0% found this document useful (0 votes)
13 views20 pages

Legislation and Economic

The presentation discusses the evolution and components of environmental legislation, emphasizing the integration of legal frameworks with economic instruments to address environmental challenges. It highlights the historical development of environmental laws, the role of market-based tools like taxes and tradable permits, and the importance of transparency and public participation. The conclusion stresses the need for adaptable policies that ensure equity and promote innovation while effectively reducing pollution.

Uploaded by

jtnatividad934
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
13 views20 pages

Legislation and Economic

The presentation discusses the evolution and components of environmental legislation, emphasizing the integration of legal frameworks with economic instruments to address environmental challenges. It highlights the historical development of environmental laws, the role of market-based tools like taxes and tradable permits, and the importance of transparency and public participation. The conclusion stresses the need for adaptable policies that ensure equity and promote innovation while effectively reducing pollution.

Uploaded by

jtnatividad934
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 20

Presentation by Julius Joseph Sabio and Jomar Pintor

LEGISLATION
AND
ECONOMIC
Math, Science and Technology
INTRODUCTION
Environmental governance depends on legislation to establish enforceable
standards for pollution control and resource management. Economic theory views
environmental degradation as a market failure, often driven by negative
externalities—where polluters do not bear the full social costs of their actions. Over
time, environmental legislation has evolved from basic common-law principles to
comprehensive statutory frameworks and international treaties.
To achieve environmental goals more efficiently, legal mandates are increasingly
combined with economic instruments such as taxes and tradable permits. These
market-based tools, including Pigouvian taxes and cap-and-trade systems, help
internalize external costs while encouraging innovation. Modern environmental
economics also supports rigorous cost–benefit analyses, ensuring that regulations
generate net benefits for society.
The integration of law and economics enables policymakers to design flexible,
enforceable policies that uphold environmental integrity while fostering economic
growth. Transparency and public participation are crucial for ensuring
accountability and the successful implementation of these policies.
This presentation will begin by examining the foundations and structure of
environmental legislation, followed by a discussion on economic instruments and
their role in promoting sustainable and equitable outcomes.
Environmental legislation provides the legal foundation
for protecting ecosystems, public health, and natural
resources by defining obligations, prohibitions, and
enforcement mechanisms. Over time, legislation has
evolved from common-law nuisance remedies to
comprehensive statutory frameworks at national and
international levels. Modern laws combine command-
and-control standards, market-based instruments, and
voluntary programs to address complex environmental
challenges.
HISTORICAL EVOLUTION OF
ENVIRONMENTAL LEGISLATION

Environmental law began with common-law principles like trespass and


nuisance, offering limited protection against pollution and land-use
issues. The Industrial Revolution prompted the first formal regulations,
including 19th-century British laws aimed at reducing coal smoke and
chemical waste to safeguard public health. In 1969, the U.S. National
Environmental Policy Act (NEPA) created a framework for environmental
assessments, requiring Environmental Impact Statements for major
federal projects. On the global stage, the 1972 Stockholm Conference
initiated the era of international environmental law, eventually leading to
the formation of numerous multilateral environmental treaties.
CORE COMPONENTS OF
ENVIRONMENTAL LEGISLATION
Environmental statutes are built around key components that ensure
effective regulation and accountability. These include:
Scope and Definitions: Clearly identify pollutants, sources, and
regulated entities to provide a strong legal foundation.
Standards and Limits: Set maximum allowable levels for emissions or
discharges, often based on ambient conditions or available
technology.
Permitting and Compliance: Require permits for certain activities,
with specific conditions and ongoing monitoring to ensure
compliance.
Enforcement and Penalties: Define consequences for violations,
including fines, corrective actions, and both civil and criminal
penalties.
Reporting and Transparency: Promote accountability through
mandatory public disclosure of emissions and enforcement activities.
CORE COMPONENTS OF
ENVIRONMENTAL LEGISLATION
Environmental statutes are built around key components that ensure
effective regulation and accountability. These include:
Scope and Definitions: Clearly identify pollutants, sources, and
regulated entities to provide a strong legal foundation.
Standards and Limits: Set maximum allowable levels for emissions or
discharges, often based on ambient conditions or available
technology.
Permitting and Compliance: Require permits for certain activities,
with specific conditions and ongoing monitoring to ensure
compliance.
Enforcement and Penalties: Define consequences for violations,
including fines, corrective actions, and both civil and criminal
penalties.
Reporting and Transparency: Promote accountability through
mandatory public disclosure of emissions and enforcement activities.
PRINCIPAL TYPES OF ENVIRONMENTAL
LAWS
COMMAND-AND-CONTROL
REGULATIONS:
These statutes set specific limits or technology requirements (e.g., catalytic converters for
vehicles) and rely on inspections and penalties for enforcement. While straightforward, they
can be rigid and costly if not periodically updated.
Market-Based Instruments:
Policies such as emission taxes, tradable permits, and fee systems place a price on pollution,
incentivizing cost-effective reductions. For example, cap-and-trade under the EU Emissions
Trading System demonstrates how permit markets can cut CO₂ emissions by nearly 47% below
2005 levels.
Voluntary and Hybrid Approaches:
These include initiatives like eco-labeling, negotiated agreements, and carbon offsets that blend
regulatory support with voluntary industry commitments. Such approaches can reduce administrative
burdens and motivate proactive environmental efforts.
KEY NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL
FRAMEWORKS
National Environmental Policy Act (NEPA, USA)
NEPA’s requirement for Environmental Impact Statements introduced procedural
environmental rights, influencing over 100 nations’ environmental review laws.

