SSRN Id1126088
SSRN Id1126088
by
JOHN QUIGGIN AND DAN HUNTER*
*
John Quiggin is the Australian Research Council Federation Fellow, School of Economics and
School of Political Science and International Studies, University of Queensland. Email:
[email protected]. Dan Hunter is a Professor of Law, Melbourne Law School, University of
Melbourne, Australia, and an Adjunct Associate Professor of Legal Studies, Wharton School,
University of Pennsylvania. Email: [email protected]. Order of attribution was
randomly determined. This research was supported by an Australian Research Council Federation
Fellowship for Quiggin, and by a Research Fellowship from the American Council of Learned
Societies and a grant from the Wharton–Singapore Management University Research Center for
Hunter.
203
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
I. Introduction
The statement, “it’s hard to compete with free,” encapsulates the most
important recent developments in intellectual property policy and some of
the most significant social trends of our time. The phrase was probably
first used to label music file-sharing; the apocryphal lament of an unnamed,
music-industry executive explaining why her company was doomed. The
spread of the general purpose computer and the internet removed the
barriers to easy and widespread reproduction and dissemination of music
files.1 Various pundits prophesied the death of an industry built on earlier
technological verities, that now had to compete with “free” distribution of
its own material.2 Of course, the effect of these technological changes was
not restricted to music. The concerns of the recording industry are now
mirrored in all creative industries that produce proprietary content capable
of being digitized, such as film, television, data, and text.3
Beyond this narrow interpretation, the statement also embodies a
fundamental change in the way innovation is occurring in our society. Due
to the same technological changes that are threatening the music business,
amateur production of information and innovation is on the rise. The most
obvious example is the weblog, where individuals produce vast amounts of
commentary, opinion, diary-notes, criticism, and observations, almost
always with no economic motivation.4 Other examples include citizen
journalists who produce significant newspaper reportage and opinion-
writing,5 the rise of Wikipedia6 as a meaningful alternative to commercially
produced encyclopedias, sites like Amazon,7 where consumers provide
extensive product reviews, and the free, or open source, software
movement that has produced everything from the most popular webserver
1. Doug Fine, Beyond Napster: Copyright, Fair Use and Intellectual Property Collide in
Cyberspace, STANFORD LAWYER, Summer 2001, http://www.law.stanford.edu/
publications/stanford_lawyer/issues/60/napster.html.
2. This idea is encapsulated in the catchphrase “information wants to be free,” generally
attributed to Stewart Brand. However, as Brand notes, “[o]n the one hand information wants to be
expensive, because it’s so valuable. The right information in the right place just changes your life.
On the other hand, information wants to be free, because the cost of getting it out is getting lower
and lower all the time. So you have these two fighting against each other.” STEWART BRAND,
THE MEDIA LAB: INVENTING THE FUTURE AT MIT, 202 (1987).
3. See, e.g., The Motion Picture Association of America, Anti-Piracy,
http://www.mpaa.org/piracy.asp (last visited Jan. 6, 2008).
4. USES OF BLOGS (DIGITAL FORMATIONS) (Axel Bruns and Joanne Jacobs eds., 2006).
5. See, e.g., OhmyNews, http://english.ohmynews.com/.
6. Wikipedia, Main Page, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Main_Page/; Free Software
Foundation, http://www.fsf.org (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
7. Amazon.com: Online Shopping for Electronics, Apparel, Computers, and more,
http://www.amazon.com/.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
his assistance, and leave him at liberty to divert himself with his playfellows. One of
the greatest improvements that has been made upon this machine, since it was first
invented, was in this manner the discovery of a boy who wanted to save his own
labor.”
See SMITH, supra note 16.
18. Wikipedia, Guild, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Guild (last visited Nov. 20, 2007).
19. WILLIAM HYDE PRICE, THE ENGLISH PATENTS OF MONOPOLY 5 (1913).
20. See generally KARL POLANYI, THE GREAT TRANSFORMATION 33-130 (1957)
(discussing the developing market economy of the Industrial Revolution).
21. Id.
22. BRAD DELONG, THE CIRCULAR FLOW OF ECONOMIC ACTIVITY (Apr. 9, 1998),
http://econ161.berkeley.edu/multimedia/circular.html.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
23. MARILYN WARING, COUNTING FOR NOTHING: WHAT MEN VALUE AND WHAT WOMEN
ARE WORTH (2d ed. 1999).
24. Gary Becker, THE ECONOMIC APPROACH TO HUMAN BEHAVIOR (1976).
25. See, e.g., Marilyn Manser & Murray Brown, Marriage and Household Decision-
Making: A Bargaining Analysis, 21 INT’L ECON. REV. 31 (1980).
26. KARL MARX & FRIEDRICH ENGELS, THE COMMUNIST MANIFESTO, CH 1, (Verso 2000)
(1848) (“[The bourgeoisie] has pitilessly torn asunder the motley feudal ties that bound man to his
“natural superiors”, and has left remaining no other nexus between man and man than naked self-
interest, than callous “cash payment.”).
27. Although such motives are frequently referred to in corporate public relations
publications.
28. See SMITH, supra note 16, Book I, Chapter II, I.2.2 (“It is not from the benevolence of
the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we can expect our dinner, but from their regard to their
own interest.”).
29. See generally Dan Hunter, Cyberspace as Place and the Tragedy of the Digital
Anticommons, 91 CALIF. L. REV. 439 (2003).
30. Robert Ellickson, Property in Land, 102 Yale L.J. 1315, 1367-8 (1993).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
31. Derivative markets existed long before the pre-modern period, such as in derivatives
like grain contracts, but the range and scale of derivatives expanded during the modern era, and
especially during the Twentieth Century. See generally EDWARD SWAN, BUILDING THE GLOBAL
MARKET: A 4000 YEAR HISTORY OF DERIVATIVES (2000).
32. The development of markets arose from revolutions in communication. Prices can only
be transmitted through an effective communication mechanism, so new markets emerge when
communications allow price signals to be exchanged. Until the Industrial Revolution,
communication was extremely limited, but this didn’t matter because the scale of production was
very localized and messages could pass between the necessary actors in the innovative process.
As the scale of production expanded markets emerged when effective a mechanism of
coordination/communication emerged.
33. Dan Hunter, Culture War, 83 TEX. L.REV. 1105, 1112 (2005).
34. ROBERT P. MERGES, PETER S. MENELL, & MARK A. LEMLEY, INTELLECTUAL
PROPERTY IN THE NEW TECHNOLOGICAL AGE, 20-32 (2006).
35. See Hunter, supra note 33
36. See THOMAS P. HUGHERS, AMERICAN GENESIS: A CENTURY OF INVENTION AND
TECHNOLOGICAL ENTHUSIASM, 1870-1970 (1989). For an account of the social and business role
of intellectual property (especially patents) since 1970 see Wesley M. Cohen’s and Stephen A.
Merrill’s Introduction to the book Patents in the Knowledge-Based Economy. PATENTS IN THE
KNOWLEDGE-BASED ECONOMY 1, 1–2 (Wesley M. Cohen & Stephen A. Merrill eds., 2003).
