Royal
Royal
by Gabriel M. Royal
B.S. in U.S. History & American Politics, May 2012, United States Military Academy
M.P.A. in Public Administration, May 2022, The George Washington University
A Dissertation submitted to
The Faculty of
The Columbian College of Arts and Sciences
of The George Washington University
in partial fulfillment of the requirements
for the Doctor of Philosophy
Dissertation directed by
Joseph Cordes
Professor of Economics, Public Policy and Public Administration
The Columbian College of Arts and Sciences of The George Washington University
certifies that Gabriel Michael Royal has passed the Final Examination for the degree of
Doctor of Philosophy as of March 31, 2023. This is the final and approved form of the
dissertation.
Gabriel M. Royal
ii
Abstract of Dissertation
Bitcoin still dominates the cryptocurrency space by tenure and market cap, despite its
continued reliance on PoW protocols. Where most academic work focuses on Bitcoin’s
propensity for electricity consumption, these essays examine the Bitcoin network’s
relationship with nation-state public policy. The first essay explores the governance
highlights the relevant policy implications therein. The second essay examines how the
cryptocurrency mining ban. Finally, the third essay assesses whether the economic
incentive structure built into the Bitcoin protocol can align with environmental and
energy public policy goals through an empirical analysis of mining data centers in Texas.
iii
Table of Contents
Abstract of Dissertation………………………………………………………….……...ii
Table of Contents……………………………………………………………….……….iv
List of Figures…………………………………………………………………….....……v
List of Tables……………………………………………………………………………vii
Glossary of Terms……………………………………………………………………...viii
Bibliography…..……………………………….……………………………………….196
Appendix B: : Essay 3 LMP Data Detailed Results, Tables and Figures …………..….232
iv
List of Figures
Figure 2.11 2021 Bitcoin Bull Run, China Ban, and 2022 Market Price Crash……….104
v
Figure 3.1 Notional Example of Curtailment………………………………………….133
Figure 3.2 Distance Between West Texas VRE Hubs and Metro Areas………………134
Figure 3.4 The “Duck Curve”: CAISO’s Net Load for Jan. 11, Years 2012-2020……139
Figure 3.5 Hourly Wholesale Energy Price Frequency in West Texas in 2021……….167
Figure 3.7 Example of Select Data Centers with Energy Mix Concentric Rings……...172
Figure 3.8 ERCOT Average LMP and Natural Gas Price Over Time…………………176
Figure 3.13 Average LMPs During High Demand Hours May-August ’22………...…180
Figure 3.14 Fort Stockton Electricity Use vs. LZ West Energy Prices………………..183
Figure 3.15 Fort Stockton Electricity Use vs. System Wide Demand…………………184
vi
List of Tables
Table 2.3 China and Total Network Hashrate Around the Ban…………………………94
Table 2.4 Paired two-sample t-test: Non Top-4 Mining Pool Hashrate……………….101
Table 2.9 Summary of Bitcoin Network Metric Changes Around the Ban……………115
Table 3.5 Power Plants Near Bitcoin Mining Facilities by Energy Technology ……...173
Table 3.6 Power Capacity Near Bitcoin Mining Facilities by Energy Technology...…173
vii
Glossary of Terms
transactions) that can be simultaneously used and shared within a large decentralized,
publicly accessible network. Or, the technology used to create such a database (Merriam
Webster 2011).
Central bank digital currency (CBDC): two kinds of existing central bank money are
cash and reserves held by eligible financial institutions. CBDC is “a generic term for a
third version of currency that could use an electronic record or digital token to represent
the digital form of a nation's currency. CBDC is issued and managed directly by the
(Frankenfield 2021)
finance systems through the use of blockchain-based smart contracts that are composable,
interoperable, and open source” (U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission 2021).
Distributed Ledger Technology: the protocols and supporting infrastructure that allow
computers in different locations to propose and validate transactions and update records
viii
Network Hashrate (TH/s): the amount of computing power across the network
Stablecoins: a cryptocurrency or digital asset tied to the value of a fiat currency. For
example, Tether (UST) works and transacts on a blockchain and 1 UST equals/is
Smart contracts: computer code that automatically executes all or parts of an agreement
and is stored on a blockchain-based platform. Can either be the sole manifestation of the
agreement between the parties or might complement a traditional text-based contract and
Commonly used and replicated on a blockchain, thereby benefitting from the security,
permanence and immutability that a blockchain offers (Levi et al. 2018, Harvard Law).
ix
Dissertation Series Introduction and a Brief Primer on Bitcoin
This energy is productive of wealth and is imperishable… [it] is the security upon which I
believe we can base the currency for Muscle Shoals… Under the energy currency system,
the standard would be a certain amount of energy for one hour that would be equal to $1.
- Henry Ford, 1921 (New York Tribune 1921)
In December 1921, Henry Ford toured a nitrate plant in Muscle Shoals, Alabama
with Thomas Edison and offered to pay $5 million for a 100-year lease of the plant,
existing dam, and land around Muscle Shoals. He vowed to complete a massive new
dam, creating thousands of jobs and building a ‘75-mile city’ out of a sparsely populated
bunch of farm towns (McClung 1922). But he did not stop there. His vision for Muscle
Shoals was a city where currency was based on energy, not gold. Ford believed “the
cause of all wars is gold” (New York Tribune 1921) and fixing money’s dependence on
gold would end horrific bloody conflicts like The Great War which had ended just three
years prior. Muscle Shoals would serve as a shining example of what a new national
development of “good money” and “all we can do is by some, sly roundabout way
introduce something they can’t stop” (Hayek 1984). It is unclear whether Satoshi
Nakamoto was familiar with Ford’s idea for an energy-based currency system or sought a
solution to Hayek’s problem when they developed Bitcoin in 2008.2 But they created an
1
Rather than borrowing the estimated $30 million required to complete the dam, Ford suggested the United
States Treasury pay for the dam by issuing the $30 million in currency backed by the eventual dam’s
productive capacity. Ford’s dream was not realized, facing too much political opposition to pass in the
Senate (Kazek 2013).
2
Satoshi Nakamoto is the pseudonym under which the author(s) wrote “A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash
System,” better known as the Bitcoin white paper in 2008. To this day, Nakamoto’s gender and whether
Nakamoto is/was one person or many remains a mystery. I refer to Nakamoto as “they/them” for the
1
energy-based currency designed to disintermediate third parties and remove the need for
transactions (i.e., miners) must prove to the network that they have expended
computational effort to solve an encryption.3 Miners receive rewards for solving these
algorithms and adding valid blocks of transaction data to the blockchain – a distributed
ledger (i.e., publicly available historical record) accounting for all past transactions.
Other members of the network can verify the validity of publicly broadcast transactions
and choose to reject any attempt to add an invalid block to the chain. The longest chain
serves as the majority decision of network, so bad actors risk expending computational
The more computational power dedicated to solving these algorithms, the greater
a miner’s chance of winning a block reward becomes.5 This makes cheap electricity
critical to mining economics.6 As Edison was touring Muscle Shoals, his protégé Samuel
Insull was pioneering widespread grid electrification and time of use rates; two novel
ideas which now enable low-cost Bitcoin mining in the United States (Insull 1910).
According to the Cambridge Center for Alternative Finance (CCAF), Bitcoin consumed
about 100 Terawatt Hours (TWh) in 2021, exceeding the consumption of several small
purposes of this dissertation. Hayek is not mentioned in Nakamoto’s writings, but they displayed some
understanding of Austrian economics in an online discussion forum post in 2010 (Champagne 2014).
3
For a more comprehensive review of proof-of-work, other consensus mechanisms, blockchain
functionality/design choices, and cryptography, see Wang et al. 2019.
4
Dwork and Naor (1992) effectively introduce proof-of-work cryptography as a technique to combat junk
mail. Haber and Stornetta (1991) invented blockchain as an idea for “How to Time-Stamp a Digital
Document.” Nakamoto largely combined the novel ideas of others with the invention of Bitcoin (See
Figure 1.3).
5
Miners typically organize into pools. Pools then win blocks and distribute rewards evenly according to
how much mining power individual miners contributed. See section 2.2.3.
6
An overview of Bitcoin mining economics is included in Appendix A.
2
countries and accounting for about 0.55% of global electricity production (CCAF 2022;
Carter 2021). From a normative standpoint, whether this is good use of energy is a matter
of perspective and opinion. For some, the existing financial system works well. The idea
best. At worst, it exacerbates the many threats climate change poses to the long-term
viability of human civilization on earth. For others, Bitcoin represents the manifestation
governments.
This dissertation is a series of three essays wherein normative questions about the
their implications for public policy. Bitcoin introduces a new hybrid governance structure
of decentralized human and digitally automated control, now called the decentralized
autonomous organization (DAO). The first essay defines and grounds an understanding
of this new governance structure in network theory principles from computer science,
disruption in their processes while essay 2 evaluates how successful they can be in doing
so. The second essay considers a practical example of the relationship between DAOs
and nation-state policy. For years, most of the computing power supporting the Bitcoin
3
network was based in China until it explicitly banned cryptocurrency mining in June
2021. China’s ban and a great deal of publicly available data about the Bitcoin network
provide an opportunity to study how DAOs respond to adverse policy interventions. This
essay is largely an examination of DAO adaptability and contains lessons learned for
policymakers weighing various digital asset public policy prescriptions in the United
States.
cryptocurrency mining regulation and considers where the economic incentive structure
in “proof of work” (PoW) mining clashes or aligns with energy and environmental public
policy goals in the United States. Miner migration from China contributed to the influx of
studies related to Bitcoin, energy infrastructure, and the environment shows the need for
more rigorous, empirical work on the state of Bitcoin mining to inform good policy.
Essay 3 describes the relationship between Bitcoin mining and Texas’ power grid using
data from the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) and the Energy Information
Administration (EIA).
The essays in this dissertation each make various contributions to the different
subfields of public policy. The first essay focuses on theoretical frameworks for
understanding the relationship between nation-states – created and led by humans – and
in the social sciences as a useful starting point, but also shows where new theoretical
work is needed to apply to DAOs like Bitcoin. Miners are the primary stakeholders in the
4
second and third essays, providing a look at the human aspect of the Bitcoin network and
how antagonistic or friendly state policy approaches affect their decision making.
Incorporating environmental and energy concerns into the third essay includes all of
humanity as stakeholders in the question of what to do about digital asset public policy. It
also applies the interdisciplinary lens described in the first essay in the evaluation of an
innovative energy policy approach in Texas. The methodology builds on other works in
energy economics but is novel in its empirical evaluation of the impacts of flexible loads
military leaders besieging an enemy city from different locations must figure out how to
communicate with one another by messenger to coordinate a plan of attack with traitors
in their midst. To solve the problem, these leaders need an algorithm which guarantees all
loyal generals will adopt the same, “good” plan. This allegory serves as an analogy for
fault redundancy in computer systems and several researchers have proposed proofs and
algorithms to solve it for decades (Lamport et al. 1982). It is also critical to understanding
Designing consensus algorithms with Byzantine fault tolerance has been a goal in
computer science for decades because of hacking attempts by bad actors and software
errors which commonly occur in digital information systems (Castro and Liskov 1999).
5
decentralization and still provide a myriad of economic benefits (Casey et al. 2018).7 A
desire for more participatory, network-based forms of governance has existed in America
since the early 1900s, and technology has helped flatten organizational structures and
streamline the exchanges of information and value. But DAOs represent a fundamental
shift – an attempt to build systems requiring no trusted third party or centralized authority
well to understand why people choose to opt-in to alternative forms of doing finance –
particularly when the reasons speak to a lack of trust in institutions. Essay 1 describes
Bitcoin through the lens of these DAO governance insights to discuss public policy
implications in a practical way. But a brief discussion of the history of money and digital
currency helps illuminate why Nakamoto felt Bitcoin was needed in the first place and
It is commonly accepted that money should serve three functions (St Louis Fed):
2. Unit of account: Money should provide us with a reliable way of assessing and
3. Medium of exchange: We should be able to use money in lieu of simply trading goods
7
Stablecoins and central bank digital currencies use blockchain technology to tie digital money to the value
fiat currency to capitalize on some of these benefits like cross-border payments and final settlement
efficiency.
6
allowed for evolutions in money as we strive to develop currencies which fulfill these
three functions and possess these characteristics. As the world gets “flatter” (in terms of
trade, travel, globalization etc.), the need for money which can travel quickly across
trade using some form of money going back centuries. Records show commodities priced
in salt bars in 19th century Northern Ethiopia and the practice of using salt bars as money
in the region may go as far back as before the common era. Salt bars held some form of
intrinsic value in and of themselves – almost everyone had some use for salt – but they
failed as a stable store of value since something as common as the rainy season could
effectively flood the money supply (Pankhurst 1964). Cowrie shells have little practical
value beyond the aesthetic and were used as money in Africa as a medium of exchange
between the 14th and 19th centuries (Gregory 1996). Cowrie shells were durable, portable
and functioned as a remarkably simple unit of account. But their supply was not fixed
within West Africa. Once European companies understood cowrie shells could purchase
slaves, they flooded West Africa with tens of thousands of tons of shells over a short
period of time, crippling their value and effectively ruining a key function of commerce
Gold has a few practical applications and derives some intrinsic value from its
aesthetic appeal. Its supply is not fixed, but it is very difficult to extract more. Gold
served as a reliable unit of account and medium exchange across borders for centuries.
But it is heavy, hard to transport in large quantities, and not easily divisible. Fiat currency
– particularly in digital form – suffers from less portability and divisibility challenges
7
relative to gold. But fiat currencies are effectively unlimited in supply which can factor
into inflation.8
Most of our money is deposited and digitized by commercial banks.9 But private
forms of e-money bear a striking resemblance to state bank notes in the United States
(Weber 2015). Until 1863, individual states issued their own notes and passed their own
laws governing the supervision and regulation of their state bank operations. This caused
several issues: acceptability and counterfeiting chief among them. Though Weber (2015)
notes transactions were often more efficient in this system and over issuance was rarely
an issue. M-Pesa is an early e-money success story. In Africa, mobile phone users
borderless exchanges of value with final settlement within seconds (Economist 2013).
But most forays into non-state digital cash failed due to reliance on central authorities,
slow adoption, and the inability to solve the “double-spend” problem (Gensler 2018).
Nakamoto invented neither digital cash nor blockchain (see Figure 1.3). The
novelty of Bitcoin lies in combining the two to solve for “the double-spend problem
using a peer-to-peer network” (Nakamoto 2008, 1). When defining e-money (i.e.,
ledger entry numbers effectively become the money itself. The double-spend problem
arises when payees cannot verify if their transaction involves a coin that was already
spent. Typically, this sort of digital money problem is solved by a central authority.
8
On August 15th, 1971, changing international dynamics, growing deficits and a need for inflationary US
monetary policies finally pressured Richard Nixon into suspending gold convertibility, ending the Bretton
Woods system (Bordo 2019). Bretton Woods indirectly placed major restrictions on federal government
spending. Without it, the federal government no longer had to uphold promises to convert dollars into gold
from the nation’s reserves. This effectively “untied” the U.S. dollar from something of tangible value,
established the dollar as a pure fiat currency, and allowed for potentially unlimited supply.
9
97% of money in circulation is digitized by a bank (Mookerjee 2021).
8
Instead, Nakamoto proposed a network solution with absolute transparency to avoid
financial censorship and “the arbitrary inflation risk of centrally managed currencies”
transaction off the previous one, and distributing the historical ledger, nodes can verify
energy expenditure required for miners to add blocks to the chain and Bitcoin’s block
reward provide the game theoretical incentive structure for rational network participants
to behave honestly. Lastly, Bitcoin’s inflation rate is controlled by the block reward
embedded in the Bitcoin Core software and consensus rules.11 Essay 2 explores Bitcoin’s
history as a store of value and a medium of exchange. Bitcoin is far from being used
anywhere as a unit of account.12 Still, Bitcoin’s rise in market value and user base (Figure
alternative finance.
10
When announcing version 0.3 of Bitcoin, Nakamoto said, “Escape the arbitrary inflation risk of centrally
managed currencies! Bitcoin’s total circulation is limited to 21 million coins.”
11
Nearly every four years, block rewards are cut in half until a total of 21 million Bitcoin are in circulation.
At this point, miner rewards are limited to the fees associated with processing transactions. This should
occur around the year 2140 (Khalif 2022).
12
I have found no examples of goods and/or services priced in some static amount of Bitcoin as opposed to
a dynamic BTC/USD or some other fiat-based exchange rate.
9
Essay 1
Abstract:
information are not particularly controversial, but the utility and broad applicability of
multidisciplinary literature review of network theory. I find trust (or the lack thereof)
plays a critical role in DAO network design choices (1.3), blockchain economics (1.4),
and the push away from more centralized forms of governance (1.5). Bitcoin’s inception
illustrates the role trust plays in DAO decision-making (1.7). Public policy prescriptions
for regulating or influencing DAO behavior must account for “hybrid governance,”
distinguishing between the human and digital elements of their networks. More broadly,
10
1.1 Introduction
military leaders besieging an enemy city from different locations must figure out how to
communicate with one another by messenger to coordinate a plan of attack with traitors
in their midst. To solve the problem, these leaders need an algorithm which guarantees all
loyal generals will adopt the same, “good” plan. This allegory serves as an analogy for
fault redundancy in computer systems and several researchers have proposed proofs and
algorithms to solve it for decades (Lamport et al. 1982). It is also critical to understanding
Satoshi Nakamoto’s stated intention with the invention of Bitcoin was the secure
transfer of value between two parties without the need for a trusted third-party
(Nakamoto 2008).13 They sought to solve the Byzantine General’s Problem and apply
that solution to value exchanges in the digital world rather than the exchange of
theories from a wide range of disciplines including economics, game theory mathematics,
Nakamoto’s invention is the unification and application of the novel ideas of others (see
Figure 1.3).
Any rush to answer public policy questions about what to do with cryptocurrency
without considering what ethos lies at the core of these new efforts to decentralize
finance is a missed opportunity to learn more about why people choose to opt-in to such
13
Satoshi Nakamoto is the pseudonym for the creator (or creators) of Bitcoin. Their true name and identity
is still the subject of much speculation. Hal Finney, an early pioneer of Bitcoin who corresponded with
Nakamoto frequently before Finney’s death, suspected Nakamoto was a “young man of Japanese ancestry”
(Finney 2013).
11
systems in the first place. As an asset, Bitcoin is a cryptocurrency, but its underlying
new method of organizing and operating the exchange of information and/or value within
a network where smart contracts and code eliminate the need for trust in third parties. The
This essay begins with a brief review of DAO origins and early definitions/views
of DAOs from various research perspectives (1.2). I contend that DAOs are best viewed
as networks with a new hybrid form of governance. The bulk of this paper grounds an
public administration literature. Early computer science network theory (1960s) centered
on how to communicate in the presence of faults and offers a useful framework for
understanding how DAOs utilize network distribution and automated processes for
economic research on network effects in the 1980s, and I consider how various network
effect mechanisms work within DAOs (1.4). Public administration scholars begin to give
serious consideration to governance by network outside the context of the firm during the
(1.5). Finally, I outline these DAO-specific network theory insights as they relate to
public policy (1.6) and show them at work in the Bitcoin network (1.7).
12
1.2 Origins and Early Research on Decentralized Autonomous Organizations
Five years after first offering his own formal definition for the term, Chohan
(2022) laments that DAOs still suffer from “definitional ambiguity” as the social sciences
this definitional ambiguity by reviewing the conceptual origins of the DAO (1.2.1) and
focusing on the role smart contracts play as a mechanism of governance (1.2.2). Finally,
gaps in the existing research on DAOs demonstrate the need for a unifying,
multidisciplinary framework for understanding how public policy relates to this novel
Nakamoto’s release of the Bitcoin white paper in 2008 triggered several online
discussion forum posts and e-mails between cryptography enthusiasts and Bitcoin’s core
software developers.14 In 2013, one such enthusiast named Daniel Larimer began using
source software distributed across the computers of their stakeholders” (Larimer 2013;
Hassan and DeFillipi 2021). Larimer and others effectively sought to generalize and
apply the governance structure at work in Bitcoin, namely blockchain and an open,
distributed network of users, to other organizations (Hsieh et al. 2018). They envisioned
DACs as corporations where shareholders own, run, and revenue share according to
14
These crypto enthusiasts are colloquially referred to as “cypherpunks” and they communicated with
Nakamoto on bitcointalk.org until Nakamoto’s last known communication on the forum in December 2010
(Champagne 2014).
13
applications to banking, electronic courier, venture capital, and escrow services. Vitalik
Buterin, the eventual inventor of the Ethereum network, expanded on the DAC concept in
a 2013 article in Bitcoin Magazine15 and proposes the phrase ‘decentralized autonomous
organization’ a year later as a more general and inclusive term for the use of autonomous
DAO (Larimer 2013; Buterin 2014; Hsieh et al. 2018). They envisioned DAOs with
virtually zero human control, immune to government regulation. In describing the “future
of DACs,” Larimer (2013) said “Like Bitcoin, DACs armed with a set of inviolable core
laws are far safer to deal with than corruptible human organizations… DACs don’t need
regulation, you don’t want to regulate them, and happily you can’t.”17 But DAOs are
coded and designed by humans. Human decision-making plays a role in choosing to join
or leave a DAO, and – even in Bitcoin – mechanisms exist for humans to modify core
software and change consensus rules.18 While governments may not be able to change
on-chain protocol and automated operations directly, they have several tools at their
interested in regulating DAOs (OSTP 2022) and much of the nascent DAO-related
15
Buterin is also the co-founder of Bitcoin Magazine
16
Werner Dilger, a German computer science professor, appears to be the first to use the phrase
‘decentralized autonomous organization’ in any formal or academic context. Dilger used it to describe a
theoretical system for a self-sustaining, ‘intelligent home’ of the future for a common family (Dilger 1998).
Dilger makes no mention or allusion to anything resembling blockchain technology or how we envision
DAOs today.
17
From a Larimer blogpost in 2013 on LetsTalkBitcoin.com about ‘distributed autonomous corporations’
(another early colloquial DAO variant).
18
At the time of writing, Bitcoin Core is on version 24.0.
19
The second essay in this dissertation series is about the effects of government interventions on DAOs –
specifically, the impact of the China cryptocurrency ban on the Bitcoin network.
14
literature explores this DAO-government relationship. But a consensus definition for
forms,” (Lakhani 2018, 10) but academics and outside observers have struggled to pin
down what DAO governance means and often disagree on the limits of its applicability.
Hassan and DeFillipi (2021) define a DAO as “a blockchain-based system that enables
formal definitions for DAOs mention the use of smart contracts to assign roles and
operational functions to user-members of the organization (Chohan 2022; Singh and Kim
2019; DeFilippi and Hassan 2018). Smart contracts are transaction protocol embedded in
code (Wright 2021) and changing this code requires some form of consensus among
Unlike corporations, DAOs like Bitcoin lack formal leadership and are not
registered to operate under any specific jurisdictional authority. A true DAO should have
one person or small group of persons – but the level of autonomy and decentralization
may vary (DeFillipi and Wright 2018). The use of smart contracts in organizational
processes does not necessarily constitute DAO governance. Smart contracts can simply
program functions to run when triggered by certain events or when certain conditions are
met. Krishnan (2020) described a potential use case where a user could make a payment
15
which triggers a software command to unlock a rental car’s doors. Here the use of a smart
contract does not mean we should consider the rental car company a DAO. Organizations
can use smart contracts to automate certain processes but maintain human, hierarchical
However, smart contracts can also govern the allocation of resources and control.
This application is core to DAO governance. One of the most common use cases for
smart contracts in DAOs is for tokens which are transferable and tradeable (Krishnan
2020). Users can gain decision-making power or a share of ownership in the DAO by
goal.20 In DAOs, control of such smart contracts is not owned by any one or small group
of persons but by the members of the organization. Defillipi and Wright (2018) describe a
ride-sharing use case where a DAO could replace a company like Uber. Artificial
intelligence could aid in matching drivers to users, smart contracts would handle
automatic payments from customers to drivers for services rendered, and even collect
administrative fees required to keep the DAO online. While this is entirely automated,
code could also allow for a negotiation between the driver and customer, adding an
element of human control. Furthermore, the DAO could tokenize ownership in the
organization by awarding tokens to drivers per service or in exchange for capital. Here
smart contracts effectively govern both equity within the organization and the doing of
20
Of course, this kind of structure can allow for concentration of power, so DAOs try to ensure
decentralization in various forms. Some of these approaches are discussed in detail later in this essay.
16
1.2.3 Existing Research on DAOs and Government
DAOs lack solid definition and treatment from a legal standpoint besides SEC
warnings that they can be used to offer unregistered securities illegally (Tse 2020;
Pranata and Tehrani 2022). Some DAO governance studies highlight the practical issues
associated with this legal ambiguity (Rodrigues 2018; Werbach 2018). DeFillipi and
Wright (2018) introduce the concept of lex cryptographia, or the idea that the only law
organizations like DAOs truly follow is that which is embedded in code. Combined with
lack a specific jurisdiction and any “personhood” status to grant legal rights to or hold
new institutional technology of governance” (Davidson et al. 2016, 2) and discuss the
possibility of an apolitical crypto-economy which rivals capitalism and becomes its own
formal academic discipline (Babitt and Dietz 2014; Pilkington 2015). Others see DAO
governance as best suited for smaller scale use cases like a new form of corporate
governance (Sims 2019; Kaal 2020). But skeptics see DAO governance as a solution in
search of a problem to solve, where security risks outweigh any benefits that the
democratization of finance might bring. TheDAO21 was one of the first decentralized
Morrison et al. 2020; DeFillipi and Wright 2018). The idea was for TheDAO to use smart
contracts to govern decisions ranging from “distribution and management of its $150
21
TheDAO was the name of a single decentralized autonomous organization when the concept was still
relatively new. It is italicized for emphasis so as to not confused the singular TheDAO organization with
DAOs more broadly.
