Cummins 1996
Cummins 1996
O~NCS
EI.ShaClER Journal of Public Economics62 (1996) 237-273
Abstract
We use firm-level panel data to explore the extent to which fixed investment
responds to tax reforms in t4 OECD countries. Previous studies have often found
that investment does not respond to changes in the marginal cost of investment. We
identify some of the factors responsible for this finding, and employ an estimation
procedure that sidesteps the most important of them. In so doing, we find evidence
of statistically and economically significant investment responses to tax changes in 12
of the 14 countries.
1. Introduction
of the effects of various tax parameters on firms" user costs of capital have
been prepared and then compared across countries (for the first such study,
see King and Fullerton, 1984; most recently, see OECD. 1991). empirical
evidence has not been overwhelmingly supportive of significant effects of tax
policy on investment (see, for example, the review in Chirinko, 1993).
Neoclassical models of investment that rely on the user cost of capital
model (see Jorgenson, 1963; and the application to tax policy in Hall and
Jorgenson, 1967) or q models (see. for example, Tobin, 1969; Hayashi,
1982; Summers. 1981) generally have little explanatory power for invest-
ment. Estimated adjustment costs are implausibly large, rendering any
inference about the effects of changes in market valuation or tax parameters
on investment difficult at best. Indeed. the user cost of capital and q
approaches usually fail to explain investment as well as simple ad hoc
accelerator models (see, for example, Clark, 1979. 1993: Bernanke et al.,
1988; Oliner et al., 1995), and measures of outpu*,, corporate cash flow, or
profitability generally improve the fit of empirical investment models
significantly, l The weight of the existing evidence appears to lean toward the
interpretation that tax variables have little effect upon firm investment.
In this paper we attempt to measure the effects of tax reforms on business
investment using an extension of the tax-adjusted q model. In so doing we
improve upon existing approaches by using tax reforms to better identify
determinants of investment decisions. In particular, we argue that tax
reforms are natural experiments for measuring the responsiveness of
investment to fundamentals affecting the net return to investing, since they
represent discrete events with a large and discernible effect on the return to
investment.
This approach builds on that in our earlier paper (Cummins et al., 1994)
in which we analyze models of business fixed investment for US firms.
There. the estimated effects of neoclassical fundamental,, on investment
were more statistically and economically significant than those generally
found in earlier studies, and the estimates implied reasonable adjustment
costs in both the tax-adjusted q and user cost of capital specifications. For
the United States. we found that following each major tax reform since
1962, the cross-section pattern of investment changed significantly. In
addition, our estimates of structural parameters were economically similar
across different specifications of the same basic structural model over a
36-year period. 2 As discussed below, we find similar patterns in our
IThe often poor empirical performanceof neoclassical models has led some researchers to
abandon the assumptionsof reversible investment and convex adjustment costs used in testing
neoclassical models in favor of approaches based on "irreversible" investment. Scc the
discussions and reviewsof studies in Dixit and Pindvck (1994) and ttubbard (1994).
"Our results have since been corroborated using plant-level data by Cabellero et a[. (1995).
J.G. C~tmmins et al. / Journal o f Public Economits 62 (1~36) 237-273 2.~)
exploration of tax reforms outside the United States. The estimated effects
of fundamentals of the neoclassical model are economically significant and
plausible, and are relatively similar across most of the countries we study.
This suggests that the stylized fact that investment does not respond to tax
changes affecting the net return to investing is incorrect for the sample of
firms we study.
To pursue this, we employ a rich firm-level panel dataset on tax reforms
in 14 countries to study the investment decisions of over 3000 firms. We rely
on firm-level panel data instead of aggregate time-series data because they
allow us to overcome several important problems that have hampered
previous attempts to isolate tax effects. First, the time-series variation in
investment incentives is clearly not exogenous. Governments tend to
institute investment incentives when aggregate investment is perceived to be
"low' and remove them when aggregate investment is perceived to be ~high'.
Second, since corporate tax parameters are changed often, it is difficult to
judge what a firm's expected tax treatment is in any given year. Finally, if
the stock market value of the firm is noisy, it may be hard to isolate tax
effects if movements of these are dominated by noise from other sources.
We rely on a cross-sectional variation in tax parameters just following tax
reforms in order to overcome these estimation problems.
T h e paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the model we
estimate. Section 3 reports estimation results using standard estimation
techniques. Section 4 discusses the problems that may lead to bias in the
results reported in Section 3, and then describes our two proposed alter-
native estimation procedures. Section 5 reports the results we obtain using
these procedures. Section 6 concludes.
Assuming convex adjustment costs, there are four standard ways to obtain
empirical investment models in the neoclassical approach. Each begins with
the firm maximizing its net pr,;~cnt value. The first-order conditions lead to
a Euler equation describing the period-to-period optimal path of invest-
meat. Abel and Blanchard (1986) solve the difference equation which
relates investment to its expected current and future marginal revenue
products. Alternatively. the Euler equation itself may be estimated (see, for
example, Hubbard and Kashyap, 1992; Bond and Meghir, t994). As in
Auerbach (1983), investment can be expressed in terms of current and
future values of the user cost of capital, and, under some conditions,
expressed in terms of average q. This final approach was first suggested by
Tobin (1969), with the necessary conditions supplied by Hayashi (1982). We
relate the q model of investment to the approach discussed below. Since the
240 J.G. Cummins et al. I Journal o f Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
where I and K are investment and the capital stock, respectively; i and t are
the firm and time indexes, respectively; /z is a firm-specific constant; Q is
the tax-adjusted value of Tobin's q (see the derivation in Appendix A); and
e is the error term. That is,
q, , - g , 0 - r ~ , )
Q'.' = (1 - ~',) ' (2)
where r is the corporate tax rate, p is the price of capital goods relative to
output, and F is the present value of tax savings from depreciation
allowances and other investment incentives. F~r example, with an invest-
m e n t tax credit (ITC) at rate k, F is
3. Standard approach
STable 3 details the depreciationand inventoryvaluat/on rules for the tax year 1992. For a
more completede.~criptionof the changesin theserulesover the sampleperiod,see Appendix
B.
Table t to
Statutory maximum marginal colporate income tax rates
Couotr}, 1981 1982 ,1983 , ,1984 1985 198~ 1987 1988 1999 199t1 1991 19~2
Australia ~ 0.46 0.46 0.46, 0.46 0.46 0,49 11.49 0.39 1L39 0.39 0,39 11.39
Belgium" 0,48 0.45 0.45 Q.45 (;.45 0.45 11.43 0.43 11.43 l).41 O.39 I).39 '
Canada ''a I.I.483 0.483 0.472 Q.46 0.483 0,483 0,464 0,391 I).391 O.391 0,391 11.391
Canada ¢'a 0,42 11.42 11.4f 0,411 0,42 0,42 0,391 0.371 0.361 0.350 0,340 0.340
Denmark 0,40 0,40 11.40 0.40 0.50 0.50 0.511 0.50 0.5(I 0.411 0.38 0,38
France ~ 0,50 0,5d 0,50 0,50 0.50 0,45 0,45 0.42 11.39 11.37 0.34 0~34 ~'
Germany I 0.56 0.56 0,56 0,56 0,56 0,56 0,fU 0,56 0,56 0.50 0.519 0.519
Ireland s 0,45 0.50 0.511 0,50 0.50 0,50 0,50 0,47 0.43 Q,43 0.40 11.4o
Italy' ,.h 0.363 0.413 0.413 0,464 0,464 0.4fi4 0.464 0,464 0,464 0,464 0,478 O.552 '
lapan 0.42 0.42 0,42 0.433 0.433 0,433 0,42 11.42 0,40 0,375 0,384 0.384 "x
Nether|ands 0.48 0.48 11.48 11.43 0,43 0.42 0.42 0.42 0,35 0,39 11,35 035
New Zealand 0,45 0.45 0.45 0.45 0,45 0.48 0,4,q 0.28 0.33 0.33 0,33 0.33
Norway i 0.5(~ 0.51}8 11,5118 0,508 ().50ff 0,508 0,50g 0.508 1),508 0.508 11.508 028
Spain 0.33 0.33 0.35 0.35 11,35 11.35 1),35 0,35 tL35 {).35 0.35 11,35
Sweden ~ 0.58 0.58 0,58 0.52 11.52 0.52 0.52 0,52 11.52 11.40 0,30 0.30 ~,~
Swhzerland k 0.098 I).1198 0.098 0.01J8 0.098 0,098 11.098 0.098 0.098 0.098 0.098 0,098
UK ~ 11.52 0.52 0.52 0.45 0.40 0,35 0,35 ft,35 0.35 0,34 0,33 11.33
US ~ 0.46 .0.46 ...... 0.46 , , 0.46 0.46 0.46 tl,40 0,34 0.34 11.34 0.34 11.34 ~
Notes;
"Undistributed profits were taxed al the rate of 0.50 until an imputation system came into operation in July 1987.