37. The intellectual property protocol to the foundational international free trade agreement,
the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, is the most compelling example of Western
governments’ reliance on intellectual property, and their efforts to entrench the system in
international trade. See Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (Apr
15, 1994) (TRIPS), reprinted in THE LEGAL TEXTS: RESULTS OF THE URUGUAY ROUND OF
MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS Annex 1C at 321-53 (Cambridge 1994). See generally
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
extended criticism, which well may be correct, but is not the focus of this
article. 49 For the purposes of this article, the expansion of intellectual
property is important only because it created the paradigm for innovation
policy in Western societies.
Capitalist societies see innovation as dependent on exclusive property
interests, and a marketplace where people can exchange these property
interests.50 We assume that it is necessary to propertize intellectual activity
if we wish to spur creativity or inventiveness. This assumption is based on
the fear that the benefits of intellectual activity will be under-produced if it
is inadequately commoditized because of public goods and free-rider
concerns. For the last two hundred years this model has produced great
social benefits51 and so we reasonably assume that new types of
innovations will conform to this model. This model of innovative activity,
however, has always under-produced innovations that have significant
value but which have not been commoditized within the intellectual
property system.52
This point has long been recognized in relation to fundamental or
“pure” research, where the link between discovery and any commercial
application is too indirect to allow propertization.53 Fundamental research
has been analyzed as a public good, that is, a good that is both non-rival
and non-excludable.54 In fact, information is the canonical example of a
non-rival good, since making information available to one person does not
reduce its availability to others. Rather, if anything, dissemination to one
person makes it more available to others. On the other hand, information in
general, is not excludable—it can be kept secret or patents and other forms
of propertization can restrict its use.55 The crucial feature of fundamental
research is that excludability is either unfeasible or undesirable.56
in mapping it. See Dennis Fernandez & Mary Chow, Intellectual Property Strategy in
Bioinformatics and Biochips, 85 J. PAT. & TRADEMARK OFF. SOC’Y 465, 467 (2003).
49. See generally LESSIG, supra note 42, at 107. By creating valuable, but time limited
property rights, and powerful interests centered on those rights, IP policy has generated a one-
way ratchet effect, reflected in widespread reference to various extensions of the term of
copyright as the “Mickey Mouse Protection Acts,” the point being that the need for an increased
term of protection is found to be most pressing whenever Mickey is nearly due to fall into the
public domain.
50. Sony Corp. of Am v. Universal City Studios, 464 U.S. 417, 429 (1984) (the Constitution
authorizes Congress to convey limited monopoly privileges “to motivate the creative activity of
authors and inventors by the provision of a special reward, and to allow the public access to the
products of their genius after the limited period of exclusive control has expired”).
51. See Arrow, supra note 15.
52. Id.
53. Id.
54. Id.
55. Id.
56. Id.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
57. Paul A. Samuelson, The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure, 36 REV. OF ECON. & STAT.
387 (1954) (provides a classic statement of this principle).
58. Id.
59. Id.
60. Id.
61. Id.
62. The typical examples of public goods are lighthouses and defense, but increasingly
information is used as a clearer, more modern example. There is evidence that lighthouses may
not always be public goods. See Ronald Coase, The Lighthouse in Economics, 17 J.L. & ECON.
357 (1974).
63. See Wikipedia, ARPANet, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/ARPANET (last visited Jan. 6,
2008).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
78. Posting entitled Field notes on the Hybrid Economy, to On the Waterfont,
http://www.americanacademy.de/home/program/on-theaterfront/blog/2007/05/07/
fieldnotes_on_the_hybrid_economy/98/detail/ (May 7, 2007).
79. See generally Dan Hunter & F. Gregory Lastowka, Amateur-to-Amateur, 46 WM. &
MARY L. REV. 951 (2004).
80. See, e.g., Matthew Sag, Piracy: Twelve Year-Olds, Grandmothers, and Other Good
Targets for the Recording Industry’s File Sharing Litigation, 4 NW. J. TECH. & INTELL. PROP.
133 (2006).
81. See, e.g., Adam Mathes, Associate Product Manager, Google Print Team, The Point of
Google Print (Oct. 19, 2005, 14:04 PST), http://googleblog.blogspot.com /2005/10/point-of-
google-print.html But see Thomas C. Rubin, Associate General Counsel for Copyright,
Trademark and Trade Secrets, Microsoft Corporation, Association of American Publishers
Annual Meeting: Searching for Principles: Online Services and Intellectual Property (March 6,
2007) (transcript available at http://www.microsoft.com/ presspass/exec/trubin/03-05-
07AmericanPublishers.mspx).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
1. The Internet
The expansion of the internet has been one of the most spectacular
technological and cultural developments humanity has ever seen. Twenty
years ago the internet was an obscure network connecting a few thousand
academics and students.82 Today it is a major feature of the lives of around
a billion people, including the majority of the population in most developed
countries.83
Much discussion of the internet is still shaped by the “dotcom” boom
of the late 1990s, in which as much as a trillion dollars was spent in the
pursuit of largely spurious projects for commercial exploitation of the
internet.84 E-commerce and the dotcom boom were a diversion from what
should be seen as the central path of internet development, in which the
crucial feature is the free sharing of information. It was the free exchange
of information that made the Internet so attractive and that led to its success
in competition both with proprietary online services, such as Delphi and
AOL, and with more tightly controlled government initiatives, such as the
X.25 protocol.85 Freely sharing information was crucial to both the design
and construction of the Internet and to the provision of useful content.
The software underlying the Internet has always relied heavily on
voluntary effort.86 The development of virtually every fundamental feature
of the network, from the basic transmission control protocols or internet
protocols (TCP/IP protocols), through low level programs that route mail
and resolve domain names, to more recent applications-level in open-
source software, has drawn on voluntary effort.87 The non-commercial,
voluntary character of the network extends beyond the infrastructure and
beyond software, and the provision of content on the network has also often
been voluntary.
Before the rise of the web the most interesting internet content was
found in the UseNet systems of newsgroups, covering almost every
imaginable topic from atheism to zoology.88 Vigorous attempts to privatize
and commercialize content were made during the “dotcom” era, with only
modest success.89 Newspapers and other mass media built up substantial
websites, attracting much attention away from Usenet and personal
websites.90 However, attempts to charge for access to such sites have had
very little success, and even reliance on advertising has proved to be
problematic.91
Since the end of the “dotcom” boom, the development of the Internet
has relied increasingly on collaborative efforts based on free sharing of
information.92 UseNet is no longer a dominant forum for discussion and
the provision of content, but not because newspapers or other commercial
sources were able to provide a better market-based service. Instead, blogs
and other amateur, collaborative content have taken the place of both
UseNet and commercial commentary. Furthermore, the range and scope of
amateur content provided for free on the web knows almost no bounds.
From the reviews of users on all manner of sites—including Amazon,
epinions.com, and rottentomatoes.com—to homework support, legal
advice, and more, the internet, combined with user donations of time and
expertise generates an enormous corpus of knowledge. Much of this
content is produced by amateurs.
87. See, e.g., Eric S. Raymond, The Cathedral and the Bazaar, FIRST MONDAY (1998)
http://www.firstmonday.org/issues/issue3_3/raymond/.
88. See Wikipedia, Usenet, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Usenet (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
89. E.g. Shirky: Fame vs. Fortune: Micropayments and Free Content (Sept. 5, 2003),
http://www.shirky.com/writings/fame_vs_fortune.html.
