public choice theory
public choice theory
DOI 10.1007/s11127-014-0160-8
BOOK REVIEW
G. P. Manish
Any system of division of labor necessarily involves social cooperation; each individual, in
order to satisfy his own wants, must first cater to the needs of others. Thanks to the
increased productivity that results from the specialization of labor, engaging in such a
process of cooperation has the potential to significantly improve the living standards of the
participants. However, while such a process is more productive, it is not one that is
automatic; it only operates under certain conditions. Indeed, men would stop interacting
with others to satisfy their needs if there was widespread predatory and opportunistic
behavior. What incentive, for instance, would a producer have to embark on a process of
production if he faced a high probability that his employees will renege on their contracts
or that miscreants will destroy his factory? Social cooperation, in other words, requires
anti-social behavior to be stifled; it requires a certain amount of predictability in the actions
of individuals.
Moreover, successful social cooperation requires a solution of the fundamental eco-
nomic problem: ensuring that the available supply of scarce means is allocated to serve the
highest valued ends. The various factors of production must be combined to yield a
production structure that caters to those needs that consumers rank highest; no resource
should be assigned to the satisfaction of a lower-ranked end while one that is ranked higher
remains unsatisfied. Stated differently, producers must coordinate their actions to best
satisfy the prevailing consumer preferences. Any successful attempt at such coordination,
however, faces the endemic hurdle of imperfect knowledge. The various participants in the
division of labor are not blessed with omniscience; they lack the necessary knowledge that
would enable them to make the best use of the resources they possess.
Mired in the imaginary world of long run equilibrium, mainstream neoclassical eco-
nomics is oblivious to these obstacles that stand in the way of successful social cooper-
ation. Its arid mathematical models, engaged in an in-depth analysis of a world where the
economic problem has already been successfully resolved, simply assume away the
problems that any economy faces in achieving an optimal coordination of means and ends.
G. P. Manish (&)
Sorrell College of Business, Troy University, 137R, Bibb Graves Hall, Troy, AL 36082, USA
e-mail: [email protected]
123
Public Choice
123
Public Choice
how to utilize the resources in their possession; the need to compete incentivizes them to
incur the costs of the discovery of knowledge despite the unknown returns.
Moreover, once knowledge is discovered and utilized in a certain market, prices serve to
disseminate it across the length and breadth of the economy, enabling participants in other
markets to make their resource allocations more efficient. And last but not least, the market
possesses an inherent system of error correction through profit and loss. The feedback
provided by profits and losses ensures an allocation of resources that minimizes mistakes
and erroneous decisions. Thus, while the market economy does not ensure a completely
rational allocation of resources, it generates the best possible outcome given the realities of
human ignorance.
In addition to providing a robust defense of a private property order, the authors also
develop the conceptual foundations required to analyze the fascinating questions of how
institutions emerge and how they evolve over time. They delineate a detailed typology of
institutions, distinguishing between internal institutions, or ‘‘rules that evolve within a
group in the light of experience,’’ and external institutions that are ‘‘designed externally’’
and ‘‘imposed on the community from above by political action’’ (p. 108). Moreover, they
also note that while the former, for the most part, are enforced without formal sanctions
and thus constitute informal institutions, the latter, requiring a formal enforcement
mechanism, can be termed formal institutions. On the basis of this typology the authors
distinguish between two types of social orders. An institutional structure composed pri-
marily of internal institutions would constitute a spontaneous order, wherein the actions of
individuals are ‘‘ordered indirectly or in a spontaneous, voluntary way because the various
agents obey shared institutions’’ (p. 152). In contrast, a rule system comprised largely of
external institutions gives rise to a planned order in which an ‘‘outside authority plans and
implements an order by instructions or directives to achieve a joint purpose’’ (p. 152).
While acknowledging the key role that external institutions play in facilitating social
cooperation, especially by way of state-provided justice and maintenance of the rule of
law, the authors stress the vital role that internal institutions play in ensuring a robust and
thriving private property order. Indeed, they argue that essential external institutions, such
as the rule of law, can never be foisted on pre-existing internal institutions that are hostile
to the norms essential for respecting and enforcing private property rights. It follows that
the imposition of alien external institutions via revolutions necessarily ends in failure and
social chaos, as was the case in both the erstwhile Soviet Union and in Nazi Germany (p.
431). Instead, there is an inherent inertia, an unavoidable path dependency that charac-
terizes institutional change (p. 437). Recognition of the key role played by internal
institutions also helps explain why some societies, such as post-communist China, have
been able to successfully evolve toward a market-based system, whereas other nations, like
those in Eastern Europe, have struggled with the transition from socialism to capitalism
(pp. 457–482).
All in all, Institutional Economics provides a robust and enlightening defense of a
market-based system of the division of labor that depends on a clearly defined and well-
enforced system of private property rights. It is primarily designed to be a textbook and
would be ideal for instructors who wish to introduce students to the subject of institutional
economics. At the same time, the book is also a worthwhile and informative read for all
those seeking to explore questions regarding the economic consequences of different
institutional structures and the rules that govern the evolution of institutions; questions that
largely remain unaddressed by neoclassical economics.
123