Microeconomics I
Microeconomics I
nd
Course material for 2 Year
January, 2025
Haramaya University
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS
ii. From the view point of interest whether to deal with economic explanations/
understandings/ or with what should be done to change or improve the existing
economic conditions (whether to deal with value judgement or not), we can divide
economics as positive economics and normative economics.
iii. One way of dividing the world economy is on the basis of the economic policies a
country follows. From this perspective, we can divide world economy in to three:
Command economy, mixed economy and market economy.
iv. We can also classify economics into different areas of economic specializations.
Some of these are: Agricultural, Natural Resources, Environmental, Health, Education,
Welfare, Labour, Industrial, Behavioural, Public, Monetary, Institutional, Development,
Mathematical and Quantitative, Urban, Rural, Regional, International, Law and
Economics, etc.
The fundamental objective of economics, like any science, is the establishment of valid
generalizations about certain aspects of human behaviour. Those generalizations are
known as
theories. A theory is a simplified picture of reality. Economic theory provides the basis
for
economic analysis which uses logical reasoning. There are two methods of logical
reasoning:
inductiveanddeductive.
3) The Market Economy: The organizing principles, here, are the forces of demand and
supply. The determination of what to produce is made by consumers, and the force of
demand causes prices to go up for certain products when consumers desire more of
them.
In a sense, consumers vote with their money. The result of this voting process
determines what will be produced. Suppliers combine resources, determining how
things are to be produced. Assuming suppliers are self-interested and seek to maximize
their profits, they tend to combine inputs to produce any good or service at the lowest
possible cost. This determination depends on the prices of resources. Suppliers will use
more of relatively abundant resources because they are relatively cheap. This, in turn,
helps conserve the scarcer (more expensive) resources. The goods are then distributed
to consumers who have the purchasing power to buy them. Those who have more
purchasing power receive more goods and services.
4) The Mixed Economic System: In the real world we find that economies are the blend
of traditional, planned and market economic systems. In practice every economy is a
mixed economy in the sense that it combines significant elements of all three systems.
Scarcity
The fundamental economic problem that any human society faces is the problem of
scarcity. Scarcity refers to the fact that all economic resources that a society needs to
produce goods and services are finite or limited in supply. But their being limited
should be expressed in relation to human wants.
Thus, the term scarcity reflects the imbalance between our wants and the means to
satisfy those wants.
Scarcity is the imbalance between our desires and available resources. Then economic
scarcity forces us to make economic choices. Wants are insatiable, because no matter
how much people have, they always want more of them. Since not all wants can be
satisfied, individuals have to pick and choose among the possibilities open to them.
Every society is faced with the same problems of scarcity and choice.
Choice
If resources are scarce, then output will be limited. If output is limited, then we cannot
satisfy all of our wants. Thus, choice must be made. Due to the problem of scarcity,
individuals, firms and government are forced to choose as to what output to produce, in
what quantity, and what output not to produce. In short, scarcity implies choice. Choice,
in turn, implies cost. That means whenever choice is made, an alternative opportunity is
sacrificed. This cost is known as opportunity cost. Scarcity limited resource limited
output we might not satisfy all our wants choice involves costs opportunity cost.
Opportunity cost
In a world of scarcity, a decision to have more of one thing, at the same time, means a
decision to have less of another thing. The value of the next best alternative that must
be sacrificed is, therefore, the opportunity cost of the decision.
Quantity Demanded- the specific amount of a commodity that people are willing and
able to buy at a particular price, i.e., the quantity of a good or service that consumers
demand at price Birr 1, the quantity they demand at price Birr 2, etc.
Demand Schedule- a tabular listing that shows the quantity demanded at various
prices, ceteris paribusThe phrase ceteris paribus means other things remain the same.
20 Demand curve
15
5
Individual’s demand for a product is the quantity of the good that consumer would buy
at various prices.
Table 2.2: Individual Demand Schedules
In a more general case, in which the market consists of n consumers with individual
demand functions for goods X is defined as:
Xi = f (PX)
Where Xi represents the quantity demanded of good X by individual i.