90. The most successful, not surprisingly, has been The New York Times. See The New York
Times, http://www.nytimes.com.
91. A notable manifestation is the development of “pop-up blockers” designed to prevent
the appearance of the most intrusive forms of advertising. Such blockers are now included in
standard browsers and operating systems.
92. See generally Quiggin, supra note 11.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
2. Open-Source Software
The rise of the Linux93 operating system has focused attention on the
idea of open-source software. In addition to Linux—which runs much of
the internet backbone and servers—important examples include the Apache
web server,94 the mySQL and myPHP database systems,95 the sendmail mail
router,96 the BIND domain name server,97 and the Firefox web browser.98
The central idea of open-source is that software is distributed free of
charge, but this is only a necessary, and not a sufficient, condition for
software to qualify as open-source.99 Users can modify open source
software as they see fit, and can choose whether to make their
modifications publicly available, but cannot charge for the use of software
derived from an open source program.100
Open-source and the Internet have something of a symbiotic
relationship. On the one hand, as noted above, most of the software
fundamental to the operation of the Internet is developed using some
variation of the open-source model.101 Moreover, the Internet as a
communications system makes it feasible to co-ordinate the efforts of
hundreds or even thousands of programmers scattered around the world,
using source code repositories such as SourceForge and Savannah.102 As a
result, tens of thousands of open source applications are currently under
development.103
The open source movement is significant to understanding amateur
content production because it demonstrates some features of amateurism
that are significant. First, the label “amateur” refers to the creators and
authors of the material, and does not preclude commercialization that may
occur outside the production of the creative work.104 So in the open source
movement many companies adopt and support open source programmers
within their own company, and generate ordinary returns on investment
from the provision of goods and services that support or rely on the open
source programmers, as discussed below.
IBM is the most obvious example. At one point it attempted to
penetrate the market for personal computer operating systems—controlled
of course by Microsoft and its Windows operating system—and failed
miserably.105 It now spends its own resources supporting the open source
Linux operating system, and sells consulting services and hardware that
rely on Linux. It claims that it has spent U.S. $1 billion on supporting
Linux106, and estimates that it earned U.S. $2 billion in server sales revenue
from that investment in 2004 alone.107 Any discussion of amateur content
production should, therefore, not assume that amateur production
necessarily precludes commercial development around the production of
the content. It simply means that the content will be generated for non-
commercial reasons.
Studies of open source development also go a long way to articulate
the myriad motivations of amateur producers. Importantly, amateur
content producers are not necessarily altruists. One could easily dismiss
the significance of amateur content by suggesting that only so many people
in the world exist who put others before themselves. The impact of people
who donate to charity, volunteer at the soup kitchens, and drive electric
cars may well be outweighed by those who are out for number one, work in
investment banking, and drive SUVs. Amateur content producers, as
exemplified by open source programmers, do not create content just for
altruistic reasons.108 Some of the reasons they do so include: (1) because
they enjoy expressing themselves, and within modern Western societies
have the leisure time to devote to self improvement; 109 (2) because of the
hope of attracting a record deal, book contract, or advertising deal;110 (3) to
prove that they are alpha computer programmers, and are more technically
savvy than the pitiful excuses for programmers who claim to be experts; 111
and (4) because they want their name to live on as a creator of their
work.112 The multiple motivations of amateur producers are significant,
because they do not fit neatly into the utilitarian calculus assumed by
economic theory. Amateur content producers are emphatically not just
utility maximizers who will start making widgets if the return on
investment for widgets is better than the return on investment for producing
content.
3. Blogs
A blog113 is a personal webpage in a journal format, with software that
automatically puts new entries (“posts”) at the top of the page, and shifts
old entries to archives after a specified period of time, or when the number
of posts becomes too large for convenient scrolling.114 Some other
elements, while not universal, are regarded by many as essential aspects of
blogging. The most important elements are facilities for readers to make
comments on individual posts and for other bloggers to link to posts with
criticism, praise, or merely to point to an interesting article. Most bloggers
also locate themselves within a larger community through the device of a
“blogroll,” that is, a sidebar with a list of permanent links to other blogs
likely to be of interest to readers.115
Although either individuals or groups can run blogs, individuals
typically provide the content.116 That is, single authors write each post and
117. Id.
118. Id.
119. Id.
120. Live Journal.com – Start a Free Blog / Journal Today, http://www.livejournal.com.
121. Instapundit.com, http://www.instapundit.com.
122. Daily Kos: State of the Nation, http://www.dailykos.com.
123. Links, rather than monetary flows, are the main currency of the blog world.
124. Sifty’s Alerts: State of the Blogosphere, October 2005 Part 1: On Blogosphere Growth,
http://www.sifry.com/alerts/archives/000343.html (Oct. 17, 2005).
125. Id.
126. These blogs are a variant of “spam” that is sometimes referred to as a “splog.”
Wikipedia, Splog, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Splog (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
4. Citizen Journalism
Citizen journalism, or “participatory journalism,” is where ordinary
people play “an active role in the process of collecting, reporting, analyzing
and disseminating news and information.”129 It is closely related to
blogging, inasmuch as the participants in the process are generally non-
professionals.130 But, unlike blogs, the emphasis in citizen journalism is on
collecting significant numbers of individuals reporting local news, rather
than on single individuals contributing opinion pieces or commentary.131
127. “The “long tail” is a term coined by Chris Anderson demonstrating a demand graph that
(broadly) follows a poisson distribution, with heavy consumer demand for a small number of
goods, and small demand for a huge number of goods. The significance of the internet is that it
allows for the provision of these poorly demanded goods in the long tail at a viable price because
there is little or no marginal difference in the cost of internet retailing for a small number of
goods as for a large number of goods. Unlike physical stores, internet stores do not have hard
limits on stocking poorly subscribed goods. Hence the internet opens up the long tail of the
poorly subscribed goods to sale and commercial usage. See Chris Anderson, The Long Tail,
WIRED, Issue 12.10, http://www.wired.com/wired/archive/12.10/tail.html.
128. CHRIS ANDERSON, THE LONG TAIL: WHY THE FUTURE OF BUSINESS IS SELLING LESS
OF MORE (2006).
129. SHAYNE BOWMAN & CHRIS WILLIS, WE MEDIA: HOW AUDIENCES ARE SHAPING THE
FUTURE OF NEWS AND INFORMATION (2003),
http://www.hypergene.net/wemedia/download/we_media.pdf.
130. AXEL BRUNS, GATEWATCHING: COLLABORATIVE ONLINE NEWS PRODUCTION (2005).
131. See Leander Kahney, Citizen Reporters Make the News, WIRED, May 17, 2003,
http://www.wired.com/news/culture/0,1284,58856,00.html; Daniel Terdiman, Open Arms for Open-Source
News, WIRED, July 22, 2004, http://www.wired.com/news/culture/0,1284,64285,00.html; Posting of Clive
Thomson to Collision Detection, http://www.collisiondetection.net/mt/ archives/000365.html#000365 (May
15, 2003, 11:55 EST).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
141. See generally Antje Gimmler, Deliberative Democracy, the Public Sphere and the
Internet. 27 PHILOSOPHY & SOCIAL CRITICISM 21 (2001).
142. See generally, DAN GILLMOR, WE THE MEDIA: GRASSROOTS JOURNALISM BY THE
PEOPLE, FOR THE PEOPLE (2004).