17
million dollar fund, risk, residual claims, voting rights, and voting itself… achieved
through the consensus of the investing community” (Morrison et al. 2020, 1). But when
users and hackers found vulnerabilities in TheDAO code, nearly $50 million was
Some early qualitative research explores how DAOs might change various nation-
state security dynamics. Leaderless or decentralized organizations have long been topics
of interest for those studying social resistance, civil disobedience, and terrorism
(Beckstrom and Brafman 2006; Sageman 2008; Michael 2012; McFate 2018). But
Krishnan (2020) argues that adding blockchain, digital autonomy (smart contracts), and
anonymity elements seen in DAOs add a new level of evasiveness for governments
contending with social resistance and/or terrorism. The internet provided the platform for
a new kind of illicit black market called “Silk Road,” but it also enabled the FBI’s
cybercrime team to track its users and servers to usher in its eventual downfall (Kushner
2014). Krishnan (2020) outlines how a Silk Road running on DAO governance would
make it harder to shut down. Conversely, it could provide citizens with workarounds to
censorship and suppression of civil rights in totalitarian states. In three case studies in
Africa,22 Gladstein (2021) finds Bitcoin’s DAO structure helps individuals protect their
identities in anonymous exchanges of value with nothing more than a phone and internet
data. He argues this enables families living under centralized governments which brutally
punish their citizens for owning precious metals or foreign currencies the opportunity to
22
Nigeria, Sudan, and Ethiopia
18
blockchain governance in the public sector, Tan et al. (2022) find that leveraging
decisions seem highly technical (e.g., blockchain architecture, specific smart contracts)
but implementation at the macro level involves normative and subjective concerns (e.g.,
accountability, control of governance). This limits the DAO public sector use case.
Distributed ledger technology and blockchain was designed to increase trust, legitimacy,
and transparency between transactions within a system, but whether “the transaction rules
are fairly established” in the first place is “beyond the technical scope of blockchains”
(2). While citizens may feel blockchain-based government processes are more
decentralized and transparent, questions about who designs or changes the system create
a “governance paradox” where blockchain loses its value as the central party ends up in a
mitigate concerns when trust is low (Meijer and Ubacht 2018), highly automated (non-
human controlled) DAOs only risk exacerbating that lack of trust by obscuring the notion
of accountability further (Tan et al. 2022). Removing the human aspect of governance in
favor of over-automation risks missing out on the “embedded public values in public
sector organizations” (8) in the pursuit of transparency and efficiency. Public blockchains
may execute primary rules and functions well but lack secondary rules which capture the
nuance of informal social dynamics and the flexibility required in delivering most
social/public goods (Hart 1961; Simpson 2014; Yeung and Galindo 2019).23
23
Hart (1961) argues every legal system needs secondary “rules of change” which govern how primary
rules change, flex, and adapt to the needs of the governed. Simpson (2017) and Yeung and Galindo (2019)
applied this idea to blockchain based systems in the public sector.
19
1.3 DAOs: Hybrid Governance with Multidisciplinary Roots
DAOs possess both human and technical (i.e., coded, automated) elements –
policies aimed at thwarting, supporting, or regulating a DAO must consider both. Hsieh
et al. (2018) describe machine consensus as the process of enforcing smart contracts
along the blockchain through code. But “humans must first decide what protocol to run
before the machines can enforce it,” (Lopp 2016) requiring a social consensus among
DAO stakeholders. Janssen et al. (2020) suggest academia is replete with research
focusing on the technical aspects of blockchain but lacks insights concerning the
which guide and coordinate the behavior of actors and the technology” (16) within these
new organizations. Pedagogically, DAOs lie at the nexus of computer science and several
social sciences. But scholars tend to study and define DAOs only within the context of
Just as DAOs rely on hybrid governance (i.e., a mix of human and automated
control), a great deal of cross-disciplinary literature focuses on the formal and informal
forces at work in networks. ‘Network governance’ emerges as a new subfield for public
academic inquiry in the late 1990s, but pluricentric conceptualizations of public and/or
Studies of the underlying mechanisms powering network effects help explain DAO value
24
However, Reijers et al. (2021) is an excellent example of the multidisciplinary approach to understanding
on-chain governance, legal philosophy, and economist interests colliding with the advent of blockchain
governance.
20
proposition in terms of the ‘cost of trust’ (1.4). Finally, network theories in public
administration illustrate the role trust plays in decentralized authority, shedding light on
the motivations behind the creation of Bitcoin and early DAO development (1.5).
Security
Writing during the height of the Cold War, Paul Baran’s (1964) “Typology of
the terminology for network typology he offered is still commonly used today. With the
backdrop of a potential looming nuclear threat, Baran felt the existing communications
apparatus in the United States was highly vulnerable to single points of failure and attack
(Yoo 2019; Hafner and Lyon 1996). Through his work at the RAND Corporation, he
Baran made two early contributions along the path to DAO governance: 1) a
useful typology for classifying network decentralization (Figure 1.1); and 2) combining
nodes, stations and links (Baran 1964, 1). A purely centralized network has a singular
node with a link to each station. Destruction of the central node effectively kills the
many nodes each with links to stations they own and links to other nodes. Reliance on a
single link/node is not required, but attacks on single links/nodes can offline several
21
stations. The distributed network has many nodes which double as stations with links to
other nodes with double as stations. The destruction of one link may have no effect on the
overall strength of the network beyond severing one of several links between station-
nodes. The destruction of one station-node has no effect on the remaining station-nodes.
Baran said, “We will soon be living in an era in which we cannot guarantee survivability
of any single point. However, we can still design systems in which system destruction
Trust is the driving motivator in network security research. The presence of bad
systems based on this distributed network model, posing centralization as the key
network vulnerability. But his novel contention that distributed system operation must be
necessarily digital proves remarkably prescient for modern network security research
(Baran 1964, 17). Redundancy only succeeds in making networks more resilient if nodes
are “able to make independent routing decisions and reroute traffic autonomously in the
22
face of partial network failure” (Yoo 2019, 166). Today’s basic personal computing
firewalls rely on automatic algorithms and distributed network setups for digital security
(Alfaro et al. 2006), but this was a revolutionary idea in 1964 – and incredibly difficult to
pull off. In fact, Baran’s idea was never adopted by the Air Force because the Defense
communications systems and the proposal was ultimately scrapped (Abbate 1999, 21).25
cryptocurrency, and DAOs. Bitcoin was designed to operate much like Baran’s
how Bitcoin works and echoed both key features of Baran’s proposal: a distributed
network model and digital operation of the system embedded in code. Nakamoto
unwittingly) used several principles of Baran’s network typology to operate it and used
many of the same terms to describe its operation. On the very first page, Nakamoto
control more CPU power than any cooperating group of attacker nodes” (Nakamoto
2008, 1). While transactions are processed on a blockchain, its network is effectively
secured by independent operators who choose to run the code necessary to validate those
transactions. Note that these independent validators of Bitcoin’s network are commonly
referred to as “nodes,” (3) just as Baran described the operators of his communications
network.
25
Though it should be noted that frequency-hopping technology used in military radio communications
today is based on Baran’s idea for a distributed network over which transmissions can “hop” between
frequency bands several times per second according to some encoded pattern to avoid intercept.
23
1.3.2 Network Typology and Automated Security in DAO Governance Framework
various aspects of DAO governance. The words ‘decentralized’ and ‘distributed’ are
often used interchangeably, but Baran’s distinctions help clarify and distinguish key
differences between the two. The question determining the network’s classification is:
network need not share the same typology.26 Wang et al. (2019) argue an ideal DAO is
Network security (i.e., resistance to network attack) increases with its level of
decentralization, but decentralization alone cannot ensure network security without sound
cryptography and invulnerable code. Smart contract robustness must increase as DAO
network distribution increases as well. Hackers took advantage of flaws in the TheDAO’s
smart contract governance (Reijers et al. 2021). This is primarily an issue for the digital
helped enable the hack (Mark et al. 2016). TheDAO’s downfall had as much to do with
failing to account for bad faith actors within the network as flawed transaction
verification methodology did. Furthermore, its smart contracts lacked rules/methods for
dealing with such an instance (DuPont 2017). Core developers had no way of returning
26
In Bitcoin, mining pools possess disproportionate power and the costs of becoming a miner are
somewhat high, while the power of each node validating transactions is equal and the cost to run a node is
relatively low. Thus, nodes are distributed but the mining aspect more closely resembles a decentralized
network.
24
funds or rectifying the situation immediately – proposed changes required approval by
token-holder vote.27
Fully centralized systems suffer from a single point of failure at the point of
central authority (Figure 1.2). In perfectly distributed systems, each member shares equal
authority. Partially decentralized systems may have members with varying degrees of
authority or particularly high barriers to entry for prospective new members.28 Truly
decentralized systems may have actors with more power than others, but still benefit from
less exposure to the possibility that 51% of the network could fall under the control of a
bad actor (or actors) to carry out invalid transactions or act against the best interests of
27
Even in the face of obvious fraud, several discussants on TheDAO discussion forums remained wary of
centralized control. Many likened the hard fork solution core developers proposed (and which was
eventually adopted) to bank bailouts seen in the wake of the Great Recession (DuPont 2017).
28
There are a myriad of possibilities depending on DAO design but imagine if squares in Figure 1.2
represent core software developers with the sole ability to alter code and triangles own a disproportionate
amount of tokens which represent their equity in voting decisions. Additionally, the difficulty of adding a
new “dot” to the network can factor into decentralization.
25
the network.29 This affords them significant security advantages over more centralized
networks. Aside from decentralization, there are few security techniques to provide
protection against 51% attacks because of how consensus protocols are designed to work
The question determining the network’s adaptability is: what happens when a
change needs to be made? More centralized authority in the hands of fewer members of a
DAO allows them to adapt quickly to flaws in the core protocol (i.e., hacks, faults etc.).
to alter code are capable of instituting changes but are less agile in doing so.30 For this
reason, cryptographic processes and smart contract logic must be sound to protect the
integrity and security of their network since there are no elite players like a CEO to make
quick, unilateral decisions in the face of adversity. In open networks, the burden of
responsibility to evaluate the soundness of core software security protocols falls to the
user. Information asymmetries can arise when the threshold for truly understanding
From a public policy perspective, network typology speaks to how, where and to
what extent a DAO can be influenced. The digital element of a DAO network is governed
entirely by the smart contracts within the core software. Assuming no glaring security
29
A “51% attack” is different than what happened with TheDAO collapse, but they have occurred before on
several cryptocurrency blockchains. Though notably, Bitcoin has never suffered a 51% attack (Sayeed and
Gisbert 2019).
30
This refers to a network’s ability to quickly make changes to core protocol, but it is worth nothing that
adaptability can be built into core protocol. The difficulty of mining a Bitcoin adjusts over time depending
on the amount of computing power dedicated to mining across the network. This is known as a “difficulty
adjustment,” and the core software is designed to change the difficulty commensurate with a target of 10
minutes to mine each block along the chain.
31
The next section of this paper expounds upon the issue of information asymmetries in DAOs
26
consensus rules of the organization.32 Unless governments can gain enough control of
membership within the organization (e.g., acquiring voting rights), exerting pressure on
existing members may be the only way to modify core software. For example,
environmental concerns about energy use and the carbon footprint of cryptocurrencies
provide the public policy rationale for switching from proof-of-work (PoW) to a less
consensus mechanisms are embedded in core software, programmers must develop new
this point. Though Ethereum recently switched from a PoW to PoS consensus
mechanism, Bitcoin remains on its original PoW system. Understanding where a network
is truly decentralized and automated helps delineate where the digital, hard to change
aspects of DAOs end and where human control, power, and influence begins. DAOs may
be non-hierarchical but many are not entirely leaderless. For example, the Ethereum
community recognizes seven kinds of stakeholders with varying roles and responsibilities
in the governance process (Ethereum 2022).33 The barriers of entry for each kind of
stakeholder vary drastically, as does the influence they hold over the network. Since
inception, Ethereum has had a clear set of “primary core developers” followed by
“primary non-development members” (Buterin 2014) who played a critical role in two
32
In the event of fraudulent or criminal activity, government enforcement agencies often take advantage of
both an in-depth knowledge of how DAOs work and sloppiness on the part of those who try to use them
nefariously. After the Colonial Pipeline Co. paid hackers in Bitcoin in May of 2021, the FBI was able to
use Bitcoin’s public ledger to track the subsequent transactions from the hacker’s public address. The FBI
did not elaborate on how it eventually seized funds (Uberti 2021), but it is nearly impossible to crack the
“elliptic curve digital signature algorithm” cryptography protecting Bitcoin private keys. Experts suspect
“bad IT hygiene” on the part of the hackers (i.e., improperly storing private keys, transparent IP address
details etc.) (Sigalos 2021) rather than security vulnerabilities in Bitcoin’s blockchain.
33
For example, the cost of being a “node operator” is significantly lower than being a “miner/validator.”
27
hard forks of the Ethereum blockchain34 and serve as the final authority on proposed
changes to the Ethereum protocol.35 “Protocol Developers have no way to force people to
adopt network upgrades” (Ethereum 2022) but those who do not upgrade risk being left
behind.
Furthermore, Vitalik Buterin’s power and influence as the highly visible leader-
influential people” list and Forbes magazine’s “30 under 30” list. He spearheaded the
launch of, and all major subsequent changes to the Ethereum network since 2015 and
wrote a book promoting the merits of PoS-based blockchains (Buterin 2022). Bitcoin has
34
One during the aftermath of TheDAO hack, the other to move Ethereum from a proof-of-work (PoW) to
proof-of-stake (PoS) validation system
35
These changes are known as Ethereum Improvement Proposals (EIPs). The process to get an EIP from
proposal to approval is outlined on the Ethereum website.
28
leadership (Table 1.1). Bitcoin’s creator(s) released its white paper under a pseudonym,
worked to modify it for a few years, and then disappeared into obscurity (Champagne
2014). This makes it comparatively difficult to garner enough support to execute protocol
network participants they should adopt a less energy-intensive consensus mechanism like
markets with demand externalities where “benefit to a subscriber depends upon how
many of his communication partners also subscribe” (Oren and Smith 1981, 467). With a
focus on practical use cases for networks in national defense, Baran (1964) saw each
“network effect” at work where each additional subscriber-user added to the value of the
network.36 Before reaching an equilibrium or “critical mass subscription level” (Oren and
Smith 1981, 484), each additional subscriber receives more benefits than the last. Due to
the greatest example of such a product at the time (Coase 1987): if 100 people own
telephones, the value of owning their respective telephones increases when the 101st
telephone is purchased and added to the network. Critical mass points are a function of
charges) and whether the system suffers from the negative externalities of congestion at
some point (Katz and Shapiro 1985; Liebowitz and Margolis 1994).
36
Marris (1964), Artle and Averous (1973), Rohlfs (1974) also offered up models and theories of
interdependent demand for communications-type services which factored into the economics-centric
network research of the 1980s.
29
Katz and Shapiro (1985) expanded this analysis beyond monopolistic
communications networks. Much like Oren and Smith (1981) they defined positive
consumption externalities as “products for which the utility that a user derives from
consumption of the good increases with the number of other agents consuming the good”
(Katz and Shapiro 1985, 424) and use telephone networks as the primary example. But
telephones were a bit too simplistic to capture all the dynamics at play. They felt that
the benefit of simply adding another hardware computer to a network. Incentives lead to
the creation of new programs and software to run on computers and increase their
functionality further.
1992). But unlike the monopolistic view of the telephone, firms compete in these other
markets, and Katz and Shapiro developed a model to capture the dynamics of competition
in markets with positive consumption externalities. They conclude public policy would
have to consider both protecting firms’ technological innovations while ensuring healthy
competition between firms. Societal pareto optimality must take both static efficiency
(improving existing products) and dynamic efficiency (developing new products) under
“costs of compatibility” (439) and adaptability to protect the firm’s intellectual property
37
Perhaps an overly simplistic example of this can be seen with the popularity of Apple’s iPhone. They are
allowed to change the kind of charger used in newer models of their phones, despite some cost of
compatibility/adaptability to the consumer. However, Apple’s entitlement to ownership of several design
30
Their work in this field expanded well beyond their initial model. Katz and
Shapiro led a symposium for studies of network effects, or the broader economics
surrounding systems where component parts are complementary and boost value when
combined. Scholars of network effects found market competition between such systems
was different than with individual products in three important ways (Katz and Shapiro
1994). First, expectations really matter; and studying expectations in the context of
network effects opens new opportunities to examine the consumer’s ability to make
willingness to pay for a network effect product is not just based on its immediate utility,
paradigm) and who else may buy it in the future. Similarly, coordination matters. If the
internet is the software which makes the hardware of a computer more valuable, much of
that potential value is tied to expectations that others will collaborate, share ideas, and
boost collective human capital. Finally, compatibility is an issue where many scholars
expanded upon Katz and Shapiro’s (1985) earlier work summarized above. How do
consumers evaluate the cost of technology adoption, or choose between two rival
incompatible systems (Katz and Shapiro 1994)? They found that imperfect competition,
some market inefficiencies where “it is theoretically possible for government intervention
to improve market performance” (112) as not all network effects are necessarily positive
network externalities.38 Incumbent firms benefit from network effects, naturally seek to
elements of smartphones has been contested in court for decades and several antitrust suits continue for the
country’s largest corporation.
38
Katz and Shapiro ultimately admitted they were far away “from having a general theory of when
government intervention is preferable to the unregulated market outcome” (113).
31
box out potential rivals and also possess certain rights in protecting their intellectual
property.
economists considered the roles social dynamics play in firms. Though commonly
associated with public management today, ‘network governance’ originated as the study
scholars in the 1990s. They sought to distinguish behavior within and between firms
(Ring and de Ven 1992; Larson 1992; Kreiner and Schultz 1993; Jones et al. 1997) from
previously dominated the field of economics (Richardson 1972). Coase (1937) and Simon
(1962; 1985) provided early inspiration for economists to consider firms separate from
their component parts. Firms form to limit transaction costs independent persons would
face in the absence of cooperation (Coase 1937) and maximize different individual
competencies (Simon 1962). But Simon (1985) implored the field to expand studies of
economic cooperation by considering a “view of the nature of the human beings whose
behavior we are studying” as “fundamental in setting… and informing our research” (77).
Such studies in the 1980s and 90s were dubbed the interdisciplinary field of “new
NIE birthed two concepts critical to understanding why firms work as a method of
dynamics play a role in each. The study of transaction costs was not new to the field, but
39
In an essay on transaction cost economics, Williamson (1979) first mentioned “new institutional
economics” in 1979, but expounded on the origins and development of NIE as a wide movement in
economics in 1998 (Williamson 1998).
32
Oliver Williamson was the first to define (1979) and advocate for TCE as a method of
studying organizations with transaction costs as the basic unit of analysis (Williamson
1981; 1986). His theory expanded upon the Coase Theorem (1937) in suggesting that
1981, 559) and the optimal organizational form should seek to minimize transaction
costs.40 By joining individuals together in pursuit of a common goal, firms may reduce
incentives for opportunism (Provan and Gassenheimer 1994) and try to replace it with
interfirm trust instead (Noteboom 1996). Williamson (1998, 2000) distinguishes between
governance structures suffice for “ideal” transactions in law and economics (Williamson
1998). Ideal transactions utilize general purpose technologies and require no safeguards
between parties whose identities are irrelevant (Macneil 1978). As transactions utilizing
special purpose technology increase in their complexity, more safeguards are required.
Contractual safeguards leverage penalties built into contract language to deter contractual
are so complex they require organization “under unified ownership within hierarchy,”
TCE was widely considered the branch of NIE concerned with firm governance
and predictive behavior (Williamson 1998), but Jones et al. (1997) were among the first
to incorporate both TCE and social network theory into a framework for identifying when
and how network governance works (913). TCE logic informs when network governance
may emerge: when problems are complex, requiring adaptation, coordination, and
safeguarding exchanges more efficiently; and when other modes of organizing (market
40
TCE is critical to understanding the economic benefits of vertical integration (Levy 1985).
33
and hierarchical) are at a competitive disadvantage (917). A network governance
structure can reduce the cost of trust in transactions by bringing transactions within the
firm. Entire industries revolve around profiting off a lack of trust between parties (e.g.,
contract law) and reducing the cost of trust is a key component of TCE literature
Still, trust issues exist within firms as well (Mellinger 1956). Participative
management styles and democratic organizations were found to increase trust among firm
1990s as the social mechanism by which intrafirm trust could be built. Embeddedness
stems from the idea that transactions have a human, relational component (Granovetter
1985) and that repeated positive exchanges generate trust (Buskens 1998). Jones et al.
(1997) saw embeddedness as the connective tissue between social network theory and
defined by how many mutual contracts (“third” parties) are linked indirectly. The level of
another, how likely future interactions are among participants, and how likely
participants are to talk about these interactions” (924). This incentivizes the diffusion of
and safeguards exchanges within the network. Even something like “negative gossip” can
considered interfirm patterns of social behavior and the economic outcomes that result
34
Table 1.2. Economic Network Theory and DAO Concepts
Foundations Economic Concept DAO Concept Public Policy Implications
Network Effects: Competition concerns; encourage positive
Demand Externality (Positive) externalities vs. discourage natural monopolistic
Communications Network
(Oren and Smith 1981) Value co-creation (Yang 2021) tendency
Theory:
Capacity Limits/congestion (Negative) Digital platform governance tradeoffs
Typology (Baran 1964)
(Katz and Shapiro 1985; Liebowitz and (McIntyre 2017; Chen and Patel 2021) intergenerational rivalry, compatibility (Katz
Externalities and Pricing (Squire
Margolis 1994) Blockchain Trilemma and Shapiro 1992; Farrell and Saloner 1986)
1973; Littlechild 1975)
Positive Consumption Externalities (Buterin 2017; Abadi and Brunnermeier
Value increase with new subscribers
(Katz and Shapiro 1985) 2018) users value shared responsibility and
(Artle and Averous 1975)
hardware-software paradgm (Church and ownership in decentralized ecosystems (Yang
Gandal 1992) 2021); public admin. implications
transaction transparency; public blockchain
Distributed Ledger Technology transaction broadcasting
(Swanson 2014; Davidson et al. 2019; Sims
Transaction Cost Economics 2019) semantically-defined contract advantage;
Theory/Nature of the Firm
(Williamson 1975; 1981; 1998) Transparency; Information Diffusion smart contract inflexibility may induce transaction
(Coase 1937)
Embeddedness (Nakamoto 2008) costs; DAO use case limitations
Complex hierarchical systems (Simon
(Granovetter 1985; 1992; Williamson 1994) Blockchain (Sklaroff 2017; Meunier and Zhao 2019; Murray
1962)
Embeddedness in Network Effects (Haber and Stornetta 1991) et al. 2021)
Human psychology in economics
(Uzzi 1996; 1997; Dnyawali and Madhavan DAC/DAO "bootstrapping"
(Simon 1985)
2001; Simsek et al. 2003) (Larimer 2013; Buterin 2013; 2014) minimize cost of trust in traditional finance
"cost of networking" (Catalini and Gans (Chiles and Macklin 1996; Casey et al. 2018)
2016)
information asymmetries for DAO participants
smart contracts (Chohan 2017; 2022;
Network Governance (Jones et al. 1997) Singh and Kim 2019; DeFillipi and Hassan
semantic gaps (Wang et al. 2019)
Macroculture (Camerer & Verpsalainen 2018; Wright 2021)
New Institutional Economics
1988)
(NIE): TCE, Embeddedness practical governance issues; lack of flexibility in
opportunism (Provan and Gassenheimer consensus rules (Dwivedi et al. 2021)
DAO gov. (Dupont 2017)
1994; Noteboom 1996)
open source software collaboration
1.4.3 TCE, Structural Embeddedness and Network Effects in the DAO Framework
The previous section of this paper poses trust as a main factor in DAO network
compromised central authority. In economics, the idea that individuals might seek their
(Williamson 1993). The psychology of trust for economic agents (Ho 2021) and
essential to economics. Public blockchain-based DAOs seek to mitigate this cost of trust
by relying on a new kind of transparent, distributed ledger to verify ownership and past
transactions without the need for the type of centralized authority which makes
35
In an op-ed on distributed ledgers and blockchain technology, a group of
prominent regulators and digital currency educators including Gary Gensler, Chair of the
Securities and Exchange Commission, said “We believe this technology could reduce the
ingrained ‘cost of trust’ that currently adds friction to commerce and enriches trust-
intermediating gatekeepers across the economy” (Narula et al. 2018). But they questioned
the long-term fate and value proposition of decentralized systems. Catalini and Gans
(2016) contend the true economic innovation in blockchain technology, DAOs, and
cryptocurrency lies in the shift away from centralization. They showed how several
verification,” as embedding incentives and governance rules into protocol reduce the
(Catalini and Gans 2016). Still, the field lacks empirical studies comparing the
performing the same functions. Permissionless networks without centralized control and
self-contained incentive systems do not operate without costs and fees. There is
tremendous value to be gained from exploring where human action and centralization
The substitution of code for the human element of organizational power and
process is the central difference between DAOs and firms relying on network
bureaucratic structures within firms and formal contractual relationships between them”
(911). Relationships are often informal and “based on implicit and open-ended contracts”
36
(914) and eventually lead to a “macroculture" of shared values and knowledge
autonomous parties” (Jones et al. 1997, 930) who tacitly understand the unwritten rules
which benefit the organization (Camerer & Vepsalainen 1988; Williamson 1991).
firms as “autonomous” and adaptable, just as DAOs strive to be. But the major difference
between DAO and network governance lies in that DAOs effectively try to formally
embed what is informal in network governance using smart contracts. When “code is
law” (lex cryptographia) and the code is vulnerable, DAO members protected by
(Camerer & Verpsalainen 1988), but when “code is law,” the potential exists for
“semantic gaps” (Wang et al. 2019, 876) between the code written in smart contracts and
intended organizational rules. Here, DAO governance suffers from a lack of flexibility
governance.
