Lecture 1-2 EPMP673-Functions and Applications to Economic Problems
Lecture 1-2 EPMP673-Functions and Applications to Economic Problems
College of Education
School of Continuing and Distance Education
2014/2015 – 2016/2017
Nature of Mathematical Economics
• Mathematical economics is not a distinct
branch of economics
• It is an approach to economic analysis
– It allows economists to use mathematical language to
analyze economic relationships
– It also draws on mathematical theorems to aid
reasoning
– It employs mathematical techniques such as matrix
algebra, differential and integral calculus, etc.
Prof. Senadza 2
Mathematical vs. Nonmathematical
Economics
• There is no fundamental difference between
mathematical and non-mathematical economics
– mathematical economics uses symbols and equations
– but non-mathematical (literary) economics uses words
and sentences in the statement of economic
assumptions, relationships and conclusions
• Symbols are defined in words but they are more
convenient to use in deductive reasoning
• Equations are also more powerful for analyzing
situations involving three or more variables than
geometrical methods
Prof. Senadza 3
Mathematical vs. Nonmathematical
Economics
• The mathematical approach has the following
strengths
– The language is more concise and precise
– Draws on a wealth of mathematical theorems
– Allows us to explicitly state all assumptions
– Allows generalization of analysis to the n -variable
case
Prof. Senadza 4
Mathematical Economics vs. Econometrics
• The term “mathematical economics” is sometimes
confused with a related term called “econometrics”
– Econometrics deals mainly with the measurement of economic
relationships
– It uses empirical data and employs statistical methods of
estimation and hypothesis testing
• Mathematical economics on the other hand concerns itself
with the application of mathematics to theoretical aspects
of economic analysis
• The two are however complementary
– Econometrics depends on the mathematical formulation of
the economic relationship of concern
– Mathematical economics relies on econometrics for the
validation of the theoretical formulation
Prof. Senadza 5
Economic Models
• An economic model is a simplified theoretical
framework of how the economy behaves
• If the model is mathematical it will consist of a set of
equations relating a number of variables
• A variable is something whose magnitude can change,
i.e., it can take on different values
– Economic examples of variables: price, profit, revenue, cost,
national income, etc.
Prof. Senadza 6
Economic Models
• Endogenous Variables:
– those whose values are determined within the model
• Exogenous Variables
– those whose values are determined outside the model
• A variable that is endogenous to one model may be
exogenous in another model
• Example of economic model:
– Consumption function: C = a + bY
• C: endogenous
• Y: exogenous
Prof. Senadza 7
Economic Models
• Because their magnitudes can change, variables are
often represented by symbols
– Example: P, , R, C, Y, etc.
• But if we know the specific value then we freeze the
variable at that value
– Example: Y = 100 or P = 12
• An economic model can be solved to give the solution
values to a set of variables
– Example: equilibrium price or profit-maximizing level of output
Prof. Senadza 9
Economic Models
• Variables often have some fixed numbers or constants written in
front of them;
– for example: 2P
• A constant is a magnitude that does not change
• When the constant is joined to a variable it is called the
coefficient of the variable
• Coefficients are sometimes represented by symbols rather than
numbers for generality;
– for example: αP
• The symbol represents a given constant but since it has not been
assigned to any specific number it can take virtually any number
• So it is a constant that is variable and we refer to it as parametric
constant or simply parameter
Prof. Senadza 10
Economic Models
• We distinguish between 3 types of equations
– Definitional (identity) equations
– Behavioural equations
– Equilibrium conditions
• A definitional equation sets up an identity between 2
alternative expressions that have exactly the same
meaning
– ≡ TR – TC
Prof. Senadza 12
Economic Models
• A behavioural equation specifies the manner in
which a variable behaves in response to changes in
other variables
– Y = a + bX
• Y: endogenuos variable
• X: exogenous variable
• a: constant
• b: parameter & coefficient of exogenous variable X
• Equilibrium conditions are for cases where the model
involves the notion of equilibrium
– Qd = Q s
– S=I
Prof. Senadza 13
Functions
• Functions are very important in economics because of the
functional relationships that exist between and among many
(economic) variables.
• For example, in simple demand and supply functions, quantity
demanded/supplied depends on price; in a production
function output depends on the quantity of labour and capital
inputs used; cost and revenue functions depend on quantity
produced/ sold; consumption depend on disposable income;
etc.
• These are referred to as economic functions.
• One variable is a function of another if the first variable
depends upon the second.
Prof. Senadza Slide 12
Functions
• Suppose that the average weekly household expenditure on food
(C) depends on the average net household weekly income (Y).
• This functional relationship symbolically may be written as:
C = f(Y)
• Or more explicitly (assuming a linear relationship) as:
C = a + bY
– Where a and b are parameters
– If the values of the parameters a and b are known, then for any given value
of Y, we can find the value of C.