143. Gleenslade, http://blogs.guardian.co.uk/greenslade/2006/10/net_journalism_
rewrites_old_me.html (Oct. 16, 2006, 11:37 GMT).
144. Media in Transition, http://www.vincentmaher.com/mit/?p=4 (Feb. 2, 2006, 16:10).
145. Quiggin, supra note 11.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
Finally, the rise of the audiovisual sharing site YouTube and its
competitors demonstrates how improved bandwidth and hard disk storage
generates new opportunities in amateur production. YouTube allows users
to post their audiovisual content, whether it be amusing videos of their life,
clever animation, stupid dog tricks, or alternative videos for their latest pop
musical favorite.155 It also allows, of course, for the reposting of material
which is copyrighted to another, usually commercial, owner. The two most
interesting things of note about YouTube usage are: first, that the low
production quality of the material is not a sufficient disincentive from
widespread adoption by internet users, and, second, the way in which
sharing of information is such a formidably interesting exercise for users
that it drives the adoption of this new form of amateur production and
dissemination.
1. Motivations
A wide range of motives lead people to contribute to amateur
collaborative innovation. Possible motives include altruism, self-
expression, advocacy of particular political or social views, display of
technical expertise, and social interaction.160 Different motives will be
dominant in different situations. The first example of amateur
collaborative innovation to attract widespread attention was that of open
source software, where the “gift economy” analysis of Eric Raymond
attracted widespread attention.161 Raymond stressed the elements of
reciprocity and display of technical expertise, making the analogy of the
potlatch in which goods were ritually destroyed as a demonstration of
superabundant wealth and power.162 As will be discussed below, these
motivations are particularly relevant to software projects, but less so in
other cases.
The rise of blogs, beginning in the late 1990s, depended on a rather
different range of motivations. The originators of blogs were technically
sophisticated users similar to those involved in the open software
movement, who used blogs largely as collections of links to interesting
158. BILL IVEY and STEVEN J. TEPPER, Cultural Renaissance or Cultural Divide, The
Chronicle of Higher Education, May 19, 2006 (on file with author).
159. Morris Berman, Hegemony and the Amateur Tradition in British Science, 8 JOURNAL OF
SOCIAL HISTORY 30 (1975).
160. Lakhani & von Hippel, supra note 108.
161. Raymond, supra note 87. See also Yochai Benkler, Coase’s Penguin, or, Linux and the
Nature of the Firm, 112 YALE L.J. 369, 381-399 (2002) (examining the nature of peer production
of content in various copyright-based industries including, inter alia, software production, data
analysis, essay-writing, and commentary); Yochai Benkler, Sharing Nicely: On Shareable Goods
and the Emergence of Sharing as a Modality of Economic Production, 114 YALE L.J. 273, 325
(2004) (detailing the scale, economics, and some motivations for non-commercial production of
various types of goods).
162. Raymond, supra note 87.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
163. See generally REBECCA BLOOD, WE’VE GOT BLOG: HOW WEBLOGS ARE CHANGING
OUR CULTURE (2002).
164. Blogger was the first commercially available bloggin system. It was bought by Google
and is still available. Blogger, http://blogger.com (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
165. Id.
166. Wikipedia, Warblog, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Warblog (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
167. Id.
168. Quiggin, supra note 11.
169. USES OF BLOGS , supra note 4.
170. MySpace, http://www.myspace.com (last visited Nov. 19, 2007).
171. See LiveJournal.com, supra note 120.
172. Wikipedia, Wikipedia: About, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Wikipedia:About (last
visited Jan. 25, 2008).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
2. Mixing Motives
There are many different motives behind amateur collaboration
contributions on the internet. In general, these motives are complementary,
183. For example, consider federalism. In many federal systems, valid federal laws generally
‘crowd out’ state laws, not merely in cases where the two are directly inconsistent, but also, in
cases where federal law on a given topic preempts state law or “covers the field,” leaving no
room for the states to legislate. See, e.g., U.S. CONST., art. VI, cl 2 (“This Constitution, and the
Laws of the United States which shall be made in Pursuance thereof; and all Treaties made, or
which shall be made, under the Authority of the United States, shall be the supreme Law of the
Land; and the Judges in every State shall be bound thereby, any Thing in the Constitution or
Laws of any State to the Contrary notwithstanding.”).
184. As economists hasten to point out, the existence of gains from trade means that this does
not imply conflict between the parties to a market transaction: both can gain more than they get.
On the other hand, this doesn’t mean there isn’t conflict, for both could do better at the expense of
the other.
185. The thinking of sociologists, such as Weber, Goffman and Hirschman, can contribute a
lot to this argument. Most importantly, there is some potential for exploration of the
circumstances in which personality is role-specific in some fundamental sense, rather than in the
trivial sense where a role is defined by the performance of specific functions.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
186. Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, Book I, Chapter I opens with the example of a
pin factory, in which the simple job of making a pin is divided into eighteen distinct operations,
each the task of a dedicated specialist. SMITH, supra note 16 at 12-13. Cf. CARL MARX, The
German Ideology, in MARX-ENGLES COLLECTED WORKS, VOLUME 5 (Maurice Cornforth, et al.
eds., W. Lough trans., Lawrence & Wishart) (1845) (holding that a division of labor would
disappear under socialism: “in communist society, where nobody has one exclusive sphere of
activity but each can become accomplished in any branch he wishes, society regulates the general
production and thus makes it possible for me to do one thing today and another tomorrow, to hunt
in the morning, fish in the afternoon, rear cattle in the evening, criticize after dinner, just as I have
a mind, without ever becoming hunter, fisherman, herdsman or critic.”)
187. Neither corporations nor bureaucracies were wholly new. The scale and sophistication
of the institutions that emerged in the Nineteenth Century, however, and the scope of the
activities they undertook, was unparalleled in previous history.
188. Wikipedia, History of Software Engineering, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
History_of_software_engineering (last visited Jan. 8, 2008).
189. F.P. BROOKS, THE MYTHICAL MAN-MONTH: ESSAYS ON SOFTWARE ENGINEERING,
ANNIVERSARY EDITION (2d ed. 1995) (arguing that adding additional programmers to a project
can slow it down).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
190. F.P. Brooks, No Silver Bullet: Essence and Accidents of Software Engineering, 20
COMPUTER 10-19 (1987).
191. Id.
192. OFF. OF INT’L AFF.: NAT’L RES. COUNS., INTERNET COUNTS: MEASURING THE
IMPACTS OF THE INTERNET (1998).
193. Some tasks have been broken down to the point where they can be performed at low pay
rates on a piecework basis, as in the case of the Amazon Mechanical Turk system, where remote
workers classify photos for low rates of pay. After an initial popularity, interest in this system has
waned. Wikipedia, Amazon Mechanical Turk ,
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Amazon_Mechanical_Turk (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
194. Wikipedia, Beenz.com, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Beanz.com (last visited Jan. 8,
2008).
195. Wikipedia, Flooz.com, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Flooz (last visited Jan. 8, 2008).
196. Shirky, supra note 89.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
The only new system of payment to emerge, Paypal, has not succeeded in
displacing high-transaction cost options such as credit card payments.197
The disappearance of communication costs and the persistence of high
transaction costs associated with monetary payments the Internet has
therefore favored systems of cooperation based on voluntary, unmonitored
production over systems based on small monetary incentives.