The market demand for good X (Xm) is given as:
The market demand curve (see Figure 2.2), therefore, could be considered to show the
relationship between market demand (Xm) and price PX , other things remaining constant.
Table 2.3: Market Demand Schedule
Price 0 1 2 3 4 5
Quantit 80 60 55 40 25 10
y
The market demand curves are similarly obtained from simple horizontal summation of
individual demand curves as given below:
Price
6
5 Market demand curve
4
3
2
1
0 10 25 40 55 60 80 Quantity
Law of Demand- is a principle stating that as the price of a commodity increases, the
fewer consumers will purchase per unit of time, ceteris paribus. As price increases, the
quantity demanded decreases per unit of time, ceteris paribus. Why?
● Substitution Effect- When a price of a good starts to increase relative to the
price of other goods, then people start to buy less of that good and more of its
substitutes.
● Income Effect- When price increases relative to income, people begin to buy
less of the good whose price has increased.
Demand function- shows the functional relationship between the quantity demanded of
a good and its price, ceteris paribus.
It is defined as: Q = f (P)
The demand function gives quantity demanded as a negative function of price. The
most widely used functional form is a linear demand curve, which is given as:
Q = a- bp Where, a is the intercept and -b is the slope (- ve).
Movement along the demand curve and shift in the demand curve
Changes in the determinants of demand cause changes in demand. These changes in
demand which result from changes in its determinants can be classified into movement
along the demand curve and shift of the demand curve.
Movement along demand curve- refers to that change in the quantity demanded of a
good because of changes in the prices of that good while other factors affecting
demand (such as price of other goods, income etc.) remaining the same (unchanged). In
this case it is the Qd that changes. This represents what is called change in quantity
demanded.
P D
P1 a
P2b
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Figure 2.3: Movement along the Demand Curve
Example 2.1
Suppose a demand function for a theater ticket is given as . If now price
changes from Birr 2 to Birr 2.50, its effect will be a decline in quantity demanded from
96 tickets to 95 tickets. On a demand curve this can be shown by a movement from
coordinate (2, 96) to coordinate (2.50, 95).
Shift in the demand curve- The demand curve is drawn on the assumption that other
things remain the same. If, however, the factors assumed constant change, their effect
would be shifting the demand curve. Shift in demand curve results from changes in one
or more of the factors that affect demand except the price of the commodity. Increase
in demand is shown by the outward shift of the demand curve whereas inward shift of
the demand curve represents decrease in demand. Eg. When income of consumers
change (positive), when price of other substitutes change (positive). Here, the demand
changes.
P1
D D1
D 2
0 Q2 Q Q1 Q
Figure 2.4: Shift of the Demand Curve
When the tastes of the people change in favor of bread, it would be reflected by an
increase in demand for bread. At every price, consumers demand a larger amount than
before. This, as shown in Figure 2.4, shifts the demand curve from D to D 1. The opposite
would have occurred if tastes change against bread, in which case there would be
decrease in demand, represented by a shift from D to D 2.
The price of related goods and services also has effect on demand depending on the
nature of the other goods. There are two classes of such goods:
Substitute goods- such goods are substitute to one another. As a result, an increase
in the price of such related goods leads to increase in demand for the other good.
Consider Pepsi Cola and Coca Cola. If the price of Coca Cola increases consumers will
shift from the consumption of Coca Cola to Pepsi Cola. This implies increase in the
price of Coca Cola results in the increase of the demand for Pepsi Cola.
Complementary goods- these are goods that are jointly consumed. As a result, a rise
in the price of one such good results in decline in demand of the other good.
Consider the case of sugar and coffee. Coffee is consumed together with sugar. Thus,
increase in the price of sugar causes decline in demand for coffee. The converse is
true for decrease in the price of sugar.