This lack of flexibility plays into the transaction cost economics of DAOs. Recall
that TCE works along a continuum of contractual complexity (Williamson 1998). DAOs
smart contracts can govern both simple transactions (e.g., “A” send value to “B”) and
complex ones (e.g., ownership rights) using special purpose technology (e.g., blockchain,
distributed ledgers, cryptography). DAOs also utilize various incentive structures to deter
bad actors from violating consensus rules rather than relying on unified ownership. For
37
example, Bitcoin miners who attempt to add an invalid block to the chain risk receiving
no block reward for the work (energy) expended. Thus, the TCE at work in DAO
DAOs attempt to do the same through the public transparency and cryptographic
enforcement of their distributed ledgers (Swanson 2015; Davidson et al. 2019; Sims
2019). In fact, Catalini and Gans (2016) claim DAOs provide lower authentication costs
1981).41 But others argue that smart contract inflexibility creates transaction costs relative
to traditional, semantically-defined contracts (Sklaroff 2017; Murray et al. 2021). For this
reason, Meunier and Zhao-Meunier (2019) specify simple, natively digital transactions as
the best use case for DAOs seeking to avoid the need for a trusted third party in the
process.
different than the embeddedness at work in traditional conceptions of the firm. Most
framework (Jones et al. 1997) does not apply in the context of a DAO. Granovetter
is “the degree to which exchange parties consider one another’s needs and goals” (Jones
et al. 1997, 922) and the behaviors they exhibit as a result (e.g., information sharing)
(Uzzi 1996). Blockchain and distributed ledger technologies are based on information
41
Again, empirical studies comparing the transaction and administrative costs of DAOs and firms are
needed to substantiate these claims.
38
diffusion through transaction transparency, but the impacts of what limited social
interactions occur between DAO participants is unknown. DAO message boards and
instant messaging social platforms (e.g., Discord, Reddit) certainly provide platforms for
the sharing of ideas and open-source software.42 However, consensus rules written into
core software (e.g., proof-of-work, proof-of-stake) are what tie DAO network
Recall that structural embeddedness is the extent to which two parties have
mutual contacts – and share information about those mutual contacts. Structural
governance (Moody and White 2003), but information diffusion and transparency are
core to the blockchain and distributed ledger aspects of any DAO (Nakamoto 2008;
Swanson 2014; Pilkington 2015; Davidson et al. 2019).43 In this sense, the digital aspect
of DAO governance is quite literally structurally embedded into its code while the human
aspect is more akin to whatever relational embeddedness results from discourse between
network participants.
networks (Oren and Smith 1981). Whether designed to exchange value (e.g.,
cryptocurrency), pool capital (e.g., The LAO) or support online gaming (e.g.,
42
Returning to an earlier example, Ethereum encourages R&D discussions, publishing research and even
runs a “Core Developer Apprenticeship Program”
43
Distributed ledger technology (DLT) refers to the system by which information and/or transactions are
recorded across geographic space simultaneously. Public blockchains use DLTs and make all information
contained them within publicly available – serving as a sort of consensus historical record.
39
GameDAO),44 DAOs get better as more users are added to the network until reaching
externalities are present, Katz and Shapiro (1992) raised the potential for issues of
intergenerational rivalry when “an older technology with an installed base competes
against a newer technology lacking such a base” (57). Policies involving licensing
compatibility, so the market is not biased for or against certain products and technologies
(Farrell and Saloner 1986). Models exist for determining whether existing incentives “to
adopt a new technology are socially excessive or insufficient” (Katz and Shapiro 1992,
56) (Farrell and Saloner 1986), but no such models and studies exist specific to DAO
may result in significantly different rates of financial technological adoption across age
Existing research touts the advantages decentralized governance enjoys over more
centralized platforms thanks to network effects. Chen et al. (2021) find sharing
responsibilities, rights and control with participants causes them to act in the interests of
the overall network and attracts more participants. Yang (2021) adopts a view of DAOs
participation in different layers or subsystems of the network may vary, but they each
(short-term, long-term profits, and value exchange respectively) but each new miner,
44
The LAO is a venture capital DAO designed to be compliant with U.S. law (similar to crowdfunding).
GameDAO provides a platform for users to play in games designed by others or design their own.
40
investor, and user added serves to push the network towards the benefits of further
distribution.
Shapiro 1994) in DAOs abound. The degree to which regulators should try to protect
consumers from themselves – particularly when DAOs involve the exchange of fiat
currency for tokens – is up for debate. But what is clear is that few people possess the
requisite knowledge to read code and comprehend the smart contracts running these
discourage the natural monopolistic position of the network. Lack of recognized legal
status and DAO ownership play a confounding role amidst antitrust concerns (DeFillippi
and Wright 2018). Developers create inherently open-source software in the public
domain – unlike in other markets, there is nothing proprietary about DAO code.
Conversely, this also allows for anyone to create competing DAOs at any time.
However, network effects have natural negative externalities which may mediate
such policy concerns as well. Capacity limits may result in crowding and congestion
within the network as additional participants are added (Katz and Shapiro 1985;
based systems must also reach a saturation point where additional user-members reduce
41
The advent of blockchain-based systems leads to theoretical debates about a
“Blockchain Trilemma.”45 Buterin (2017) claims blockchains can possess only two of
point to their scalability problem (Croman et al. 2016). Because cryptocurrencies operate
on decentralized networks and exchanges of value require high security, their efficiency
methods (i.e., credit cards).46 Assuming the trilemma holds, any secure DAO must also
be limited in scalability. Thus, DAOs processing high amounts of data should reach some
capacity where they suffer the same negative externalities (i.e., congestion) as seen in
other networks (Katz and Shapiro 1985; Liebowitz and Margolis 1994) unless they
has been engaged in a near-constant state of critical self-examination. One topic of debate
is whether practitioners and scholars of public administration are too far removed from
those whom government is meant to serve. So far, this paper has explored network
theories and their derivatives to describe how, why, and when DAOs work and the
resulting public policy implications therein. This section explores why people find
45
Brewer’s (2000) “CAP” theorem stated that shared data systems could only possess two of three
properties simultaneously: consistency, availability, and tolerance to network partitions. 45 Distributed
databases would tradeoff between consistency and network partitions while forfeiting availability (Brewer
2000).45
46
Several studies explore how to solve scalability issues (Kim et al. 2018; Zhou et al. 2020) and even
suggest the Blockchain Trilemma is already obsolete due to new innovations in blockchain technology. I
discuss one such innovation later in the discussion about Bitcoin.
42
resemble desires for more participatory, representative, and decentralized provisions of
public services.
1.5.1 Polycentricity
With the help of Charles Tiebout, Vincent and Elinor Ostrom developed and
popularized the concept of polycentric governance in political economics from the 1960s
through the early 2000s. As economists developed theories of TCE, network effects, and
political economy scholars developed governance theories through the lens of public
finance. Economists considered the merits of socialism (Mises 1922; Lange 1938) in the
wake of stark class divisions, economic depression, and a World War. Polanyi (1951)
first used the term ‘polycentricity’ to describe a system in which individuals possess
some autonomy in decision-making within a larger rules-based order, and their decisions
impact or “adjust” the decision-making calculus of other individuals (Carlisle and Gruby
2019).47 For Polanyi, socialists erred in thinking central planning could reach Pareto
observation that metropolitan governments benefit from multiple independent (and often
al. 1961). Since metropolitan areas are home to a variety of stakeholders with different
needs, public goods are more efficiently produced and distributed “at different levels of
special aggregation” (Stephan et al. 2019, 21). These political units often compete with
one another and “enter into various contractual and cooperative undertakings or have
47
Polanyi saw analyzing polycentric tasks and problems economically in the aggregate as useful but using
aggregate economic ‘science’ to understand the decision-making causes and/or motivation behind
individual actions was presumptuous and ultimately dangerous to human liberty.
43
recourse to central mechanisms to resolve conflicts” (Ostrom et al. 1961, 831) that make
their patterns and behavior quite predictable. This theoretical work is supported by
metropolitan areas over more centralized local governments (Ishak 1972; Ostrom et al.
1973; Ostrom et al. 1973; Rogers and Lipsey 1974; Ostrom and Whitaker 1974; Ostrom
neighborhoods” (Ostrom 2010, 644) and no evidence was found to support widely held
In the Ostrom view, trust plays “the central role in coping with” and “overcoming
social dilemmas” (Ostrom 2010, 662) when perfectly rational individuals should expect
selfishness which precludes them from any ability to solve problems collectively without
a government presiding over the administration of maximum social welfare (Loomes and
Sugden 1986). Citing the failures of several highly centralized governments in preserving
common resources (e.g., climate, oceans), Dietz et al. (2003) touted the benefits of
participants in these microsituations build trust that others will reciprocate and cooperate,
resulting in net benefits for all despite incomplete information regarding future events
(Poteete et al. 2010). Decentralized governance is complex, but not necessarily chaotic
44
(Andersson and Ostrom 2008) in the delivery of public goods and services. It serves as a
remedy for the otherwise helplessly trapped individual in the rational model (Ostrom
2010).
ubiquity of internet access transformed communication, space, and time so that cities
with once easily defined borders now looked like functional metropolitan regions
focused on the flow of people and information between centers rather than municipal
government or the physical structures of where people reside (Parr 2005; 2007; Hall and
Pain 2006; Hall 2009). Scholars questioned whether urban government was too narrow a
lens through which to view a phenomenon which could refer to any multimodal human
activity (Kloosterman and Musterd 2001). Others questioned the mechanisms by which
polycentricity worked, emphasizing the need for firm definitions for the functional
linkages between nodes and sub-centers (Green 2007; Vasansen 2012). For this subset of
researchers, trust is rarely mentioned as a mechanism for polycentric success. Like the
transport infrastructure serve as remedies for the problems of geographic space and
from various academic disciplines, particularly during the 1990s. Jones et al. (1997)
synthesized TCE and social networking theories (e.g., embeddedness) into an economic-
45
specific framework for network governance as sociologists declared the rise of a new
network society (Castells 1996; van Dijk 1999). Social networks used micro-electronics
to process information within the network, giving people access to a diverse set of
information. O’Toole (1997) recognized the network concept taking hold in business,
nonprofit, and some governmental sectors and implored public administration to pursue
world it seeks to operate in and points out mismatches between the administrator and
Provan and Milward (1995) were among the first to offer a theory of network
networks. However, in Provan’s most recent work on the topic of network stability, his
conclusions were modified slightly. Provan and Lemaire (2012) stated the limited
Provan and Milward (2001) still viewed principal-agent theory as a useful lens
or client, the effectiveness of the network depends entirely upon the “level” of network
46
(2001) review relevant research about the intersection of network theory and the public
public network management and come to a different conclusion. The concept of network
social capital (O’Toole 1995; Fountain 1998) and conceptions of accountability are often
ambiguous (O’Toole 1997). For Agranoff and McGuire, this diminishes the applicability
(2001) find social capital, shared learning, and negotiation are the ingredients which
made up the concept of groupware: the synergistic effects associated with group tasks
(Agranoff and McGuire 2001). Public administration scholars differ on the role trust
plays in building social capital and the power it holds in network governance. Clegg and
Hardy (1996) referred to a “façade of trust,” (679) where “power over” remains just as
powerful in policy networks as “power to.” Others argued trust is required in any public
network – even centralized ones – due to the nature and fundamental importance of the
problems public networks try to solve (Moynihan 2009). Provan and Kenis (2007)
framed trust in a more nuanced light with their discussion of ‘trust density,’ contrasting
dyadic trust with the kind of “dense web of trust-based ties” (238) which enables shared
governance within networks. They argued network governance can still be effective in
47
the presence of low-density trust provided participants believe collaboration to be
beneficial.
resources (Howell et al. 2019; Tan et al. 2022). Well-designed DAOs take the
motivations, roles, and responsibilities of various network actors and stakeholders into
governments appear less suited to solve the increasingly complex problems of a diverse
polity (Sorensen 2002; Goldsmith and Eggers 2004; Eggers and O’Leary 2009; Sorensen
and Torfing 2015). Just as technological advances changed how people and information
move across geographic space and created new functional metropolitan sub-regions
(Castells 1996), it now enables the borderless and permissionless transfer of information
and/or value in DAOs. Still, DAOs suffer constant failures in the trial and error of this
new form of organization just as Sorensen and Torfing (2015) saw “inherent risks and
While decentralizing the provision of public goods may have benefits, public
governance. Fung and Wright (2003) warned explicitly against radical “demands for
their government might alleviate the tensions between the governed and their
government. Sorensen and Torfing (2005) found network self-governance fails without
some form of regulating ‘meta-governance,’ but the push for inclusion in democratic
processes is natural and healthy. Like Crawford and Ostrom (2005), Sorensen and
48
Torfing (2005) posed meta-governance as setting the conditions (i.e., incentives, identity
development, shared values) for trust building and reinforcing norms. Pure self-regulating
governance networks like DAOs could “lead to the atomization and fragmentation of
institutional structure for incorporating the best parts of network governance into a new
political institutions that allegedly govern society top-down” (Sorensen and Torfing
2005, 200). But decentralizing government is radically different than replacing its
functions entirely with automation. Early DAO enthusiasts sought to eliminate the need
services (Larimer 2013). DAOs attempt to engrain all governance functions into a
environments that are highly dependent on these values” (3). In the disintermediation of
trust, blockchain technology lowers the level of control any single actor or institution has
over a DAO’s processes. Trust lies in the fidelity of the transaction rather than in third
different sense than the way it is described in building social capital in network
governance (Sorensen and Torfing 2005). The aim of DAO governance is to use
49
technology to develop systems in which participants can be indifferent to intra-network
trust. “The DAO represents a new species of governance characterized by the alienation
of trust from the ownership and control of the organization” (Morrison et al. 2020, 12).
(Tummers and Knies, 2016), DAOs turn the democratic concept of ownership and
accountability on its head. DAO membership may constitute some level of equity in the
DAOs, network governance, and the push for government decentralization share a
authority away from the state towards local or self-governance could delegitimize the
democracy” (696). New questions emerge about the decision-making competence of “the
people” and how the sovereign citizen might engage in decision-making processes.
Sorensen’s questions about where sovereignty lies relative to “the people” echoes
a trend seen across public management and public administration scholarship at the turn
of the 21st century. Denhardt and Denhardt (2000) famously asked, “In our rush to steer,
are we forgetting who owns the boat?” (549) in reference to the analogy of how to best
row and steer government with a renewed focus on a more involved democratic polity.
50
McSwite (1997) re-examined the historical discourse around the Anti-Federalist spirit
and recasts the American origin story as one where colonists wanted a personal, heuristic
central bank. Bitcoin was born out of the Great Recession and a desire for a peer-to-peer
(Nakamoto 2008).48 More faith is placed in “the people” or the member-nodes ability to
understand and take ownership of their own governance and responsibilities. As open
inclusion (Vincent and Evans 2019), censorship resistance and increased privacy
(Catalini and Gans 2019). But technological utopianism in American society historically
lacks practical solutions to social problems (Segal 1985). Atzori (2015) argued DAOs can
enable the very fragmentation Sorensen and Torfing (2005) warned about. Rather than
(Crawford and Ostrom 2005) over-decentralizing governance now risks having the
opposite effect. Society risks the “regression of human communities into a pre-political
condition” (Atzori 2015, 25) not unlike “Hobbesian deregulated landscapes” (Marden
DAO governance:
48
Bitcoin’s founding is examined in detail in the next section
51
1) DAOs vary in design but possess both a human and digital element. Digital decision-
making is ruled by the base DAO core software. But this code is designed and often
changed by various human stakeholders. Understanding the hybrid nature of each DAO –
where digital control stops and human control and/or influence begins – is critical to
crafting effective policy. Unilateral policies mandating changes to core features of a well-
participants to avoid single points of failure. DAOs often consist of various kinds of
stakeholders with varying degrees of power and influence over the network. In this sense,
there are varying degrees of decentralization between and within DAOs. While increased
network distribution among those with decision-making power may provide better
defense against bad actors, it requires broader consensus in changing core software. As a
result, we can conclude highly distributed networks may suffer from a lack of
adaptability (absent any automated adaptability built into base code). Additionally, the
ability to read and understand code and smart contract logic presents information
asymmetry issues.
3) Because increased distribution adds an element of security, DAOs benefit from the
networks. At some saturation point, we can expect capacity limits and congestion to cap
DAO scalability.
4) DAOs try to formally embed informal social systems found in network governance
using smart contracts (the ‘embeddedness’ concept literally embedded into code).
52
Distributed ledgers and blockchain can reduce the cost of trust in TCE. But they may also
suffer from a lack of flexibility and are better suited for uncomplicated tasks and
processes.
5) Trust is a key concept in both DAO and network governance. Public administration
has been frustrated by the question of how to develop effective and inclusive forms of
governance for years to build trust with citizens. DAOs seek to form systems in which
DAO design choices can largely be seen as trust tradeoffs between human influence
These insights can help analysts and policymakers better understand how DAOs
work in relation to nation-state governments. In this section, I apply the lessons drawn
from this review of network theory to Bitcoin to distill broad conclusions about DAO
governance into specific policy applications for the world’s original DAO and most
popular cryptocurrency. Nakamoto invented neither digital cash nor blockchain. In fact,
Bitcoin’s novelty comes from combining and applying several academic concepts listed
in Figure 1.3 to the transfer of value. Social science theories on decentralization and
network organization guide the incentive structure built into Bitcoin to keep various
money informed the creation of the digitally automated portion of Bitcoin’s hybrid
governance (1.7.1). Baran’s network typology can be applied to classify different aspects
53
of the Bitcoin network (1.7.2). I then demonstrate how network effects (1.7.3),
Nakamoto’s white paper (2008) references and applies Haber and Stornetta’s (1991;
1993; 1997) work on using linked digital timestamping for document certification to form
the basis for Bitcoin’s blockchain. The idea for requiring computer effort to validate
transactions came from Hashcash, an idea for combatting junk mail (Dwork and Naor
1993; Back 1997; 2002). A digital stamp in the header of an email requiring computing
time and effort to obtain prior to sending would signal that the sender was unlikely to be
a spammer. Bitcoin combines these two ideas so that transactions are recorded on
timestamped blocks and PoW is required to solve for a block’s nonce (an arbitrary
number used only once) and earn the block reward. Changing transactions within a block
would require attackers to commit more computer power to re-do the work, and each
block is deterministic from the last. This combination of ideas distinguished Bitcoin from
previous attempts at electronic money which failed to solve the double-spend problem
(Figure 1.3).
49
A full and in-depth explanation of PoW cryptography, SHA-256 hashing algorithms etc. is outside the
scope of this essay but is summarized rather succinctly in the Bitcoin white paper (Nakamoto 2008).
54
Figure 1.3 Academic and Technological Inspirations for Bitcoin (author)
There are several stakeholders within the human element of Bitcoin’s governance
(Table 1.1). Some individuals simply choose to hold Bitcoin as an investor or transact in
it. Miners conduct the PoW algorithm hashing to compete for block rewards and process
transactions in the process. Other network participants run independent nodes capable of
broadcasting and confirming the validity of other transactions. Each node holds the
distributed ledger’s history of transactions. They help secure the network by adhering to
55
the consensus rules; validating and blocks and transactions within blocks. rejecting
invalid transactions. Programmers can code and propose changes to the Bitcoin Core
software. These core developers submit bitcoin improvement protocols (BIPs) and review
the proposals of others. Miners signal support for BIPs by adding a certain digit visible in
blocks along the chain. An even smaller group operating on the software repository are
known as ‘maintainers’ with authorization authority to merge new code with Bitcoin
Core. Nodes then choose whether to update to new software depending on if they agree
From a public policy perspective, Bitcoin’s popularity and the mining incentives
built into Bitcoin’s core protocol are lucrative enough to motivate thousands of miners to
expend massive amounts of energy to mint new coins. Approximately 105 TWh of
electricity was expended to mine Bitcoin in 2021 (CBECI 2022), equal to roughly 2.6%
of total electricity consumption in the United States for the year (EIA 2022). This energy
consumption is a top concern for the environmentally conscious. But the PoW aspect of
above.
second largest cryptocurrency by market cap, recently switched from PoW to a less
merge”), but we should not expect a similar push in the Bitcoin network. In 2017,
concerns about Bitcoin’s scalability and processing speed caused some to call for an
50
If nodes opt not to upgrade, the blockchain effectively splits into two systems operating in parallel. This
is called a “fork” and is covered in some limited detail with the discussion of Bitcoin Cash.
56
increase in block size (Bier 2021). On one side of the debate, originalists felt Bitcoin
should emphasize a high degree of security with low barriers to entry for miners and node
operators to serve as the best store of value. On the other, supporters of what would
become “Bitcoin Cash” felt larger block sizes posed negligible risks to network security
agreement could be reached, dissenters “hard forked” the blockchain into Bitcoin Cash
(Bier 2021).
Bitcoin Cash is still active today, though the original Bitcoin is far more relevant
in terms of active users and market cap. Originalists won the “block wars” – a clear
triumph for those who valued maximum competition among miners and decentralized
governance over scalability. Bitcoiners have similar concerns about moving away from
PoW. Some argue Ethereum’s new proof-of-stake model centralizes power in the hands
of the largest miners (Koss 2022). LeClair and Rule (2022) take issue with reliance on
“social governance” to deter bad actors rather than the “economic incentives and real-
world physical constraints” found in PoW. While the Ethereum merge proves there is
consensus protocols, environmentalist groups have been unsuccessful thus far in gaining
Miners organize into pools and are compensated based on how much
using a secure hash algorithm. For this reason, blocks are typically won by pools, not
individual miners. Additionally, the barrier to entry to mining is quite high. Mining is
57
expensive in terms of hardware and electricity costs. So, while individual miners may
resemble a distributed network, the advent of pools makes the overall mining network
look decentralized with certain stations possessing more power than others.51
Running a full node is relatively cheap and each node possesses equal power to
validate transactions.52 There are approximately 15,000 reachable nodes in the Bitcoin
network, with no more than 11% of nodes located in a single country (Bitnodes 2022).
programmers and core software maintainers represent are a much more centralized
network, the consensus required from a decentralized network of miners to signal support
for protocol changes followed by actual adoption of new protocol software by this highly
distributed network of nodes make effecting major changes to core code very difficult.
1.7.3.1 Users
demonstrates positive demand externalities (i.e., network externalities) due to the utility
gains they enjoy from each user added to their networks (Van Hove 1999). The number
of Bitcoin users is hard to pin down since wallet addresses are anonymous and there is no
limit to how many addresses a single individual can have. But the number of wallet
51
Currently, no single mining pool controls more than 22% of total network hashrate. This is covered in
more detail in the second essay in this dissertation series. Because of fears of a 51% attack, historically
miners have left large mining pools as they approach 50% of Bitcoin mining power (Hajdarbegovic 2014).
52
Full node hardware costs between $300 and $400. It then consumes no more energy than a personal
computer would. Amazon’s AWS Marketplace estimates approximately $0.24/hour to run a Bitcoin full
node.
58
addresses and changes in the wealth distribution of the asset across those addresses can
give us an indication of whether the Bitcoin network is truly benefitting from demand
externalities (Figure 1.4). Over the last ten years, the number of overall active Bitcoin
addresses has steadily risen along with the proportion of low balance holders (<1.0 BTC).
Transactions between addresses indicate whether holders are using Bitcoin as a medium
of exchange. As of January 2023, the network processes roughly six times as many
The usage of Bitcoin as a payment system on the base layer is still a long way
away from all-time highs in December 2017 (Figure 1.5), but it may have something to
do with the advent of Bitcoin’s ‘layer 2’ protocol, better known as the ‘Lightning
Network.’ The Lightning Network was invented to solve Bitcoin’s scalability problem
micropayment channels between users to facilitate payments and unburden the main
blockchain (Poon and Dryja 2016).53 Because these transactions occur off-chain, reliable
data on exactly how many transactions occur is hard to approximate. One study estimates
over 120,000 payment channels opened between January 2018 and July 2019 (Lin et al.
2020), which would help explain the drop in visible, on-chain transactions since 2018.
53
A full explanation of the Lightning Network is outside the scope of this essay, but users effectively
transfer Bitcoin locked up on the base layer to Lightning wallets and conduct peer to peer transactions on
layer 2. They can close these two-way micropayment contracts and transfer their funds back to the base
layer whenever they choose. Since lightning network transactions occur between two known parties on
their own private channel, they are not broadcast to the entire network and settle nearly instantaneously
without the need for energy-intensive PoW protocol.
59
Figure 1.4 Bitcoin Addresses by Balance (author)54
Figure 1.5 Bitcoin Transactions per Second (14-day moving average) (author)55
1.7.3.3 Miners
mining/securing the network, has steadily increased despite major downward asset price
movement in recent years (Figure 1.6). This signals some degree of bullishness among
miners even in the face of lower profits. High hashrate makes executing an attack on the
54
Data sourced from CoinMetrics
55
Data sourced from CoinMetrics
60
network very difficult and expensive to pull off, so additional mining power coming
online effectively adds network security and increases the asset’s fundamental value
proposition. Competition among miners drives innovation to develop the most efficient
1.7.3.4 Adoption
compatibility with vendors and widespread adoption by institutional players (Van Hove
1999). Just as in communications products, e-money can reach a critical mass where the
2021 was a significant year for institutional Bitcoin adoption. 14 publicly traded
companies ended the year with over 1000 BTC on their balance sheet (Radmilac 2022),
including Microstrategy and Tesla. Liberty Mutual Insurance (NYDIG 2021) and Fidelity
Investments (Tellez 2021) invested in Bitcoin mining and technology companies. Visa
56
Data sourced from CoinMetrics
61
rolled out several cryptocurrency-related products and reported $2.5 billion in payments
by customers with “crypto-linked cards” in the first quarter of 2022 (Holland 2022).
Still, there is a big difference between customers using such cards to pay U.S.
dollars for products at a vendor to get cash back in Bitcoin and paying the vendor in
Bitcoin. More research is needed to show how the rate of institutional adoption of
electronic money products. From the standpoint of individual users and miners, Bitcoin’s
adoption rate appears to be growing despite a massive drop in market price. Despite
several hard forks, competing cryptocurrencies, and some policies aimed at curtailing
Bitcoin mining and adoption (e.g., China’s cryptocurrency ban), Bitcoin appears to be
benefitting from the positive externalities of network effects in several ways. Among
U.S. adults, major discrepancies for cryptocurrency adoption exist across age and gender
(Faverio and Massarat 2022).57 Assuming adoption continues at the same pace, social
inefficiencies (i.e., the differences between marginal social and private costs and benefits)
are sure to arise with Bitcoin and any PoW-based cryptocurrency due to the negative
As with any DAO, the cost of trust between parties in a Bitcoin transaction is not
related to embeddedness in the traditional social network theory sense. Bitcoiners and
other crypto enthusiasts are a very active subculture on online forums and social media
platforms. Empirically based research examining who typically uses and/or supports
Bitcoin is lacking, but one study finds higher rates of Bitcoin use in nation-states with
57
Surprisingly, cryptocurrency adoption is rather consistent across income groups. Whites are less likely to
invest in trade, or use a cryptocurrency than Blacks, Hispanics, and Asians (Faverio and Massarat 2022).