~'Excess profils surtax at the rate of 0.04 applied until 1982,
Additional corporate income tax levied by state and/or municipa~ government which is rebated or deductible at the federal level
'~The corporate income tax rates in the third row are the general rates. The rates in the fourth row are those for manufacturir~g and processing income.
A split-rate system, which applied a higher tax rate of 0.42 to distributed profits, was in effect from 1989 until 1992.
t Distributed profits taxed at n lower rate of 0.36~
e Corporate income tax is levied at a lower rate of 0.10 on manufacturing films,
Distributed profits were taxed at a 0.t0 lower rate until 1988. In 1989, distributed profits were taxed at a 0.05 lower rate, The split-rate system was permanently
abolished in 191~.
' Additional corporate income taxes were levied at munieipa} love} and for a lax equafizatior, fund', resulting in a combined rate of 0.23 which was mJl deductible
front the federal rate of 0,278, Effective 1992. th~ federal corporale income ~.;~xwas abolished, the municipal rate was lowered to 0.11, and the 'lax equalizalion fuud' ~I
rate was increased tO 0.17. %
Additional corpoYate income tax levied at municipal level, which was deductible al federal level, was abolished in 1985.
Federal, cantonal and municipal corporate income taxes, which are typically parti~dly deductible against o n e anolher, are levied at graduated rates based on tile
proportion of taxable profits to equity capital, Top federal rate reported.
tThe rate for 1990 was retroactively changed from 0,35.
Table 2
Rates of investment incentives"
Country 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992
Australia" 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0.18 0 0 0 11 0 0 0 ""
Belgium' 11.05 0.(15 0.05 0,05 0,05 0,05 0.05 0.05 0.05 004 0.03 0
Canada a 0.07 0,07 0.07 0.07 0.117 0.07 0.115 0.03 0 0 13 0
Denmark" 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (I 0 0
France" 0,10 0.15 0 (I 0 O 0 0 11 0 0 0
Germany 0 0 0 (I 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 ~"
lrehmd 0 0 0 0 I) 0 0 0 11 0 11 0
Italy 0 0 tl 0 1) (I 0 0 0 0 l) 0 '~
Japan 0 0 0 (1 11 (I 0 0 0 0 11 0 "-,
Netherlands t 0.12 0.12 0.12 11.125 0.125 0.125 0.125 0 0 0 0 0 ~-
New Zeahmd 11 0 (I 0 0 0 11 0 0 0 0 0 =::
Norway 11 0 0 0 0 0 0 1) 0 (] 0 0
Spain ~: 0.15 0.15 11.15 (1.15 0,15 (I,15 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.05
Sweden t, 0,10 0.10 0.10 11 0 0 (1 0 0 0 0 0 ~'=
Switzerla,d 0 0 (I 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 (I
IJK (I 0 0 0 0 0 (1 0 0 0 () 0 ~
US d 0.1 0.08 11,08 0.08 l),08 0.08 0 I) 0 0 0 0
Notes:
" All countries ill the sltmple have investmcm incentives for specilit: regions,or industries, for certain types of business lixed investment, or fi)r
research and development, which are not reported, 3"
" Investment incentive was it deduction.
• Investment incentive was a deduction. Before 1982, the incentive was an inveslnlent reserve.
d Investment incentive was an ITC. In Canada, rcginnal and some asset ITCs were retained at reduced rates after 1988. ~
• A limited investment reserve is available. See footnote h below for a description.
t Investment incentive wits an r r c (called "WI R'). In 1984, the various W l R rates were combined into one uniform rate: before 1984 the rate
reporled is that for mtmt fixed assets. Beginning in 19911, an investment deduction is awtilable at degressive rates ranging from 0.18 to 0.02 ti)r
relatively small.scale investment: no deductiolr is allowed after the cut-off tl~tal is reached. to
~ Investment incentive is an ITC. In 1985 a statutory rate for fixed assets wits instituted; before 1985 the rate reported is that for the typical .~.
iflvestmenl grant.
i, lnvestnlenl incentive was ill| investment allowance. Until 1990, all illVe~luleal reserve program wits also available, It allowed companies to
set aside and deduct, at their own discreliou, up to 50% of their pre-lax profits Ik~r future investments fit a countereyclieal fund. The benclit of
the fund was that it could he used for inunediatc depreciation of new assets acquired.
Table 3
D e p r e c i a t i o n and i n v e n t o r y valuation rules (1992)
Country Depreciation Accelerated Asset Inventory
method ~ depreciation revaluation valuation method
available" permitted (ta~ purposes) ~ .~
Equipment Structures
Auslralia DB. SL SL no no AC, FIFO, SC. SI
Belgium DB. SL DB, SL yes yes AC, FIFO, LIFO
Canada DB DB no no AC. FIFO, SI ~'
Denmark DB SL no yes AC, FIFO, LIFO
France ~ DB, SL DB. SL yes limited AC. FIFO. LIFO. SC
Germany d DB, St, DB, SL yes no AC,LIFO, SI ....
Ireland DB. SL SL no yes AC, FIFO
Italy SL SL yes limited AC, FIFO. LiFO
Japan DB, SL DB, SL yes no AC. FIFO. LIFO, SI
Netherlands DB, SL DB, SL yes yes AC. FIFO. LIFO
New Zealand DB SL no yes AC. FIFO ,~
Norway' DB DB no yes FIFO
Spain DB, SL SL yes no AC. FIFO ~.
Sweden DB, SL SL no yes FIFO ~
Switzerland DB, SL DB. SL yes no AC, FIFO
UK DB. SL SL no yes AC. FIFO
USA DB SL yes no AC. FIFO, LIFO
Notes: ~'
DB denotes Ifie decJining balance method.
SL denotes the straight llne method, t.~
A C denotes the average cost method. "~,~
FIFO denotes the first-in-first-out method.
LIFO denotes the last-in-first-out method.
SC denotes the standard cost method.
Sl denotes the specific identification method.
Statutory depreciation and inventory valuation methods are reported, or when the tax authority allows any 'appropriate' method, the methods generally used are
reported. When the authority does not specify appropriate melfiods, those generally accepted are reported.
Accelerated depreciation is for specific regions or industries, and for certain types of assets. Exact rules vary widely by country.
LIFO acceptable when used in consolidatod financial reporting.
,s As of assessment year ll)gl), LIFO was permil[ed.
As of assessment year 1992, accelerated depreciation was abolished.
Table 4
Means and medians of sample variables
Country Value Q I /K ~ Y/K OI /K CF/K RE/ K 1)/01
Australia 402.059 2.553 0.205 0.113 3,314 (I.241 0,241 0A)55 0.261 .~
( 130.1411) (1.378) (0.128) (0.098) (2,128) (0.2t8) (0.226) O.057) (0.2531
Belgium 369,1H11 1,505 t),29(t 0.243 5,976 0.248 (1,476 11.078 0.232
(54.706) (0.615) (0.223) (1t.187) (4.699) (0,192) (0.354) 0,0591 (It.IS3) ~
Canada 422,9111 2.123 0.216 0.124 3.304 0.2111 0,2tt5 !1.(t52 (), 125 g
1132.7251 (0.8981 (0.1421 (O,IL~) (1,6791 (0.144) (t1,163)
Denmark 98.585 I. 166 11.236 0.151 4.897 0.211 0,334 0,I18 (L133
(4(I,567) (1).64(1) ( O. 195 ) (0.1431 (4. I 71 ) (0.169 ) 10.2691 ().tP)2) (0. I t 4)
France 349.033 2.3tXl (),304 ().209 7,662 0,429 0,449 0.156 0.15g
( 126.673 ) ( I. 1781 10.2591 (0.186) (6,4~t) (11,330) (0,347) {),0~6 ) (0. l I H) ~.
Germany 037.884 2,219 0,324 0.254 6.099 0,238 0.388 0.051 11,213 g,.