While transaction costs failed to decrease, costs of strategic interaction
increased through large-scale commercial collaborations. The general
problem is that the value of a product is only realizable when a substantial
number of contributions are made to it, which creates a range of potential
conflicts, including hold-up problems.198 The hold-up problem arises when
a number of participants must make specific contributions to ensure that a
project succeeds. The last contributor can demand a disproportionate share
of the value of the project, with the threat of not contributing otherwise. On
the other hand, if contributions are not unique, first movers can establish
property rights and capture the entire value of the project.199 The creation
of license conditions that require free sharing, such as General Public
Licenses200 and Creative Commons Licenses, can avoid the potential for
such strategic behavior. While these licenses require that participants forgo
potential income from intellectual property in the creation of software, they
protect everyone from the risk of being required to pay for access to
projects to which they have contributed without reward.201
197. At the time of its takeover by eBay, Paypal had turnover of around $50 million per
quarter. Drew Cullen, eBay buys PayPal, THE REGISTER (July 8, 2002),
http://www.theregister.co.uk/2002/07/08/ebay_buys_paypal/.
198. See generally O.E. WILLIAMSON, MARKETS AND HIERARCHIES (1975).
199. B. Klein, R.G. Crawford, & A.A Alchian, Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and
the Competitive Contracting Process, 21 J.L. & ECON. 297 (1978).
200. The GNU General Public License, http://www.gnu.org/copyleft/gpl.htmlCC licenses at
creativecommons.org (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
201. See e.g. Creative Commons Share-Alike License 3.0:
3. License Grant. Subject to the terms and conditions of this License, Licensor hereby
grants You a worldwide, royalty-free, non-exclusive, perpetual (for the duration of the
applicable copyright) license to exercise the rights in the Work as stated below:
to Reproduce the Work, to incorporate the Work into one or more Collections, and to
Reproduce the Work as incorporated in the Collections;
to create and Reproduce Adaptations provided that any such Adaptation, including any
translation in any medium, takes reasonable steps to clearly label, demarcate or
otherwise identify that changes were made to the original Work. For example, a
translation could be marked “The original work was translated from English to
Spanish,” or a modification could indicate “The original work has been modified.”;
Open source software was the first important example of the change in
the conditions of software production. While it facilitated the production
of software, the open source movement retained, largely intact, the
distinction between producers (in this case programmers) and consumers
(computer users). Compared to traditional methods of production, the open
source approach allows for contributions from a much larger class of
computer professionals, but these still account for only a small proportion
of users.202
4. Collaboration
In contrast to [the production of commercial software?], in social
software systems such as blogs, the distinction between producers and
consumers has largely broken down. While the production of blogging
software still requires high-level technical skills, the construction of the
blogosphere is as much a social as it is a technical task. The result is that
bloggers themselves play a central role in the development of the
interlinked set of technologies and institutions that constitute the
blogosphere.203
This is not a wholly new development. A number of analysts, notably
von Hippel, have explored the idea that, to a large extent, customers drive
innovation.204 Von Hippel, however, focuses primarily on large industrial
customers of companies supplying capital goods.205 The implications of
innovation undertaken by thousands of individual users of information-
based products are more far-reaching and profound.
You may Distribute or Publicly Perform the Work only under the terms of this
License. You must include a copy of, or the Uniform Resource Identifier (URI) for,
this License with every copy of the Work You Distribute or Publicly Perform. You
may not offer or impose any terms on the Work that restrict the terms of this License
or the ability of the recipient of the Work to exercise the rights granted to that recipient
under the terms of the License.
Creative Commons Legal Code, http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/legalcode (last
visited Jan. 8, 2008).
202. For example, Firefox has hundreds of millions of users but has, at most, a few thousand
developers. See Browser Statistics, http://www.w3schools.com/browsers/browsers_stats.asp (last visited
Jan. 8, 2008); Wikipedia, Mozilla Firefox, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Firefox (last visited Jan. 8, 2008);
Wikipedia, Market Adoption of Mozilla Firefox, http://en.wikipedia.org/
wiki/Market_adoption_of_Mozilla_Firefox (last visited Jan. 8, 2008).
203. Quiggin, supra note 11.
204. ERIC VON HIPPEL, THE SOURCES OF INNOVATION (1988).
205. Id.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
Blogs provide one of the most important focal points for innovation on
the Internet. A clearer example of technological innovation driven by
blogs is that of the various versions of RSS/RDF.206 RSS is an effective
implementation of what used to be called “push technology.”207 So that
users do not need to visit their favorite sites on a bookmark list to find new
content, the sites themselves generate a short report for users that notes
recent posts and comments. A client program called an aggregator, such as
NetNewsWire, collects these reports for all the sites one may wish to
visit.208 In order for this technology to succeed, it requires a workable
underlying RSS/RDF specification, user-friendly aggregator software, and
a large enough number of sites generating RSS feeds to sustain user
interest. As a result of the time-consuming nature of blogging, blog readers
welcomed the RSS innovation, even with the rough edges that
characterized its early stages. This in turn produced pressure on bloggers
to implement RSS, and therefore, on developers of blog software to make
this as easy as possible. Once the groundwork had been laid in the
blogosphere, RSS spread rapidly. Most major news sites now offer RSS
feeds, as do web browsers like Safari and email readers like the Mac Mail
client.
RSS/RDF is also the most prominent single example of the benefits of
XML/XHTML209 over the simpler HTML, which served the World Wide
Web for its first decade.210 Progress in Web and internet technology is
driven by the most demanding users, and, increasingly, these are the
members of creative communities such as the blogosphere.211
The link between social and technological innovation in social
software systems, of which blogging is the prime example, has been so
close that it is, in many cases, impossible to assign a direction of causality.
If the blogosphere blurs the distinction between producers and
consumers, this distinction is nonexistent in Wikipedia. Apart from a
206. RSS stands for “Really Simple Syndication” or some variant of this. See Wikipedia,
RSS, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/RSS_(file_format) (last visited Jan. 25, 2008). RDF stands for
“Resource Description Framework.” See, Resource Description Framework (RDF)/W3C
Semantic Web Activity, http://www.w3.org/RDF/ (last visited Jan. 25, 2008). RSS and RDF are
both mechanisms for simply subscribing to internet sites which are updated over time.
Wikipedia, RSS, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rss (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
207. Wikipedia, Push Technology, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Push_technology (last visited
Jan. 25, 2008).
208. Wikipedia, NetNewsWire, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Netnewswire (last visited Jan.
25, 2008).
209. XML is a more general form of a markup language that allows for the inclusion of
semantic content rather than simple display markup (although it can do that as well).
210. Wikipedia, XML, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Xml (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
211. Quiggin, supra note 11.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
handful of paid staff, the project is entirely driven and designed by users.212
Among the two million registered editors, a thousand or so are
distinguished as administrators with additional powers to make structural
changes, block vandals and so on, but these are merely enthusiastic and
well-regarded users who have been nominated and approved by others. 213
Admittedly, the basic operation of Wikipedia relies on expert-written
software, most crucially on MediaWiki, a collaboratively developed214
piece of open-source software, which manages the database operations
required to manage user-generated content and make it readable.215
MediaWiki, however, merely provides a framework for a software and data
structure based on categories, templates, userboxes, and other features
which users generate without any central organization.216 More important
than any of the specific software features of either MediaWiki or its user-
generated extensions are the array of social institutions variously titled
collaborations, cabals and so on, that manage various subprojects and
determine the directions in which the project as a whole evolves. The
structure of Wikipedia emerges from the operations of these groups rather
than from any central design.