U.S. Clean Air Act (1970, amended 1990)


The Clean Air Act established National Ambient Air Quality Standards and a market-based
Acid Rain Program, yielding benefit-cost ratios up to 90:1 through health and environmental
gains.

European Union Directives and Regulations


EU legislation, such as the Air Quality Directive and the Water Framework Directive, sets
binding targets across member states, with infringement proceedings for non-compliance.

International Environmental Agreements


Multilateral agreements—like the Montreal Protocol and Paris Agreement—set global or
regional targets, often including financial and technical assistance mechanisms for developing
countries.
Policy in Action: Impactful Environmental Legislation

Montreal Protocol (1987)


Phased out ozone-depleting substances, achieving a 98% reduction in CFC production by
2010 and generating health benefits valued at over US $1 trillion.

EU Emissions Trading System (2005– )


Demonstrated that tightening emissions caps and auctioning allowances can reduce
industrial CO₂ emissions by nearly 50% without stifling economic growth.

Philippines Clean Air Act (RA 8749, 1999)


Establishes emission standards and permits; a proposed carbon tax could raise PHP 100 billion
annually for health and infrastructure, based on a PHP 1,000/ton CO₂ levy.
Economic Analysis of Environmental Solutions

Economic analysis helps explain why environmental problems occur, often due to market
failures and externalities, and demonstrates how tools like taxes, tradable permits, and
subsidies can effectively address these issues. Empirical studies show that carbon taxes can
generate significant revenue with minimal impact on economic growth. Similarly, cap-and-
trade systems have proven effective in reducing emissions without harming GDP or
international competitiveness. While renewable energy subsidies have expanded clean energy
capacity, their impact on greenhouse gas (GHG) reductions varies.
Theoretical frameworks, including Pigouvian pricing, the Coase theorem, and the Porter
hypothesis, support these tools. Benefit-cost analyses ensure that these strategies result in
net societal benefits. Additionally, co-benefits such as health improvements and increased
productivity further enhance the value of these approaches. However, effective policy design
must account for factors such as equity, political acceptability, and coordination to achieve
sustainable outcomes.
Economic Theory and Market Failures

Market Failure and Externalities


Environmental degradation is a classic market failure: private markets ignore external costs of
pollution, leading to overproduction of harmful emissions compared to the social optimum.

Cost–Benefit Analysis
Rigorous cost–benefit analysis evaluates whether the benefits of regulation (e.g., reduced
health costs, ecosystem services) exceed compliance costs, guiding policymakers toward
economically efficient standards.
Economic Instruments for Environmental Policy

Pigouvian Taxes (Carbon Tax)


A Pigouvian tax charges polluters a fee equal to the marginal social cost of emissions,
aligning private incentives with societal welfare. Macroeconomic models show that carbon
taxes can raise considerable revenue—often recycled to lower distortionary taxes—with only
modest impacts on GDP growth.

Tradable Permits (Cap-and-Trade)


Cap-and-trade systems set a fixed emissions cap and let firms trade permits, yielding cost-
effective reductions where they are cheapest. U.S. proposals predict varying profit impacts
depending on permit allocation but generally show limited GDP effects.

