
will be V(T) - B > O whereas if they do not, the value of equity would b,
zero. If V(T) < B, then the firm will not make the payment and default
the firm to the bondholders because otherwise the equity holders would have
to pay in additional money and the (formal) value of equity prior to such
payments would be (V(T) - B) < 0. Thus, the initial condition for the debt
at T = 0 is
Armed with boundary conditions (9), one could solve (8) directly for the
in the literature.
= V - F(V,T), and substitute for F in (8) and (9), to deduce the partial
Subject to:
that (10) and (11) are identical to the equations for an European call
isomorphic price relationship between levered equity of the firm and a call
option not only allows us to write down the solution to (10)-(11) directly,
results in these papers to the equity case and hence, to the debt. From
where
and
and
x 2 , X1 - /F
- 11 -
From (12) and F = V - f, we can write the value of' the debt'issue
as
r
F[V,T] = Be {i [h2(da2T)] + [h (d,a2 )]} (13)
where
d - Be-r /V
h l (d,;
a T'
) = -[
- 2T log(d)]/a/ri
h 2 (,a2
d 1) - [2T + log(d)]/aciT
where
and R(T) is the yield-to-maturity on the risky debt provided that the firm
2
two variables: (1) the variance (or volatility) of the firm's operations,
and (2) the ratio of the present value (at the riskless rate) of the promised
value ratio where debt is valued at the riskless rate, it is a biased up-
Since Merton [5] has solved the option pricing problem when the
i .................................
- 12 -
term structure is not "flat" and is stochastic, (by again using the iso-
the risk structure with a stochastic term structure. The formulae (13) and
(14) would be the same in this case except that we would replace "exp[-rt]"
by the price of a riskless discount bond which pays one dollar at time T in
the future and "a2 T" by a generalized variance term defined in [5, p. 166].
F = -f < 0
r r
where again subscripts denote partial derivatives. The results presented
in (15) are as one would have expected for a discount bond: namely, the
firm and the promised payment at maturity, and a decreasing function of the
time to maturity, the business risk of the firm, and the riskless rate of
interest.
more light on the characteristics of this structure to work with the price
- 13 -
ratio P F[V,T]/B exp[-rT] rather than the absolute price level F. P is the
dollar delivered at that date with certainty, and it is always less than or
2
where T c~ T. Note that, unlike F, P is completely determined by d, the
of the firm's value over the life of the bond, and it is a decreasing function
of both. I.e., 2
Pd - (hl)/d < 0 (17)
and
PT -'(h
- 1)/(2d/T) < 0 (18)
lyzing the risk structure: namely, g- y/o where fay is the instantaneous
standard deviation of the return on the bond and a is the instantaneous standard
deviation of the return on the firm. Because these two returns are instantane-
bond in terms of the riskiness of the firm at a given point in time.5 / From
y = VFV/F
= [hl(d,T)]/(P[d,T]d) (19)
=g[d,T].
poses of this section, we simply note that g is a function of d and T only, and
ay r
^_______III___LI_---(_4_·IC-L_----
- 14 -
where (ay - r) is the expected excess return on the debt and (a - r) is the
expected excess return on the firm as a whole. We can rewrite (17) and (18)
and
H22
Ha2 == e g[d,T]['(h)/4(h)] > 0; (24)
of both d and a . While from (25), the change in the premium with respect to
of the risk structure as measured by the term premium, we show that the pre-
dH ad
dr Hd ar
(26)
= -g[d,T] < 0.
of the riskiness of the bond. I.e., can one assert that if R - r is larger
for one bond than for another, then the former is riskier than the latter? To
"riskier." Since the risk structure like the corresponding term structure
is a "snap shot" at one point in time, it seems natural to define the riskiness
__._ -----
· · -s
Table I. Representative Values of the Term Premium, R - r
2 2
d R-r (%) a d R-r(%)
0.d 0.00 0.03 0.2 0.01
0.03 0.5 0.02 0.03 0.5 0.16
0.03 5.13 0.03 1.0 3.34
1.0
0.03 20.58 0.03 1.5 8,84
0.03 5
. 4. 4 0.03 3.e
0.03 3.0
cr2
d R-r (%) a 2 ....