(251.688) ((1.t.169) (0,273) ((),237) (5.050) (0.1751 (0,351) 0.032 ) (0.17./) ~-
Italy 321,14(1 1,846 (I.272 0.182 4,27(I t).321 (I.424 ILII3 11.222 _~
(109.455) (0.856) (11,204) (0,164) (3.285) (O,21h")) 10.2911 0,056) (11,1791
Japan 2174,025 5.5111 0.248 0,150 5.489 0,326 0,301 0.095 0.154
(889.983) (4.1001 (0.211 ) (l). 143) (4.417) (11,2311) ((t,252} 0.(t59 ) (0.13o) '~'
Netherlands 718.493 1.292 0.239 11.167 6.187 1),335 11.377 0.130 11,222
( 102,748,) (0,~12) ((t. 189 ) ~tl. | 50) (4,342) (0,232) ((I. ~14) 11.(~)4) (0.232) ~-,~
Norway 205.992 1.579 0.263 0.139 3,892 0.199 11.177 It.(X)9 O, I 13
(72.7(11) (1).633) ((I.1761 (g.126) (2.99(I) (0.164) ((I.1621 , t,e" 8 ) 1o.o9t)
Spain 315,376 1.645 0.148 (I, 110 3.233 0.229 0,234 t1,o52 0.217
(122.587) (0.793) (O.(Igo) IlL [ l I) ( 1.747 ) 10.140) (0.1771 (0.(t29) (0.189) _~
Sweden 328.292 0,835 tt.242 (I, 128 4.893 0.352 0.293 0,(197 o.184 ~.
(128.254) (0,273) (0.177) (11.123) (4.023) (0.247) ((1,222) 10.t149) (0.154)
UK 672.885 1,967 0.249 O. 125 5,702 0.423 0.428 (I.Igl 0,260
1123.282) (0.769) (0.171) (0.114) (4.293) (8,311 ) (0.317) (0.1201 (0,244) ,'~
US 050,524 3,222 0.251 0.171 5,583 0.342 0.339 0.1211 0,12(1
(126,444) (t,408) (0.168) (0,145) (4 015) (0,239) (0.257) (0.080) (0.033)
Noles:
Medians are in paremheses bctr , the means.
~v~lU~: is the real market value ul the firm at the ¢nd-of-ilscal-ycar converted to US dollars usir,g the end-of-fiscal-year exchange rat,:,
The ratio of investment to beginning-of-period capital stock is I/K.
The variable 8 is the rate of depreciation,
The ratio of sales to beginning-of.period capital stock is F/K,
The ratio of operating income In beginning.of-period capital stock is OI/K.
The ratio of cash flow to bcginr'ng-of-pcriod capital stock is CF/K.
The ratio of retained earnings to beginning-of.peri(xl capital stock is RE/K.
The ratio of dividends to b~ginniag-of-puriud operating income is D/OL
246 J.G. Cummins et ~d. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
larger, ceteris pafibus. This elfect is most distinct in evaluating the value of
Japanese firms.
Median values of tax-adjusted q range from a low of 0.273 (mean 0.835)
for Sweden to a high of 4.10 (mean 5.50) for Japan. Note that the
tax-adjusted q is the shadow value of capital less its acquisition cost. As
such, it is comparable to q - 1 rather than q. The magnitudes appear
reasonable, with the exception of those for Japan, in which estimated q
values are large relative to those in previous studies.~ However, few
comparisons are available to assess these numbers in countries other than
Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
T h e values of the ratio of investment to beginning-of-period capital stock
median and mean are reported in column 3. The former indicate a range of
per year investment of about 8 % - 2 7 % of the capital stock; the latter of
about 1 5 % - 3 2 % ot the capital stock. The depreciation rates are reported in
column 4.
In the columns 5 - 9 of Table 4, we report information on five variables on
firm characteristics and performance. The median and mean ratios of cash
flow to the beginning-of-period capital stock are larger in most countries
than the ratio of operating income to beginning-of-period capital stock. The
ratio of retained earnings to beginning-of-period capital stock is reported in
column 8. The ratio is highest in Denmark, France, the Netherlands, the
United Kingdom, and the United States. The ratio of dividends to begin-
ning-of-period operating income is reported in the final column. Firms in
most all countries appear to pay out a larger share of their earnings than
those in the United States. This finding is somewhat deceptive, however,
since the sample of firms for the United States contains a much larger
proportion of (often smaller and younger) firms that pay no dividends.
Table 5 provides four different sets of estimates of the basic Q model
using panel data for the 14 countries in our sample. In the first row. ordinary
least squares (OLS) is used to estimate Eq. (1), after first differencing the
model to remove firm-specific fixed effects and adding year d u m m y vari-
ables. T h e second row adds the first difference of once-lagged cash flow, CF.
relative to the capital stock, K (i.e. CF,., t / K i . , _ z - C F ~ . , , / K , . , s) as a
regressor to the specification in the first row. The third row provides the
generalized method of m o m e n t s (GMM) estimates of the specification in the
first row. with the instrument set (levels of the second and third lags of Q,
I / K , and C F / K ) reported below the row. Similarly, the fourth row provides
"~Fhevalues of tax-adjusted q do not include the market value of land in the calculationof the
replacement cost of the capital stock because the Global Vantage datasct does not separately
report the book value of land for non-financialcorporations. As a result, the tax-adjusted q for
Japanese firms is larger than in comparable studies (see, for example. Hoshi and Kashyap,
1990).
T a b l e ,5
,...,
rl'ax-adjusled q m o d e l illVt/S[llll~ll| Ctluatiolls: S t a n d a r d a p p r o a c h
Coumry
A,US BI!L CAN DNK IRA (iER ITA JPN NLD NOR SPN SWE UK LISA
OLS ~"
Q,, 11,1152 11.117}t I1.11.I~1 11.124 11.1167 (I,II3! II,I)f17 11.1117 1l.I)3fi 0,1143 11.1134 ILl07 t).05S I).031) ~-.
((I.I)1151 (0.1116) (11.1)1)3) 111.0161 (O.()11S) (11.1)1),3) Ill.Ill l) (ll,ll(12) 11),007) (IL(II3 } Ill.0101 (IL(Ilgl (O,[X)3) (11,()111) :.,,.
11.11~12 I)r(197 I1.1111 I1.1~11 11.137 11.1156 11.1167 O.(158 IL1))19 11.195 0.174 11,148 11.119U I).1173 ".
1(.1157 111177 11.1143 (I,213 1(.1177 0.032 11.1178 1),(118 11.031 I).1)29 0.1138 11.112 0.1~311 11.1)34
(t),(ltl'/I (11.1117) 1(I.I)114) (11.112.]) 10,111191 (0 ()l)l~) (11.111.;.) (O,(X)2) {II.I)11S) 111.1)15) (0.1113) 111.1)23) (I).OI).l) (11.1)111) ~,
(UI-/K , r i -11. t82 11.11tl2 (I.Ilf, N 11.117t1 -11.179 (I.I)~B 0.11611 11.1112 -tl.I)tJ6 11.519 4).1!41 11.136 -11.1152 11.1)1t3
#' (0.11771 (O.IITLI) (11.11421 (l).(INfi) (11.1172) (11.1155) (11.1181 (IL(M3) (t1.11131 10,141) (1t.165) 111.162) ( 11.1134) fILl)117) ~,~
111N4 IL lotl o. 114 I1. INII It lgLJ I).(~'12 0.1178 I).(g~6 11.1172 I1,164 O. 161 11.144 I1.114 11.1188
(iMM ~
I),Ofil) IL 1113 O,1141 I)+IIM I),l)h5 I).O95 1).(151 ILI)]t/ ll.(Ibtt OJ)fi9 (I,(M4 ILI)51 11.1162 I).IMN
(I).IIIL)) ( I),O.|4 ) (11.111191 (l) IlN5) lOAM]) (l).lgil) [I).(ll N) IILI)1)8 ) (0.1144) ((1.1131 ) (11.028) (11.1!47) 111.1113) (O.(K)61
11.293 11.3114 ll.g.15 11.131 11.21)7 11.731 1.67 1.34 1.94 2.23 11.7611 1.15 I.h4 7.114
p- ~-'altl~" I).tlqN I).gIJN I}975 l).gtJlJ (I.giJt) 11.9~tI I).N92 O.IJ31 0.857 O.816 I).98(1 O.9511 II.S~/0, I).218 ~.