0 10 20 30 40 50Q
Figure 2.5: Supply Curve
Determinants of Supply
The supply of goods or services is affected by several factors. The factors that influence
supply include:
1. The price of the good (P).
2. The level of technology (T).
3. The price of factors of production (Pf).
4. The number of suppliers/firms (S).
5. Expectations (E).
6. Others (Weather, Price of other commodities that use the same or similar set
(bundle) of inputs: Eg. Land to use for Corn or Wheat..If E(profit) from corn is
greater than E(profit) from Wheat, we expect the supply of corn to increase,
Producer Expectations of price change).
Everything that affects supply works through one of these determinants. Supply
function is, then, defined as
Qs = f (P, T, Pf, S, E, Z)
Supply Price 0 1 2 3 4
schedule of
firm 1 Quantity 0 10 20 30 40
Supply Price 0 1 2 3 4
schedule of
firm 2 Quantity 0 15 30 45 60
Suppose in the above example, firm 1 has a larger market share and firm 2 has a
relatively lower market share. Accordingly, firm 1 has larger supply curve while firm 2
has a lower supply curve. In this case, the industry (market) supply curve is given in
Figure 2.6 below.
P S2 S1
(S1+S2)=market supply
P2
P1
0 Y
Figure 2.6: Market Supply Curve
The market supply is the horizontal summation of individual supply curves. For price
level less than P2 firm 2 supplies no output at all. As a result the market supply curve
coincides with firm 1’s supply curve. For price level less than P1 since firm 1’s level of
output is zero, market supply will also be zero. Such market supply curve is a graphical
depiction of how much will be offered for sale in the market at various prices.
In a more general case with n number of firms in the industry (market), the market
supply function S(p) is given as:
, where Si is the supply function of individual firms.
Supply Function- shows the functional relationship between price and quantity
supplied, ceteris paribus. And it is generally defined as:
Q = f (P)
The most widely used functional form is the linear supply curve, which is given as:
P2 a
0 Q 1 Q2 Quantity
Figure 2.7: Movement along the supply curve
0 Q2 Q1 Q
Figure 2.8: Shift of the supply curve
Price/kg
5.00 4 thousand excess supply S
4.00
3.00
2.00
1.00 4 thousand excess demand D
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Thousand Kg
Figure 2.9: Market Equilibrium
At a price of Birr 2.00, suppliers want to supply 4 thousand kg of coffee and demanders
want to purchase 8 thousand kg. The quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied by 4
thousand kg. This means that some consumers do not get the desired amount at price
Birr 2.00. Some of these consumers will offer more and bid the price up. As the price
rises, the quantity supplied, being a positive function of price will rise and the quantity
demanded, being a negative function of price, will fall. This will continue until the price
reaches Birr 3.00. At Birr 3.00, the amount consumers wish to purchase is exactly equal
to the amount suppliers wish to sell. This is the equilibrium price (market clearing
price). The output which corresponds to the equilibrium price is called the equilibrium
quantity.
It is important to note that the point representing equilibrium price and equilibrium
quantity is not the same thing as the point where the amount sold equals the amount
bought. Quantities bought and quantities sold are always equal. But at equilibrium the
quantity that suppliers wish to sell is exactly equal to the quantity demanders wish to
purchase, i.e., the equilibrium represents coincidence of wishes on the part of
consumers and producers.
● Excess demand causes an upward pressure on price. Thus price converges to the
equilibrium price.
● Excess supply causes a downward pressure on price. Thus, price follows a path
towards the equilibrium.
Once equilibrium is reached at the point of equality of the demand curve with the
supply curve, it remains there as long as demand and supply remain unchanged.
Numerical Approach to Equilibrium
At the equilibrium position, the demand function is exactly equal to the supply
Example: Suppose the demand and supply functions in a particular market are given as:
At equilibrium Qd = Qs
Rearranging
The equilibrium Price is, therefore, P = 15.
For any given change in demand, the change in equilibrium price is higher and the
change in equilibrium quantity is lower the steeper the supply curve (the higher the
slope of the supply curve). The converse would be true if supply curve is flatter.