– Any value of Y chosen will produce one unique corresponding value C.
– In the above function, Y is called the independent (exogenous) variable and C
is called the dependent (endogenous) variable.
– There are several other examples of the functional dependence of variables
that we shall examine.
Prof. Senadza Slide 13
Figure 1. A Coordinate System
• Recall that a rectangular (or a
Cartesian) coordinate system is
obtained by first drawing two
perpendicular lines, called
coordinate axes.
• The two axes are respectively
the x-axis (or the horizontal axis)
and the y-axis (or the vertical
axis).
• The intersection point O is called
the origin.
• The coordinate system in Figure
1 is also called xy-plane.
• The coordinate axes separate
the plane into four quadrants,
which are numbered in Figure 1.
Prof. Senadza Slide 14
Figure 2. A Coordinate System
• Any point in the
coordinate plane
constitute an ordered
pair, written as (x, y); i.e.
x comes first and y comes
second.
• This implies that a y value
is associated with an x
value as shown in Figure
2.
• In Figure 2, we illustrate
two ordered pairs; P(3,4)
and Q(-5,-2).
• n 2 y a0 a1 a2 x 2 Quadratic function
• n 3 y a0 a1 x a2 x a3 x
2 3
Cubic function
• a) 5 x 2 y 4
x 2y 8
• b) 4 x 3 y 1
2x 9 y 4
x
b b 2 4ac 9
9 4(2)(5)
2
2a 2(2)
9 41
• x => x 0.649,3.851
4
Prof. Senadza Slide 50
Applications to Linear models in
Economics
Partial Market Equilibrium Analysis (Demand and Supply)
• We specify the relationship between quantity demanded and
price as
Qd f ( P)
• Assume the relationship is linear then we have
Qd a bP a, b 0
• Similarly, we specify the relationship between quantity
supplied and price as
Qs f ( P ) Qs c dP c, d 0
• a, b, c and d are constants.
Prof. Senadza Slide 51
Partial Market Equilibrium Analysis
(Demand and Supply)
• Note that the demand equation could be written with price
as the subject, so that
a 1
Q a bP P Q P Q P f (Q)
b b
where a 1
b and b
• Similarly, for the supply function
P h(Q ) P Q
c d , 1d
• Thus Q=f(P) and P=f(Q) are inverses of each other.
Prof. Senadza Slide 52
Finding Equilibrium Quantity and Price
Algebraically
• Equilibrium graphically is where demand and supply curves
intersect.
• Equilibrium algebraically means Qd = Qs, thus, equating the
demand function to the supply function,
Qd a bP
Qs c dP
a bP c dP P (b d ) a c
ac
P e
bd
bd 0
Prof. Senadza Slide 53
Finding Equilibrium Quantity and Price
Algebraically
• Equilibrium quantity is obtained by substituting P in
demand or supply equation.
• Using demand,
ac
Q a b
e
bd
a(b d ) b(a c)
Q
e
bd
ad bc
Q e
b d 0; ad bc
bd
Prof. Senadza Slide 54
Finding Equilibrium Quantity and Price
Algebraically
• Note that we could have used the technique for solving
simultaneous equations to determine the values of P and Q.
Q a bP..................(1)
Q c dP................(2)
(1) (2) 0 ( a bP) (c dP)
0 ( a c) P(b d ) P(b d ) a c
ac
P
bd
• Then substitute P into (1) or (2) to obtain Q.
Prof. Senadza Slide 55
Solving for equilibrium Quantity and
Price algebraically
• Example: Given the following demand and supply functions,
find the equilibrium price and quantity.
Qd 25 1 P
2
Qs 50 2 P
• Solution: In equilibrium, Qd = Qs.
25 1 P 50 2 P 5 P 75 P 30
2 2
• Substitute P=30 in Demand (or supply) equation.
Q 25 1 P Q 25 1 (30) Q 10
2 2
• P e
4 4 2
4(1)(5) => P
e 46
=> P e
1,5
2(1) 2
• y a 0 a1 x1 a 2 x12 b1 x 2 b2 x 22 Quadratic
Prof. Senadza Slide 70
Functions of Two or More
Independent Variables
• For example, we know that the demand for a good depends
not only on the price of the good in question but on the
price of a related good, so that we can write
Qd 1 f ( P1 , P2 ) Qd 1 a 0 a1 P1 a 2 P2
• which is a linear function.
• It is possible to have quadratic or other forms of functions of
two or more variables.
• Similarly, output is usually written as a function of two
variables, capital and labour
• Q = f (K, L) = A L
K
• In market 2,
o 1 P1 2 P2 o 1 P1 2 P2
( o o ) ( 1 1 ) P1 2 2 P2 0.......... .......... .( 2)