Applied Economics IV Lecture Notes
Applied Economics IV Lecture Notes
Philipp Ager
University of Mannheim and CEPR
IV Lecture Notes
September 10, 16, 23 and 24, 2024
1 / 64
Non-technical Introduction to IV-Estimation
2 / 64
Inconsistency of OLS
y = βx + u
3 / 64
Threats to Identification
2 Reverse causality
3 Measurement error
4 / 64
Definition of an Instrument
5 / 64
Instrument Validity
6 / 64
Example
Yi = α + ρSi + γAi + ei
7 / 64
Three important causal effects
The last effect is the one we are ultimately interested in, the
returns to schooling ρ
8 / 64
Three important equations
Some “IV language” which relates to the three causal effects
of the previous slide
1 First stage: Regression of schooling on the instrument
(causal effect #1)
Si = π10 + π11 Zi + ϵ1i
These conditions are sufficient for the first stage and reduced
forms to have a causal interpretation
10 / 64
Important to know (2)
11 / 64
Linking the three equations
Yi = α + ρSi + ηi
= α + ρ[π10 + π11 Zi + ϵ1i ] + ηi
= (α + ρπ10 ) + ρπ11 Zi + (ρϵ1i + ηi )
= π20 + π21 Zi + ϵ2i
12 / 64
Indirect Least Squares (ILS)
π21
ρ=
π11
13 / 64
Two-stage Least Squares Estimation
14 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
Quarter-of-birth as instruments
15 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
16 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
Men born earlier in the calendar year tend to have lower average
schooling levels
19 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
20 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
21 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
Wald estimator: return to education is the ratio of the difference
in earnings between men born in 1st /other quarters of the
year and the corresponding difference in schooling
22 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
23 / 64
Example: Angrist and Krueger (1991, QJE)
24 / 64
Buckles and Hungerman (2013, RESTAT)
26 / 64
Recap: IV with a constant causal effect
Linear model:
Yi = α + ρDi + ηi
27 / 64
Heterogeneous Treatment Effects
28 / 64
Heterogeneous Treatment Effects
29 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (1)
30 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (2)
The sub-populations
LATE framework partitions any population with an instrument
into a set of three instrument-dependent subgroups:
Compliers: the subpopulation with D1i = 1 and D0i = 0
Always-takers: the subpopulation with D1i = D0i = 1
Never-takers: the subpopulation with D1i = D0i = 0
31 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (3)
There are four possible pairs of values (Di (0), Di (1)), given
the binary nature of the treatment and instrument
Problem: we only see the pair (Zi , Di ), not the pair (Di (0), Di (1))
32 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (4)
π0 ≡ E[D0i ]
π1i ≡ (D1i - D0i ) is the heterogeneous causal effect of the
instrument on Di
33 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (5)
34 / 64
Assumptions for Identification (1)
35 / 64
Assumptions for Identification (2)
37 / 64
Assumptions for Identification (4)
4 Monotonicity assumption
The instrument may have no effect on some people, all those
who are affected are affected in the same way
It is not the case that the instrument pushes some people
into treatment while pushing others out ⇒ no defiers
38 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (6)
Effect of Z on Y
ρIV ,LATE =
Effect of Z on D
E[Yi |Zi = 1] − E[Yi |Zi = 0]
=
E[Di |Zi = 1] − E[Di |Zi = 0]
39 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (6)
40 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (7)
41 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (8)
42 / 64
Local average treatment effects (LATE) – (9)
The key insight is that the data are informative solely about
the average effect for compliers
The data are not informative about the average effect for
never-takers because they are never seen receiving treatment
The data are also not informative about the average effect for
always-taker because they are never seen without treatment
43 / 64
Distribution of Compliance Types* (p.41)
44 / 64
Average Outcomes by Instrument and Treatment
πc πn
E[Yi |Di = 0, Zi = 0] = πc +πn · E[Y0i |c] + πc +πn · E[Y0i |n]
πc πa
E[Yi |Di = 1, Zi = 1] = πc +πa · E[Y1i |c] + πc +πa · E[Y1i |a]
45 / 64
Proportion of treated who are compliers
46 / 64
Example: Probability of Compliance
47 / 64
General Remarks (1)
48 / 64
General Remarks (2)
49 / 64
General Remarks (3)
Generalizations:
Generalization in three important ways:
Multiple instruments (e.g., a set of quarter-of-birth dummies)
Models with covariates (e.g., controls for year of birth)
Models with variable and continuous treatment intensity (e.g.,
years of schooling)
50 / 64
IV — More Applications
51 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
Devereux and Hart find modest effects for men and no positive
returns for women
52 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
53 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
54 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
55 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
Reduced-form: regresses log weekly earnings (Y ) on a
quartic function of year-of-birth (YOB) and the LAW variable
56 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
57 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
Col. 1-3 (first row): the law increased the average school
leaving age by about a half of a year
Col. 4-6 (first row): the law has a positive but insignificant
effect on weekly earnings
Col. 7-9 (first row): the 2SLS coefficients imply that one
year extra schooling increase earnings by about 2%, but
coefficients are always statistically insignificant
58 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
59 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
60 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
61 / 64
Example: Devereux and Hart (2010)
Summary
62 / 64
Pro and Cons of IV (Becker 2016)
63 / 64
Homework
64 / 64