P S P
P1 e1 S
P0e0 P1 e1
P0 e0
D 1
D0 D 0 D1
0 Q0 Q 1 Q 0 Q0 Q1 Q
(a) (b)
Figure 2.12: Effects of Difference in the Slope of Supply
In the figure above, the supply curve in (a) is much steeper than the supply curve in (b).
Accordingly, the resulting changes in equilibrium price and quantity for any given shift
of the demand curve are different.
Assume the changes in demand in the two cases are equal. As demand shifts from D 0 to
D 1, the changes in equilibrium price and quantity are given by (P1- P0) and (Q 1- Q0)
respectively. Yet (P1- P0) is higher in (a) than in (b), and (Q 1- Q0) is higher in (b) than in (a).
As the demand curve shifts, the change in equilibrium price is higher and the change in
equilibrium quantity is lower for the steeper supply curve than for the flatter one.
This implies, therefore, that for any given change in demand, change in price will be
higher and change in quantity lower the steeper the supply curve.
D
0 Q2 Q0 Q1 Q
Figure 2.13: Effects of Shift in Supply
The effect of such shift in supply would be decline in equilibrium price because the
increase in supply exerts downward pressure on price, and increase in equilibrium
quantity because now that the total supply at each price is higher compared to the
initial condition, producers wish to sell off their products at lower prices. Accordingly,
the equilibrium price and quantity change from P0 to P1 and from Q0to Q1 respectively.
If, on the other hand, supply decreases as given by the leftward shift of the supply curve
from S0 to S2, there will be consequent shift of the equilibrium point from e0 to e2. The
effect of such change in supply is increase in equilibrium price and fall in equilibrium
quantity because, with demand remaining the same, producers are willing to sell lower
quantities at each price. The equilibrium price and quantity change from P0 to P2 and
from Q0 to Q2 respectively.
The magnitude (size) of the changes in equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity due
to change in supply depend on:
● The size (magnitude) of supply change
● The slope (elasticity) of demand
First, let us consider changes in supply of different magnitude for any given demand
curve. Large change in supply causes large changes in equilibrium price and quantity
than a small change in supply (See the Figure below).
(a) (b)
P S0 P S0
S 1 S1
P0e0P0 e0
P1 e1
P1e1
0 Q0Q1 Q 0 Q0 Q1 Q
Figure 2.14: Shifts in Supply in Different Magnitude
In Figure above, the change in supply is large in panel (b) than in (a). Accordingly, the
changes in equilibrium price and equilibrium quantity are larger in (b) than in (a).
Now consider the effect of difference in the slope of the demand curve on the changes
in equilibrium price and quantity.
P P S0
S0 S1S1
P0e0P0 e0
P1e1P1 e1
D D
0 Q0Q1 Q 0 Q0 Q1Q
(a) (b)
Figure 2.15: Effects of Difference in the Slope of Demand
Suppose the shifts in supply in the above two diagrams are equal. For any given shift in
supply, therefore, the higher the change in equilibrium price and the lower the change
in equilibrium quantity will be, the steeper the demand curve. Demand is steeper in (b)
than in (a). Accordingly, the change in price is higher in (b) than in (a), while change in
quantity is higher in (a) than in (b).
The change in price is higher and the change in quantity is lower for the former demand
function (which is steeper) than the latter (which is flatter). Therefore, for any given
change in supply, the effect on price is higher and the effect on quantity is lower the
steeper the demand curve.
ELASTICITY
Elasticity measures the percentage point responsiveness of demand and supply to a
percentage point in any of their determinants.
The determinants of demand and supply may change for a host of reasons. In studying
the effects of factors that affect demand and supply, we are interested not only in the
direction of change but also in the magnitude of the change. With regard to price, the
slope of the demand and supply functions could be considered.
Slope = dQ/dP,
Where, dQ is the change in output and dP is the change in price.
Slope measures by how much output changes for a very small (say a unit) change in
price. In this sense, slope is a measure of responsiveness but it presents some problems.
The most important one is that the slopes of demand or supply functions depend on the
units in which price and quantity are measured. Output could be measured in units,
kilograms, litres, gallons etc while price is measured in currency units such as Birr,
Dollars etc. Therefore, slope measures certain kg per Birr, some liters per Dollar etc.