62
high “country individualism” scores (Foley et al. 2021). Bitcoin is assumed to be a
libertarian idea, and Nakamoto (2008) said “It’s very attractive to the libertarian
viewpoint.” But in the United States, Bitcoin has broad support and opposition across the
political aisle.58 Critics lament a culture of “Bitcoin maximalism” among many online
stems from the aforementioned “block wars.” But data supporting a definitive Bitcoin
The transaction cost economics of Bitcoin are based on the use of distributed
ledger technology (DLT) and blockchain to eliminate the trusted intermediary and reduce
multiple, mutually distrusting participants in an economic system” (Casey et al. 2018, 9).
As long as transaction fees to network participants stay low, blockchain-based DAOs like
Bitcoin simply use transparency and automated processes to honestly record and
complete transactions.
Figure 1.7 Bitcoin Median Tx Size vs. Tx Fees (14-day moving average) (author)59
58
For example, the most comprehensive piece of cryptocurrency-related legislation to date (S.4356) is co-
sponsored by Democrat Kirsten Gillibrand and Republican Cynthia Lummis.
59
Data sourced from CoinMetrics
63
Bitcoin’s base layer is particularly appealing for settling very large transactions
and the legacy payment system needs a 21st century upgrade. Since the Federal Reserve
started using telegraph wires to transfer funds between banks, automated clearinghouse
(ACH) services developed in the 1980s are the most significant, broadly applied
point out how relatively cheap it is to transfer large sums of money on its blockchain
protocol (Figure 1.7). One analyst conducted an on-chain settlement efficiency analysis
of the 7-day moving average of volume of Bitcoin transacted fees charged on the
protocol’s base layer and found that an average transaction value of $95,142 and a
median transaction value of $751 was transferred for every $1 of fees in November 2021
(LeClair 2021). Domestic wire transfer fees within the U.S. average roughly
Bitcoin was the first financial tool to leverage this technology, but DLT and
blockchain are by no means exclusive to Bitcoin now. Policymakers must consider ways
to reduce the cost of trust by simply leveraging this technology in other forms. For major
financial institutions and large corporations, cryptocurrencies and central bank digital
payments face high costs, low speed, limited access, and insufficient transparency (FSB
2021). A Republican working group for the House Financial Services Committee cited
payments as its first principle for CBDC development in the United States (Financial
60
However, in 2019 the Federal Reserve announced the building of the FedNow service (in progress) to
enable instant payments between banks and customers 24/7 (Powell 2021).
64
Services Committee Republicans 2021). The private sector has a vested interest in
eliminating fees and slow speeds associated with large cross-border payments for
enabling the exchange of value for various types of digital assets” (JP Morgan 2021) and
CBDC). They found that completely different cloud infrastructures and systems could
become interoperable on the blockchain, increased visibility for both central banks could
be achieved, and “know your client” (KYC) burdens could be minimized (Onyx JP
Morgan 2021).
now known as the decentralized autonomous organization. DAOs use hybrid governance:
human stakeholders with various interests and motivations are bound together by smart
contracts written into core software governing several aspects of organizational control
and operation. These organizations are best viewed as a series of networks made up of
humans with varying levels of power and influence over changes to the digital
governance of the organization. Distribution of power and authority away from individual
human stakeholders in DAO networks is critical to their security but can cause a level of
organizational inflexibility which leads some researchers to advocate for a rather limited
65
Writing in the wake of the Great Recession, Nakamoto’s (2008) white paper
specifically cites frustrations with how “the entire money system depends” on a “trusted
central authority” (2). They included a note in the first block of Bitcoin’s chain:
“Chancellor on brink of second bailout for banks,” a London Times headline about the
state of centralized economic planning in the wake of the Great Recession, and uploaded
the first source code for Bitcoin six days later (Champagne 2014). Trust is not just
central motivator behind the very invention of Bitcoin. After Enron and Bernie Madoff, a
generation learns that “honesty comes at a price,” just as “the need for trust and
middlemen allows behemoths such as Google, Facebook, and Amazon to turn economies
of scale and network effects into de facto monopolies” (Casey and Vigna 2018). There
are several public policy implications associated with this unique form of DAO
governance – especially when applied to storing and exchanging value in the form of
cryptocurrency. But the push to use systems which disintermediate governments and
institutions from the exchange of information and value raises questions about
66
Essay 2
China’s Crypto Ban: How Decentralized Networks React to Hostile Policy Interventions
Abstract:
Beginning in May 2021, the People’s Bank of China enacted a series of policies
rendering cryptocurrency transactions and mining illegal, citing their role in enabling
illicit finance and their impact on the environment (2.2). The ban was the largest
exogenous public policy shock to the Bitcoin network to date, setting up a natural
experiment (2.4). This essay examines the ban’s impact on the digital and human
decentralized cryptocurrency network conditions and compares these metrics before and
after the intervention (2.5). It also considers the decision-making calculus of Bitcoin
miners displaced by the ban (2.6). I find little evidence of any long-term impacts to the
Bitcoin network after the ban (2.7). Additionally, much of the mining activity lost in
China relocated to Texas primarily because of the availability of cheap energy, but new
well. Interestingly, new evidence suggests several miners are still operating in China
undetected. Bitcoin’s quick rebound calls into question the effectiveness of individual
nation-state bans on curbing cryptocurrency use and energy consumption. More broadly,
67
2.1 Introduction
develop a natively digital system of value exchange without the need for a trusted third
party. It became the catalyst for the birth of a broader movement towards systems of
decentralized finance (DeFi). Less than 14 years after the invention of Bitcoin, the global
cryptocurrency market capitalization eclipsed $2 trillion, up from $600 billion the year
organizations (DAOs) without government involvement or permission. But this does not
policy lacks studies examining the impacts of exogenous policy shocks to organizations
and/or assets which run on decentralized network consensus mechanisms (e.g., DAOs,
smart contracts embedded into code to govern the allocation of resources, assign roles
This study asks, How did the Bitcoin network change after China’s
cryptocurrency mining ban? to fill that gap.63 After providing some background
information (2.2), this essay establishes, defines, and explains the significance of key
metrics of cryptocurrency asset viability (2.3). On-chain data from the Bitcoin
61
According to Coinmarketcap.com
62
For a comprehensive definition and overview of DAO governance, see Essay 1 in this dissertation series.
63
In May 2021, the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) prohibited financial institutions from conducting
cryptocurrency transactions. The PBOC then banned the mining of cryptocurrency specifically in June.
Finally, all forms of cryptocurrency exchange were banned in September 2021 (PBOC 2021). This study
focuses on the cryptocurrency mining aspect of the ban, specifically.
68
data speak to network security and decentralization, perceptions of Bitcoin’s value as an
asset, and its utility as a medium of exchange (2.4). I then use statistical analyses to
compare those metrics before and after the policy intervention to describe the ex-ante and
ex-post states of the Bitcoin network and explore whether ex-post changes correlate with
the timing of China’s mining ban (2.5). The ban serves as an opportunity to see how the
loss of computational power. The actions of cryptocurrency miners displaced from China
provide insights into the decision-making calculus of the network’s human element
2.2 Background
and mint new units of the cryptocurrency (i.e., tokens, coins) into circulation. Thus, a
intangible, non-physical digital asset. The physical nature of these mining operations
yields environmental policy concerns about energy use and greenhouse gas emissions
(Benneton et al. 2021; Roeck and Drennen 2022). The digital assets themselves can help
facilitate illicit finance (Fletcher 2022) and present a host of questions about how they
should be treated (i.e., regulated) as financial instruments (Clayton 2017; Hacker and
Thomale 2018) when used legally. These policy implications led President Biden to call
for a review of digital assets among all federal agencies dealing in financial regulation to
69
develop a comprehensive, interagency approach to addressing DeFi (Exec. Order No.
14067, 2022). The order comes at a time when the United States is now the world leader
and several DeFi products and cryptocurrency exchanges are the subjects of government-
led litigation.64
technology can revolutionize financial transactions (Davidson et al. 2016) and create a
new form of apolitical international economics (Babitt and Dietz 2014; Zamfi 2015;
Pilkington 2016). The technological ideas and infrastructure they run on (e.g.,
blockchain) offer tremendous opportunities and use cases for traditional fiat currencies
like providing financial services to the unbanked (Schuetz and Venkatesh 2020) and
and Liang 2016). Stablecoins, or “digital assets that are designed to maintain a stable
increased over 500% from 2020 to 2021 (Liao and Carmichael 2022). But stablecoins
carry significant risks. One such risk is that stablecoin holdings are not FDIC-insured like
a bank account, nor are they subject to the kind of audits and stress tests eligible financial
institutions which hold digital USD reserves with the Federal Reserve are. There is
comparatively little transparency about how DeFi platforms are leveraged and how they
would meet a 1:1 exchange of stablecoins for USD in the event of a massive liquidity
64
The U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) has announced litigation against Ripple Labs Inc.
(2020), Chicago Crypto Capital LLC (2022), the former CEO of FTX Trading Ltd., Samuel Bankman-
Fried (2022) to name just a few.
70
crisis. Since stablecoins are used to trade cryptocurrencies and several traders do so with
leverage, some feel the growing size of the stablecoin market poses some threats to
Markets 2021).
Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) may offer the chance to bring some of
the same functionality and advantages of stablecoins and cryptocurrencies under the
purview of a central bank. The two kinds of existing central bank money are cash and
reserves held by eligible financial institutions. CBDC is “a generic term for a third
version of currency that could use an electronic record or digital token to represent the
digital form of a nation's currency. CBDC is issued and managed directly by the central
bank” (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve 2021). For major financial institutions
and large corporations, CBDCs offer tremendous promise for eliminating market
Cross-border payments face high costs, low speed, limited access and insufficient
transparency (FSB 2021). A Republican working group for the House Financial Services
among cross-border payments as its first principle for CBDC development (Financial
65
The private sector has a vested interest in eliminating fees and slow speeds associated with large cross-
border payments for fiat/reserve currencies. In 2020, JP Morgan launched Onyx, “a blockchain network
enabling the exchange of value for various types of digital assets” (JP Morgan 2021) and conducted a
simulated experiment in June 2021, using a common multi-CBDC network to facilitate cross-border
payments between the Monetary Authority of Singapore (denominated in Singapore Dollars CBDC) and
Banque de France (denominated in Euro CBDC). They found that completely different cloud
infrastructures and systems could become interoperable on the blockchain, increased visibility for both
central banks could be achieved, and “know your client” (KYC) burdens could be minimized (Onyx JP
Morgan 2021).
71
Another potential advantage of CBDCs is in banking the unbanked. According to
the Federal Reserve, 6% of Americans are unbanked (no bank account) and 16% are
underbanked (may have a bank account but rely on alternative financial service
products). This is an equity issue, as there are serious consequences for being
underbanked and these individuals are more likely to be minorities, poor, and less
educated than the fully banked population (Federal Reserve 2020). The Financial Health
Network estimated that underbanked and unbanked Americans spent $189 billion in fees
and interest on financial products in 2018 (Financial Health Network 2019). A CBDC
directly with a central bank providing some financial services rather than through a
individual privacy and autonomy since their programmability and central control affords
CBDCs could infringe upon the very financial privacy rights popular cryptocurrencies
right balance between fostering financial innovation, securing financial system integrity,
and protecting the public from bad actors (Ducas and Wilner 2017). Likewise, energy and
environmental considerations are chief concerns among nations like the United States
seeking to slow the impacts of climate change (OSTP 2022). Blockchains are
exchanges of value and data transfer, and they lack specific legal and policy frameworks
66
Bitcoin was specifically designed with this in mind. Nakamoto (2008) sought a peer-to-peer electronic
cash transfer system without government approval/involvement. Bitcoin was designed to run on a trustless
and permissionless system with no counterparty risk or third-party verification.
72
for addressing them comprehensively (DeFilippi and Wright 2018). Prasad (2021; 2022)
echoes the concerns of many economists (Bohme et al. 2015) in imploring U.S.
CBDCs could threaten monetary sovereignty and existing national currencies. The
“future of finance” may be filled with promise, but it is also murky – especially in the
absence of official policy statements indicating how the world’s leading economy might
President Biden’s order on digital assets directs the Federal Reserve and other
CBDC. As for non-state cryptocurrencies on public blockchains (e.g., Bitcoin), the order
focuses on the energy, climate, and pollution impacts of cryptocurrency mining. The
subsequent White House Office of Science and Technology Policy (OSTP 2022) report
recommends Congress and the Biden administration “might consider legislation to limit
or eliminate the use of high energy intensity consensus mechanisms for crypto-asset
extreme approach to cryptocurrency policy relative to the rest of the world. According to
73
illegal in just thirteen countries.67 As more countries and territories establish laws,
regulations, and policies specific to cryptocurrency, subsequent studies might analyze the
regimes are more likely to restrict cryptocurrency use and legality. Of the 13 countries
where cryptocurrency is illegal or heavily restricted by law, only one is considered “free”
China’s. As a starting point, the legal and regulatory frameworks and precedents
governing currency in the U.S. and China before the creation of cryptocurrency differ.
The U.S. Constitution and subsequent laws were designed to establish the government’s
sovereignty as the issuer of its own currency and have historically “been exclusively
applied to prosecute counterfeited dollar bills and coins” (Xie 2019, 467) and do not bar
the creation of virtual currencies. From there, the U.S. approach to regulation has
whether virtual currencies and their derivatives meet the standard for treatment as a
67
Private cryptocurrencies only, excludes CBDCs and state-sponsored digital assets. Turkey is the only
country to institute a cryptocurrency ban around the same time as China (Turkey’s ban was announced in
April 2021) (Thomson Reuters 2022). However, there is no evidence of a significant Bitcoin mining
presence in Turkey prior to the ban (CBECI 2022).
68
Russia, China, India, Iran, Mexico, Colombia, Bolivia, Bangladesh, Turkey, Egypt, Algeria, Morocco are
all considered “not free” or “partly free” according to Freedom House’s Freedom in the World weighted-
scale methodology. Ecuador is the only nation with a “free” designation and somewhat restrictive
cryptocurrency regulations according to the Reuters study.
69
The three-factor “Howey test” is used as the standard for what is classified as a security. Its derived from
the SEC v. W.J. Howey decision. Still, neither Congress nor the SEC nor any federal court has explicitly
ruled whether specific cryptocurrencies are commodities or securities, and the debate is still ongoing
(Henderson and Raskin 2019)
74
(PBOC) laws expressly forbid anyone outside the Chinese central bank from “printing or
issuing token tickets which could replace renminbi” (Xie 2019, 472).
China’s path to an all-out ban on cryptocurrency evolved over time. In 2013, the
PBOC declared Bitcoin was not a currency, but a “virtual asset or digital commodity”
(PBOC 2013) and barred “financial institutions and payment companies from engaging in
Bitcoin-related businesses” (Xie 2019, 474). However, the public was still allowed to
trade virtual assets and digital commodities like Bitcoin. In 2017, depreciation of the
renminbi (RMB) and large capital outflows led China’s State Administration of Foreign
Exchange (SAFE), to place a cap on the amount of foreign currency its citizens could
exchange, annually (PBOC 2017; Xie 2019).70 Due to SAFE’s limited ability to monitor
cryptocurrency transactions, the PBOC also expanded upon its 2013 announcement by
(PBOC 2017). The PBOC then launched investigations into large cryptocurrency trading
In 2021, Bitcoin’s price and trading volume surged, prompting a joint statement
on May 18th from three Chinese financial regulatory bodies expanding and specifying
institutions, payment institutions, and other member units” (PBOC 2021) were
disallowed from participating in. Three days later, the Financial Stability and
70
$50,000 USD worth of foreign currency per year, after which a permit from SAFE is required.
71
SAFE’s purview is limited to certain appointed banks, so they were “unlikely to have the supervisory
capacity to monitor crypto transactions that can take place without a Chinese bank account” (Xie 2019,
479).
75
forthcoming “crack down on Bitcoin mining and trading behavior” (China Government
Network 2021). News reports indicate several provinces where Bitcoin mining was
prevalent (Sichuan, Qinghai, Xinjiang, and Inner Mongolia) shut down miners in early
May before the PBOC formally instituted its country-wide ban on mining in June (Feng
et al. 2021; Zhang 2022).72 Finally, all forms of cryptocurrency exchange were formally
banned in September 2021 (PBOC 2021). Between May and July, over 60% of the total
amount of computing power dedicated to mining Bitcoin across the entire network,
known as network hashrate, came offline – the largest such drop since Bitcoin began.73
Literature on why nations like China and the U.S. might differ in their approach to
cryptocurrency regulation is scarce. Dion (2013) sees the U.S. following long-standing
remains as the country's legal tender, but the law does not require the exclusive use of
dollars in the exchange of goods and services. The Federal Reserve has regulations
designed to monitor and regulate banking and lending practices where the PBOC has a
wider scope for issuing laws and regulations designed to maintain tight control on
capital.74 Xie (2019) argues the Chinese approach is designed to “maintain existing
regulatory consistency and conserve institutional resources,” (491) and that the U.S. is
more comfortable with folding technological ambiguity into existing legal frameworks
wherever possible.
72
Local governments faced pressure to meet energy efficiency targets. Inner Mongolia began banning
cryptocurrency mining as early as March (Akhtar 2021). A series of deadly coal mining accidents led to the
Xinjiang government suspending all coal-based mining in April, pending an inspection and review of other
coal mines (Pan 2021). Coal was a significant energy source providing electricity to mining farms in the
area.
73
I elaborate on the ban’s effect on network hashrate in section 2.5.1. Data collected from Blockchain
Explorer.
74
In 2014, Federal Reserve Chairwoman Janet Yellen said, “The Federal Reserve simply does not have
authority to supervise or regulate Bitcoin in any way. This is a payment innovation that is taking place
entirely outside the banking industry” (Tracy 2014)
76
Another possibility is that China views blockchain technology as an opportunity
to seize a geopolitical monetary advantage with their own CBDC and views other
its CBDC pilot program in Shenzhen. Commonly referred to as the eCNY or “digital
yuan,” China became the world’s first major power to launch a fully functioning CBDC
(Deutsche Bank 2021).75 In July, the PBOC released a white paper about eCNY research
and development. The purpose of the white paper was to outline the objectives of the
eCNY system and “to seek public comments, as well as to deepen communication with
all those concerned and join hands with them in building an open, inclusive, inter-
operable and innovative currency service system for the era of digital economy” (PBOC
2021, 1). The brief, 15-page document does not address issues faced during the pilot’s
rollout, says very little about CBDC programmability, and has scant details of how user
privacy might be protected under the eCNY system. But the document makes one thing
abundantly clear: China intends to expand eCNY use well beyond its pilot program and
will market its use to financial service companies, commercial banks, and corporations
DAOs and digital assets are broadly defined terms encompassing a wide range of
concerns necessarily differs for each type of asset. Even a focus on cryptocurrencies
alone is too broad in scope for meaningful empirical or theoretical research. Several
75
The renminbi (RMB) is the official name of China’s currency, but its principal unit is the Chinese Yuan
(CNY). The “eCNY” or “digital yuan” are the colloquial terms for what the PBOC calls “the Digital
Currency Electronic Payment” (DC/EP), a CBDC issued directly by the Chinese central bank. Its value is
fixed to RMB valuation (Huld 2022).
77
estimates suggest roughly 20,000 different cryptocurrencies exist today (Kharpal 2022;
Jones 2022).76
specifically for several reasons. First, it has the highest market capitalization of any
crypto-asset – over twice that of the next highest cryptocurrency by market cap,
Ethereum – and it has maintained this dominance since its inception for over a decade.77
This speaks to its current significance despite the emergence of other cryptocurrencies
and its sustained popularity over time. Second, launched in 2009, Bitcoin is the original
the easiest to study due to its data availability. Transactions, wallet addresses, block
timing, and other information are all fully transparent and available on the blockchain.
Accurate market pricing data have been available since its inception, as well.
several financial regulatory institutions in the United States. Gary Gensler, Chairperson
of the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, has stated on record several times that
than as a security (Gensler 2018). Gensler argues that all other cryptocurrencies are at
least somewhat controlled by a centralized entity which stands to profit more than other
stakeholders in the network. Commodities are typically raw materials like gold and are
76
Because cryptocurrencies are relatively simple to create, require no official approval, and are not all
listed for trading on exchanges, it is impossible to know precisely how many different cryptocurrencies
exist.
77
Coinmarketcap.com
78
Ethereum launched in 2015. Vitalik Buterin, Ethereum’s lead designer and creator, was a Bitcoin
enthusiast who co-founded Bitcoin Magazine in 2011.
78
often regulated less stringently than securities and their derivatives. Similarly, the
From a public policy perspective, Bitcoin has perhaps never been more salient as
a topic of study and debate due to recent changes to Ethereum. In September 2022,
reduce its energy consumption and assuage concerns about its carbon footprint and
environmental impact. Bitcoin now stands alone as the only major cryptocurrency relying
on PoW, and in many ways Ethereum 2.0 serves as a referendum on the viability of PoW
The incentive structure built into Bitcoin mining is just one of several key aspects
monetary policy is outside the scope of this essay. But an abbreviated overview of
For starters, we must return to the concept of lex cryptographia, or the processes
and operations of an organization occurring according to embedded code only. The rules
and smart contracts embedded within that code must prevent bad actors from taking
advantage of the system. Proof-of-work systems are designed to make it cost prohibitive
for bad actors to alter the blockchain or operate outside the consensus rules of the
protocol. For this reason, the Bitcoin core software is open-source code, all transactions
79
Past SEC chairs have argued that Ethereum has also reached a level of decentralization to be considered a
commodity. A bipartisan bill introduced to Congress also seeks to formally classify both Bitcoin and
Ethereum as commodities.
80
For a comprehensive review of the differences between proof-of-stake, proof-of-work, and other
blockchain consensus mechanisms, see Wang et al. (2019).
79
are broadcast transparently across the network, and the record of all historical
transactions on the blockchain are publicly available. Additionally, Bitcoin nodes capable
of verifying valid blocks and transactions serve as checks on the network by running the
Bitcoin core software. These nodes are relatively cheap to buy and are only as energy
cryptocurrency) associated with adding a new block to the chain. There is only one
reward per block, paid entirely to the miner who discovers the solution first. The data
Once a miner solves the puzzle and “wins” a block, it must broadcast the solution for
verification by other miners and nodes. Invalid data can be immediately detected and
ignored. If this occurs, not only do bad actors not receive the block reward, but they get
For this reason, the more decentralized the network becomes (more honest nodes
and miners), the more secure it becomes. A group of miners would need to control more
than 50% of the hashrate to alter PoW blockhains with invalid data.83 Specifically,
Bitcoin is designed to adjust to the amount of hashing power dedicated to solving these
cryptographic puzzles and adding new blocks to the chain across the entire network.
81
The cost of the hardware and memory storage required to independently run a node is somewhere
between $250 and $400 depending on the manufacturer and various pricing options.
82
Only 21 million Bitcoin can ever come into existence (assuming core code does not change). New
Bitcoin are ‘created’ through the mining process. As time goes on, the block reward decreases, effectively
reducing the rate of inflation built into the monetary policy. Once all 21 million Bitcoin are mined, miners
will receive fees built into each transaction to incentivize miners to add transactions to blocks promptly. At
the current rate, the 21 million cap will not be reached until around 2140.
83
This is called a 51% attack. A great deal of game theory analysis has been done on this subject regarding
cryptocurrency security (Sayeed and Marco-Gisbert 2019).
80
These difficulty adjustments (how hard it is to solve the puzzle) occur automatically
every 2016 blocks based on how difficult it was to find the previous 2016 blocks.84
Individual miners organize mining pools for several reasons. As overall network
hashrate increases, the probability of a single miner winning a block reward decreases
and it becomes nearly impossible for an individual miner to win a block without pooling
their hash with others. At current levels of network hashrate, it is highly improbable for
even the most well-capitalized individual miners to win blocks without collaboration.85
Mining pools now win block rewards and split those rewards amongst the individual
miners in their pools according to how much hashrate they dedicated to solving that
block. Mining pools may also offer certain hosting, flexible payment, software, security,
In the cost accounting analysis of a large-scale Bitcoin miner, energy is the most
the Bitcoin hashing algorithm known as SHA-256. The Antminer S19 Pro is currently the
most profitable mining equipment available at an average cost of $3734 per ASIC
(Hashrate Index 2023), before power, cooling, and hosting costs. To remain competitive,
miners must generate enough revenue to cover the initial hardware costs of these ASICs,
any debt service associated with capital raises, their respective fixed costs (e.g., data
84
With the goal of adding a new block every 10 minutes, these difficulty adjustments occur approximately
once every two weeks.
85
Let’s assume a single miner has 1000 highly efficient application-specific integrated circuits (ASICs).
The Antminer S19 Pro has a maximum hashrate of 110 Th/sec at an average cost of $3734/miner (Hashrate
Index 2023), before power, cooling, and hosting costs. For that $3.74 million investment, 110,000 Th/sec
represents just .044% of an overall network hashrate of 250 million Th/sec.
86
Appendix A provides a more in-depth breakdown of the mathematical relationship between Bitcoin
price, network hashrate, and the cost of energy, which ultimately determines how profitable Bitcoin mining
can be.
81
center hosting), plus the cost of running the machines designed to solve the hashing
algorithm. Overall network hashrate, the price of Bitcoin, and the price of energy are the
virtually zero impact on network hashrate and the price of Bitcoin, finding areas with
collecting regional data on Bitcoin mining in September 2019, over 75% of the network
hashrate came from mainland China (Figure 2.1). Xinjiang province is abundant in cheap
wind and solar power generation and Sichuan province was once abundant in seasonal
hydropower (Xu and Stanway 2022). During the peak of China’s rainy season in
September 2020, Sichaun province accounted for over 50% of hashrate in China (Figure
2.2). Furthermore, China is more willing than other nations to fill energy gaps with cheap
coal despite its propensity for pollution and higher greenhouse gas emissions (Standaert
87
Any large-scale miners using financing and capital raises to acquire ASICs and cover other costs must
also consider the interest rates and the cost of capital in their profitability analyses. These factors are less
significant for self-financed individual miners, but they must factor mining pool fees into their
considerations.
88
CBECI extrapolates from a sample of Bitcoin mining information (hashrate, location (based on IP
addresses), energy consumption, regional energy mix) shared by mining pools to provide estimates of
entire Bitcoin network’s overall energy use and associated GHG emissions by location over time. It is the
authoritative source used for most Bitcoin mining data analysis. Details on how their data is collected and
extrapolated, as well as the acknowledged limitations of their methodology can be found at on the CCAF
website.
82
Figure 2.1 Share of Bitcoin Network Hashrate by Country (CBECI 2022)
Figure 2.2 Seasonal Impact on Bitcoin hashrate by Chinese province (CBECI 2022)
geolocational data on mining facilities across the globe and then extrapolates this data to
generate an estimate of the geographic distribution of Bitcoin’s hashrate over time. This
data is based on the IP addresses of miners connected to mining pool servers. Though
83
widely considered as the best estimator of geographic hashrate distribution (Harper 2019;
Carter 2021; OSTP 2022), CBECI recognizes that the assumption of IP address accuracy
is a significant one. The use of virtual private networks (VPNs) to spoof IP addresses and
obfuscate locational data across the Bitcoin network can introduce noise in CBECI
estimates. CBECI has some limited ways to recognize when the impacts of VPNs are
“particularly visible” in mining pool reporting and takes steps to proportionally adjust
mining pool identities are encrypted and pseudonymized between the pool and the
application programming interface (API) from which CBECI pulls its data (CBECI
2022).89 Ultimately, CBECI concludes the VPNs “only moderately impact the validity of
the overall analysis” (2022) because VPNs increase network latency, reducing miner
revenues in the process. This puts miners using VPNs at a competitive disadvantage
metrics of its utility and viability as a digital asset. This necessitates some examination of
both Bitcoin’s original, expressed purpose (i.e., what was Bitcoin meant to do?) and its
most popular use case currently (i.e., how do people view/utilize cryptocurrencies
today?). It is widely accepted that money serves three purposes: 1) a store of value; 2) a
medium of exchange; and 3) a unit of account. The Bitcoin white paper (Nakamoto 2008)
Nakamoto set out to establish “an electronic payment system based on cryptographic
89
The Cambridge Center for Alternative Finance (CCAF) which founded and runs CBECI stresses it “has
at no point access to the underlying IP addresses or any other sensitive pool data” (CCAF 2022).
84
proof instead of trust, allowing any two willing parties to transact directly with each other
without the need for a trusted third party” (1). The white paper briefly explains the intent
inflation free” but otherwise mentions value only in the context of transactions or as it
lasted just two years after the release of the Bitcoin white paper (Champagne 2014).
During this time, most of their correspondence continued to center on how Bitcoin would
operate as an exchange of value. But some of this correspondence gives insight into what
they thought about Bitcoin’s potential as a store of value. First, Nakamoto felt Bitcoin’s
value derived from its immunity to government control and its decentralized network
describes Bitcoin as an escape from “the arbitrary inflation risk of centrally managed
currencies! Bitcoin’s total circulation is limited to 21 million coins.” They also explicitly
addressed concerns with Bitcoin’s propensity to consume energy. In a forum post, one
and that mediums of exchange did not need to have value to be useful. But Nakamoto
(2008) believed mediums of exchange needed to have some value to work, and Bitcoin’s
value would be derived from its network of miners and honest validator nodes. They also
argued that Bitcoin and gold mining are similar in that the energy expended to mine gold
90
It does not mention unit of account, either. Most likely because any brand new, unadopted currency
would obviously not serve as anyone’s unit of account.
91
On the cryptography mailing list they were a part of, Nakamoto replied to “You will not find a solution
political problems in cryptography” with “Yes, but we can win a major battle in the arms race and gain a
new territory of freedom for several years. Governments are good at cutting off the heads of a centrally
controlled networks like Napster, but pure P2P networks… seem to be holding their own” (Nakamoto
2008).
85
“is a waste, but that waste is far less than the utility of having gold available as a medium
of exchange” (Nakamoto 2010). Lastly, Nakamoto clearly felt Bitcoin’s value would
benefit from network effects, explicitly stating they expected value per coin to increase
with the number of users, triggering “a positive feedback loop” (Nakamoto 2009)
store of value. In 2022, the Bitcoin network processed between 200,000 and 300,000
transactions/day for most of the year on its base layer (Coinmetrics 2023). However,
Bitcoin now take place on the Lightning Network – a ‘layer 2’ protocol designed to
facilitate micropayments and free up traffic on Bitcoin’s base layer blockchain.92 But the
users who have bought and held their Bitcoin for at least six months. Since 2019, on-
chain data shows 70% and 80% of all Bitcoin supply has been held by long-term holders
(Radmilac and Van Straten 2022). Despite several bear market periods in which the
market price of Bitcoin has dropped over 60% in a short period of time, long-term
holders rarely divest their Bitcoin holdings. Data shows the most committed holders
typically acquire more Bitcoin during periods of low prices (Radmilac and Van Straten
2022).
cryptocurrencies with DAO governance are different than other commodities in that their
92
One study estimated the Lightning Network processed over 800,000 transactions in February 2022
(Arcane 2022). See Essay 1 of this dissertation series for a more in-depth explanation of the Lightning
Network.
86
value is so closely tied to the health of the network which processes transactions and runs
core software.93 If gold mining and bullion exchanges ceased to exist, gold would retain
its intrinsic value and individuals could still find ways to trade it, if needed.
Cryptocurrency miners effectively execute all base layer transactions. Exchanges provide
an interface for users to trade fiat currency for cryptocurrency in a nominal sense, but
exchanges effectively issue users the right to withdraw crypto coins/tokens from the
exchange’s holdings on the blockchain.94 Users do not truly “own” their cryptocurrency
until they withdraw it from the exchange and manage their own private keys. Exchanges
do not play a role in processing on-chain transactions. Token transfer on the blockchain
occurs between private key holders with miners processing transactions. For this reason,
several metrics in Table 2.1 have to do with the distribution and security of different
93
Cryptocurrency ownership also differs from equities ownership. Equities or stocks serve as shares or
portions of a company. Bitcoin “possession” is nothing more than ownership of ledger entry numbers.
94
The collapse and bankruptcy of several prominent cryptocurrency exchanges in 2022 occurred because
exchanges did not own the reserves necessary to restore funds to exchange users. What they experienced is
very similar to a bank run. Several users thought they “owned” the cryptocurrencies held on these
exchanges. In reality, most exchanges had some reserves, but not nearly enough to survive when users
decided to sell and/or withdraw their tokens all at once.
87
Table 2.1. Measures of Bitcoin Network Security, Health, and Distribution
Metric Units Data Source Description
The amount of computing power
Total Network Hashrate TH/s Blockchain Explorer dedicated to mining across the
entire Bitcoin network
The amount of computing power
Country Share of Hashrate % per country/month CBECI
dedicated to mining by country
Mining Pool Hashrate Distribution % blocks/day blockchain.com % of blocks mined by each pool
daily closing price of 1 BTC
Market Price $USD Yahoo! Finance
denominated in USD
average number of Bitcoin
transactions/sec (7-day
Transactions per second Coin Metrics transactions processed per second
moving avg.)
per day
daily average of time between
Block Time minutes BitInfo Charts
blocks added to the blockchain
number of reachable nodes
Nodes Online* # nodes bitnodes.io
verifying transactions
Nodes by Country* % bitnodes.io % distribution of nodes by country
*raw numerical data unavailabe. Graphic depictions only available through bitnodes.io
knowledge that can be gleaned from pre/post statistical analyses. The first aspect of
China’s ban was announced on May 18, 2021, targeting financial institutions
participating in “business related to virtual currency” (PBOC 2021). Three days later, a
forthcoming ban on cryptocurrency mining was announced, but not formally instituted
across all of China until June. The final aspect of the ban barring any form of
The timing of the three different aspects of the ban, and gaps between
identification of causal mechanisms therein. For example, the first aspect of the ban was
the third of three such crackdowns (2013, 2017, 2021) specific to financial institutions.
88
Following the 2013 and 2017 announcements, the price of Bitcoin dropped over 30%
within the next 10 days. Price action following the announcement of the forthcoming
mining ban was likely impacted by the financial institution aspect of the ban and a host of
other potential contributing factors which are difficult to control for. Bitcoin’s price
tumbled 13% from $56,700 to $49,100/BTC in one day after electric-vehicle maker Tesla
announced it would no longer accept Bitcoin as a form of payment on May 12th. When
the PBOC’s expanded ban on financial institutions was announced six days later, (PBOC
2021) the price of Bitcoin was already down almost 15% from the previous day, closing
at roughly $37,000/BTC. For some metrics (e.g., total network hashrate, country share of
network hashrate), drawing a causal relationship between the ban and changes to that
metric are clearer than others (e.g., market price), but most of the analysis in this study is
This study focuses on the mining aspect of the ban and relies on statistical
analyses of several Bitcoin metrics to paint a picture of the Bitcoin network before and
after miners in China were ordered to shut down their operations. The mining aspect of
the ban represents the greatest departure from previous Chinese policy positions. Mining
crypto-related financial services is not insignificant, but Bitcoin was designed to facilitate
services industry). Furthermore, the financial services ban did not constitute a stark
change in China’s cryptocurrency policy disposition. The third and final aspect of the ban
clearly states all “virtual currency-related activities are illegal financial activities” (PBOC
2021) which represents some departure from previous policies which allowed private
89
Chinese citizens to continue trading cryptocurrencies. But China had already prohibited
the exchange of fiat currency for cryptocurrency and barred Chinese financial services
industries from facilitating such cryptocurrency trading in China four years prior (PBOC
2017).95 The only new specified “virtual currency-related [activity]” in the order which
had not been barred prior to September 2021 was the “[exchange] of one virtual currency
The policy intervention is also designated as a period (May ’21 through June ’21)
rather than a single point in time. As previously mentioned, evidence suggests some
miners in certain provinces began shuttering operations as early as April 2021, but news
reports of the forthcoming ban broke in May before the formal ban was implemented in
June. Starting with the one-year period (May ’20 through April ’21) before PBOC’s
crypto ban allows us to build an ex-ante profile of the overall condition of the Bitcoin
network by each metric before the policy intervention. The period for ex-post analysis of
network conditions is designated as the one-year period (July ’21 through June ’22) when
dislocated miners found new hosting sites outside of China. Data for all metrics in Table
2.1 is available from May 2020 through June 2022 except for country share of hashrate
since CBECI locational mining data has only been published through January 2022.
The following sections analyze metric trends before and after the PBOC’s
cryptocurrency ban. Each section begins by offering a formal definition of each metric
and/or the Bitcoin network. I then cover the data collection process and present a
95
In 2013, the PBOC specifically prohibited the use of Bitcoin as a payment instrument for goods and
services as well (Xie 2019; PBOC 2013).
96
In the “Notice on Further Preventing and Resolving the Risks of Virtual Currency Trading and
Speculation” (PBOC 2021), Section 1.2 lists illegal “virtual currency-related activities.” Nearly all the
listed activities were already prohibited between 2013-2017.
90
statistical analysis of the pre and post periods to discern whether there are observable
confounders and/or barriers to causal analysis, as well as any useful information which
The total amount of computing power dedicated to mining Bitcoin across the entire
network. Critical to network security, asset store of value, and asset functionality as a
medium of exchange.
the network effectively becomes more expensive. If attackers control over 50% of
network hashrate in PoW-based systems, they can create a new blockchain with a new
timestamp server and distributed ledger technology to account for the double-spend
problem. The public and transparent nature of broadcast transactions and the blockchain
hashes mining equipment work through over time as they order transactions and compete
for block rewards. Basic home computing equipment is capable of thousands of hashes
per second, but mining equipment specifically designed to solve the SHA-256 hash
97
This means hashes are determined from inputs only – it is virtually mathematically impossible to
determine inputs from outputs. This is critical to the blockchain’s immutability and transaction
irreversibility over time, as each blocks timestamp is built off the previous.
91
Figure 2.3 Bitcoin Network Hashrate (million TH/s) Around the Ban (author)98
During the 12-month ex-ante period before China’s cryptocurrency ban, hashrate
generally increased by 154,000 TH/s per day.99 After approaching a new all-time high on
May 13th, 2021, China’s massive share of global hashrate (Figure 2.1) came offline in the
span of just two months. Network hashrate crashed from 186 million TH/s to just 58
million TH/s on June 27th (Figure 2.3).100 But Bitcoin’s mining difficulty – which adjusts
every 2016 blocks – dropped on July 3rd making it easier for miners based elsewhere.101
Older, less efficient mining equipment suddenly became profitable (Sigalos 2021). No
evidence exists that a serious 51% attack was attempted during the intervention period,
despite half the network hashrate coming offline. Hashrate recovered at a rate of 281,000
TH/s per day during the ex-post period, surpassing the previous all-time high by early
December 2021.
98
Data pulled from Blockchain Explorer.
99
Each Antminer S19 Pro miner has a maximum hashrate of 110 Th/s. So, this is roughly the equivalent of
adding 1400 new ASICs-worth of mining power across the network each day
100
Policy intervention period shaded yellow. The red dot marks the lowest point of Bitcoin’s network
hashrate on June 27, 2021.
101
2016 blocks is roughly every two weeks
92
Table 2.2a. Paired two-sample t-test: Total Network Hashrate
ex-ante ex-post
Mean 134.648 172.058
Variance 445.272 1621.460
Observations 365 365
Degrees of Freedom 364
T Statistic -24.6614
P(T<=t) two-tail 1.1815E-79
t Critical two-tail 1.9665
Table 2.2b. OLS Trend Statistics
ex-ante ex-post
Slope 0.1541 0.3473
Standard Error (slope) 0.0067 0.0083
R-squared 0.5936 0.8281
F-statistic 530.2785 1748.9064
Residual sum of squares 96215.3169 488764.4937
Regression sum of squares 65863.8047 101447.1165
Table 2.2 compares only the one-year ex-ante and ex-post periods using a paired
two-sample t-test of means and the ordinary least squares method of a linear best fit for
the data.102 The t-test yields a low p-value providing some support for claims that the
treatment effect had a significant impact on mean hashrate between the two periods. In
fact, mean hashrate increased during the year following the intervention period. Hashrate
increased at a faster rate after the ban, and OLS statistics indicate the regression model
provides a better explanation for the higher variance seen in the ex-post year than the year
prior.
Both CBECI data (Figure 2.1) and news reports indicate a disproportionately
large share of Bitcoin’s network hashrate was based in China prior to instituting a
complete ban on cryptocurrency mining.103 Quantitative evidence supports claims that the
mining ban played a significant role in the unprecedented drop in network hashrate
between May and July 2021 as China-based miners shutdown operations and began to
102
The two-month intervention period is excluded because it is likely to be driven by many idiosyncratic
factors that are of little interest to policymakers.
103
I expand on this in the next section regarding country share of network hashrate.
93
relocate. However, the drop in network hashrate cannot be entirely explained by the loss
of China-based hashrate. Monthly network hashrate grew in absolute terms through May
2021 while China’s absolute hashrate began its decline in March. Total network hashrate
dropped by 41.1 EH/sec from May to June, while China’s absolute hashrate decreased
Table 2.3. China and Total Network Hashrate Around the Policy Intervention
March April May June July
Total Network Hashrate (monthly avg., EH/sec) 159.6 157.2 161.2 120.1 100.4
Change from previous month (EH/sec) -2.4 4.0 -41.1 -19.7
% Change from previous month -1% 3% -26% -16%
China monthly absolute hashrate 78.3 72.4 71.0 41.1 0
Change from previous month (EH/sec) -5.9 -1.4 -29.9 -41.1
% Change from previous month -8% -2% -42% -100%
Bitcoin’s sudden decline in market value during this period (see section 2.3.4)
likely contributed to network hashrate losses. While hashrate does not typically correlate
with Bitcoin’s market price, studies suggest there may be some unidirectional causal
relationship from Bitcoin price to hashrate, just as oil and gas revenues/losses drive the
purchase/shut down of rigs (Fantazzini and Kolodin 2020; Rehman and Kang 2021).
Miner revenues are tied to Bitcoin’s market value, so miners with less efficient ASICs
can often afford to keep their machines on when the price of Bitcoin is high. These
miners will keep less efficient ASICs running so long as the price of energy is below the
breakeven price at which they know their machines will be profitable.104 All else equal,
more efficient mining machines effectively raise this breakeven price of energy. As
104
Returning to the discussion of mining economics, the decision for whether Bitcoin miners will turn their
machines on or off is mostly dependent on four things: the price of Bitcoin, the price of energy, the
efficiency/performance level of the mining equipment, and network hashrate. Though ASIC efficiency
erodes over time, their lifecycle is relatively predictable. Based on the known hashing efficiency of their
ASICs, miners can generate a profitability matrix based on the two more volatile variables in this equation,
bitcoin price and the overall hashrate of the network, to determine how much revenue they can generate per
unit of energy. This results in a breakeven price for energy, below which miners know their machines will
be profitable, and above which it is effectively counterproductive and economically unfeasible to mine.
94
Bitcoin prices drop, the rational, but less efficient miners will be forced to turn off their
“geographic distribution of Bitcoin’s total hashrate over time” (CBECI 2023).106 Critical
Country share of network hashrate lies at the center of this paper’s main research
question: what happens when a single country – which serves as a base for the majority
operation (i.e., mining)? We know from the previous section that Bitcoin quickly
bounced back from the loss of hashrate, but changes in country share of network hashrate
speak to how the geographic distribution of the main engine of Bitcoin changed as a
result of China’s ban. As seen in the previous section, non-China hashrate grew
significantly over time before and after the policy intervention, so this section includes
analysis of absolute levels of country hashrate as well. Increased distribution makes the
These data are sourced entirely from CBECI estimates. Estimates are based on IP
addresses of mining facility operators shared with CBECI through mining pools which
105
This assumes a constant overall network hashrate. If network hashrate and mining difficulty drops low
enough, it can make older equipment more profitable again. As mentioned earlier, this occurred once
network hashrate bottomed out in July (Sigalos 2021), but less efficient miners were likely priced out by
drops in market value in June.
106
Their full methodology for estimating hashrate by country/region can be found on the CCAF website.
95
voluntarily participate in CBECI’s studies. Participating mining pools represent between
33%-38% of total network hashrate (CBECI 2022). This means use of VPNs to spoof
locations and representative sample size concerns are limitations to their methodology. It
seems unlikely that miners hashing illegally after the ban would voluntarily participate in
location disclosure. But CBECI takes several steps to protect miner identities, and
For most of the year preceding China’s cryptocurrency ban, the United States and
Russia were the only two countries which to consistently account for more than 5% of
global hashrate.109 China’s share of global hashrate began to decline in November 2020
as more hashrate came online in neighboring Kazakhstan and in the United States.
Kazakhstan added a little over 1 exahash (EH)/sec per month between October 2020 and
107
See Section 2.2.3 for a more detailed breakdown of how CBECI addresses methodological shortcomings
108
Raw data from CBECI (2023)
109
Malaysia accounted for roughly 5% until dropping off below 4% after January 2021.
96
April 2021 while monthly absolute hashrate tripled in the United States over the same
period. During the intervention period, China’s hashrate came offline completely by July
2021, leaving the United States as the new leader in global hashrate. U.S.-based hashrate
remained consistent in absolute terms between April and June 2021, but jumped
The ex-post period brings about the most evenly distributed months of network
hashrate geographically since CBECI began tracking mining locational data. Canada’s
accounts for a greater than 5% share of global hashrate by June 2021. China re-emerges
as a significant contributor of network hashrate in September 2021, but the U.S. remains
the new post-ban global leader. The U.S. share of hashrate never surpasses more than
97
Figure 2.8 Ex-post Country Share of Network Hashrate (top)
Figure 2.9 Ex-post Country Share of Network Hashrate (bottom)
Absolute hashrate CBECI data suggests China-based mining was virtually non-
existent in July and August 2021 and then 30 EH/sec suddenly came back online in
September 2021. The amount of power and physical infrastructure required to support
mining that much hashrate means the likelihood that those operations shutdown, moved,
and subsequently returned is highly improbable (Kaloudis 2022). The more likely
geolocational mining distribution but fall short of meeting a reliable enough standard to
justify robust empirical support for causal analysis. In fact, this jump in China-based
hashrate in CBECI data prompted the Cambridge Center for Alternative Finance (CCAF)
estimates. CCAF (2022) admits “a comeback of this magnitude within the period of one
98
month would seem unlikely given physical constraints… Instead, a more likely
explanation lies within our top-down research methodology” and its vulnerability to VPN
impact” the validity of their estimates unless “sudden shocks” (CCAF 2022) occur which
alter miner risk tolerance and expectations. They argue China’s ban represents such a
shock which prompted “a non-trivial share of Chinese miners” (CCAF 2022) to operate
covertly with foreign proxies (high in network latency) until determining local proxy
services (relatively lower in network latency) offered sufficient protection from Chinese
state enforcement. This theory is supported by anecdotal evidence from several news
reports (Kaloudis 2022; Feng 2022; Browne 2022). Regardless of how exactly miners
obfuscate their locations, quantitative and qualitative evidence show large-scale mining
operations still exist in China, calling the ban’s efficacy and/or China’s enforcement
The percentage of blocks on the Bitcoin blockchain mined by each mining pool, daily. Or
a market share of the most popular bitcoin mining pools. The true level of
Pools act as a centralizing force upon an aspect of the Bitcoin network which is
it could act independently to conduct a 51% attack on the network or execute false
transactions. Therefore, it is critical that no single pool amasses too much control over
network hashrate for distributed consensus to serve its true purpose. Bitcoin has never
99
suffered a 51% attack. At the end of 2021, no mining pool controlled more than 17% of
the overall network hashrate. When one mining pool eclipsed 42% in 2014, several
miners joined other pools to prevent the possibility of a 51% attack (Blockchain.info;
Hajdarbegovic 2014).
Figure 2.10 Percentage of Blocks Won Daily by Major Mining Pools (author)110
Figure 2.10 shows the percentage of blocks won daily by major mining pools
from May 2020 through July 2022.111 While the share of blocks won by specific pools
certainly changes, the overall distribution remains consistent throughout the time around
China’s ban, with no single pool amassing more than 31.5% of network hashrate at any
time.112 Unless known mining pools announce and/or distribute their block rewards to
miners, there is no way of knowing who wins individual blocks by simply looking at
110
Aggregated by Blockchain.com (2023), pulled from the on-chain explorer and data from known mining
pools. Intervention period highlighted in yellow. Blockchain.com did not have data for daily blocks won
for Foundry USA during this time period. I pulled Foundry USA’s daily blocks won and added it to the
data set shown in these figures. Several mining pools, particularly those with a history of being based in
China, reported connectivity issues towards the end of 2021 (Gkritsi 2021). This may explain the sudden
drop off of reported blocks won by Poolin between October 2021 and January 2022.
111
Known pools with a low capacity to win blocks (<2 blocks per day on average) were excluded from
these Figures and analysis.
112
F2Pool hit the high mark for the time period in December 2020
100
native block information along the blockchain.113 Known mining pools are now so big
that the winners of most blocks are known. However, unknown or “stealth” miners have
captured most blocks since Bitcoin’s inception (Redman 2022). There is no way to
identify who these unknown block winners are, but it is highly unlikely that they
Table 2.4. Paired two-sample t-test: Non Top-4 Mining Pool Hashrate
ex-ante ex-post
Mean 50.13% 44.30%
Variance 0.0022 0.0037
Observations 365 365
Table 2.4 compares the means of the daily percentage of blocks won by all miners
outside the top four most dominant pools during the ex-ante and ex-post periods. Though
no single mining pool approached the 50% threshold, the top four mining pools became
more dominant after the ban. Prior to the mining ban, miners outside the top four mining
pools were responsible for half the blocks won compared to 44% after the ban. If this
trend continues, independent miners and smaller mining pools are less likely to win block
rewards and pressure to join a dominant mining pool will increase. However, there is no
reason to suspect China’s mining ban is responsible for this trend. Three of the top four
dominant mining pools during both the ex-ante (AntPool, F2Pool, and Poolin) and ex-
post (AntPool, F2Pool, ViaBTC) periods are based in China. AntPool and F2Pool
113
Bitcoin block information include software version, previous block hash, merkle root, timestamp,
difficulty target, and nonce (Gensler 2018). Miners can embed custom “dummy” data in blocks if they so
choose, so the blockchain often includes written messages that serve no real practical purpose.
114
Bitcoin forums are full of speculation on this topic. Because addresses and activity can be seen on-chain,
and the difficulty of controlling so much hashrate in a coordinated way without being identified, unknown
block winners cannot be controlled by a single pool.
101
remained in the top four during the ex-post period and Poolin continued to win a
top-four miner during the ex-post period as well.116 So far, there is no indication that
China’s various cryptocurrency bans will force mining pool companies to relocate even
In the early years after its inception, Bitcoin was mostly exchanged between early
miners, cypherpunks, and other cryptography enthusiasts. It was first listed on an online
exchange with a floating exchange rate in 2010 (Gemini 2022). Significant trading
volume and some mainstream curiosity led to Bitcoin’s first “bull market” run in 2011 as
price jumped from $1 to $30/BTC in just two months. In 2013, Bitcoin eclipsed
$1000/BTC in October after starting the year around $30/coin. There have been four bull
runs in Bitcoin’s history (2017, 2021 also), each characterized by parabolic rises in price,
followed by huge losses and volatility in price discovery. Still, even after pull backs,
Bitcoin has maintained higher prices than those prior to each bull run.
There are generally two schools of thought regarding Bitcoin’s market price
volatility around bull runs and crashes. The first has to do with Bitcoin’s built-in
limitation on supply inflation through the periodic halving (approximately every 4 years)
of block rewards, making it deflationary relative to fiat currencies and some other more
inflationary assets. Halving the reward also makes production more expensive, but lowers
115
AntPool is owned by Bitmain Technologies, a privately owned company with its headquarters still
located in Beijing. F2Pool officially lists their location as “decentralized,” but its headquarters was
originally established in Beijing. Poolin is also headquartered in Beijing.
116
Foundry USA, based in Rochester, NY, won the second-highest amount of blocks during the ex-post
period.