5. Conclusions
The model of productivity growth associated with the Internet is
radically different from the Twentieth Century industrial model described
above. Society’s reliance on Internet innovation and its unique
collaborative processes has reversed the flow of innovation. Instead of
being a passive recipient of innovations developed elsewhere, the
household sector, broadly defined to include all the activities undertaken by
individuals other than for pay or to produce items that can be sold or
licensed, is now the focus of some of the most significant innovations that
are taking place in society. Amateurs, rather than professionals, drive
innovation.
The crucial reason for this reversal is the reduction in communication
costs made possible by the Internet. Internet technology has reduced the
cost of freely sharing information to a level close to zero. Indeed, it is
often easier to make contributions using web-based applications, where
output is freely available by default, than to produce the same information
with a desktop application.
217. The philosophical basis for this argument is probably best articulated by the open source
and free software movement, as exemplified by the Free Software Foundation’s explanation of
that they mean by “free”: “free software is a matter of liberty, not price. To understand the
concept, you should think of free as in free speech, not as in free beer.” GNU Project, The Free
Software Definition, http://www.gnu.org/philosophy/free-sw.html (last visited Nov. 24, 2007).
218. See William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law,
18 J. LEGAL STUD. 325 (1989); Joseph P. Liu, Copyright Law’s Theory of the Consumer, 44 B.C.
L. Rev. 397 (2003) (stating that the animating theory of copyright is that “the author of a
copyrighted work is an individual who is motivated to create primarily by the hope or anticipation
of economic gain”).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
219. This issue is perhaps most obvious in the laws relating to information and in the tension
between copyright and the First Amendment, where the property interests inherent in copyright
intersects with the speech interests under the Constitution. See, e.g., Paul Goldstein, Copyright
and the First Amendment, 70 COLUM. L. REV. 983, 988-90 (1970). But see Eldred v. Ashcroft,
537 U.S. 186, 219 (2003) (“The Copyright Clause and First Amendment were adopted close in
time. This proximity indicates that, in the Framers’ view, copyright’s limited monopolies are
compatible with free speech principles. Indeed, copyright’s purpose is to promote the creation
and publication of free expression.”).
220. BENKLER, supra note 13.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
public policy is to help rather than hinder, it must be designed to take into
account the particular nature of the amateur modality.
The Sections below go on to tease-out the appropriate policy
prescriptions that emerge as a result of the unusual nature of amateur
content production. These policy prescriptions include legal regulatory
provisions, as well as a number of policies about public provision of inputs
that are necessary for the flourishing of the amateur sphere.
the organization. Similarly, a bureaucracy allows only limited scope for the
operation of such motives as desire for self-expression. A position in a
bureaucracy is a classic example of a role where the performance is
dictated by the position rather than by the player.224
Bureaucracies can be innovative, but the mode of innovation is quite
different from that of the amateur. An idealized case of a bureaucratic
innovation might begin at the bottom of the bureaucratic hierarchy, with
the observation of problems or opportunities by workers engaged in the
delivery of services. The results of these observations are then transmitted
up the hierarchy to a point where an executive decision can be made to
adopt an innovation or to engage in a research program. The outcomes of
this decision are then transmitted down the hierarchy for implementation.
Many of the major innovations of the Twentieth Century arose in this
fashion. The classic example is the Manhattan Project, which produced the
atom bomb and laid the basis for the development of nuclear power.225
More generally, a wide range of publicly funded research operates in this
fashion, with large teams of researchers operating on projects funded by
granting bodies such as the National Science Foundation.226
As Coase, Williamson, and others have pointed out, private
corporations also operate as bureaucracies.227 Within the private sector, the
decision to undertake activity within a firm, such as the production of an
input, is an alternative to market transactions or contracts with outside
parties.
229. The Role of NSF’s Support of Engineering in Enabling Technological Innovation: IV.
The Internet, http://www.sri.com/policy/csted/reports/techin/inter2.html (last visited Jan. 8,
2008).
230. For example, during the dotcom bubble Melbourne University gained $130 million from
the public offering of “Melbourne IT,” a spinoff of the university’s network and domain name
administration function. See Wikipedia, Melbourne IT,
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Melbourne_IT (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
231. Williamson, supra note 228.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
challenging, that will bring them fame, or that will solve a significant
problem for some particular group of people they want to help. They will
be less likely to work on boring tasks that improve the functioning of the
system but that do not have a big impact on anyone in particular.
Similarly, in examining a collectively produced product like
Wikipedia, poorly written passages and whole pages in need of editing are
prevalent.232 Contributors, however, mostly find line editing an
unrewarding task compared to writing new pages, adding new facts, or
correcting factual errors.233 Quite possibly the only person who will
actually notice such a contribution is the original author and they may not
be grateful. The benefit to readers from a better article may not provide
sufficient motivation. Public policy could assist in filling this gap, either
through direct provision of undersupplied Internet services, or through the
provision of funding to groups undertaking such provision, such as the
Wikimedia foundation.234
On the other hand, the analysis presented here casts doubt on the
currently popular policy of encouraging and subsidizing venture capital
enterprises. The investments encouraged by venture capitalists in the
“dotcom” era may have rewarded their promoters, but they produced little
of lasting social value, at least by comparison with the vast sums that were
invested.235
In summary, rather than seeking to drive people harder in the search
for increased productivity, government macro-economic policy should be
oriented towards making room for creativity and facilitating its expression.
Similarly, while competition has its place, public policy should be at least
as much concerned with promoting cooperation. Assumptions about the
competitive nature of innovation are, therefore, under-supported in the new
environment of today. If governments want to encourage the maximum
amount of innovation in light of amateur production then they need to de-
emphasize competition and emphasize cooperation.
C. Intellectual Property
Intellectual property law is our society’s primary legal and public
policy framework for innovation. Multiple forces—including the
expectation that commercial innovation is the only innovation that matters,
the rhetoric of property ownership, and the value of commercial content
236. See generally Hunter, supra note 33 (analyzing the intellectual property culture war
“through a Marxist lens”).
237. The role of the patent system in relation to amateur innovation and open source
production is explored generally by von Hippel. See von Hippel, supra note 71. See also Amy
Kapczynski, Samantha Chaifetz, Zachary Katz & Yochai Benkler, Addressing Global Health
Inequities: An Open Licensing Approach for University Innovations, 20 BERKELEY TECH. L.J.
1031 (2005)(a discussion of amateur innovation and pharmaceutical development).
238. The U.S. Constitution says that Congress may protect patents and copyright “[t]o
promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts,” which relies on the standard utilitarian, felicific
calculus. Standard accounts of intellectual property rely on this justification, and it has to be
conceded that this is the dominant basis for the analysis of copyright these days. See e.g. William
Fisher, Theories of Intellectual Property, in NEW ESSAYS IN THE LEGAL AND POLITICAL THEORY
OF PROPERTY 168 (Stephen R. Munzer ed. 2001); Landes, supra note 218; Liu, supra note 218 at
397 (noting that the animating theory of copyright is that “The author of a copyrighted work is an
individual who is motivated to create primarily by the hope or anticipation of economic gain.”).
Other justifications for copyright and patent exist, most notable Lockean labor-desert theory and
Hegelian personality theory, see e.g. Justin Hughes, The Philosophy of Intellectual Property, 77
GEO. L.J. 287 (1988). Neither of these appear likely to supplant utilitarianism as the primary
motivation for the grant of intellectual property rights in modern societies.
239. Hunter & Lastowka, supra note 79.
240. Id.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
241. Id.
242. Id.
243. Id.
244. Id.
245. YouTube, supra note 155; Wikipedia, supra note 6; OhMyNews, supra note 5.
246. Hunter & Lastowka, supra note 79.
247. This type of algorithm can suggest all manner of content that users might be interested
in, based on their previously expressed preferences, and is often called collaborative filtering. See
Dan Hunter, Philippic.com, 90 CALIF. L. REV. 611, 630 (2002); Hunter & Lastowka, supra note
79.
248. See Pandora, http://pandora.com.
249. See Jeff Leeds, “The New Tastemakers,” N.Y. TIMES, Sept 3, 2006,
http://www.nytimes.com/2006/09/03 /arts/music/03leed.html?th&emc=th.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
250. See, e.g., Los Angeles Times v. Free Republic, 2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 5669 (C.D. Cal.
March 31, 2000).
251. Id. at *6.
252. Id. at *29.
253. Id. at *80.
254. Id. at *30.
255. Id. at *12.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
Free Republic site had the potential to interfere with these markets.256
Emboldened by this sort of approach, other news services have recently
warned blog proprietors that they will scan for copyright infringement, and
some websites of old media moguls warn bloggers against providing
hyperlinks to their story pages.257
Free Republic highlights a problem with the cultural practice of some
types of amateur content: the blogosphere could not exist in its current,
vibrant form if copyright owners actually enforced copyright in relation to
all the millions of infringements that take place on it each day. It is not an
answer to say that copyright owners do not usually bother to sue, since this
just leads to selective enforcement and an uncertainty in the scope of
appropriate use. It would be better to establish a principle that, for
example, non-commercial use of copyright material (as on a blog or in
other amateur content forms) is not copyright infringement, in much the
same way that it is not trademark infringement to make non-commercial
use of a trademark.258
This appears to be a simple prescription, but it is likely to be
controversial.259 Amateur content is already crowding out established
copyright industries in certain content areas. Commercial newspapers, for
example, are struggling to remain relevant in an era of free news, opinion,
and comment.260 Clashes are expected, and more in the future, where the
crowding out becomes more significant.261 Until now, the Internet and
blogosphere. Whatever the outcome, it is not necessary to force material to the blogosphere,
since it already has sufficient material for a vibrant use and reuse of content.
262. As an aside, it is important to note that “fair use” defenses are not going to suffice here.
The Free Republic case squarely addressed the fair use defense and got it wrong. The widespread
re-use of entire swathes of copyright material in the blogosphere is very likely to strike a judge as
objectionable, since the concept of amateur production is not within the copyright system. Indeed,
this type of use is inimical to the copyright system.
263. See Free Software Foundation, supra note 6.
264. Dan Hunter, Digital Rights Management and Mass Amateurization, INDICARE
MONITER, May 30, 2005, at 15, available at http://www.indicare.org/tiki-
read_article.php?articleId=106.
265. See, e.g., U.S.-Australia Free Trade Agreement, U.S.-Austl., art. 17, § 9, March 3, 2004,
available at http://www.ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral/Australia_FTA/
Final_Text/Section_Index.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2008).
266. LAWRENCE LESSIG, FREE CULTURE (2004).
267. See generally Lawrence Lessig, Free Culture (2004).
268. Knud Böhle, Editorial, INDICARE MONITOR, May 30, 2005, at 2.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
D. Cultural Policy
Innovation policy is the responsibility of national sovereigns, but
increasingly it is subject to “international pressures.” The significance of
innovation and intellectual property policy to the economic strength of the
one remaining superpower means that U.S. innovation policy is
increasingly reflected in the intellectual property systems of sovereign
domestic powers. This comes about through numerous means. Perhaps the
most important is through the connection to international trade.
During the 1990s, the United States led a fundamental change in
international intellectual property policy-making—Uruguay Round of the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade included the agreement on Trade-
Related Aspects of Intellectual Property that tied domestic intellectual
property protection to international trade.272 This meant that the U.S. Trade
Representative gained the ability to strong-arm countries whose intellectual
property systems were not aligned with U.S. interests: if a country wanted
access to U.S. (and Western European) markets, then it had to toe the line
by protecting American intellectual property interests.273
This move led to the flourishing of new intellectual property
legislation and enforcement around the world, including in countries such
as China which hitherto had been unmoved by arguments that it should
protect intellectual property as a matter of its domestic interest.274
The United States also works outside of multinational agreements and
actively pursues bilateral treaties that tie even greater access to U.S.
markets with even stronger intellectual property protection.275 In a series of
271. As an aside, it is worth noting that DRM has the potential of being a notable benefit to
amateur content by providing a simple and effective way of denoting attribution interests for the
long term. We should be careful, therefore, to assume that DRM is always bad, and that
commercial use of DRM will always trend towards over-control of the content. Hunter, supra
note 264.
272. JOHN BRAITHWAITE & PETER DRAHOS, GLOBAL BUSINESS REGULATION (2000).
273. Id.
274. Peter K. Yu, From Pirates to Partners: Protecting Intellectual Property in China in the
Twenty-First Century, 50 Am. U.L.Rev 131, 133-54 (2000).
275. The problem with multilateral agreements is the difficulty in gaining support among
many nations with divergent interests, and so the provisions tend to be watered down to a level
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
bilateral Free Trade Agreements, the U.S. struck deals with a number of
countries.276 These agreements provide more open access to U.S. trade
markets in exchange, in part, for intellectual property protection that ties
the interests to U.S. innovation policy.
When selling these deals to foreign lawmakers, the U.S. intellectual
property interests—and the U.S. Trade Representative who acts as their
muscle—cannot rely on the same arguments as they might exercise back
home. Neither Singaporeans nor Australians nor even Canadians care
much about the workers in intellectual property-related jobs in Hollywood,
California, Redmond, Washington, or Blue Bell, Pennsylvania. So the
rhetoric used relies on a combination of consumer economics (“The Free
Trade Agreement means cheaper drug prices and access to new movies”) or
simplified Hegelian property theory (“This is our property and we should
be allowed to stop others from using it without reimbursement.”).277 These
arguments are hard to resist, and coupled with the threat of U.S. trade
sanctions, regularly prevail. 278
Except in one area: culture. National governments have been
successful in applying the rhetoric of cultural protection against the rhetoric
of property and commercial innovation. The best example of this is, of
course, the French. For years the French have imposed strong protection for
cultural content industries such as music, film and books.279 Complaints by
the United States over “unlevel playing fields” have fallen on deaf Gallic
ears.280
The reference to the protection of indigenous cultural industries and
local content is one of the few ways in which countries can justify
that is acceptable to all. The benefit of bilateral agreements is that regulations can be tailored to
the needs of only two parties; which in this context means that intellectual property protection
may be tailored to US needs in return for trade benefits to the other party.
276. See, e.g., U.S.-Austrailia Free Trade Agreement, U.S.-Austl., art. 17, § 9, March 3, 2004, available
at http://www.ustr.gov/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral/Australia_FTA/Final_Text/ Section_Index.html. See also
INDUSTRY FUNCTIONAL ADVISORY COMMITTEE ON INTELL. PROP. RIGHTS FOR TRADE POL’Y MATTERS,
THE U.S.-AUSTRALIA FREE TRADE AGREEMENT (FTA): THE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROVISIONS (Mar.
12 2004), available at www.ustr.gov
/assets/Trade_Agreements/Bilateral/Australia_FTA/Reports/asset_upload_file813_3398.pdf;
United States-Morocco Free Trade Agreement, U.S.-Morocco, art. 15.9, § 4, June 14, 204,
available at www.ustr.gov/assets/Trade_Agreements /Bilateral/Morocco_
FTA/Flnal_Text/asset_upload_file118_3819.pdf; United States-Singapore Free Trade Agreement,
U.S.-Sing., art. 16.7, § 2, May 6, 2003, available at www.ustr.gov/assets/Trade_
Agreements/Bilateral/Singapore_FTA /Final_Texts/asset_upload_file708_4036.pdf.
277. For an analysis of the different justifications for intellectual property protection see
Hughes, supra note 238.
278. SELL, supra note 37.
279. Alan Riding, French Film Industry Circles the Wagons, N.Y. TIMES, Sept 18, 1993,
http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9F0CE7D61139F93BA2575AC0A965958260.
280. Id.
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
amateur content is, or should be, extremely important to the large range of
counties (and smaller geographic entities like states and provinces) that are
not commercial exporters of content.
Places like Canada, Singapore and Australia will never be able to
compete with the mass media content produced by Hollywood and Britain
for English language content: the barriers to entry in broadcasting and mass
media are too high, the expertise and cost for the production are too
expensive and/or difficult to acquire, and the local markets which would
consume this content are too small to make it a commercial viable
proposition.287 The same is true for place like Quebec and Côte d’Ivoire
for francophone content; or Timor Leste for Portuguese language content,
and so on. The large and well-established content industries in these
countries have almost-unassailable leads in the creation, production and
distribution of content of mass-media products in these languages.
Little opportunity is available for smaller or less-developed countries
to develop mass-media industries that can compete in markets controlled
by these bigger players. But amateur content is produced for little cost, and
for non-commercial reasons. It does not have the same economic structure
as that which drives the mass media industry. So if these minor places
want alternatives to mass media content—and if they want alternatives
which speak to their specific interests and needs, and not the needs of
Parisiens or Los Angelenos—then they should encourage amateur content
production as a matter of local cultural policy.
Encouraging an amateur content movement therefore has important
implications for the cultural policy of numerous countries. First, it
provides opportunities for self-expression and creative self-development
for the citizens of those countries and those populations. Leaving aside
those communities which impose strong censorship obligations on their
citizens, nations have an interest in producing creative individuals who feel
empowered to express their creativity. Not only do these people produce
creative works that are socially meaningful, their presence is correlated
with improved economic activity even in non-creative arenas.288 Then
there is the issue of the audience for this creativity: nations-states clearly
have a benefit in having material which reflects the interests and needs of
its people. Obviously, in a competition over who is more likely to produce
material that reflects the national culture, and appeals to the people of, say,
Malta, Hollywood executives are going to be less interested than Maltese
amateur content producers. Therefore national regulators, who want to
V. Amateur Hour
The observation that we are living through an “information
revolution” has become a cliché, yet most discussion of this revolution
takes for granted that economic activity will go on much the same as
before, only at a more frenetic pace. The archetypal metaphor is that of
“turbocapitalism.”290 However the speed and scope of innovation being
observed now suggests that the future will reveal, not merely a quantitative
change in pace but a qualitative transformation of social and economic
institutions. The nature of such transformations prevents their
consequences from being foreseen with any accuracy, so the projections to
be considered are necessarily speculative. Nevertheless speculating about
the future, inevitably making errors, is better than moving forward into the
unknown while directing our attention backwards at the economic and
social institutions of the past.
Discussion of the Internet, and particularly the rise of amateurism, is
often Utopian. Indeed, the Internet is rather like Harry Potter’s Mirror of
289. Mark Rockwell, Muni Wi-Fi Gets Warmer, WIRELESS WEEK, April 13, 2006,
http://www.wirelessweek.com/muni-wi-fi-gets-warmer.aspx.
290. E. LUTTWAK, TURBO CAPITALISM: WINNERS AND LOSERS IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY
(1999).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
Erised, which shows the viewer whatever they most want to see.291 Among
the academics who built the Internet this was a co-operative world in which
sharing based on mutual esteem would displace the profit motive and
render large corporations obsolete. When the emergence of the World
Wide Web coincided with the 1990s stock market boom, the mirror showed
a route to instant riches, and produced the “dotcom” mania.
Now something more akin to the older vision of collaborative creation
is re-emerging. Ideas of this kind range from the relatively sober292 to the
kind of utopianism that sees its apogee in speculation about a “singularity”
that will fundamentally transform human existence.293
Focusing on the realistic end of the spectrum, the steady growth in the
volume and sophistication of highly hypertextual components of the Web,
such as blogs and wikis, is giving rise to a steady flow of innovations that
are fundamentally transforming the way in which people interact with
information. As yet, the impact of these developments is confined
primarily to early adopters in the household sector, though these already
number in the tens of millions. However, where the early adopters have
led, the mass of household users will eventually follow.
Given this broad base, predicting that the Internet will drive
productivity innovations in the business and government sector for some
years to come is safe. The crucial question is whether this kind of model
can be extended to broader ranges of social and economic activity,
particularly those involving interaction with physical goods. The ways in
which this might happen remain unclear. One possibility is through the
extension of open and programmable intelligence to household goods and
perhaps to the way in which houses themselves work. An early example is
the TiVo programmable service, the capacities of which have been
extended by “hackers” apparently with the tacit compliance of the supply
company.294
Whatever the outcome in these areas, one thing is completely clear.
Amateur production is here to stay. The significance of this has been
utterly lost on almost all areas of policy development. It is time to change
this, to respond to the enormous opportunity that amateur innovation offers.
291. J.K. ROWLING, HARRY POTTER AND THE SORCERER’S STONE 213 (paperback ed. 1999).
292. LESSIG, supra note 42.
293. RAY KURZWEIL, THE SINGULARITY IS NEAR: WHEN HUMANS TRANSCEND BIOLOGY
(2005).
294. See, e.g., Jack Keegan, “Hacking TiVo,”
http://www.keegan.org/jeff/tivo/hackingtivo.html (last visited Jan. 25, 2008) (“First of all, there
are a few definitive links that must be stated up-front. First is the TiVo Hack FAQ. Second is the
TiVo Underground forum, where all the TiVo hackers post about hacks, new releases, etc (I'm
jkeegan there). TiVo employees monitor this forum and post from time to time.”).
N_HUNTTERQUIGGIN_FINAL.DOC 2/1/2008 11:14:20 AM
***