This, in turn, creates problem of comparison where responsiveness is measured in
different units. It is not possible to compare responsiveness measured as X kg/Birr with
one measured as Y pounds/Dollar.
Definition: Elasticity is a measure of the sensitivity or responsiveness of quantity
demanded or quantity supplied to changes in price (or other factors).
Elasticity measures the way one variable (dependent variable) responds to changes in
other variables (independent variables). We express the dependent variable (Y) as a
function of the independent variables (Xi) as in the following function:
Y = f(X1, X2, X3,…,Xn )
In this function, Y is given as a function of n variables. As any one of these variables (Xi)
changes, there will be consequent change in the value of Y.
The formula to determine the responsiveness of Y to changes in the Xi can be expressed
as
………..,
Price Elasticity of Demand
The price elasticity of demand () is defined to be the percentage change in quantity
demanded divided by the percentage change in price.
The sign of the elasticity of demand is generally negative, since demand curves
invariably have a negative slope. Accordingly price elasticity of demand can be stated as:
In elasticity, we consider the absolute value of the coefficients. The negative sign in
front of an elasticity coefficient indicates only that the relationship between price and
quantity demanded is negative. A demand with –2 elasticity coefficient is said to be
‘more elastic’ than the one with –1.
If a good has an elasticity of demand greater than 1 in absolute value, it is said to have
an elastic demand. Such values imply that a given percentage fall in price causes more
than proportionate rise in price.
Example
Assume that a consumer purchases 10 units of a good when price is Birr 4 and 18 units
when price falls to Birr 2. Compute price elasticity of demand.
The horizontal intercept of the demand curve will be obtained by setting P=0.
Accordingly it occurs at Q=a. The vertical intercept, on the other hand, is obtained by
setting Q=0. It is defined at P= a/b.
P
a/be =
e>1
a/2be = 1
e<1
e = 0
0 a/2 a Q
Figure 2.18: Elasticity along a Linear Demand Curve
At the horizontal intercept the price elasticity of demand is zero.
In between these two points, there must be a price-quantity combination at which price
By cross multiplication
e = 0 None Perfectly
inelastic
PD
P2
P1
0 Q1 Q
Figure 2.19: Vertical Demand Curve
If a demand curve is given by a horizontal line, which is also a limiting case, a very small
decrease in price would cause an infinite quantity of the good to be demanded. If price
rises, in contrary, the quantity of the good falls to zero. Such a curve is referred to as a
perfectly elastic demand curve.
P
P1 D
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Figure 2.20: Horizontal Demand Curve
or
In its logarithmic form, it is stated as: ln q = ln A – ln P
P
P1
P2 D
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Figure 2.21: Rectangular Hyperbola Demand Curve
The price elasticity of demand of a rectangular hyperbola is unitary throughout the
demand curve.
Price Elasticity of Demand and Total Revenue
When dealing with demand curves, the concern is with price and quantity relationships.
Quantity, or the number of items sold multiplied by price equals the total revenue
generated.
In order to see how firms set and change prices, the relationship between total revenue
and elasticity could be considered.
It is important to recognize that a price change has two opposite effects on total
revenue. The first is that a price decrease, by itself, will decrease total revenue. The
other is that with a price decrease, quantity demanded increases, thus increasing total
revenue. The net effect on total revenue depends on whether the relative price decrease
exceeds the relative increase in quantity demanded or vice versa.If demand is elastic,
fall in price causes increase in total revenue. If, on the other hand, demand is inelastic,
the effect of fall in price would be decrease in total revenue.
Price Price
P1 P1
P2 P2 D
0 Q1 Q2 Quantity 0 Q1 Q2Quantity
On both demand curves, the price falls from P1 to P2 and output increases from Q1 to Q2.