Q,, 0.1)34 I1.1JU6 ILIM4 II.I)~Y 11.07-1 (I. Ilg I1.1($1} 1l.ll2tl I).O-Ih 0.113~) ILI)45 O.II~tJ 11.(146 ILIM2
Ill.Ill4) 111.11411 Ill.ill l) OLI)gII) (ll.l)3fi) III.IM2 } Ill.OIq) 111.1)117) 111.11311 1(I.II331 (11.11291 111.11781 (11.11131 (ILI)1~) t~
I('/'/K l, , t 11.1)83 11.1~5 11.1115 IL164 (I.IISl~ I1.11t)O 11.1164 11.24g 11.188 11.488 11.316 I).1115 (I,233 IL177
111.2371 111.1651 111.11511) |11.1691 (O. l l l ) Ill. Ill4 ) (l}. IbY) (ll.(Ig4) II). 193) (1).203) 111.2631 (IL4131 (0.065) 111.01t) )
~1 11,51!4 1.85 1.34 11.253 O.2(~2 11.661 I.t~5 I.fitl 1.88 1.73 tl.h86 [. 18 1.115 2:;,1 !'a
p- ~.'ahle I1,~J73 ().7~3 (I.1~55 ().tllJ3 11.992 (I.I156 II.NI)11 ((.gl)9 I).758 I).7195 ((,IJS.~, II.Ngl (L~;~)2 I1.1M3 i~
IVs Q,, ~, ~; (ILK),, ~ ~; (CF/K),, :., ,
Sourct,; Aulhors' calculaliolts usillg (ilnbal Vantage data. ]'he dttpentlcnl variable is I,.,IK,, i. The ratio of cash 1low to bL,ginning-of-p¢[iod capital sll~ck is ( ' F / K
Variables are delink, d ill Ihe Itqgl. Standard e m i r s ill ¢l~cfticJ¢lll~;, in parcnlhttscs, art: ¢Oll|plllgd (fort| a hL,l¢lrt~kt2dasli¢-¢oxlsislclll colrlclalion matrix. "l'h¢ regtcssio|ls a[c
baszd on it differenced vvrsioa ~1( Eq. (I) ;is described in tile Icxl. Year dummy wmablcs are included bul not rept~rted.
248 J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
and the United States the coefficient estimates are statistically significant,
T h e point estimates for Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States
are similar to those reported in previous studies using similar specifications,
As with the basic Q model, overidentifying restrictions are not rejected for
any country. Two conclusions are suggested by the estithates in Table 5,
First, estimates on Q are usually statistically significant and qualitatively
similar across countries, but imply large adjustment costs. Second, invest-
m e n t displays an excess sensitivity to cash flow (at least for the generally
larger firms in our sample) in only a subset of countries.
~The first technique that follows was also used to study US panel data in Cummins et aL
(1994), where results across many different US lax reforms were compared. Other stud,s in
the same spirit include Cumminsand Hasseu (1992) and Auerbnch and Hassctl (1991). Both of
these focused on estimating the response of US firmsto shocks to their user costs caused by the
Tax Reform Act of 1986.
250 J_G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics (~2 (1996) 237-273
First, we consider a modified version of Eq. (1) which states that the
d e v i a t i o n of true ( l / K ) from the value linearly p r e d i c t a b l e using i n f o r m a t i o n
a v a i l a b l e at time t - 1 is
(I,.,/K .... )-P,., i(1,.,/K,.r ~ ) = ( Q t . , - P , . , _ i Q , . , ) 3 " + e , . , , (4)
the whole panel of data. In the second stage, we use the cross-section to
estimate the adjustment cost parameter, which is explicitly assumed identi-
cal across firms. Hence. we estimate the following model for each country-
tax-reform year:
where the variables with caret marks are firm-specific projections using
period t - 2 information. To focus on the tax surprise we set Q equal to the
variable Q T which contains twice-lagged values of non-tax variables and
C O n l e m p o r a n e o t t s values of the tax parameters:
q,.,_,_-P,_:(1-Fi.,)
Q,., = QL., - (I - 7 , ) (7)
In the years following substantial changes in the tax code. 3' should be of
the expected sign and precisely estimated if the identifying assumptions are
correct. In periods in which there were no changes in the tax code, 3' should
be imprecisely estimated, and, to the extent that we are measuring the
structural variable with significant errors, biased toward zero. In periods in
which there were changes that were part of a previous tax reform (such as
the reduction in the US corporate tax rate from 40% in 1987 to 34% in
1988). the value of 3, depends on whether linear projection techniques
adequately describe firms" expectations following an initial tax reform. If
they do adequately capture expectations. 3' is unidentified. ~
Since the second-stage estimation is simply OLS, in order to construct this
estimator, we made the additional identifying assumption that around tax
reforms we can observe Q used by firms when formulating their investment
decisions. In principle, this includes the non-tax elements as well. To be
especially cautious about the introduction of contemporaneous values of the
non-tax components of Q. and to highlight the variation due to tax changes.
we assume that the firm's expected value for each non-tax component of Q
is equal to that variable's value at the beginning of the previous period. That
is. we construct Q, by combining the tax components for period t and the
non-tax components for period t - 2. it is this variable that we forecast in
the first stage, and this variable that we use to construct the "surprise'. Tax
information is the only information dated ahead of year t - 2 that is included
on the right-hand side of the second-stage regression. For example, the
expected interest rate in 1987 is assumed to be the year-end rate for 1985.
Violation of the assumption concerning the observability of Q would
~The identification occurs only when we encounter a period in which the firm observes a
change in Q that cannot be predicted will' the informationin it, (as. for example, duringa tax
reform). If the projection m~asures Q perfectly, then ~" wouM be unidentified given the
definilion of 0 in Eq. (5).
252 J.G. Cummins et aL / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
introduce into the second-stage regression the deviation of "true" .Q from the
assumed Q. That is, because of the assumptions about the e,~n-tax part of
Q, the error term in Eq. (4) includes the term y Q N , , where QN, represents
the contemporaneous non-tax information in Q,. If positive shocks to a
firm's Q N , are closely correlated with the cross-section variation in the tax
variables, then the estimate of 3' may be upwardly biased.
The second approach we consider is based on the same basic intuition that
tax variables may allow us to measure Q more precisely around tax reforms.
If contemporaneous tar. fundamentals explain an especially large share of
the "true' variation in Q around tax reforms, then an alternative approach is
to use these as instrumental variables to overcome the measurement error
problem. In the next section we also present estimates based on this insight.
If our description of the source of the very low coefficients reported in the
previous section is correct, then both of these approaches should provide
significantly larger estimates of y.
h is important to define the tax experiments carefully. In the United
States, for example, the 'Fax Reform Act of 1986 was passed late in that
year, and it is unclear whether investment decisions made in 1986 antici-
pated these changes. To avoid such confounding timing problems we
sidestep years in which reforms occur. Using this example, we estimate a
first-stage projection equation for each firm, using data available for that
firm through 1985 and then construct forecasts for 1987, the first post-reform
year? We pay the same attention to timing for each tax change we study,
forecasting post-reform investment with ;nformation available in the year
prior to the reform, and examining effects of changes in the tax-adjusted q
on investment in the first post-reform year.
5. I. O v e r v i e w
"Pagan (1984) has shownthat the second-stageparameterestimates and their standard errors
are consistent and asymptoticallyefficient, respectively, when the second-stage regressorsare
innovations. We require numerous assumptionsto map our problem to that result, and, for
generality, we would prefer maximum likelihood. The likelihood function [or this two-stage
estimator is nnt difficult to write down. but estimation would be extremely cumbersome
because o[ the large number of nuisance parameters.
J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (trY36) 237-273 253
p r o v i d e s t h e b e s t e x p e r i m e n t o f t a x r e f o r m a n d p r e s e n t results o n l y f o r t h a t
y e a r . TM
In s e v e r a l o f t h e c o u n t r i e s w e s t u d y t h e r e w e r e several c h a n g e s in t h e
c o r p o r a t e t a x c o d e d u r i n g t h e s a m p l e p e r i o d . A s will b e c l e a r b e l o w , w h e r e
w e d e s c r i b e t h e r e f o r m s we s t u d y f o r e a c h c o u n t r y , we c o n s i d e r t w o p r i m a r y
f a c t o r s w h e n c h o o s i n g t h e ' b e s t ' e x p e r i m e n t f o r e a c h c o u n t r y . First, w e
f o c u s o n l a r g e c h a n g e s in t h e t a x c o d e , b e c a u s e t h e s h o c k s to Q d r i v e n b y
t a x e s s h o u l d b e as l a r g e as possible in o r d e r to m a x i m i z e t h e p o w e r o f tile
a p p r o a c h e s . S e c o n d l y . t h e a s s u m p t i o n t h a t firms c a n o b s e r v e the c o r r e c t tax
v a r i a b l e in t h e y e a r o f the e x p e r i m e n t is likely t o be v i o l a t e d in a y e a r in
w h i c h t h e c o r p o r a t e tax c o d e is b e i n g r e v i e w e d . F o r e x a m p l e , if a c o u n t r y
l e g i s l a t e d a c h a n g e t o t h e tax c o d e in 1987 t o t a k e effect in 1988, b u t w a s
f u r t h e r r e v i e w i n g t h e c o d e f o r a n o t h e r r e f o r m , 1988 is n o t likely t o b e a
g o o d y e a r t o e x a m i n e the effects o f t h e 1987 c h a n g e s . T h e effects o f f u r t h e r
a n t i c i p a t e d c h a n g e s m i g h t s w a m p t h e effects o f p r e v i o u s c h a n g e s . )1
T a b l e 6 s u m m a r i z e s t h e e s t i m a t i o n results f o r e a c h c o u n t r y u s i n g t h e first
o f o u r a l t e r n a t i v e a p p r o a c h e s , In a d d i t i o n , w e p r o v i d e e s t i m a t e s o f t h e
m o d e l a u g m e n t e d t o i n c l u d e firms" c a s h flow, w h i c h h a s o f t e n b e e n f o u n d to
b e statistically a n d e c o n o m i c a l l y significant in m a n y p r e v i o u s studies, t-" W e
d e s c r i b e t h e s e results f o r e a c h c o u n t r y b e l o w .
5.2.1. Australia
In 1988, A u s t r a l i a r e d u c e d t h e c o r p o r a t e i n c o m e tax f r o m 4 9 % t o 3 9 %
and depreciation allowances were tightened.
T h e coefficient e s t i m a t e s f o r t h e m o d e l u s i n g this c h a n g e a r e r e p o r t e d in
Table 6. The first row reports the results obtained from the estimation of a
Q model using the surprises technique in Eq. (6). The coeKficient on Q is
0.605, with a standard error of 0.231. This coefficient is very similar to the
one we obtained for the United States using Compustat data in C u m m i n s et
al. (1994). A s a check that the results are robust, the second panel of Table
6 reports how the results change if the shock to beginning-of-period cash
flow is included in the Q equation; the inclusion of cash flow does not alter
the conclusions, and the estimated coefficient on the additional term is
statistically insignificant.
5.2.2. B e l g i u m
In Belgium, there were four major tax changes in the 1980s, and we
choose to study the last one. Effective in 1990, the corporate income tax was
reduced from 43% to 41%, and 39% thereafter, and the investment
deduction was phased out.
The first row for Belgium of Table 6 reports the results for 1990. The
coefficient of 1.626 on Q is the largest of the estimates in the sample, which
tend to be less than unity, but the standard error of 0.520 is large enough so
that more reasonable values are well within a standard deviation of the point
estimate. Including cash flow does not alter the point estimate, and its
estimated coefficient is not statistically significant.
5.2.3. Canada
Canada reformed the tax treatment of corporations significantly in the
mid-1980s. In 1985, el 5% corporate income tax surcharge was introduced
until the end of 1986. Further reform was proposed to lower the corporate
income ta:~ ~md to eliminate the ITC. Effective in 1987, the corporate
income tax was reduced from 46% to 45% and the surcharge was lowered
from 5% to 3%. The major reform was adopted to take effect in 1988,
lowering the corporate income tax rate from 45%, to 38% (and from 38%, to
36% on manufacturing and processing income) and retroactively phasing-out
the ITC. This suggests that 1988 is likely to be the best post-reform year in
which to apply our alternative approach.
The estimated coefficient of I).810 on Q is large and precisely estimated.
W h e n the shock to beginning-of-period cash flow is included, the point
estimate on Q is almost unaffected, although, in this case, the coefficient on
cash flow is economically and statistically significant.
5.2.4. D e n m a r k
Effective in 1990, D e n m a r k lowered the corporate income tax from 50%
to 40%. This change generated cross-sectional variations for firms because
of the changing relative value of depreciation deductions.
The point estimate for the coefficient on Q is similar to that for other
256 J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
countries and the inclusion of cash flow does not affect the point estimate.
Given the relatively small sample, the standard errors are large, and the
estimated coefficient is not quite statistically significant at the 5% confidence
level.
5.2.5. France
France has enacted seven corporate tax changes since 1980. and, given the
frequent changes, it is difficult to select one year in which firms are certain
that the existing tax code would be relevant for their current decisions over
a reasonable horizon. We choose 1990, when the corporate income tax was
reduced to 37%, with a further reduction to 34% set for 1991.
For France, the point estimate of 0.756 on Q is economically and
statistically significant, and the inclusion of cash flow, which is only
marginally significant, does not change the point estimate on Q or its
statistical significance.
5.2.6. G e r m a n y
Effective in 1990, G e r m a n y reduced the corporate income tax on retained
earnings from 56% to 50%; the rate on distributed income remained 36%.
In 1991, a temporary corporate income tax surcharge of 3.75% was !evied,
but this was the result of the unification, which one could reasonably say was
unanticipated in 1990.
For Germany, the estimated coefficient on Q is, again, large and precisely
estimated and is not affected by inclusion of the shock to cash flow.
5.2. 7. ttaly
In 1992, Italy abolished the 75% deduction for local corporate income
taxes. This resulted in an increase in the corporate incomz ta;~ from 47.8%
to 52.2%.
For Italy, the estimated coefficient on Q is 0.663, and is statistically
significant. In addition, the coefficient does not change if the shock to cash
flow is included, and the estimated coefficient on this term is not statistically
significant.
5.2.8. J a p a n
In 1988, Japan changed both the tax treatment of dividends and the
corporate tax rate, The difference in the rates of corporation tax for
retained and distributed income was removed in two stages, so that by 1990
a single standard rate of 37.5% applied.
T h e estimates for 1989 are reported in Table 6. The estimated coefficient
on Q is 0.949, with a standard error of 0.191. The point estimate is not
qualitatively changed by inclusion of the shock to cash flow, although the
estimated coefficient on this term is economically and statistically significant.
J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 ( lq~6) 237-273 257
5.2. I0. N o r w a y
Effective in 1992, Norway reduced the corporate income tax from 50.8%
to 28%, while abolishing existing investment allowances and reducing the
maximum rates of depreciation allowed.
The results for Norway for 1992 are reported in Table 6. Both the point
estimate of 1.373 on Q and its standard error of 0.528 are relatively large.
When the shock to cash flow is included, the coefficient on Q changes very
little. The coefficient estimate for cash flow is very large (consistent with the
large estimates reported in Section 3), and statistically significant.
5.2.11. Spain
Spain reduced the investment tax credit from 15% to 10% in 1988, and
again from 10% to 5% in 1989.
The point estimate for the coefficient on Q is large, but the standard error
is roughly the same order of magnitude as the coefficient. Including cash
flow decreases the coefficient on Q by about half. Moreover, the estimate of
the coefficient on cash flow is implausibly large. These results, as with those
for the Netherlands. are distinctly weaker than those for most other
countries.
5.2.12. S w e d e n
Sweden reduced the corporate income tax from 52c~ to 40% effective
1990. and to 30% in the years thereafter. Most investment reserves and
provisions were scrapped.
Thus. we choose 1990 as the year to examine for Sweden. The estimated
coefficient on Q is positive and significant, but somewhat smaller than the
coefficients for most other countries. 13 The inclusion of cash flow does not
L~One possible explanation for the smaller coefficient is that the 19~ tax reform had a
smaller marginal effect than that implied by our equation because of binding dividend
constraints. See Auerbach et al. (1995) for a discussionof this issue.
258 J.G. Cummins et at. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (toqo) 237-273
alter the estimates of the impact of Q , and the estimated coefficient on the
cash flow is imprecisely estimated.
5.2.15. S u m m a r y o f results
~ ' e have presented estimation rcsults for 14 countries, and found roughly
similar point estimates for 12 of the 14. The coefficient estimate on Q was
statistically significant in every country except the Netherlands and Spain,
where the point estimates were too low and too high, respectively. In both
countries the standard errors were very large. The other estimates ranged
from lows of about 0.6 to a high of about 1.5, with every estimate within two
standard deviations of unity) a These coefficients are roughly similar to those
we reported for the United States and to those in Gilchrist and Himmelberg
(1995) who estimate the Abel and Blanchard (1986) model using US panel
data. We find evidence of residual excess sensitivity of investment to cash
flow in Canada. Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States) ~
Using the means of I l K and 6 reported in Table 4, these estimates imply
that the adjustment costs of investment are of the order of 5 % - 1 0 % per
~l'he coefficientestimates are potentially biased upward if tax reforms are an indicator of
shifts in future fiscal regimes. Indeed. the countries with the largest coefficient estimates
(Spain. Norway, and Belgium) underwent relatively large fiscal restructuring. We thank
Michael lqaliassosfor this suggestion.
~'The findingthat excesssensitivityof investmentto cash flow is more a characteristicof UK
firms than of continental European firms is consistent with the careful study of Bond et al.
199-I-'1.
Table 7
Tax-adjusted q model: Focusing on lax variation
Country ~"
AUS BEL CAN DNK FRA GER ITA JPN NLD NOR SPN SWE UK USA
Year of tax reform
1988 19~1 1988 1990 19~ 19~) 1992 1989 1989 1992 1989 19~ 1991 1987
GMM
Q,, 0,289 f).587 0.521 0.765 0.388 0.784 I).180 0.086 0,633 0.512 0.404 0.293 0.589 0.650
10.153) (0.422) (0.127) (0,308) (0.116) (11.296) (0.120) (0.035) (0.150) (0.295) (0.233) (0.169) (0.078) (0.077)
W
IVs O'l',,; ( I /K ) ,. , 2, ,; ( C F / K ) , ~ ,., ~
ff'~ 0.516 11.213 1.47 0.820 1.58 0.520 1.36 3.45 0.257 0.289 0.458 163 1.92 7.30
p-value 0.972 0.995 0.832 0.936 0.812 0,972 O.&SI 0.486 0.992 0.991 0.977 0.803 0,750 0.120
N 75 28 173 48 83 130 90 395 44 25 26 50 403 1365 ~'
S o u r c e : Authors" calculations using Global Vantage data. The dependent variable is I , / K , , ~. Variables are deliacd in the text. The models are
estimated using GMM. Standard errors on coeflicients, in parentheses, are computed from a heteroskedastie-constant correlation matrix. The
regressions are based on a twice-differenced version of Eq. (1) as described in Ihe text and are for each country tax reform year.
260 J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
6. Conclusions
I~We chose to express the instruments in levels since this has been common in the previous
literature (see. for example, Blundell et al., 1992), Since we include lags of the levels of the
instruments, there is little practical difference between using levels and differences.
J.G. Cummins et aL / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273 2.61
Acknowledgements
+ (1 - m,)O,E,. , D . . . . , ] / E . , = P , . , . (AI)
where i and t are the firm and time indexes, respectively; E~. t is the
expectations operator of firm i conditional on information available at time
t; V is the value of the firm's equity; S is the value of new shares issued; D
represents the dividends the firm pays; z is an accrual-equivalent capital
gains tax rate; m is the personal tax rate on dividends; and O is the dividend
received by the shareholder when the firm distributes one currency unit of
retained earnings.
In the absence of any speculative bubbles, solving Eq. (A1) forward yields
the following expression for the market value of the firm's equity at time t:
V,., = E,., = - ,
where /3i. j is the time j discount factor for tint1 i; and " O , = ( l - m ~ ) O , /
(1 z~). The variable -q is the tax discr;mination parameter that determines
-
where "r is the marginal corporate tax rate; F ( K . N ) is the firm's production
function (Fx > 0. F~K < 0); C(I, K ) is the real cost of adjusting the capital
stock ( C t > O. C u > O. C K < O, CK~ < 0); N is a vector of variable factors of
production; w is a vector of real factor prices; B is the market value of
outstanding debt; i is the nominal interest rate paid on corporate bonds; ~'~
is expected inflation; p is the price of capital goods relative to the price of
output; and F is the tax benefit of investing. For example, with an
investment tax credit at rate k. F is
The fifth constraint is a transversality condition that prevents the firm from
borrowing an infinite amount to pay out dividends:
([~T-I )
lim__ /3i i B, r = 0 . V,.
To derive the Euler equation for investment, we set the derivatives of the
firm's maximization problem equal to zero at time t:
r {,-,:,,,
-,,)lp, + (A3)
L \ '-",/
and
E,. ,{ill ,+ i( 1 - zt+ ,)(FA+- CA') + (1 - 8+)A.... ~} = A t , , (A4)
where A is the shadow value of an increase in firm i's capital stock (i.e.
marginal q) at time t. Eq. (A4) states that it is optimal to invest until the
return on a marginal unit of capital in period t + I equals the cost of capital
in period t + 1.
To derive the equation we estimate, we posit a quadratic adjustment cost
function:
,,,I li., "~ '-
C(I,. ,, K. ..... ) = -~t K~.~_l - It,) K,. ,_,, (A5)
li. , 1 [ A , . , - p , ( l - F,. , ) ]
Ki .---'-~ =/~i + ~ -1~ , . ~ " (A6)
B . 1 . Firm-specific variables
T h e variables we used are defined as follows. To facilitate replication and
extension of our empirical results and to aid researchers in data construction
on this relatively unfamiliar dataset, we provide the data item numbers in
parentheses after each variable. Gross investment is the s u m of the change
in the net stock of tangible fixed assets (76) and depreciation (I1)) 8 A more
precise estimate of depreciation can be obtained (12), but we choose the one
above since most firms do not separately report the more precise figure. The
h,vestment variable is divided by the value of its own beginning-of-period
capital stock. Output is defined as net sales/turnover (1), and is also divided
by the value of its own beginning-of-period capital stock. Operating income
is defined exactly as such (14). Net income is defined as income before
extraordinary ,terns (32). Total income tax is defined exactly as such (23).
Cash flow is the sum of net income and depreciation. These variables arc
~Defining gross investment as the change in the gross stock of tangible fixed assets (77) is
impracticable because that data item is frequently not reported by firms, or was not required to
be reported by firms (e.g. German firms did not report the gross stock of fixed assets until
1985). There is no data item in Global Vantage comparable to the capital expenditures data
item in Compnstat.
J.G. Cummins et al. I Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273 265
B.2.4. Australia
Depreciation of assets is calculated on the cost price and the useful life of
the assets (which before 1991 was estimated by the tax authority), which the
taxpayer estimates based on the statutory definition. The tax authority
continues to publish recommended depreciation rates which the taxpayer
may elect over estimating useful life. Plant and machinery may be depre-
ciated on either a straight-line (SL) or declining-balance (DB) basis. In the
absence of a formal election for the SL method, the DB method is used.
Most assets acquired after 1992 are depreciable by reference to a six-rate
schedule, with useful lives ranging from three to more than 30 years and DB
rates ranging from 10% to 60%. SL rates are two-thirds of DB rates. Assets
may be depreciated at a lower rate at the option of the taxpayer. Assets with
an effective life of less than three years or low cost assets may be
depreciated immediately. Structures may be depreciated at 2.5% per year if
construction commenced after September 1987, 4% if construction com-
menced between August 1984 and September 1987, and 2.5% if construc-
tion commenced before August 1984. The period over which the deprecia-
tion may be claimed is 40 years for structures subject to the 2.5% rate and
25 years for structures subject to the 4% rate.
For valuation of stock, the tax authority accepts average cost (AC),
standard cost (SC), specific identification (SI), and first-in-first-out (FIFO).
Last-in-first-out (LIFO) and base-stock methods are not allowed.
B.2.5. Belgium
Depreciation of assets is calculated on the cost price and the useful life of
the assets and is allowed as of the financial year in which they were acquired
J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal o f Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273 267
or produced and must be applied every year. The law allows only SL and
DB methods. SL is the normal method. The depreciation periods and the
corresponding rates are normally fixed by agreement between the taxpayer
and the tax authority, although for certain assets the rates are set by
administrative ruling (e.g. commercial buildings 3%; industrial buildings
5 % ; machinery and equipment 10% or 30%; rolling stock 20%). DB is
optional, as is a combination of both methods---if in a certain year the
a m o u n t of depreciation computed by applying DB is lower than that
computed according to SL, then a company can switch to the latter method.
Accelerated depreciation (AD) is available for certain assets based on
administrative ruling (e.g. ships and scientific equipment).
T h e tax code does not contain special provisions for the valuation of
stock. The tax authority therefore requires that the stock be valued at cost
or market value, whichever is lower. As for methods, A C , SI, FIFO, and
LIFO are accepted but the base-stock method is not.
B.2.6. Canada
T h e capital cost allowance system groups depreciable assets into various
classes (similar to the method used in ~he United States). Each class is
depreciable at a specific rate, generally on a DB basis. In the year of
acquisition, only half the normal rate m a y be claimed on that asset. The
depreciation allowances are elective, allowing the taxpayer to claim any
desired amount (subject to the maximum). The following sets out some of
the more c o m m o n types of depreciable assets with the applicable DB rates:
structures 4 % , machinery and equipment 30%, and autos and computers
30%. Asset revaluation is not allowed.
Permissible inventory valuation methods include A C and FIFO. In some
circumstances, the tax authority will accept the SC method. The LIFO
m e t h o d is not accepted.
B.2. 7. Denmark
SL depreciation for business structures is permitted. For most types of
buildings the depreciation rate is 6% of cost during the first 10 years, and
2% thereafter (a lower rate of 4% and 1% is applied to service buildings.
and a higher rate of 8% and 4% to building installations). Between 1982 and
1990 the depreciable base was adjusted annually for inflation. For equip-
m e n t DB depreciation is allowed on a collective basis. The rate may be
chosen by the taxpayer but may not exceed 30%. in any year. Tax
depreciation is not allowed for accounting purposes.
T h e A C , SI, FIFO, and SC methods are considered appropriate; LIFO is
acceptable but rarely used.
268 ,LG. Cummins et al. / Journal o f Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
B.2 8 France
Depreciation is normally computed by the SL method. However, the law
provides for other methods~ namely DB and A D . The SL method may be
applied without restriction. The rates are computed by dividing the expendi-
ture by the estimated useful life of the asset as determined in accordance
with accepted business practice. Taxpayers may opt for a varying deprecia-
tion rate based on a different useful life estimation, but this will be accepted
only if the difference is within 20% of customary practice. T h e DB method
is allowed on a more limited scale. It m a y not be applied to assets whose
useful life is less than three years nor to many classes of assets. The rate is
computed by multiplying the rate of SL depreciation by 1.5 if the useful life
is three or four years, by 2 if the life is five or six years, and by 2.5 if the life
exceeds six years. A D in the form of an initial deduction is available for
certain assets (e.g. environmental protection equipment). Only limited asset
revaluation is permitted.
T h e FIFO and A C methods are usually used. The LIFO method is not
generally permitted except when used in consolidated financial statements.
B.2.9. Gomany
Systems of depreciation allowed by law are the SL, DB, and certain other
m e t h o d s (e.g. sum of the years" digits). A switchover from DB to SL is
permitted, but not vice versa. The rates of depreciation for buildings are set
o u t in the law and for other assets in the official r e c o m m e n d e d tables (over
90 tables) that are issued by the various tax authorities. T h e taxpayer may
deviate from them in individual cases on reasonable grounds. For business
structures, the annual SL rate is 4%. The corresponding DB rates are: 10%
for the first four years, 5% for the following three years and 2.5% for the
remaining 18 years. For fixed assets a general table applies SL rates of 10%
for machinery, 20% for office equipment, 10% for office furniture, 20% for
computers, and 20% for motor vehicles. If the assets are depreciated
according to D B , then the annual rate is limited to three times the SL rate
with an allowable m a x i m u m of 30%. A D is allowed for certain special assets
(e.g. those in development areas or private hospitals) and if justified by
excessive wear and tear. Asset revaluation is not allowed.
F r o m the assessment year 1990, LIFO is allowed. A C and SI are typical
methods; FIFO is not allowed unless it approximates actual physical flows.
B.2.1o. Italy
Depreciation of tangible assets is permitted on a SL basis. Depreciation is
determined by applying the coefficients established by the tax authority,
reduced by half for the first fiscal year. These coefficients are established for
categories of assets based on normal wear and tear in various productive
J.G. Cummins el al. / Journal of Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273 269
sectors (rates for structures vary from 3% to 7%, and for machinery and
equipment from 20% to 25%). A D is also allowed. In addition to normal
depreciatien, the deductible amount may be increased by 200% in the year
in which the asset is acquired and in one of the following two years.
Moreover, normal depreciation may always be increased -'n proportion to
more intense use of the asset (intensive depreciation), l'he amount of
depreciation may be less than normal depreciation, and the difference may
be spread over subsequent fiscal years. Only limited asset revaluation is
permitted.
Any system of inventory valuation is permitted provided it is not less than
if the LIFO method is used.
B.2.11. Japan
The amount depreciable on assets per year is computed on the assumption
that their salvage value is 10% of the acquisition cost. However, companies
may claim depreciation until the residual value of the asset reaches 5% (i.e.
up to 95% of acquisition costs). The statutory useful lives of assets are
prescribed by the tax authority. They range from 4 years (for motor
vehicles) to 65 years (for office buildings). Special depreciation is available
for assets subject to abnormal wear and tear and due to extraordinary
circumstances. A D is also available for designated assets and industries (e.g.
environmental protection equipment and ships). Initial-year depreciation
rates range from 8% to 30%, and further A D can follow. Asset revaluation
is not allowed.
For valuation of stock, the tax authority accepts AC, SI, LIFO, and
FIFO. The method should be applied consistently and not distort the
computation of the income of a corporation.
B . 2 . 1 2 . The Netherlands
Depreciation of assets is compulsory whether the company is profitable or
not. Assets with a low cost can be fully depreciated in the year of
acquisition. All systems of depreciation ~re permitted provided that the
system is in accordance with sound business practices and that it is
consistently applied. This means that changes in the system will not be
allowed when a change is made just for tax purposes. Depreciation is based
on historic cost price, useful life, and the salvage value of the asset. No
official guidelines for depreciation exist. In practice, the rates are agreed
between the taxpayer and the tax author;ty.
Under the sound business practice principle, many systems of inventory
vaiuation are allowed (e.g. LIFO, FIFO, or base-stock methods). The
system must be applied consistently.
270 J.G. Cumminx et al. / Journal of Pubhc Economics 62 (I996) 237-273
B.2.13. N o r w a y
T h e DB method of depreciation is mandatory. The 1992 tax reform
influenced the system of depreciation by changing the division of business
assets into a smaller number of classes ann by generally reducing the
m a x i m u m rates allowed. Depreciable assets ark divided into eight classes
(maximum rates follow in parentheses): (1) office machines (30%), (2)
goodwill (30%). (3) motor vehicles (25%), (4) equipment (20%), (5) ships
(20%), (6) aircraft (20%), (7) industrial structures (5%), and (8) commercial
~truetures (2%). Assets in classes 1-4 are written down on a collective basis;
c!asses 5 - 8 are depreciated individually. A D for ships, aircraft, and certain
strl: 'tures has been abolished as of 1992. Assets with an estimated life of less
than three years and low cost assets may be depreciated immediately.
The FIFO method must oe used for inventory valuation.
B . 2 . 1 4 . Spain
Depreciation is allowed on all tangible and intangible fixed assets on the
basis of their normal useful life. Depreciation may be calculated by the SL
method. In certain cases (e.g. industrial machinery and computers), the DB
m e t h o d is permitted. Rates for depreciation arc contained in official tables.
Examples of general m a x i m u m SL rates follow (with the m i n i m u m rate
following in parentheses): industrial structures 3% (2%), commercial struc-
tures 2% (1.33%L machinery 8% (5.6%), tools 20% (12.5%), office
furniture 10% (6.67%), computers 25% (16.7%L and motor vehicles 14%
(9.1%). Assets intensively used may be depreciated at a maximum rate
increased by 33% for each additional shift. U n d e r the DB method, the
annual depreciation rate is increased by 50% (if the useful life is less than
five years) or by 100% (if the useful life is five years or more). The tax
authorities can accept, at their discretion, special A D (or even free
depreciation) for certain assets and industries. Asset revaluation is not
permitted.
Accepted methods for inventory valuation are A C (in practice, the
generally applied method) and FIFO. The LIFO and base-stock methods are
not accepted for tax purposes.
B.2.15. Sweden
Machinery and equipment are normally depreciated by the DB method.
T h e m a x i m u m depreciation allowance is 30% of the aggregate book value of
all assets at the beginning of the tax year, plus the cost of assets acquired,
less the amount received for assets sold during the year. Should a SL
depreciation of 20% per year on all assets result in a lower book value in
any year, the annual depreciation may be increased correspondingly. If the
J.G. Cummins et aL / Journal of Public Economics 62 (19ctti) 237-273 271
References
Abel, A.B. and O..L Blanchard. 19~. The n[e~ent value of profits and c}clical movements in
investment. Economelrica 54. 249-273.
Alonso-Borrego. C. and S. Bcntolila. 1994. In,.estment and q in Spanish manufacturing firms.
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 56. 49-7II.
AIv,orth. J.. t988, The finance, investment, and taxation decisions of multinational,; (Basil
Blackwell. Oxh~rd).
Auerbach. A,J . 197'4. Wcallh maximization and the c~)st of capital. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 93, 4";3-446.
Auerbach. A.J,, 1'4~,3.Taxation. corl~-,ratc financial policy, and the cost ~f capital. Journal of
Economic Literature 21. ~,~)5-q411.
Auerbach. A.J. and K.A. Hassett. 19~,H.Recent U.S. in'.estment bcha;R)r and the Tax Reform
Act of 1986: A disaggregate ,.jew. Caracgit:-Rochester Conference Series on Public P~lic~, 35.
185-215.
Auerbach, A.J.. K.A. Hassett and J. S6dersten, 1995. Taxation and corporate investment: The
impact of the 1991 Swedish tax reform. NBER Working Paper .";o. S,t89.
Bernanke. B.S.. H. Bt~hn and P.C. Reiss. 1988. Alternative non-nested specification tcsls of
time-series im.estment models. Journal of Econometrics 37, 1 3~;.
Blundell. R.. S. Bond° M De,,'ereux and F, Schiantarelli. lt~t~2, |n'.eslment and Tobin's Q:
Evidence from company panel '~lata. Journal of Econometrics 51. 233-258.
Bond. S.R. and C. Meghir, 1994. D}namic in;estment m~dels and the firm's financial policy.
Resiev, of Economic Studies 61, 197-222.
Bond. S.R.. J. Elston. J. Mairesse and B. Mulkay. 1994. A comparison ~ff empirical in'~estment
equations using company panel data for France. German'.. Belgium. and the U.K.. Mimeo.
Oxford Uni',er,ity
272 J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal o f Public Economics 62 (1996) 237-273
Bradford, D.F., 1981, The incidence and allocation effects of a tax on corporate distributions,
Journal of Public Economics 15, 1-22.
Cabellcro, R.J., E.M.R.A. Engel and J.C. Haltiwanger, 1995, Plant-level adjus:ment and
aggregate investment dynamics. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2, 1-54.
Chirinko. R.S., 1993, Business fixed investment spending: A critical survey of modelling
strategies, empirical results, and policy implications, Journal of Economic Literature 31.
[875-1911.
Clark, P.K., 1979. Investment in the 1970s: Theory,, performance, and prediction. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity No. 1, 73-113.
Clark, P.K., 1993. Tax incentives and equipment investment, ~rookings Papers on Economic
Activity No. 1, 317-339.
Coopers & Lybrand. various years, International accounting summaries (Wiley, New York).
Coopers & Lybrand. various years, international tax summaries (Wiley, New York).
Cummins, J.G. arm K.A. Hassett, 1992, The effects of taxation on investment: New evidence
from firm-level panel data, National Tax Journal 45, 243-252.
Cummins, J.G., K.A. Hassett and R.O. Hubbard, 1994, A reconsideration of investment
behavior using tax reforms as natural experiments, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
No. 2, 1-74.
Cummins, J.G.. T.S, Harris and K.A.Hassett, 1995. Accounting standards, information ~ow,
and firm investment behavior, in: M. Feldstein, J.R. Hines and R.G. Hubbard, eds.. Effects
of taxation on multinational corporations (University of Chicago Press. Chicago).
De Long, J.B.. A. Shleifer, L. Summers and R. Waldman, 1990. Noise trader risk in financial
markets, Journal of Political Economy 98. 703-738.
Devereux, M. and F. SchiantarcUi, 1990, Investment, financial factors, and cash flow: Evidence
from U.K. panel data. in: R.G, Hubbard, ed., Asymmetric information, corporate finance.
and investment (University of Chicago Press. Chicago).
Devereux, M., M.J. Keen and F. Schiantarelli, 1994. Corporate tax, investment and the role of
tax asymmetries: Evidence from company panel data, Journal of Public Economics 53.
395-~-18.
Dixit, A.K. and R.S. Pindyck. 1994, Investment under uncertainty (Princeton University Press.
Princeton).
Fazzari, S.M., R.G. Hubbard and B.C. Petersen. 1988. Financing constraints and corporate
investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity No. 1. 141-195.
Galeotti, M.. F. Schiamarelli and F. Jaramillo, 1994. Investment decisions and the role of debt,
liquid as~ts, and cash flow: Evidence from Italian panel data. Applied Financial Economics
4, 121-132.
Gilehrist. S. and C.P. Himmelberg. 1995. Evidence on the role of cash flow for investment.
Journal of Monetary Economics, 36. 541-572.
Hall. R.E. and D.W. Jorgenson, 1967, Tax policy and investment behavior. American
Economic Review 57. 39!-414.
Hayashi, F., 1982, Tobiu's marginal q and average Q: A neoclassical interpretation, Econo-
metrica 50, 213-224.
Hayashi, F,, 1085, Corporate finance side of the O theory of investment. Journal or Public
Economics 27, 261-280.
Hayashi, F. and T. Inoue. 1991, The relation between firm growth and O with multiple capital
goods: Theory. and evidence from panel data on Japanese firms, Econometrica 59, 731-753.
Hoshi. T. and A.K. Kashyap, 1990, Evidence on q and investment for Japanese firms, Journal
of the Japanese and International Economy 4. 371-4l)0.
Hoshi, T., A.K. Kashyap and D. Scharfstein, 1991. Corporate capital structure, liquidity and
investment: Evidence from Japanese industrial groups, Quarterly Journal of Economics lt~6,
33-60.
J.G. Cummins et al. / Journal o f Public Economics 62 (I996) 237-273 _7,73
Hubbard. R.G., 1994. Investment under uncertainty: Keeping one's options open, Journal of
Economic Literature 32, 1816-1831.
Hubbard, R.G. and A.K. Kashyap. 1992. Internal net worth and the investment process: Ar~
application to U.S. agriculture, Journal of Political Economy lfiO, 5~k%534.
Hubbard. R.G., A.K. Kashyap and T.M+ Whited. 1995. Internal finance and firm investment.
Journat of Money, Credit and Banking 27,683-701.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, various years. Annual report.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, various years. European tax handbook.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, 1993, Guide to European taxation: Vol. lI: The
taxation of companies in Europe.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation. various issues. Tax nev+s service.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, 1993, Taxes and investment in Asia and the
Pacific: Part I1: Countries.
International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, 1993, Taxes and investment in Canada.
Jorgenson, D.W., 1963, Capita~ theory and investment behavior, American Economic Rev/c',v
53, 247-259.
Jorgenson, D.W., 1992, Tax reform and the cost of capilal: An international comparison.
Working Paper No. 1621 (Harvard Institute for Economic R e , a r c h ) .
King. M.A.. 1977, Public policy and the corporation (Chapman and Hall. L~,r,don).
King+ M.A. and D. Fullerton, eds., 1984, The taxation of income from capital: A comparatis+e
study of the United States. United Kingdom, Sweden. and West Germany (University of
Chicago Press, Chicago).
Messere. K., 1993, Tax policy in O E C D countries: Choices and conflicts (IBFD Publications,
Amsterdam).
OIiner, S.. G, Rudebusch and D. SicheL 1995, New and old models of investment: A
comparison of forecasting performance, Journal of Money. Credit and Banking 27, 806-8_96.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1991. Taxing profits in a global
economy: Domestic and international issues ( O E C D Publications, Paris).
Pagan. ,~ 1984. Econometric issues in the analysis of regression with generated regressors,
.