102
the rate of new Bitcoin entering circulation, triggering higher demand and higher prices
and preserving mining incentives in the process. Meynkhard (2019) refers to this as a
market value after price discovery. Under this halving cycle theory, bull runs begin a few
months after the effects of halving are felt by the network. Then, Bitcoin overshoots its
true market value (due to temporary overexuberance and massive increases in trading
volume/derivatives) before settling back to some pre-bull market higher floor value.
Halvings occurred prior to three of the four bull runs (2013, 2017, 2021), but
others feel basic international macroeconomic trends, state policy, and other “black
swan” events are more causal in affecting Bitcoin volatility (Dion 2013; Borri and
Shakhnov 2019; Xie 2019). In 2013, a popular Japan-based Bitcoin exchange named Mt.
Gox was hacked (Dion 2013) and the Chinese government announced new
cryptocurrency regulations with warnings about “speculative assets” (Xie 2019) resulting
in nearly 50% drops in price from earlier highs. Borri and Shakhnov (2019) present
quantitative empirical evidence showing correlation between the “China shock” – a series
of policy implementations and announcements by the PBOC in late 2016 and early 2017
103
Figure 2.11 2021 Bitcoin bull run, China ban, and 2022 market price crash (author)117
The 2020 halving, 2020-2021 bull run, China’s cryptocurrency ban, followed by a
Bitcoin price crash and recovery, and a final price crash in 2022 has elements of both
theories (Figure 2.11). A Bitcoin halving occurs on May 11, 2020, a bull run begins
somewhere between August and November before prices reach six times their pre-
halving levels in February 2021. China’s cryptocurrency ban certainly corresponds with a
roughly 50% drop in Bitcoin market value in just over two months. But Bitcoin’s
immediate price recovery to pre-ban levels just a few months after the ban takes effect
calls into question what long-term effects this state policy intervention really has.
117
Raw data pulled from Yahoo! Finance trading charts. Yellow indicates intervention period. Green dots
show new pre/post intervention all-time highs, red dot shows post-intervention low point before recovery.
104
Table 2.5a. Paired two-sample t-test: Bitcoin Price
ex-ante ex-post
Mean 24369.43 42954.46
Variance 326612577.57 107511232.74
Observations 365 365
High variance, residuals, and standard errors in the t-test and OLS trends results
in Table 2.5 point to a great deal of volatility in Bitcoin price, particularly during the ex-
post period. The mean ex-post Bitcoin price is nearly twice that of the ex-ante period, but
ex-post OLS statistics point to no meaningful trend. The price drop from all-time highs in
November 2021 could simply mirror the same downside volatility and price discovery
which follows each bull run, but it corresponds with several macroeconomic trends and
newsworthy developments which might better explain the asset’s decline. Bitcoin saw
wider institutional adoption in 2021,118 giving it much more exposure to broader market
payment for its products corresponds with a precipitous decline in Bitcoin market value
over a week before the PBOC announced China’s forthcoming cryptocurrency mining
ban. Additionally, the federal funds rate increased dramatically in 2022. Retreats away
118
From essay 1: 2021 was a significant year for institutional Bitcoin adoption. 14 publicly traded
companies ended the year with over 1000 BTC on their balance sheet (Radmilac 2022), including
Microstrategy and Tesla. Liberty Mutual Insurance (NYDIG 2021) and Fidelity Investments (Doyle 2021)
invested in Bitcoin mining and technology companies. Visa rolled out several cryptocurrency-related
products and reported $2.5 billion in payments by customers with “crypto-linked cards” in the first quarter
of 2022 (Holland 2022).
105
from risk-on assets towards cash and less volatile assets are typical in high and/or rising
interest rate macroeconomic environments (Litzenberger and Tuttle 1970). The tech-
heavy Nasdaq Composite Index also hit all-time highs in November 2021, followed by a
Volatility and several confounders make drawing causal links between Bitcoin
price and China’s cryptocurrency ban difficult. It is possible that the combination of
negative news around China’s ban and Tesla’s announcement played a role in
temporarily halting Bitcoin’s bull run which resumed in August 2021. But the
relationship between China’s mining ban and Bitcoin’s price drop is at best correlational
7-day moving average of average daily Bitcoin transactions per second. A dynamic
measure of transaction volume119 of native Bitcoin on the layer 1 blockchain – does not
mining (Section 2.3.1). Because mining facilitates the execution of transactions, mining
bans might negatively impact the ability of the network to efficiently process
transactions. Also, the news of a major nation-state ban could lead to a loss of interest in
utilizing cryptocurrency as a medium of exchange. The drop in hashrate during the ban
119
This refers to Bitcoin’s use as a currency (i.e., the number of times Bitcoin moves between wallet
addresses)
106
Following the ban, transaction volume recovered significantly, but never reaching pre-
Figure 2.12 Average Daily Bitcoin transactions per second, 7-day moving average
(author)120
Figure 2.12 shows the 7-day moving average of the daily average of Bitcoin
transactions per second to present a smoother depiction of the metric over time, but the t-
test and OLS trend statistics in Table 2,6 use the daily averages only. OLS modeling
accounts for little variation in daily averages (r-squared) when removing the moving
average component. However, the t-test of the means indicates a significant difference
120
Raw data from Coin Metrics (2023). Intervention period highlighted in yellow.
107
between transactions per second before and after the ban. Before the ban, an average of
3.57 Bitcoin transactions were processed every second compared to just 2.94 during the
The usage of Bitcoin as a payment system on the base layer is still a long way
away from all-time highs in December 2017, but it may have something to do with the
advent of Bitcoin’s ‘layer 2’ protocol, better known as the ‘Lightning Network.’ The
Lightning Network was invented to solve Bitcoin’s scalability problem and break the
between users to facilitate payments and unburden the main blockchain (Poon and Dryja
2016).121 Because these transactions occur off-chain, reliable data on exactly how many
transactions occur is hard to approximate. One study estimates over 120,000 payment
channels opened between January 2018 and July 2019 (Lin et al. 2020), which would
Several other factors could drive Bitcoin’s transaction volume. Transaction fees,
least a very strong correlational relationship between China’s mining ban and a sustained
ex-post period of less transactions processed per second. If the relationship is causal,
Reductions in average daily hashrate during the intervention (~25%, see Section 2.3.1)
121
A full explanation of the Lightning Network is outside the scope of this essay, but users effectively
transfer Bitcoin locked up on the base layer to Lightning wallets and conduct peer to peer transactions on
layer 2. They can close these two-way micropayment contracts and transfer their funds back to the base
layer whenever they choose. Since lightning network transactions occur between two known parties on
their own private channel, they are not broadcast to the entire network and settle nearly instantaneously
without the need for energy-intensive PoW protocol.
108
correlate with a similar reduction in average daily transactions processed per second
(~18%) over the same period. But if mining power acted as the limiting factor in
transaction processing efficiency, then the recovery in network hashrate to new all-time
highs would allow Bitcoin transactions per second to return to pre-ban levels.122 It is
more likely that some other factor – which may or may not have been triggered by
something related the ban – is driving less demand for using Bitcoin as a medium of
exchange.
Daily average of time (in minutes) between completed blocks added to the Bitcoin
Bitcoin transactions are organized into blocks by miners and then broadcast on its
distributed ledger for validation. Transactions are not finalized and settled until organized
into blocks and added to the chain. Bitcoin was designed to add a new block every 10
minutes. As hashrate changes, automated smart contract algorithms built into Bitcoin’s
core software protocol are designed to adjust the difficulty of mining a new block to try
122
Additionally, the difficulty adjustments built into Bitcoin Core (discussed in the next section) are
designed to adjust for changes in hashrate to keep transactions processing efficiently.
123
Block time refers to how often a new block (which contains transaction data) gets added to the
blockchain. Each block has a data limit of 1MB. Originally, Nakamoto (2008) designed Bitcoin with no
data size limit per block. The limit was put in place so all miners would be forced to create and accept
blocks of the same size. This block size limitation impacts transaction rates, and other cryptocurrencies and
Bitcoin derivatives have adopted larger block sizes to increase throughput. The small block size requires
less bandwidth and storage capacity from validating nodes, presenting a blockchain design tradeoff.
109
Table 2.7 Bitcoin Mining Difficulty Adjustments Around Intervention Period
Date Block # Difficulty % Change Average Block time (seconds) Average Hashrate
4/15/2021 679392 2.36E+13 1.92 589 1.68792E+20
5/1/2021 681408 2.06E+13 -12.61 687 1.47416E+20
5/13/2021 683424 2.50E+13 21.53 494 1.79249E+20
5/29/2021 685440 2.10E+13 -15.97 715 1.5048E+20
6/13/2021 687456 1.99E+13 -5.3 634 1.42678E+20
7/3/2021 689472 1.44E+13 -27.94 833 1.02781E+20
7/17/2021 691488 1.37E+13 -4.81 630 9.78715E+19
7/31/2021 693504 1.45E+13 6.03 566 1.03721E+20
8/13/2021 695520 1.56E+13 7.31 559 1.11286E+20
China’s ban triggered an unprecedented drop in hashrate (Figure 2.3). Since 2010,
automated processes in Bitcoin’s core software have routinely adjusted to small changes
in block time quite well.124 But the ban served as the most significant test of the difficulty
adding blocks to the chain. An ineffective adjustment which does not sufficiently
compensate for a hashrate decrease could lead to two additional weeks of long waits for
transaction settlement. Block time stayed above 10 minutes from June 9th through July
6th, hitting an all-time high of 24.8 minutes between blocks on June 27th 2021 during the
intervention period, but the July 3rd difficulty adjustment (Table 2.7)125 succeeded in
returning block time to the 10-minute average rather quickly. July 6th saw an average
block time of 10.14 minutes, and a pre-ban pattern of average block time was restored
(Figure 2.13).
124
In the early days of Bitcoin when only Nakamoto and a few others were mining and working on Bitcoin
Core software updates, Bitcoin routinely saw block times exceeding 100 minutes.
125
Block difficulty and timing data pulled from Blockchain Explorer.
110
Figure 2.13 Daily Average Time Between Bitcoin Blocks (BitInfo Charts 2023)126
Table 2.8 Paired two-sample t-test: Average Daily Block Time (minutes)
ex-ante ex-post
Mean 10.054 9.858
Variance 1.456 1.012
Observations 365 365
Degrees of Freedom 364
T-Statistic 2.4675
P(T<=t) two-tail 0.0141
t Critical two-tail 1.9665
While the p-value of the t-test comparing the two periods indicates a statistically
significant difference of the means (95% confidence level), average daily block time
decreased by just 11.4 seconds between the ex-ante and ex-post periods (Table 2.8).
China’s ban on cryptocurrency mining led to an increase in average daily block time for
the months of May (10.4 minutes) and June 2021 (12.8 minutes), but these results
indicate the mining difficulty adjustment successfully compensated for the loss of
126
Red line (10-minute goal) and yellow highlighted intervention period added by author
111
Nodes online: Number of reachable nodes running Bitcoin Core software. Key measure
of decentralization and active interest in securing the Bitcoin network. Speaks to network
policy
For both nodes online and nodes by country, raw numerical data is unavailable for
statistical analysis. Figures 2.14 and 2.15 are taken directly from the Bitnodes website.
Bitnodes is a privately developed software which interrogates any nodes connected to the
Bitcoin network using a protocol message which is a request for information from each
node. 127 Bitnodes was developed and published online anonymously, and data on node
connections over time is not available for download. For this reason, analyses for these
sections are limited to visual inspections of the graphics posted on the bitnodes.io website
and are not included as evidence to support causal claims in this essay.
There are several stakeholders in Bitcoin’s governance. Miners conduct the PoW
algorithm hashing to compete for block rewards and process transactions while other
network participants run independent nodes capable of broadcasting and confirming the
validity of those transactions. Independently run nodes are critical to the trustless
consensus mechanisms which underpin value transfer without third party intermediation.
Node operators can facilitate the transfer of their own cryptocurrency to another address
and verify the transaction without the use of an exchange. They help secure the network
127
Bitrawr LLC is a company which provides Bitcoin network analysis and uses the same “getaddr”
protocol message as Bitnodes to estimate node activity. Their “bitcoin node distribution live map” yields
the same results as Bitnodes. Their raw data is also unavailable for download. I verified the “getaddr”
message functionality using a Bitcoin application programming interface (API). Similar methods for data
scraping node data from the Bitcoin network were used in Howell et al. (2023).
112
by adhering to the consensus rules; validating blocks and transactions within blocks and
rejecting invalid transactions. Running a full node is relatively cheap (~$300) and each
node possesses equal power to validate and/or initiate transactions. Each node holds the
distributed ledger’s history of transactions and runs the Bitcoin core software to be
counted in this metric.128 For this reason, nodes are a measure of support for the Bitcoin
network. The geographic distribution of nodes running Bitcoin core software is important
transactions increased after the intervention. There were roughly 10,000 reachable nodes
from January 2020 through June 2021, but the total reached 15,000 by January 2022.
Several potential explanations for this change exist. It is possible that displaced miners
dispersed into smaller operations. But media reports indicate it took several months for
128
The “getaddr” message only receives responses from nodes running the same protocol version. Bitnodes
specifies their use of protocol version 70001 and explicitly states “nodes running an older protocol version
will be skipped.” (Bitnodes.io)
113
many miners to find new homes (Ostroff and Yu 2021) and China-based IP addresses did
not account for a large proportion of known reachable nodes (Figure 2.15) before the ban
took effect. The expansion of cryptocurrency payment processors during this time may
also contribute to the rapid increase in online nodes. For example, BTCPay Server
which Tesla briefly explored using to facilitate Bitcoin payments for their vehicles before
abandoning the idea in May 2021 (Harper 2021). The growing popularity of the
Lightning Network and other Bitcoin derivatives provides increased utility for the use of
ban, the number of “n/a” nodes increases dramatically after the ban. We now lack
location data on nearly half the nodes running Bitcoin core software. Howell et al. (2023)
point out a broader trend towards anonymization and privacy across several peer-to-peer
cryptocurrency networks with the increased use of “the onion router” (TOR) since 2021.
the source IP address of the server running the application” (Howell et al. 2023, 5). Much
of the increase in online nodes in Figure 2.14 is from “onion” (TOR) coded nodes. In a
review of four different blockchain networks (including Bitcoin) Howell et al. (2023)
found that 54.3% of all nodes in 2021 utilized TOR.129 This makes node geolocational
analysis particularly difficult and offers further support for theories of increased IP-
129
They found TOR supported 44.5% of Bitcoin (Layer 1) nodes and 68.7% of Lightning Network nodes.
114
Table 2.9 Summary of Bitcoin Network Metric Changes Around the Ban
Metric pre/post intervention change Suspected causal or correlational relationship
ban likely caused drop in network hashrate during
Total Network Hashrate robust recovery following intervention
the intervention period
ban likely contributed to and accelerated pre-ban
Country Share of Hashrate more distributed post-intervention
trends of growing absolute hashrate outside of China
Mining Pool Hashrate Distribution no change none
robust initial recovery after intervention, followed by may have contributed to short-term losses; no long-
Market Price
losses late in ex-post period term impact
Bitcoin’s DAO governance. Like any DAO, the consensus rules governing most Bitcoin-
related operations are embedded into automated code (digital governance). But individual
miners control where and when they turn on their equipment. Though mining economics
(i.e., the price of energy) is the primary driver for these decisions, evidence is mounting
making calculus.
In a spatial analysis of Bitcoin mining across the globe over time, Sun et al.
(2022) detect Bitcoin mining in 139 countries, with the greatest concentrations of
hashrate coming from areas with abundant and cheap energy production. They describe a
system of dynamic mining where large-scale miners are more willing than small miners
to relocate when regional energy economics change. But both favorable regulatory
measures (e.g., subsidies and tax benefits) and regulator attitudes were found to
“dramatically influence” (Sun et al. 2022, 5) movement decisions of major miners while
adverse policies drive them away. In particular, China’s ban spurred a new flurry of
115
“spatial fluctuation and migration” (5) in which regulatory policy became more
Several media reports indicate that dislocated miners from China packed up and
moved their operations across the globe to Texas (Feng 2021; Sigalos 2021; Rutwitch
and Feng 2022). Of course, the opportunity to capitalize on low energy prices is a
primary consideration. But in interviews, displaced miners also cite Texas policies
favorable to Bitcoin miners and a general positive disposition among prominent Texas
politicians as reasons for settling there. Texas has a deregulated energy market, low
barriers to entry for new businesses, and advantageous tax policies for industrial energy
Texas senators Ted Cruz and John Cornyn and Texas Governor Greg Abbott have
publicly expressed support for hosting Bitcoin mining in Texas, along with the CEO of
Texas’ energy grid manager, the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) (CNBC
2022).130 ERCOT runs a deregulated market where several market participants own
power plants and delivery energy through transmission lines they own as well. Contrast
this with markets in several states where utility companies have a monopoly on the
variable energy pricing based on demand dynamics, allowing miners to take advantage of
extended periods of low energy pricing (Hartley et al. 2019; Brown et al. 2020). Another
demand response and ancillary services. Miners can be paid to provide a base load of
energy demand provided they are able to respond to grid operator instructions to curtail
130
Brad Jones, ERCOT CEO, made comments about how he believes cryptocurrency mining may actually
help develop and promote renewable energy and stabilize the Texas grid on CNBC’s Youtube Channel
116
or shut down their loads. This changes the mathematical modeling for Bitcoin mining
profitability by adding the possibility for revenue generation through participation in the
CBECI lacks quantitative data on hashrate share of individual states within the
Untied States over time – it has only an estimate of where things stood as of December
2022. But a slew of media reports across several outlets point to miner migration within
the United States away from states like New York towards Georgia and Texas (Lonnroth
2022; Saul 2022; Hutton 2022). The tone among New York state regulators and
legislative efforts to expel cryptocurrency miners out of certain areas. Despite low energy
prices and cool weather favorable to mining, major miners like Foundry USA cite
“political and regulatory ambiguity” and “the possibility of a moratorium” (Saul 2022) as
reasons for moving away from New York as a base of operations. Months after Texas
Governor Greg Abbott made it clear he wanted his state to be the world’s leading
cryptocurrency mining location (Abbott 2021), New York Governor Kathy Hochul
signed a two-year moratorium on new permits for power plants housing cryptocurrency
cryptocurrency activity within each country, and each government’s general disposition
towards strict or flexible financial regulation (Blandin et al. 2019). Historically, the
United States and China have adopted different approaches towards currency and the role
131
New York is the first and only state to restrict Bitcoin or PoW-based mining by law.
117
of the state in regulating new forms of value exchange. We should not expect the United
should objectively consider the merits of their aggressive approach. The specific research
questions of this study are aimed at determining what impacts China’s mining ban had on
Bitcoin. But the macro implications of this essay speak to whether the policies of a single
relates to the China ban and what it might mean for cryptocurrency policy more broadly.
1. Nation-state policies may impact cryptocurrency values over the short-term, but
evidence suggests cryptocurrencies like Bitcoin recover and retain their value over time.
First, there is little to no evidence to suggest the ban impacted Bitcoin as a store
of value over the long term. Other studies suggest the announcement of adverse state
policies in the past negatively impacted Bitcoin’s market price over the short-term (Borri
and Shakhnov 2019; Xie 2019). While the price of Bitcoin dropped after the ban was
announced, it recovered to new all-time highs within four months. Perhaps China’s 2021
mining ban had the same effect as other past announcements of adverse state policy. But
people a hedge against “the arbitrary inflation risk of centrally managed currencies”
(Nakamoto 2010). But the volatility in Bitcoin’s price action has made it so that only
long-term holders willing to endure massive unrealized gains and losses could possibly
118
view it that way. Bitcoin has suffered price drops of 40% or more in a four-month span
seven times since 2011.132 Still, policymakers should not expect wild price swings to
threaten the long-term appeal of Bitcoin. Even if Bitcoin performs more like a speculative
stock than a true inflation hedge, its risk-adjusted rate of return over time has been strong
enough to keep long-term holders from selling their holdings (Radmilac and Van Straten
2022).133 Bitcoiners clearly see strong enough fundamentals to endure over 70% losses,
so market price cannot be the only metric of asset value, although it is the most obvious
place to start.
Hashrate is a key metric of network security in Bitcoin. Much of the asset’s value
threshold for mining control bad actors would need to add invalid blocks to the chain or
alter transactions. The distribution of both where that hashrate is based geographically
and how much individual mining pools control are matters of decentralization also
evidence point to miners using proxy services to obfuscate their locations, China-based
miners were responsible for the majority of network hashrate throughout the pre-ban
period and the ban resulted in most of that hashrate coming offline for some time. Drops
in aggregate network hashrate occur during the intervention through some combination of
the loss of China’s hashrate (Table 2.3) and less efficient miners being forced offline due
to tightened profit margins as Bitcoin’s market value dropped. Top mining pools became
somewhat more powerful after the ban, but no single pool came close to controlling 51%
of total hashrate.
132
88%, 54%, 44%, 60%, 46%, 41%, 55% drops in 2011, 2014, 2015, 2018, 2021, and 2022 (twice)
133
Since 2014, Bitcoin has never lost value (in $USD terms) over a three-year span.
119
The rapid recovery of overall network hashrate during the ex-post period is the
most significant policy takeaway for consideration from this study. Increases in hashrate
based outside of China before the ban resumed during the ex-post period. Both CBECI
geolocational data and aggregate hashrate data show a robust and sustained recovery to
previous highs in just four months. Through some combination of rapid miner relocation
and increases in absolute hashrate already underway at the time of the ban, the broader
This calls the limits of unilateral state action into question when it comes to
negative economic market sentiments and further still from serving as a hedge against
institutional adoption, and/or nation-state policy still has a significant ability to damage
perceptions of Bitcoin’s value (i.e., market price), even as network fundamentals and
measures of its intrinsic value (i.e., network hashrate) remain solid. But impacting
network fundamentals like total hashrate would likely require coordinated action by
nation-states since the ability to locate nodes and mining operations which drive network
United States. Policymaker attitudes towards cryptocurrency mining vary across states
and local governments (Section 2.6). We can expect states with deregulated energy
markets, relatively low energy prices, and crypto-friendly policy dispositions (e.g.,
120
capacity most of the time.134 Absent some intervention, miners will continue to operate
their equipment so long as Bitcoin’s market value continues to facilitate high breakeven
energy prices. In such deregulated environments, economic incentives become the only
mining regulation in the United States may do little to affect country-wide mining
behavior over the long term. A White House Office of Science and Technology Policy
the country. Federal policymakers should move quickly to establish such clear guidelines
adjustment) into their core software making them more resilient to adverse events (e.g.,
algorithms in its core software. Difficulty adjustments occur every 2016 blocks, based on
the previous 2015 blocks, and difficulty “cannot be altered above [+300% change] or
below [-75% change] four times the current difficulty level” (Sergeenkov 2022).135 In
134
The higher the price of Bitcoin, the higher the breakeven price of energy (all else equal). It is
economically rational (i.e., profitable) to mine whenever energy prices are below the breakeven price of
energy. See Appendix A for more detail on determining the breakeven price of energy for Bitcoin mining
profitability.
135
This can be seen in the Bitcoin Core software (and viewed in Python) which can be found on the GitHub
website. For ease of communication, I reference a plain English translation provided in the Sergeenkov
(2022) article.
121
theory, a policy intended to devastate Bitcoin’s ability to add new blocks and complete
new transactions would have to remove a tremendous amount of hashrate early in a 2016-
block cycle with near immediacy across several regions where Bitcoin operates.
China’s mining ban (while not designed to destroy Bitcoin completely) called for
an “orderly phasing out” (Zhang 2022) of cryptocurrency mining in the country. Even
with roughly half of Bitcoin’s hashrate coming offline, it took almost seven weeks to do
so, and enough hashrate existed outside of China to keep adding blocks to the chain
during the intervention period, albeit slower. Transaction volume decreased somewhat
following the ban, indicating reduced use of Bitcoin’s Layer 1 blockchain for final
settlement, but block time returned to normal less than a month after the cryptocurrency
mining portion of the ban formally took effect. In total, the ban appears to have no
Treasury, and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency should consider why people
final settlement and cross-border payments (Gensler 2018; Casey et al. 2018; Onyx JP
Morgan 2021). This same technology can be leveraged for fiat currencies in the form of
CBDCs (e.g., China’s eCNY) and/or stablecoins and policymakers must consider the
advantages and disadvantages of each. CBDCs already face opposition in the United
States primarily due to financial privacy concerns.136 Both CBDCs and stablecoins may
also threaten the stability of the fractional reserve banking system (Yanagawa and
136
Senators Mike Lee (R-UT), Ted Cruz (R-TX) and Tom Emmer (R-MN) introduced three pending
legislative proposals designed to restrict or prohibit the establishment of a CBDC in the United States
during the 118th Congress.
122
Yamaoka 2019; Baer 2021). Rapid, widespread adoption of either CBDCs or stablecoins
could impact banknote deposit levels, reserve requirements, and lending costs
(President’s Working Group on Financial Markets 2021). But failure to provide a more
efficient settlement system for fiat currencies could lead to further adoption of
3. The use of proxies and other technologies to obfuscate the locations of various
and this study lacks fidelity on the sources of node activity reporting, but available data
indicates the Bitcoin network became more evenly geographically distributed in terms of
node and mining control (i.e., hashrate) after the ban. If this data is accurate, it indicates
the Bitcoin network is even less susceptible to the policies of individual nation-states
today. But there are several reasons to suspect geolocational data is unreliable, or
TOR). CCAF protects miner anonymity at the CBECI application programming interface,
recognizes VPN activity in their data (and adjusts estimates accordingly), and relies on
the network latency associated with VPN use to discourage IP address spoofing. But the
the limits of these measures in accurately accounting for VPN use. CCAF should provide
more details about these limitations and a sensitivity analysis of the parameters involved
123
in determining their estimation if CBECI data is to be empirically useful to policymakers.
Policymakers should consider the use of VPNs and TOR to protect the locations of
miners (Section 2.3.2) and node operators (Howell et al. 2023) when crafting rules and
be effective.
mining practices and data sharing. Use of TOR (Section 2.3.7; Howell et al. 2023) and
VPNs (Section 2.3.2) increased during the ex-post period, though this study lacks
evidence to support claims of a causal relationship between the ban and increased privacy
measures. The privacy of network participants was a chief concern for Nakamoto (2008)
and early cypherpunks working on Bitcoin (Champagne 2014). It is possible that adverse
public policy measures only further incentivize trends towards anonymity and discourage
4. Despite the ability to obfuscate their locations, network participants still factor the
Though the results of this study suggest there is little correlation between China’s
cryptomining ban and long-lasting changes to the Bitcoin network, policy environment
clearly matters to many cryptominers. Evidence suggests some miners based in China
remained there after the ban; either shutting down operations temporarily and restarting,
or using proxy services to obfuscate their locations until they deemed it safe to return to
business as usual (CCAF 2022; Kaloudis 2022; Feng 2022; Brown 2022). But both
quantitative and qualitative evidence shows several major mining operations were
124
dislocated by the ban and specifically sought a more favorable regulatory environment.
The United States saw an influx of displaced miners from China (Feng 2021; Sigalos
2021; Rutwitch and Feng 2022) and a migration within the country away from states with
2022), simultaneously. Despite the ability to obfuscate their locations, local regulations
and policies still factor into Bitcoin miner decision-making (Sun et al. 2022).
including deregulated energy markets and low barriers of market entry for cryptomining
businesses (e.g., Texas). Cryptomining companies can provide jobs, stimulate regional
economic growth, and expand the corporate tax base. But these benefits must be weighed
Understanding how digital assets and DAOs function and how they differ from
policy. The results of this study point to the challenges even large, influential nation-
states face when unilaterally implementing policies designed to affect digital assets
governed by well-distributed networks. But this study examines policy impacts from the
perspective of the DAO. While the Bitcoin network survived and may have even grown
more resilient as a result of China’s ban, it is entirely possible that the ban served its
purposes in the eyes of the PBOC and Chinese Communist Party. Another study might
consider the ban’s effectiveness from that perspective, including an analysis of the kind
of capital outflows and renminbi circulation China sought to control two years earlier
with its State Administration of Foreign Exchange policy without a ban in place. Finally,
this study is mostly quantitative and limited to statistical analyses of newly developed
125
metrics for understanding how these new organizations work. The human element of
DAOs (e.g., Bitcoin miners) requires a closer qualitative look (e.g., deliberate, semi-
structured interviews) than the one included in this essay to unpack the relationship
126
Essay 3
Abstract:
Bitcoin’s high energy use and carbon footprint is a major part of the public
discourse around the world’s most popular cryptocurrency. In recent years, some Bitcoin
miners have made a concerted effort to align their operations with energy and
environmental policy goals. In Texas, several politicians at the local, state, and national
levels of government and Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) leaders have
welcomed these miners, touting the benefits of incorporating flexible loads onto the
energy grid. Models and simulations suggest that flexible loads can provide grid stability
and incentivize the buildout of further renewable energy generation. But others caution
new loads may place undue burdens on a stressed energy grid. This study evaluates
several claims made about the potential benefits of proof-of-work cryptocurrency mining
using empirical data from the recent influx of Bitcoin mining on the Texas energy grid.
Results show most large Bitcoin mining data centers are in regions with high levels of
renewable power generation relative to the rest of the state while nearby wholesale
energy prices remain consistent with statewide trends. Additionally, evidence shows
resource” program – a demand response program requiring loads to cede a high degree of
control to grid operators. This essay provides policymakers with insights regarding grid
expansion, energy economics, and how to best incorporate flexible data centers into the
127
3.1 Introduction
In recent years, Bitcoin proponents have made a concerted effort to recast proof-
light. PoW mining effectively functions as a kind of highly flexible data center which can
be located anywhere.137 Renewable energy resources (e.g., wind and solar) are
environmental factors outside human control. Renewable generators often curtail output
when capable of producing more energy than the grid demands and/or can transmit.
Mining advocates argue these loads are uniquely positioned to address the increasing
curtailment and intermittency issues in electricity markets with high variable renewable
energy for renewable power generators. This could improve renewable plant economics
and incentivize VRE growth (Carter and Connell 2021; Saylor et al. 2022). Furthermore,
several studies suggest adaptable data centers are particularly well-suited to participate in
demand response programs which can help provide grid operators with greater flexibility
and improve grid stability (Chen et al. 2014; Wierman et al. 2014; Hale et al. 2016;
Klinger and Szilvas 2020). Demand response programs are used by grid planners and
The purpose of this study is to shed light on three questions regarding Bitcoin’s
long-term sustainability:
137
Mining proponents often refer to this as “location agnosticism” (Carter and Connel 2021). Since mining
equipment is small and miners require little more than internet and electricity, these data centers can be
highly modular and co-locate with any power generation source. I explain this concept in further detail in
section 3.2.2
128
1. Does Bitcoin mining incentivize renewable growth?
Crypto advocates and energy experts have discussed how Bitcoin mining can incentivize
renewable growth and increase grid stability in articles, podcasts, and blogposts while
meaningful scale. If in fact the Bitcoin network can lower its carbon footprint and
conduct mining sustainably over the long-term, the field lacks empirically based
This essay begins with an explanation of the various theoretical arguments and
models for how PoW mining data centers might play a role in the transition to a
renewable-based energy grid. Next, I take a critical look at the academic literature around
consumption associated with PoW cryptocurrencies and their potential negative effects
on the environment (e.g., pollution, e-waste, carbon emissions) while far fewer
cryptocurrency mining studies even consider its potential benefits. Finally, I look at
Bitcoin mining in Texas using geolocational data, wholesale electricity pricing, and
demand response data from the Electric Reliability Council of Texas (ERCOT) to
wholesale energy pricing trends before/after mining data centers came online, and
129
This work sheds light on the three questions above regarding Bitcoin’s long-term
sustainability and the energy economics associated with using flexible data centers in the
template for using publicly available data to determine the local impact of high loads on
electricity pricing beyond synthetic grid simulations (Li et al. 2020; Menati et al. 2022).
From a public policy perspective, the analysis, results, and conclusions of this study
regulated vs. de-regulated market structures) and PoW mining regulation and legislation.
In April 2021, President Biden set an ambitious goal for the United States:
“achieve a 50-52 percent reduction from 2005 levels in economy-wide net greenhouse
gas (GHG) pollution in 2030” (Biden 2021) with the ultimate goal of a net-zero emission
(NZE) economy by 2050. Experts generally agree that both increased electrification
electricity (the share of electricity sourced from high greenhouse gas emitters) are critical
to making meaningful progress toward NZE goals (Steinberg et al. 2017; Nadel and
Ungar 2019; Griffith 2022). In other words, power grids will need to be able to deliver
much more electricity to end users and utilize more renewable power generation to do it.
incorporating more renewable power generation onto power grids in the United States.
The first two subsections focus on energy economics. Renewable growth is costly and
theoretical use case for how PoW mining can improve renewable economics during the
130
energy transition (3.2.2). Renewable intermittency and increased reliance on electricity
also present grid stability challenges (3.2.3). This section concludes with a brief review of
electrical engineering research on the role interruptible data centers could play in
undertaking. In the Electric Power Research Institute’s (EPRI) analysis of what it would
take for the U.S. to meet 50% GHG reduction by 2030 goals, it found electrification of
end-use sectors (transport, buildings, and industry) would need to accelerate rapidly to
reduce emissions (by 23-33% compared to the current reduction of just 2% from 2005
levels) and capacity additions to wind and solar power would need to double or triple
currently projected additions for the 2020s (EPRI 2021, 3-4).138 Texas leads the United
States on this front, adding 7352 megawatts (MW) of new wind and solar capacity in
2021 – more than the next four highest states combined (American Clean Power
Association 2022).
But high levels of VRE penetration come with economic challenges. The costs of
producing wind and solar have decreased as technologies improve over time (Creutzig et
al. 2017; Victoria et al. 2021). However, the “energy and capacity revenue potential for
wind and solar generation in a wholesale market environment” (Millstein et al. 2021,
1750) declines as it becomes more abundant in a market due to its low marginal cost,
particularly during peak production times. With few exceptions, researchers found
138
The rate would need to double or triple to achieve the 50% reduction by 2030 depending on assumptions
in the EPRI (2021) model. “Assuming electrification economics and technology improvements consistent
with earlier EPRI studies” (2) the rate would need to triple, but if we assume “additional technology and
policy drivers accelerate electrification by lowering the cost of electricity-using technologies” (2) the rate
would only need to double.
131
regional transmission organizations (RTOs) and independent service operators (ISOs)139
with higher levels of wind and solar penetration levels see the largest reductions in
marginal wind and solar energy value (Millstein et al. 2021). This well-documented
economic trend is called VRE value deflation. If falling costs of renewable production
fail to keep pace with the declining value of marginal renewable energy in high
penetration markets, wind and solar may reach saturation points due to simple
integration costs for new projects increase as well, passing costs on to customers and
pricing (LMP) reflects this dynamic value of energy across different pricing nodes (ISO
NE 2022). Energy-rich areas with low levels of demand and limited transmission
capacity often experience negative wholesale energy pricing. Regions with high VRE
penetration see a higher frequency of negative LMPs relative to the rest of the United
States (Seel et al. 2021). In theory, negative energy prices should result in the cessation of
energy production – it seems nonsensical for producers to pay consumers to take energy
it costs them to generate. However, generators may continue production due to the
physical constraints or prohibitive costs associated with ramping down and subsequently
139
RTOs and ISOs are the organizations and operators which manage electric grids. They are charged with
“providing non-discriminatory access to transmission” (FERC 2022) by the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (FERC).
140
Solar power in California serves as a prime example of the paradox of renewable energy value deflation.
The rapid influx of solar generation reversed the diurnal profile of energy pricing in California – prices are
now higher in the early evenings because solar accounts for nearly 40% of generation during the daytime
when electricity prices used to be highest (LBNL 2019; California ISO 2021). This concentration of
massive cheap, clean energy has suppressed energy prices during those hours of the day when solar is most
abundant, making it particularly susceptible to value deflation (LBNL 2019).
132
restarting production. Various tax credits and subsidies allow renewable producers to
remain profitable despite paying the grid to take their energy when LMPs turns negative.
As such, continued development of new VRE projects and the profitability of existing
The grid in Texas was originally designed for a small number of centralized
power stations placed in optimal locations. Geographic mismatches between the point of
abundant renewable energy generation and high demand load centers can only be solved
the wind is not blowing, or the sun is not shining, and transmission lines are no longer
141
For example, the renewable electricity production tax credit (PTC) was first enacted in 1992 and has
been extended 12 times to help with the upfront capital costs associated with renewable plant production
(CRC 2021). The PTC was designed to decrease year over year from the date each facility began
construction. In 2021, producers received $18 per megawatt hour of wind energy produced at a qualified
facility (EIA 2021).
142
Figure 3.1 is an oversimplification of how power is produced and electricity is transmitted to demand
centers. All numbers are notional. Graphic is author-generated, but the idea for using this visual concept to
explain curtailment was drawn from a blog article titled “Bitcoin Mining and the Grid” by Blake King.
133
congested. But building out high-capacity transmission infrastructure is very costly143 and
can take over a decade to complete, while renewable plants may take just 2-3 years to
construct (NREL 2016). Estimates vary depending on assumptions and various modeling
inputs but building battery infrastructure to support 12-hour electricity storage for an 80%
renewable system could cost around $2.5 trillion (Shaner et al. 2018; Temple 2018).144 In
the absence of more storage or transmission, this excess energy gets curtailed and local
Figure 3.2 (left). Distance Between West Texas VRE and Metro Areas (ERCOT 2022)
Figure 3.3 (right). Wind (blue) and Solar (yellow) Plants in Texas (author)146
West Texas is rich in wind and solar energy generation (Figure 3.3) but far from
the major electrical load demand centers in the east (Figure 3.2). Dallas, Austin, Houston,
143
The 15,575 circuit miles of transmission lines laid during Texas’ CREZ project cost an average of $1.1
million/mile (Cohn and Jankovska 2020)
144
NREL’s zero carbon by 2050 scenario required 932 GW (932,000 MW) in battery power capacity or
6097 GWh in battery energy capacity to support 94% renewable energy generation along with “significant
round-the-clock curtailment” amounting to “nearly 200 days with curtailment in all 24 hours” (Jorgenson et
al. 2022, 7). In another NREL study modeling hundreds of scenarios, Frazier et al. (2021) found storage
estimates ranging from 130 GW to 680 GW could be enough to support an 80% renewable energy grid by
2050 depending on cost reductions, technological advances in battery development, and multiple
combinations of power generation/transmission upgrades.
145
Excess supply does not necessarily always coincide with excess demand, but carbon emitting producers
may have to make up the difference closer to high load demand centers when it does, as seen in Figure 3.1.
146
ERCOT West Load Zone highlighted. Wind and Solar plant locations mapped using QGIS according to
EIA Form 860 data
134
and San Antonio all lie at least 250 miles away from where the vast majority of Texas’
renewable energy is generated (ERCOT 2022, 18). ISOs must set interconnection limits,
or a “maximum amount of power that a facility can inject into the grid,” (Kahrl et al.
2021, 14) for all generators; and VRE projects are often capable of providing more power
than the grid can accept. Additionally, transmission lines are limited by how much power
leads to congestion and curtailment.148 Congestion occurs when transmission lines are
overloaded (i.e., trying to deliver more power than lines are designed to carry). When
congestion occurs, ERCOT must rely on higher-cost generators closer to load demand
centers to reduce power flows while lower-cost generation options are available. ERCOT
different locations” and calculates these costs based on “the difference between the
payments by loads at their locations and the payments to generators at their locations”
(Potomac Economics 2021, 19). Real-time congestion costs reached $2.1 billion by the
end of July 2022, matching total congestion costs for the entire year in 2021 (Potomac
Economics 2022).149 Because of Texas’ high (and growing) level of solar and wind
147
Point of interconnection (POI) limits are slightly different than transmission capacity limitations. POI
limits are outlined in interconnection agreements between grid managers and producers. Various power
lines have different current/amperage limits.
148
From 2005 to 2014, Texas identified competitive renewable energy zones (CREZ), or areas rich in
renewable energy potential targeted for transmission planning and development. CREZ policies were
designed to provide predictability and incentives for building renewable energy projects in the west.
Renewable development expanded so rapidly that ERCOT saw “a 150% increase in installed solar capacity
from 2020 to 2021” (ERCOT 2022, 11). Now, transmission infrastructure developed is already saturated
with renewable output. About 60% of Texas’ wind and solar resources projected to be operational on the
ERCOT grid by 2023 are planned for West Texas. This 38 GW of renewable energy in the west is “more
than double the designed capacity for the Competitive Renewable Energy Zone (CREZ) projects” (ERCOT
2022, 1).
149
These figures are especially alarming since Winter Storm Uri “accounted for almost one third of all of
the congestion costs [in ERCOT] in 2021” (Potomac Economics 2021, 20).
135
energy penetration, ERCOT’s 2023 projection of 6,700 GWh of wind and solar
curtailment due to West Texas export limits is projected to increase tenfold to about
67,000 GWh of curtailment by 2030.150 Solar power curtailment was once practically
nonexistent, but Texas has set a new record for curtailment of both wind and solar
renewable power plants have led to long interconnection queues or wait times between
when a generator requests and is granted interconnection to the grid for commercial
operation. These wait times “increased from ~2.1 years for projects built in 2000-2010 to
~3.7 years for those built in 2011-2021” (Rand et al. 2022, 21). PJM Interconnection (the
nation’s largest grid operator) faces an interconnection backlog so large they called for a
two-year pause on reviewing new projects (Bruggers 2022). This extends the time
solve the SHA-256 algorithm (i.e., cryptographic puzzles) in hopes of winning the
subsidy associated with completing a block of Bitcoin transactions and adding it to the
used to work through secure hash algorithms and “mine” Bitcoin.151 Miners organize into
pools, where they are compensated according to how much algorithm they “hash” or
150
This is a massive amount of wasted energy. For a reference point, DoE (2019) estimates 1 Gigawatt
hour is roughly equivalent to the amount of power 3.125 million solar panels or 364 utility-scale wind
turbines could produce in one hour.
151
ASICs vary by model, but individually they are each roughly the size of a shoebox.
136
contribute to solving the puzzle. Mining profitability is mostly dependent on the price of
Bitcoin (the reward for solving a block), the price of energy (the cost of powering
network hashrate (how many others are competing).152 Miners can do little to affect
Bitcoin price, ASIC efficiency, and hashrate, so they are highly incentivized to seek out
Bitcoin miners and some energy experts argue mining operations can serve as a
and setting an energy “price floor” when LMPs go negative. Mining data centers are
highly scalable, allowing miners to provide precisely as much demand capacity needed to
soak up excess power generation.153 This level of scalability plays a role in Bitcoin
mining’s “unconstrained location agnosticism” (Carter and Connel 2021). Since miners
only need to be able to broadcast and participate in the blockchain network via cellular
data or satellite internet, they can co-locate with any power generation source. Mining
data centers are commonly housed in the equivalent of a shipping container that has been
optimized for computational processing. In fact, some companies build highly modular
containers outfitted with ASICs and a self-contained airflow system.154 These containers
eliminating the need for costly transmission lines and their associated electricity losses.
152
See Appendix A for a full breakdown of mining economics. Network hashrate (defined in detail in
Essay 2) is the total amount of computing power dedicated to mining Bitcoin across the network.
153
One of the most advanced and commonly used ASICs currently is the Antminer S19 Pro with a power
consumption of 3.25 kw (Intellion Data Systems 2022). Thus, a shoebox and 3.25 kw represent the lower
bound of scalability for any Bitcoin mining data center using S19s with a theoretically unlimited upper
bound of the total number of available ASICs.
154
EZ Blockchain’s “EZ Smartbox” is one example
137
3.2.3 Grid Stability Challenges
require electricity’s share of end-use energy consumption in the United States to increase
from 20% currently to 60% by 2050 (Princeton 2021; U.S. Department of Energy 2022;
Walton 2022). This effectively triples the United States’ reliance on the power grid. The
capacities. ISOs manage this complexity constantly using projections, modeling, and
unanticipated changes in load can cause the grid frequency to deviate from this nominal
value and trigger cascading failures (i.e., “rolling blackouts”) if left uncorrected over
certain time durations (Folgueras et al. 2017). Grid operators often get commitments from
commercial loads (i.e., large energy consumers) to reduce their power demand when
electrical supply frequency drops below acceptable limits in exchange for some form of
renewable electricity generation in the United States will increase from 21% in 2021 to
44% by 2050, requiring more demand-side flexibility as VRE penetration increases (Pina
et al. 2012; Alizadeh et al. 2016; Olsen et al. 2020). In California where solar
155
A complete explanation of the dynamic set of factors that ISOs face in maintaining grid frequency is
outside the scope of this paper, but generally speaking the grid frequency cannot stray far from 60 Hz
without triggering blackouts or other destabilizing events. See Folgueras et al. (2017) for an advanced
discussion of grid frequency dynamics.
156
“Frequency response,” or a commitment for a load to reduce or eliminate consumption during an
underfrequency event is just one of several specific types of demand response programs.
138
photovoltaic (PV) penetration is high, grid managers keep a close eye on net load, or “the
difference between forecasted load and expected electricity production from variable
generation resources” (CAISO 2021, 1). Figure 3.4 depicts CAISO’s net load at each
hour of January 11th for years 2012 through 2020. The resulting net load curves show
how much controllable power generation CAISO must leverage to fill the gap between
variable generation resources and load demand across the system. These net load curves
grow increasingly steep each year as solar PV penetration increases. The “start” points on
the graph show when CAISO must begin dispatching flexible resources to meet demand
(i.e., net load curves ramp up). The “stop” points show when CAISO must reduce that
flexible generation. The lower the net load is in the early afternoon, the higher the risk of
generation. As this happens, ISOs like CAISO require more flexible, controllable
resources on the demand side which can ramp up or down inexpensively to adapt to
Figure 3.4 “Duck Curve”: CAISO’s Net Load for Jan. 11, Years 2012-2020 (CAISO)157
157
Researchers projected the steepening curves would resemble a duck and coined the term “duck curve”
(Roberts 2016; 2018). Their projections were correct. In fact, net load fell even faster than predicted
(Breakthrough Institute 2021).
139
3.2.4 How Miners Hope to Stabilize the Grid
tremendous economic benefits and potentially ensures Bitcoin is mined with clean power,
only. Miners can provide a source of revenue for projects stuck in interconnection queues
awaiting connection to the grid. But this implies a “behind the meter” Bitcoin mining
configuration, where miners draw power directly from renewable generators and not the
grid itself. In practice, most Bitcoin mining in the United States today is grid-
connected.158 Electricity from the grid can come from renewable or high carbon-emitting
power sources. Like any new load, grid-connected miners increase energy demands and
But mining proponents argue their data centers are uniquely positioned to provide
the kind of flexible base loads grid managers need to ensure stability. During mining,
each successive hash is statistically independent of the last, so the mining process is
perfectly interruptible without negating any work previously done or affecting any future
work yet to be complete. Frequency response is just one of many ancillary services (AS)
or demand response (DR) programs ISOs engage in with commercial loads to keep the
grid operational. Demand response constitutes any agreement between grid managers and
interruptible data centers in providing flexible base loads in various demand response
158
There are a few examples of large-scale Bitcoin mines operating with renewable energy sources
completely “behind the meter,” but overwhelming evidence suggests most mining occurs in grid-connected
configurations.
140
programs (Wierman et al. 2014; Patki et al. 2016; Klinger and Szilvas 2020).159
planning reserve requirement reducing the need for natural gas during periods of peak
demand (Hale et al. 2016). A data center’s suitability to participate in demand response
suggesting fully interruptible Bitcoin miners could be more effective than typical data
centers in providing demand response. Researchers found potential profits and the
amount of control ceded to operators were positively correlated in the New York
Independent System Operator (NYISO) ancillary services market, while response time
requirements and potential profits were negatively correlated (Aikema et al. 2012). One
study found that more adaptable data centers capable of dynamic control can “decrease
their energy costs around 50%, while providing the ISOs and the society in general with
cost effective demand side reserves that render massive renewable generation adoption
Using data centers as interruptible loads for grid stabilization is a novel idea
already underway in Singapore (Xia et al. 2015) and ERCOT has expressed the need for
similar controllable load resources (CLR) in Texas. Non-controllable load resources are
after an order from ERCOT to help with frequency response. ERCOT requires CLRs to
be capable of both base point following and primary frequency response (ERCOT 2022).
With primary frequency response, CLRs can drop load immediately and unilaterally to
159
Frequency response is a common demand response program, but the research reviewed in this section
covers several types of demand response.
141
bring frequency back into tolerance in the event of a generator failure and a massive drop
in frequency. But under base point following, grid operators tell resources how much load
to drop over a certain period. This type of load attenuation is more difficult to achieve
3.2.5 Summary
It is true that several synergies exist between Bitcoin’s incentive structure and
policy goals in the energy transition. Miners seek out cheap energy and the levelized
costs of wind and solar energy have decreased relative to carbon-emitting sources over
time (Lazard 2021). Early investment incentives in wind and solar projects decrease as
VRE penetration increases. Bitcoin mining can certainly provide another source of
controllable base loads provide grid operators with much needed flexibility – particularly
But if Bitcoin mining is to play a role in the energy transition, a sober assessment
of the gap between where mining is today and where this ideal, sustainable Bitcoin
between VRE power generation and Bitcoin miners is dependent on sensitivity analyses
of the factors which play a role in mining profitability: Bitcoin price, energy price, miner
efficiency, and network hashrate. More efficient ASICs increase the breakeven price of
energy (under which it is profitable to mine), but since this equipment is more expensive
160
ERCOT (2022) currently has eight such CLRs representing ~750 MW of controllable load – all of
which are bitcoin mining data centers. Compare this to ERCOT’s 7600+ MW of non-controllable load
resource capacity (only 650 MWs is data mining), as the level of control, technological sophistication, and
lengthy approval process makes CLR status more difficult to obtain.
142
than older, less efficient equipment it also requires more uptime to ensure profitability.
Simply stating Bitcoin miners will only soak up cheap, clean, and stranded energy is not
rapid downside price volatility can quickly shrink mining profit margins or make mining
unprofitable. This changes the math for VRE investors factoring mining revenues into
their planning assumptions. Lastly, flexible base load still increases aggregate energy
demand for any grid. This can add stress on the grid and increase energy prices, so the
minute details of how such loads work in demand response programs matter.
The literature review that follows aims to provide an assessment of where Bitcoin
mining currently sits along the path to sustainability. Determining Bitcoin’s energy
consumption and its carbon footprint should factor into weighing its costs against
potential future benefits. Studies specific to the feasibility of the Bitcoin-VRE partnership
include sensitivity analyses of factors critical to Bitcoin profitability outlined above and
shed some light on the pros and cons operators must consider when welcoming Bitcoin
PoW cryptocurrency mining has attracted a great deal of negative attention and
critical analysis in academic circles for its high energy use. Largely in response to this
design, and others have made changes to make their existing protocols more eco-friendly.
work (PoW) protocol to a proof-of stake (PoS) protocol with the expressed purpose of
making its network “less energy-intensive, and better for implementing new scaling
143
solutions” (Ethereum 2022) than its previous PoW system161 in September 2022. This
“Ethereum merge” left Bitcoin as the last major cryptocurrency to use the more energy-
intensive PoW protocol for validating/processing transactions and creating new coins
(i.e., mining).162 Bitcoin remains the world’s most popular cryptocurrency by market
capitalization and the amount of computing power dedicated to mining remains near all-
time highs historically despite major downside price volatility in 2022. Bitcoin’s
proponents insist that its energy-intensive protocol is critical to the security of its
network. Energy backs its value as an asset, and its use is a “feature, not a flaw”
Still, Bitcoin mining’s long-term future in the United States depends in large part
on perceptions of its ability to minimize its carbon emissions; and the academic
community plays a significant role in shaping those perceptions. Several studies estimate
Bitcoin’s overall energy use (3.3.1) and its impacts on climate change (3.3.2). The White
House Office of Science and Technology Policy (OSTP) report on “Climate and Energy
Implications of Crypto-Assets in the United States” (2022) cites several of the studies
quality of these studies (3.3.3) is of critical importance to formulating good policy. The
impacts Bitcoin mining may have on nearby communities are also relevant policy
considerations (3.3.4). Finally, I summarize the findings of other studies focused on the
161
A full explanation of the differences between PoW and PoS protocols falls outside the scope and focus
of this study. For a more comprehensive “Taxonomy of Blockchain Technologies,” see Tasca and Tessone
(2017).