d R-r(%)
0.03 0.c 0.01 0.03 0.e 0.09
0.03 0.38 0.03 0.5 0.60
0.03 1.0 2. 44 0.03 1.0 1-.64
0.03 1.s 4.98 0. * 03 1.5 2.57
0.'03 3 .O 11-07. 0.03 Z.S.. 4
- TERM
PRE'MIuM
0
0
d
*'QUAISI ' DEBT / FIRM VALUE RATIO
Fi3 xr 2.
TERM
PREMlu
0
0
VA RIANCE OF THEe FIRM
--·---------- ---------
--·-------·------------------
R-r Igr~ 3,
PREMIuM
0
0
TIME UNTIL MATUR I TY
- 15 -
in terms of the uncertainty of the rate of return over the next trading in-
is the (instantaneous) standard deviation of the return on the bond cry =- g[d,T]
However, it should be pointed out that the standard deviation is not sufficient
for each bond without the knowledge of such correlations, it can not reflect
such differences except indirectly through the market value of the firm. Thus,
> 0
> 0;
G =G V'(h 1) 1 2g) log d
G 0 (h) [I- -g+ T (29)
0O as d 1.
Figures 4-6 plot the standard deviation for typical values of d, a, and T.
Comparing (27) - (29) with (23) - (25), we see that the term premium and the
2.
2 d g G
a d g G
0.000 0.000 0.03 0.2 0.000 0.000
0.03 0.2
0.003 0.001 0.03 0.5 0.048 0.008
0.03 0.5
0.500 0,087 0.03 1.0 0.5QO 0.087
0.03 1-0
0.03 1 *5 0.943 0.1b3 0 .03 1.5 0*833 0.144
1.0U0 0.. -... 173 0.03 ..... 3-. 0,99 ... 0- 173
......
2 2 d
d g G g G
0.03 0. 0.003 0 .0 1 0-056 0-.010
0.5 0.128 0.022 0.03 0.5 0.253 0.044
0.03 1.0 0.087 0-03 1.0 - 0.500 0.087
1.5 0.745 0.129 0.03 1.5 0.651 0.113
0.03
0,03 3.0 0 *.466 0~467
.- ..... -3" . £a0- ..-..57 . . .148
r-STANDARD beluts
DEVIA tIo
OP ra
D
0sT'
_ _ -. WI
*1
I
I
I
I
I
0
o
J
1
DEBT / FIRM VALUE RATIO
G R3 " Ir
STANDARD
ItVtATI@oN
oP THE /
/9 dvl.
0 or
0
STANDARDO DEVIATION OF THE FIRM
__ ----. _.i~~____
G
a
STAf1DARrD
DEVIATION i$Au.,e 6.
OF THE
DBST
0
0
the "quasi"debt-to-firm value ratio or the business risk of the firm. How-
ever, they need not change in the same direction with a change in maturity
ing the term premiums on bonds of the same maturity does provide a valid com-
parison of the riskiness of such bonds, one cannot conclude that a higher
9/
viation .-
dG ad
Gd
dr :r
(30)
= -Td Gd < 0.
held so that the value of the firm could be treated as exogeneous to the ana-
lysis. If, for example, due to bankruptcy costs or corporate taxes, the M-M
theorem does not obtain and the value of the firm does depend on the debt-equity
ratio, then the formal analysis of the paper is still valid. However, the
=
solution, F F[V(F), ], would be required.
proof of the M-M theorem even in the presence of bankruptcy. To see this,
imagine that there are two firms identical with respect to their investment
- 17 -
decisions, but one firm issues debt and the other does not. The investor
can "create" a security with a payoff structure identical to the risky bond
(FVV) dollars of the equity and (F - FV) dollars of riskless bonds where V
is the value of the unlevered firm, and F and FV are determined by the solution
of (7). Since the value of the "manufactured" risky debt is always F, the
debt issued by the other firm can never sell for more than F. In a similar
by the levering firm. Hence, the value of the levered firm's equity can never
sell for more than f. But, by construction, f + F = V, the value of the un-
levered firm. Therefore, the value of the levered firm can be no larger than
model or the capital asset pricing model) to prove the theorem when bank-
ruptcy is possible.
We now examine a debt issue for a single firm. In this context, we are in-
terested in measuring the risk of the debt relative to the risk of the firm.
1 + d (h 2 )
g
g = 1+ D(h 1 ) (31)
- 18 -
From (31), we have 0 < g < 1. I.e., the debt of the firm can never be more
risky than the firm as a whole, and as a corollary, the equity of a levered
firm must always be at least as risky as the firm. In particular, from (13)
ratio of the present value of the promised payment to the current value of
the firm becomes large and therefore the probability of eventual default be-
comes large, the market value of the debt approaches that of the firm and the
the value of a riskless bond, and g + 0. So, in this case, the risk character-
istics of the debt become the same as riskless debt. Between these two ex -
tremes, the debt will behave like a combination of riskless debt and equity,
and will change in a continuous fashion. To see this, note that in the port-
folio used to replicate the risky debt by combining the equity of an unlevered
_______1 1 log d
gT = [-(1 - 2g) + log d](33)
0
o as d > 1.
_1__1_ I_____
F,-34Al-0 7.
1
- RTIO oF
STANODARD
- DEVI ATIOmS
DEST/ FIRM
tr
I
I
I
I A
0
"quASI DEBT / FIRM VARLE RATIO
F's-,,. 8.
4f
RATIO OF
STARIDAR b
I VIARM
b6Il1T / FIRI
w
T
I
i· · b
I.
!_..
i.
...._..
....
- 19 -
and
limit g[d,T] = , 0 < d < (35)
T+~
Thus, independent of the business risk of the firm or the length of time
until maturity, the standard deviation of the return on the debt equals half
the standard deviation of the return on the whole firm. From (35), as the
business risk of the firm or the time to maturity get large, y+ /2, for
all d.
debt can decline as either the business risk of the firm or the time until
maturity increases. Inspection of (33) shows that this is the case if d > 1
(i.e., the present value of the promised payment is less than the current
value of the firm). To see why this result is not unreasonable, consider
the following: for small T (i.e., 2 or T small), the chances that the debt
will become equity through default are large, and this will be reflected
(through an increase in or T), the chances are better that the firm value
will increase enough to meet the promised payment. It is also true that the
chances that the firm value will be lower are increased. However, remember
that g is a measure of how much the risky debt behaves like equity versus
debt. Since for g large, the debt is already more aptly described by equity
1
than riskless debt. (E.G., for d > 1, g > and the "replicating" portfolio
will contain more than half equity.) Thus, the increased probability of
meeting the promised payment dominates, and g declines. For d < 1, g will
be less than a half, and the argument goes just the opposite way. In the
is exactly half equity and half riskless debt, and the two effects cancel
- 20 -
leaving g unchanged.
finance: given a fixed investment decision, how does the required return on
debt and equity change, as alternative debt-equity mixes are chosen? Because
simplicity, suppose that the maturity of the debt, T, is fixed, and the
promised payment at maturity per bond if $1. Then, the debt-equity mix is
vious analysis, F is the value of the whole debt issue and B is the total
promised payment for the whole issue, B will be the number of bonds (promis-
ing $1 at maturity) in the current analysis, and F/B will be the price of
one bond.
(F/f) = F/(V-F). From (20), the required expected rate of return on the debt,
da
dX dy = (a - r) dB dB
dB, (36)
provided that dK/dB 0. From the definition of X and (13), we have that
Since dg/dB = gdd/B, we have from (32), (36), and (37) that
da d(a - r)g d
__L > (38)
dX X(1 + X)(1 - g (38)
_IXI_ _I_
EX PEC TED 9.
RF T RX
o(
I, X
0
MARKE T DSBT / EFgurTY RTIO
- 21 -
moves between zero and infinity, we use the well known identity that the equity
return is a weighted average of the return on debt and the return on the firm.
I.e.,
e = a + X( - ay)
y (39)
= a + (1 - g) X(a - r).
ae
e has a slope of (a - r) at X = 0 and is a concave function bounded from
above by the line a + (a - r)X. Figure 9 displays both a
and ae . While
y e
Figure 9 was not produced from computer simulation, it should be emphasized
of a.
coupon bond can be written as the sum of discount bonds' values weighted
simple formula exists for risky coupon bonds. The reason for this is that
if the firm defaults on a coupon payment, then all subsequent coupon payments
(and payments of principal) are also defaulted on. Thus, the default on one
of the event of default on the "mini" bond associated with a later maturity.
= 2
22
F+ + (rN,- ) F -r - + =0 (40)
uo = f + (rV - C) f - rf - f (41)
VV v T
subject to boundary conditions (9a), (9b), and (11). Again, equation (41)
which is the equation for the European option value on a stock which pays
solution to (41) or finite T has not yet be found, one has been found for
the limiting case of a perpetuity (T = o), and is presented in Merton [5, p. 172,
equation (46)]. Using the identity F = V - f, we can write the solution for
United States, there are preferred stocks with no maturity date and
developed for solving equations like (7) or (41). Hence, computation and
was assumed that coupon payments were made unitormly ana continuously. In
by replacing "C" in (40) by " iCi (T-Ti)" where ( ) is the dirac delta
function and T. is the length of time until maturity when the Ith coupon
1
indenture to state that "the firm can redeem the bonds at its option for a
stated price of K(T) dollars" where K may depend on the length of time until
maturity. Formally, equation (40) and boundary conditions (9.a) and (9.c)
are still valid. However, instead of the boundary condition (9.b) we have
that for each T, there will be some value for the firm, call it V(T), such
that for all V(T) > V(T), it would be advantageous tor the firm to redeem
Equation (40), (9.a), (9.c), and (43) provide a well-posed problem to solve
for F provided that the V(T) function were known. But, of course, it is not.
ment's option to redeem the bonds and that management operates in the best
interests of the equity holders. Hence, as bondholder, one must presume that
_I _ ___11___1 1_ II_____
- 24 -
management will select the V(T) function so as to maximize the value of equity,
f. But, from the identity F = V - f, this implies that the V(T) function chosen
will be the one which minimizes F[V,T; V(T)]. Therefore, the additional
condition is that
rely on the isomorphic correspondence with options and refer the reader to
F[V(T),T] = 0
Hence, appending (45) to (40), (9.a), (9.c) and (43), we solve tne problem
V. Conclusion
the whole observable; can be used to price almost any type of financial in-
strument. The method was applied to risky discount bonds to deduce a risk
2. For a rigorous discussion of Ito's Lemma, see McKean [4]. For refer-
ences to its application in portfolio theory, see Merton [5].
7. For example, in the context of the Capital Asset Pricing Model, the
correlations of the two firms with the market portfolio could be suf-
ficiently different so as to make the beta of the bond with the
larger standard deviation smaller than the beta on the bond with the
smaller standard deviation.
9. While inspection of (25) shows that HT < 0 for d > 1 which agrees
with the sign of GT for d > 1, HT can be either signed for d < 1
which does not agree with the positive sign on G .
Bibliography
1. Black, F. and Scholes, M., "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Lia-
bilities," Journal of Political Economy (May-June 1973).
4. McKean, H.P., Jr., Stochastic Integrals, New York, Academic Press, 1969.