Subsidies and Incentives


Renewable‐energy subsidies (tax credits, grants) have more than doubled federal support
since 2016, driving wind and solar capacity growth but with mixed evidence on actual GHG
reductions.
Economic Instruments for Environmental Policy

Pigouvian Taxes (Carbon Tax)


A Pigouvian tax charges polluters a fee equal to the marginal social cost of emissions,
aligning private incentives with societal welfare. Macroeconomic models show that carbon
taxes can raise considerable revenue—often recycled to lower distortionary taxes—with only
modest impacts on GDP growth.

Tradable Permits (Cap-and-Trade)


Cap-and-trade systems set a fixed emissions cap and let firms trade permits, yielding cost-
effective reductions where they are cheapest. U.S. proposals predict varying profit impacts
depending on permit allocation but generally show limited GDP effects.

Subsidies and Incentives


Renewable‐energy subsidies (tax credits, grants) have more than doubled federal support
since 2016, driving wind and solar capacity growth but with mixed evidence on actual GHG
reductions.
Empirical Evidence of Economic Impacts

Emission Taxes and Growth


Carbon taxes, when well-designed, can generate revenue and moderate emissions with small
economic drag, especially if revenues fund lower distortionary taxes.

Cap-and-Trade Outcomes
The EU Emissions Trading System cut power-sector and industrial CO₂ by around 10% in its
first phases without negative effects on employment or GDP. Similar U.S. models find that
profit impacts hinge on permit allocation methods.

Subsidies and Market Deployment


Federal renewable subsidies nearly doubled from USD 7.4 billion (2016) to USD 15.6 billion
(2022), accelerating clean-tech diffusion but yielding only modest short-term GHG declines in
some studies.
Innovation, Equity, and Just Transition

Porter Hypothesis and Innovation


The Porter hypothesis holds that stringent but flexible regulations spur clean-tech innovation,
offsetting compliance costs and potentially improving competitiveness.

Health and Productivity Co-Benefits


Improved air quality reduces respiratory and cardiovascular diseases, lowering healthcare
expenditure and increasing labor productivity—benefits that often dwarf control costs.

Just Transition Considerations


“Just transition” frameworks ensure that workers and communities dependent on carbon-
intensive sectors receive retraining and financial support, maintaining social equity and
political feasibility.
Conclusion

Effective environmental governance requires clear legal frameworks with defined standards,
enforcement, and transparency to ensure compliance and adaptability. Economic theory
identifies market failures as the root of environmental issues, emphasizing the role of cost–
benefit analysis. A combined approach using regulations and market-based tools—like taxes
and tradable permits—can provide both predictability and cost-effectiveness. Empirical data
shows emission taxes and cap-and-trade systems can reduce pollution with minimal economic
harm, while subsidies boost clean tech if properly targeted. Policies must also ensure equity
through measures like revenue recycling and just transition support, and remain adaptable
through mechanisms like standard reviews and digital monitoring. Overall, integrating strong
laws with economic tools fosters environmental protection, innovation, and societal well-
being.
THANK YOU
Ebrewan
References
Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44. https://doi.org/10.1086/466560
European Commission. (2023). The EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS). https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/ets_en
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. (2022). Climate change 2022: Mitigation of climate change. Cambridge University Press.
https://www.ipcc.ch/report/ar6/wg3/
International Monetary Fund. (2021). Fiscal policies for Paris Agreement alignment. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-
Papers/Issues/2021/07/06/Fiscal-Policies-for-Paris-Agreement-Alignment-461406
Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare (4th ed.). Macmillan.
Porter, M. E., & van der Linde, C. (1995). Toward a new conception of the environment–competitiveness relationship. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 9(4), 97–118. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.4.97
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2023). Overview of the Clean Air Act: Successes and challenges. https://www.epa.gov/clean-air-act-overview
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2024). Regulatory impact analysis: National Ambient Air Quality Standards. https://www.epa.gov/naaqs
Stockholm Environment Institute. (2020). Digitalization, remote sensing, and the future of environmental monitoring.
https://www.sei.org/publications/digitalization-remote-sensing/
World Bank & World Resources Institute. (2019). The atlas of sustainable development goals 2019: From World Development Indicators. World Bank
Publications.

You might also like