This change causes the total revenue to change. Some revenue is lost and some revenue
is gained due to the price change. In Figure 2.22 above, the lightly shaded areas
represent the revenue that has been lost and the darkly shaded areas represent revenue
that has been gained. In the case of the relatively elastic curve, panel (b) of the figure,
the decrease in price has brought about an increase in total revenue; in panel (a), the
decrease in price has brought about a decrease in total revenue.
These relationships are summarized in the table below.
Example
Price .50 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
In the table above, at a price of Birr 2.00, the total revenue (TR) is Birr 20.00. An
increase in price from Birr 2.00 to Birr 2.20 causes TR to fall from Birr 20.00 to Birr
17.60. This is because the 10 percent increase in price caused an even greater
percentage decrease in quantity demanded. The elasticity is greater than one.
Conversely, if price rises from Birr 1.00 to Birr 1.20, TR increases from Birr 20.00 to Birr
21.60 because the percentage increase in price is greater than the percentage decrease
in quantity demanded. The elasticity is less than one.
Total revenue, being the product of price and quantity, its function can be obtained by
multiplying the inverse demand function by the quantity.
Approaches to Elasticity Measurement
There are two main approaches to elasticity computation: the arc elasticity and point
elasticity. If we are measuring the elasticity between points, we are actually calculating
the average elasticity over the space between the points. This is called arc elasticity.
Elasticity between two points:
P
P1 a
P2 b
D
0 Q1 Q2 Q
Figure 2.23: Arc Elasticity
Suppose you wish to measure price elasticity of demand as price falls from P1 and P2. In
this case you are, in a way, measuring the average elasticity between point a and point b.
P
P1 a
D
0 Q1 Q
Figure 2.24: Point Elasticity
Price elasticity of demand at a particular point, such as point a, can be obtained by
multiplying the slope of the demand curve at that point by the corresponding price/
output ratio.
In this case (where the demand of a given good does not depend solely on its price), the
demand function is modified in such a way it includes the prices of related goods.
QX = f(PX, PY)
’
Where QX is the quantity demanded of good X and PY is the price of good Y.
The cross elasticity of demand coefficient may take different values depending on the
type of relationship between the two goods. If cross elasticity demand coefficient is
equal to zero, it would mean the two goods under consideration are unrelated. In this
case, any increase or decrease in price of one of the two goods has no effect on the
quantity demanded of the other good.
On the other hand, if the goods have a relationship of some sort, this value would be
different from zero. The two goods could be substitutes or complements depending on
whether the cross elasticity coefficient is positive or negative.
Definition: two goods are said to be substitutes if one good can be consumed in place
of the other. Complementary goods, in contrast, are goods that are consumed together
so that fall in consumption of one implies reduction in consumption of the other.
If the cross elasticity of demand coefficient has a positive sign it indicates that a rise in
the price of one of the two goods results in rise in the quantity demanded of the other
good. As a result the two goods are substitutes. If, however, the cross elasticity of
demand coefficient has a negative sign, it reflects that a rise in the price of one of the
goods results in decline in the demand for the other indicating that the goods are
complements.
The size (magnitude) of the cross elasticity of demand coefficient shows strength of the
substitution or complementary relationship between the goods under consideration.
i.e., the higher the value of cross elasticity, the stronger will be the degree of
substitutability or complementarity, depending on the sign.
Example: The quantity demanded of good X before change in the price of good Y was 25
units. As good Y’s price changes from Birr 5 to Birr 10, the quantity demanded of good X
has increased to 75 units.
Definition: normal goods are goods whose quantity demanded increases with rise in
consumers’ income, while inferior goods are those goods whose quantity demanded
decreases with rise in income.
The income elasticity of normal goods is positive reflecting the positive relationship
between income and quantity demanded. For inferior goods, however, income
elasticityis negative.
For normal goods, the same designation for the elasticity coefficients that is used for
price elasticity of demand can be used. If the coefficient is greater than one, I>1, the
good is income elastic, whereas if I <1, the good is said to be income inelastic.
Example
When the income of the consumer is Birr 1000, the consumer buys 100 units of a good.
If income increases to Birr 1200, the resulting quantity demanded would be 130 units.
The income elasticity demand of the consumer is given as: