Economics Week 7 Rev
Economics Week 7 Rev
Price is the most common economic factor used when determining elasticity or
inelasticity. Other factors include income level and substitute availability.
KEY TAKEAWAYS
Elasticity of Demand
The elasticity of demand for a given good or service is calculated by dividing the
percentage change in quantity demanded by the percentage change in price. If
the elasticity quotient is greater than or equal to one, the demand is considered
to be elastic.
For example, a change in the price of a luxury car can cause a change in the
quantity demanded. If a luxury car producer has a surplus of cars, they may
reduce their price in an attempt to increase demand. The extent of the price
change will determine whether or not the demand for the good changes and if so,
by how much.
For example, suppose that an economic event leads to many workers being laid
off. During this time period, people may decide to save their money rather than
upgrading their smartphones or buying designer purses. This would lead to
luxury items becoming more elastic. In other words, a slight change in income
level would lead to a significant change in the consumption of luxury goods.
Conversely, if this same brand of cereals experienced a steep price cut, we’d
expect more people to buy it, assuming its level of quality is similar to peers and
we aren't in a deep recession.
Similarly, if the price of a Kit-Kat chocolate bar increases, people will buy a
different type of candy bar.
Inelasticity of Demand
Should demand for a good or service be static when its price or other factor
changes, it is said to be inelastic. In other words, when the price changes or
consumer's incomes change, they will not change their buying habits.
Inelastic products are necessities and, usually, do not have substitutes they can
easily be replaced with.
For businesses, there are many advantages to price inelasticity. For example,
they have greater flexibility with prices because demand remains basically the
same, even if prices increase or decrease. If the business raises its prices up or
down, consumers' buying habits will remain mostly unchanged. This can impact
demand and total revenue for a business in a couple of different ways.
Examples of Inelastic Products
The most common goods with inelastic demand are utilities, prescription drugs,
and tobacco products. In general, necessities and medical treatments tend to be
inelastic, while luxury goods tend to be the most elastic.
Another typical example is salt. The human body requires a specific amount of
salt per pound of body weight. Too much or too little salt could cause illness or
even death, so the demand for it changes very little when price changes—salt
has an elasticity quotient that is close to zero and a steep slope on a graph.
While there are no perfectly inelastic goods, there are some goods that come
pretty close. For example, people need gas to drive their cars. Even if gas prices
get higher, people may not be able to stop commuting to work, taking their kids to
school, and driving to the store. Thus, people will still purchase gas even at a
higher price.
Elasticity FAQs
Elasticity is measured by the ratio of two percentages. For example, consider the
price elasticity of demand. The price elasticity of demand is measured by
calculating the ratio of the change in the quantity demanded to the change in the
price. In other words, price elasticity is the ratio of a relative change in quantity
demanded to a relative change in price.
If the price elasticity is equal to 1.5, it means that the quantity demanded for a
product has increased 15% in response to a 10% reduction in price (15% / 10%
= 1.5).
Numerical Example
If price of a product decreases from Rs.70 to Rs.60 and due to it quantity
demanded increases from 2800 units to 3000units, what will be the price
elasticity of demand. Explain your answer.
The formula for calculating PED will be:
% Change in Quantity Demanded / % Change in Price
(Q2-Q1) / Q1 * 100
PED = --------------------------------- = 0.5
(P2-P1) / P1 * 100
Therefore, the elasticity of demand between these two points is 0.5, an amount
smaller than one, showing that the demand is inelastic in this interval. Price
elasticities of demand are always negative since price and quantity demanded
always move in opposite directions (on the demand curve). By convention, we
always talk about elasticities as positive numbers. So mathematically, we take
the absolute value of the result. We will ignore this detail from now on, while
remembering to interpret elasticities as positive numbers.