162
Other PoW-based cryptocurrencies exist (see https://coinmarketcap.com/view/pow/), but the collective
computing power dedicated to mining these other cryptocurrencies are insignificant in comparison to
Bitcoin. As such, “Bitcoin mining” and overall “PoW mining” are colloquially equivalent, post-Ethereum
merge.
144
economics of renewable-based Bitcoin mining (3.3.5) and its potential impacts on grid
stability (3.3.6).
have evolved considerably over time. Early estimates suffered from a lack of precision.
Wide ranges were based on best available data, broad assumptions, and more
Malone (2014) published one of the earliest estimates of Bitcoin’s overall energy use
between 2009-2014 using historical data about Bitcoin’s mining difficulty and the
hashing efficiency163 of various mining hardware at the time. The range of energy
efficiencies for various hashing technologies yielded a wide estimate of possible overall
McCook (2014) was the first to use aggregate data about large mining pools to
(ASICs)165 were responsible for across the network and included this mix in an
hashing efficiencies and electricity prices and came up with a range of estimates much
lower than O’Dwyer and Malone’s but comparable to Vranken’s (2017) work years later.
Vranken considered capital expenditures and new research (Magaki et al. 2016) about the
use of several ASICs in specialized data centers in his estimations. Vranken found the
163
For a comprehensive explanation and mathematical model of Bitcoin mining economics, see Appendix
A
164
This is converted to TWh/year in Table 3.1 for consistent units across all estimates. With 8760 hours in
a year, 1 GW = 8.76 TWh.
165
ASICs are highly specialized Bitcoin mining hardware dedicated to solving the SH256 algorithm as
efficiently as possible.
145
upper bound of O’Dwyer and Malone’s (2014) estimate to be “completely unrealistic”
(Vranken 2017, 5) placing his upper bound 95% lower than O’Dwyer and Malone’s
(Table 3.1).
mining hardware efficiency, and estimated share of network hashrate per hardware model
were published in 2018 (Bevand 2018; Krause and Tolaymat 2018; deVries 2018) but
deVries added a new, economic-based method for projecting its expected electricity
consumption in the future. Based on Hayes’ (2017) cost production model for valuing
Bitcoin, deVries assumed miners would hash until marginal costs equaled marginal
revenue. Since “market forces drive the industry toward an equilibrium whereby firms
will earn zero economic profit” (deVries 2018, 803), deVries argued the electricity and
costs were headed based on lifetime electricity use assumptions and production costs
2022). Its index seeks to measure Bitcoin’s yearly energy consumption in TWh/year
dating back to July 2017. Its process begins by calculating miner revenues, estimating
what percent of revenues are spent on electricity “in equilibrium” and then converting
those costs to electricity consumption based on another per kWh estimate of their
146
Cambridge University’s Bitcoin Electricity Consumption Index (CBECI) is now
widely accepted by academics and Bitcoin enthusiasts alike as one of the most accurate
estimators of the Bitcoin network’s power demand (Carter 2021).166 CBECI includes
several parameters in its model and uses actual empirical data from Bitcoin mining pools.
made, and what factors into its sensitivity analysis. Table 3.1 compares yearly estimates
citations for each study on Google Scholar.167 CBECI estimates are much lower than that
of Digiconomist’s index, deVries’ 2018 estimates, and O’Dwyer and Malone’s 2014
estimates.168 Studies concluding with high and low estimates of Bitcoin’s electricity
Table 3.1 Estimates of the Yearly Electricity Consumption of the Bitcoin Network Over Time (TWh)
Author/Source Year Citations (Google) Lower bound Estimate Upper bound CBECI
O'Dwyer and Malone 2014 654 0.876 26.28 87.6 4.79
McCook 2014 37 0.911 1 1.708 4.79
Krause and Tolaymat 2016 218 2.479 5.46
Bevand 2017 26 5.61 7.15-8.27 10.93 14.44
Vranken 2017 409 0.876 4.38 14.44
Digiconomist 2017 19 5.03 13.66 14.44
Krause and Tolaymat 2017 218 8.304 14.44
Bevand 2018 26 14.19 18.4 27.47 45.44
Stoll et al. 2018 268 48.2 45.44
deVries 2018 511 22.338 67.189 78.139 45.44
Digiconomist 2018 19 43.67 71.12 45.44
Digiconomist 2019 19 39.87 69.79 57.09
Digiconomist 2020 19 46.97 59.32 68.52
Jones et al 2020 8 75.4 68.52
Digiconomist 2021 19 28.85 134.76 104.89
166
Carter is a digital asset researcher, venture capitalist and Bitcoin proponent who uses CBECI in his
articles and studies. CBECI was featured by Bitcoin Magazine in 2019 as “what might be the most
statistically sound and feature-rich model on Bitcoin’s power consumption to date” (Harper 2019). CBECI
is cited several times in OSTP’s report on crypto-assets and the environment as well.
167
The CBECI estimate column in Table 3.1 offers a comparison point for each study’s estimate across all
years since CBECI is the only index providing estimates going back to 2014. The International Energy
Agency (IEA 2022) estimates 220-320 TWh of worldwide data center energy use (excluding
cryptocurrency mining) in 2021, or 1.1-1.4% of total electricity use. The U.S. Energy Information
Administration (EIA 2022) estimates the United States accounted for 3930 TWh of electricity consumption
in 2021.
168
CBECI’s Index is highly dependent on the “average electricity cost” assumption. Their default
assumption is $.05/kWh. All CBECI estimates cited in this essay use their default assumption.
147
3.3.2 Assessing and Projecting Bitcoin’s Impact on Climate Change
debate with their study titled “Bitcoin Emissions Alone Could Push Global Warming
Above 2°C” (Mora et al. 2018).169 First, Mora et al. (2018) assumed entire blocks were
mined by a single model of ASIC or mining hardware and randomly assigned each
Bitcoin block mined in 2017 to one of 62 types of Bitcoin computing hardware and its
respective energy efficiency. Total carbon emissions were aggregated using the energy
mix of the host country (carbon emissions required per unit electricity) for each company
or mining pool winning a block multiplied by the estimated electricity required to mine
that block for all blocks in 2017.170 From there, the authors projected future Bitcoin
rates of technological adoption, Bitcoin alone could account for cumulative emissions
“likely to warm the planet by 2°C within only 16 years” (Mora et al. 2018, 1).
Krause and Tolaymat (2018) and Stoll et al. (2018) provided estimates of both the
Bitcoin network’s overall electricity consumption and its corresponding GHG emissions.
Much like CBECI methodology, Stoll et al. (2018) used known IP address locational data
169
The title of this two-page comment in Nature magazine was aggregated in blogposts, newspapers like
the New York Times, and digital climate journals from several prestigious universities. It is heavily cited
and was included in OSTP’s 2022 report on “Climate and Energy Implications of Crypto-Assets in the
United States.”
170
Mora et al. (2018) used “known server locations” of Bitcoin mining pools claiming blocks in 2017 and
then applied carbon emissions (metric tons CO2e/GWh) of the host country/countries of those known
server locations. Mining companies may locate their headquarters or servers in one or a few locations, but
mining pools usually combine hashing power from individual miners across the globe. They assumed all
blocks won by 10 mining pools (including the most popular pools in the world at the time) were hashed
entirely in China, but this is not the case. (See Essay 2, Section 2.2.3 and 2.5.3 of this dissertation series for
more details on how mining pools work)
148
to estimate the geographic distribution and subsequent energy mix of the network’s
hashrate. Krause and Tolymat (2018) provided a range of potential emissions based on
various energy mixes not necessarily based on known geographic distribution of network
hashrate. Jiang et al. (2021) found carbon emissions from China-based Bitcoin mining
alone exceeded the footprint of several small countries and encouraged policy
with its geographical data regarding miner IP addresses and several studies estimating
regionally specific electricity mix profiles to estimate yearly Bitcoin GHG emissions
since 2011. They found 2022 emissions were set to decline year over year for the first
time in the digital asset’s history. Their “best-guess” figure of Bitcoin’s 2022 carbon
countries like Nepal and the Central African Republic (Neumueller, CCAF 2022). Most
notably, Neumueller found that recent increases in mining hardware efficiency led to a
drop in the network’s annual electricity consumption while network hashrate continued to
increase, where prior to January 2021, hashrate and electricity consumption generally
149
Table 3.2 Estimates of Yearly GHG Emissions of the Bitcoin Network (MtCO2e)
Author/Source Year Citations (Google) Estimate
Mora et al. 2017 250 69
Neumueller*** 2017 0 7.65
Masanet et al. 2017 46 16
Calvo-Pardo et al. 2017 6 2.8
Foteinis 2018 49 43.9
Krause and Tolaymat** 2016-'18 218 3-13
Calvo-Pardo et al. 2018 6 16
Stoll et al. 2018 268 21.5-53.6
Jones et al. 2018 8 16.632
McCook 2018 37 0.6
Kohler and Pizzol 2019 58 17
Digiconomist 2018 19 33.5
Neumueller 2018 0 23.92
Houy 2019 29 15.5
Calvo-Pardo et al. 2019 6 15
Jones et al. 2019 8 24.567
Neumueller 2019 0 28.13
Jones et al. 2020 8 37.132
Neumueller 2020 0 34.37
Neumueller 2021 0 56.29
Jiang et al.* 2021 43 25
deVries et al. 2021 42 65
Jones et al. 2021 8 37.256
Jiang et al. 2022 43 52
Digiconomist 2022 19 64.86
Neumueller 2022 0 48.35
Jiang et al. 2023 43 106
Jiang et al. 2024 43 130
*Jiang et al. (2021) estimated Bitcoin GHG emissions for just China in the year
2021, and projected subsequent years through year 2024
**Krause and Tolymat estimate total emissions from Jan '16-Jun'18
***Neumueller's study was recently posted (at the time of this writing) as a part
of CCAF's broader efforts to track Bitcoin's usage and emissions with CBECI
Table 3.2 lists the wide range of estimates resulting from these studies.171 OSTP
(2022) cites and includes several of these estimates in their report on the climate
policy goal, this wide range of estimates makes framing the scope of the problem rather
difficult. One solution to this problem is to evaluate the merits of each study’s
methodological approach and the validity of their baseline assumptions (Section 3.3.3).
171
Greenhouse gases vary in their contribution to warming. MtCO2e refers to million tonnes of carbon
dioxide equivalent for a common measurement across gases. IEA (2022) estimates global energy-related
carbon dioxide emissions were 36,300 million tonnes in 2021. Mulligan and Heyman (2019) estimate
global gold mining accounted for 100.4 MtCO2e in 2018.
150
Policy analysts should consider establishing a standard for emissions estimation. The
OSTP (2022) report outlines the need for “evidence-based environmental performance
standards” (7) for mining issued by the Environmental Protection Agency and
should be the first steps in setting such standards. Calvo-Pardo et al. (2022) propose
aggregate measures of Bitcoin’s usage (e.g., total network hashrate) and then assign
weights for emissions input estimation (e.g., mining efficiencies, power usage
approaches begin with determining the hashrate contributions of miners in each specific
Impact
points” (1) and the dearth of objective, nuanced research regarding Bitcoin’s
environmental impact. He found two sides too obsessed with “vying for interpretive
authority to sway public opinion in their favour and persuade policymakers” to appreciate
footprint.172
172
Though surprisingly, Ciaian et al. (2022) found environmentally conscious investors were actually more
likely to have exposure to crypto-based assets in their portfolios than their peers.
151
Neumueller arguably understates the lack of objectivity and intellectual
O’Dwyer and Malone (2014) were not measuring “the energy consumption of Bitcoin
mining” so much as they were reporting how dependent any estimate was on assumptions
and/or data about the energy efficiencies of mining equipment. Presenting their findings
in Ireland, they claimed their study “shows that the power currently used for Bitcoin
which he cites Digiconomist data. DeVries’ studies (2018; 2022) are peer-reviewed and
published in online journals but cite data from an index he created which lacks detailed
explanation about its inputs, assumptions, and estimation methodology. As such, both
The alarming findings found by Mora et al. (2018) elicited several scathing
critiques.174 Houy (2019) took issue with the “inclusion of unprofitable mining rigs” (1)
in the very first step of the Mora et al. (2018) estimation methodology and found the
exclusion of this basic rational assumption of only mining when profitable led to an
173
O’Dwyer and Malone (2014) argued this estimate of 3 GW was plausible assuming miners would only
operate profitable equipment at an energy cost of $0.10/kWh – the lower bound of industrial rates in
Europe in 2013, ignoring the possibility of mining occurring elsewhere (e.g., China).
174
Houy (2019), Dittmar and Praktinknjo (2019) and Masanet et al. (2019) published direct replies to Mora
et al. (2018) in the same journal where it was first published.
152
overestimation by a factor of 4.5. Dittmar and Praktinknjo (2019) criticized the Mora et
al. (2018) “demand scenario” and the ignorance of “fundamental constraints imposed by
the transaction-processing capacity of the Bitcoin network” (1).175 Masanet et al. (2019)
replicated the Mora et al. study and found they made several mistakes in addition to using
a fundamentally flawed methodological design from the outset. Masanet et al. argued the
study’s demand scenarios lacked plausibility, credibility, failed to meet the standard of
“analytical rigour and transparency,” (1) and warned their results “should not be taken
and the environment are common. In “Bitcoin’s Growing e-Waste Problem,” DeVries
and Stoll (2021) offer no explanation for assuming a short lifecycle for ASIC mining
equipment despite evidence that old hardware models account for a significant portion of
network hashrate (Saylor et al. 2022). Jones et al. (2022) used “methods described in the
existing literature in this space” (6) citing Goodkind et al. (2020)177 and Krause and
Tolaymat (2018) in their estimates of the network’s overall electricity usage but offered
no elaboration regarding how they came up with the “average efficiency of BTC mining
rigs” (Jones et al. 2022, 6) used in their equation. Their supplementary data on emissions
factors, mining locations, and energy mix came directly from deVries (2022) with no
further elaboration.178
175
Dittmar and Praktinknjo (2019) found the Mora et al. (2018) demand scenario effectively required
global electricity generation to triple over the next five years, compared to just a 17% increase in global
electric power capacity over the previous five-year period.
176
Masanet also put forth their own estimate for Bitcoin GHG emissions (Table 2).
177
Goodkind et al. (2020) was written by the same three co-authors as Jones et al. (2022): Goodkind, A. L.,
Jones, B. A. & Berrens, R. P.
178
They also offered no explanation for their selected GHG emissions damage coefficient
153
This critique of existing literature estimating Bitcoin’s overall energy use and
emissions impact yields three takeaways for policymakers. First, more cooperation
between researchers and miners is needed to generate the most accurate possible
estimates. CBECI uses as application program interface (API) which allows mining pools
to report data anonymously (CBECI 2022). Incorporating empirical data into estimates is
address spoofing measures (e.g., virtual private networks) – but it helps limit the number
of assumptions and parameter estimates in the model. Second, academics should be more
explicit about the limits of their estimation methodologies and more transparent about the
precision of their results. Almost all the studies and indexes reviewed here fail to include
robust sensitivity analyses. Finally, knowledge of how the Bitcoin network actually
works in practice can help us identify which studies include nonsensical assumptions and
therefore yield estimates that should not be taken seriously. For example, understanding
the circumstances under which it is economically profitable for a Bitcoin miner to operate
informs which mining equipment should be feasibly included in both top-down and
bottom-up estimations.
function of distance from major Bitcoin mining locations. While several studies have
estimated aggregate costs of cryptocurrency mining, less research has focused on its
comments, public meeting records) to find common threads in the local debate around the
154
costs and benefits of hosting large-scale miners. They found citizens were concerned
about much more than potential increases in their electricity bills, suggesting that studies
like this one which focus solely on economic impacts may ignore critical elements of a
Drennen (2022) conducted a life cycle inventory and analysis of a single natural gas
power plant dedicated to Bitcoin mining. Their focus on a single plant enabled them to
develop a clear and replicable research design, yielding precise results and conclusions
based on data-driven analysis. They found a fossil fuel generator solely dedicated to
Bitcoin mining was very profitable and a significant contributor to GHG emissions in a
One criticism of overly restrictive mining regulation is that it can shut out much-
penetration in upstate New York. They found that cryptominers caused high electricity
bills for residential households and small businesses, crowded out the local economy, and
created fewer new jobs relative to other similar industries. Points about both relatively
limited job creation and higher electricity bills are substantiated by other research on the
local impacts of PoW mining (Congressional Research Service 2019) and basic energy
economic theory – all else equal, a sudden increase in demand without new supply should
cause higher prices, particularly in deregulated retail electricity markets. But their
“crowding out” conclusions were based on results that local fixed asset investments and
labor market wage levels declined due to cryptomining entrants by just 0.36% and 0.68%,
155
Benneton et al. (2021) is one of the most econometrically rigorous works on the
topic but still suffered from a flawed instrumental variable methodology and a lack of
understanding about the economics of PoW mining. Their stage 1 estimation tried to
capture “the elasticity of location-based marginal price to the price of Bitcoin" (15) with
the idea that large spikes in Bitcoin price cause an exogenous shock to electricity demand
due to cryptomining. They found each “10% increase in the price of Bitcoin is associated
to a 1.4% increase in the location-based marginal price” (16) suggesting increased mining
as the causal mechanism between the two. Assuming they behave as rational actors,
miners will run at full potential so long as they can operate below a certain breakeven
point based on Bitcoin price, network hashrate and price of electricity.179 Subsequent
increases in Bitcoin price (all else equal) will not cause such miners to suddenly turn on
suggests that wholesale prices “pass-through” to retail prices at rates below 100% across
several energy markets (Mirza and Bergland 2012; Mulder and Willems 2019; Brown et
al. 2020).
This essay explores whether Bitcoin mining might incentivize renewable growth.
2019. An exploratory qualitative case study showed hydro, solar, wind, and geothermal
179
In some markets where miners can participate in ancillary services, they may choose to turn off even if
mining would be profitable (below breakeven point) due to demand response incentives. For a
comprehensive explanation and mathematical model of Bitcoin mining economics, see Appendix A.
180
Unless the Bitcoin price jumps so high as to make less efficient ASICs profitable at the new breakeven
point.
156
2019). Semi-structured interviews revealed these miners were certainly motivated to
protect the environment, but cheap renewable energy prices enabled profit maximization
and served as the primary driver of eco-innovative business models. DeVries (2019)
largely dismissed the possibility of sustainable Bitcoin mining using renewable energy
over the long term based solely on a brief analysis of hydro-based mining in southwest
China and aforementioned faulty assumptions about ASIC utility and lifecycle longevity.
Several studies have used quantitative models and simulations to consider the
wind plants with PoW mining rigs. Shan and Sun (2019) looked at Bitcoin mining as a
They determined the optimum number of mining rigs needed to minimize curtailment at
solar PV generation sites across California and calculated potential mining profits using
curtailed energy based on the daily market price of Bitcoin. Two later studies took a more
mines with wind projects (Bastian et al. 2021) and a group of engineers from the Institute
of Electrical and Electronics Engineers (IEEE) did the same for solar photovoltaic (PV)
projects (Eid et al. 2021). Both studies ran various simulations and found mining
enhanced project profitability and could bolster early investment incentives. Findings
from Eid et al. (2021) even suggested pairing solar PV projects with Bitcoin mines was
more profitable than battery storage due to relatively lower capital costs.
Like Shan and Sun (2019), Niaz et al. (2022) ran simulations for mining curtailed
energy within a specific regional independent system operator (ISO) but focused on
Texas. However, their study used empirical data regarding curtailments, Bitcoin price,
157
and network hashrate at an hourly level and considered optimal mining scenarios from
the perspective of the ISO (maximize use of curtailed renewable energy) and the investor
(maximize profits). Most importantly, their sensitivity analysis and Monte Carlo
simulations found a floor price of Bitcoin for which mining curtailed energy would still
volatility.181 Much like Eid et al. (2021), Niaz et al. (2022) also found Bitcoin mining was
more profitable than battery storage options due to their relative costs.
Finally, this study limits its scope to examining Bitcoin mining with solar and
wind power. Early evidence suggests mining cryptocurrency off flared gas may greatly
reduce GHG emissions (Vazquez and Crumbley 2022) and mining using carbon capture
technologies may also be profitable (Niaz et al. 2022).182 Opportunities exist to study the
economics of PoW mining using hydroelectric and Ocean Thermal Energy Conversion
The second major research question of this essay is whether Bitcoin mining
contributes to grid stability. The studies above assumed grid-independent Bitcoin mining
from the perspective of renewable-only generators. But most Bitcoin mining today is
done in “front of the meter,” meaning miners draw power from the grid. This limits the
181
They found the price would need to stay above $6800/BTC. This is of critical importance because at the
time the study was submitted, BTC was trading at ~$40,000 and has since dropped as low as ~$16600.
182
Exxon has a pilot project with Crusoe Energy to run Bitcoin mining data centers off excess or flared gas
in North Dakota (Malik 2022).
183
Hydroelectric Bitcoin mining is happening in several locations around the world. Nathaniel Harmon is
an oceanographer exploring the possibility of building an OTEC-based Bitcoin mine in Hawaii.
158
connected Bitcoin mining cannot guarantee the use of curtailed renewable energy only
and raises concerns about grid stability and higher prices during periods of high demand.
paired with two kinds of flexible data centers: one used for machine learning (Amazon
Web Services) and the other for Bitcoin mining. They found pairing both types of
flexible data centers with renewable plants boosted their net present values when
compared to their standalone applications, but they argued Bitcoin mining data centers
stability and participate in demand response (DR) programs. This argument was based on
other scholarship about the relationship between data center flexibility and ability to
participate in DR (Santana-Viera et al. 2015; Bai et al. 2016; Thimmel et al. 2019). But
like the studies outlined above, the Fridgen et al. (2021) analysis focused primarily on the
energy economics of data centers and renewable plants. A great deal of scholarship
explaining how flexible data centers and interruptible loads offer solutions for renewable
intermittency exists as well (Wierman et al. 2014; Xia et al. 2015; Hale et al. 2016).
Energy experts and crypto enthusiasts have discussed potential synergies between DR
and cryptomining data centers, but few rigorous studies have focused specifically on
various types of loads and predict certain grid outcomes. Texas’ deregulated energy
market and standalone grid (separate from the Eastern and Western Interconnections)
makes it ideal for detailed synthetic grid development and DR analysis (Li et al. 2020).
Rhodes et al. (2021) used a capacity expansion model designed for high-renewable power
159
systems (Johnston et al. 2019) to model the optimal energy mix for the Texas grid under
various scenarios of increased data center demand throughout the state.184 Wind and solar
capacities were highest and natural-gas capacities were lowest in scenarios with more
data center flexibility.185 They found additional inflexible data centers resulted in more
carbon emissions than a base case with no additional data centers while more flexible data
centers could “result in a net-reduction of carbon emissions from the base case” and
“increase the resiliency of the grid by reducing demand during high-stress times”
Bruno et al. (2022) found that adding Bitcoin demand to a “long-run equilibrium
capacity investment” (2) model of the Texas grid increased renewable capacity and
carbon emissions as generation from natural gas plants would also have to increase along
with renewables to keep up with demand. However, another version of the simulation
eliminated the additional carbon emissions. Menati et al. (2022) added new
Texas power grid and looked at outcomes in terms of locational marginal pricing (LMP)
and DR profits for cryptomining facilities. Adding new mining loads increased average
LMPs statewide and created large price fluctuations. However, LMP increases were
highly dependent on the location of the new notional mine, the amount of added capacity,
and were most pronounced during the warmest hours of the day during summer
184
The software for this specific model was developed by Johnston et al. (2019). Rhodes et al. (2021)
define a capacity expansion model as “an optimization program that makes decisions about the operation,
retirement, and construction of power plans, transmission lines, and other electric grid assets.” (4)
185
With “flexibility” defined as the data center’s capability to shed load quickly in response to increased
demand
160
months.186 Ultimately, the location of cryptocurrency mines had “decisive impact”
(Menati et al. 2022, 9) in determining costs and benefits to the Texas grid. However, they
reduce their loads to maximize profits when electricity prices were high. In sum, their
findings emphasized the nuance involved with incorporating new high-capacity loads
onto electrical grids and the importance of future coordination between grid operators and
3.3.7 Summary
Using CBECI as the standard, most studies have overestimated the Bitcoin
(107.6 TWh) was comparable to 2021 levels (104.9 TWh), marking the first time mining
did not consume vastly more electricity year-over-year in the asset’s history, despite
record high hashrate (CBECI 2022). Context and perspective matter in framing this
amount of power use. The Bitcoin network consumes more power in a year than at least a
dozen countries, but less than 10 individual U.S. states. Value judgments of what
constitutes a good use of energy are highly subjective. Those who feel cryptocurrency is
a worthless endeavor see its energy consumption as obviously wasteful, just as those who
To this end, the field could benefit from more comparative studies of the energy
costs associated with securing various economic networks.188 Bitcoin proponents argue
186
LMP increases were also geographically dependent. Some regions saw little to no increase in LMP after
adding Bitcoin demand while others saw massive increases.
187
Christmas lights consumed an estimated 3.5 TWh for the month of December 2020 (Conca 2020).
188
McCook (2014) compared Bitcoin’s estimated energy use and carbon footprint relative to that of the
banking system, gold mining/recycling, paper currency minting, etc. and found Bitcoin’s consumption and
environmental impacts to be the lowest relative to the others. However, as previously mentioned, McCook
is a self-described “Bitcoin evangelist.”
161
expending energy to derive value is the whole point of its existence – it serves as the very
forcing function the asset’s security depends upon. Digiconomist, DeVries (2019), and
even OSTP (2022) have used a per-transaction basis for comparing Bitcoin to other
methods of value exchange (e.g., credit card transactions) while completely ignoring the
Bitcoin transactions now occur.189 Future research might consider Bitcoin’s scalability
through the lens of the Lightning Network and compare its energy requirements to the
2019) are needed to ensure all costs, benefits, and positive/negative externalities not
captured in quantitative data are considered in crafting digital asset public policy. The
field also desperately needs more rigorous and objective assessments of Bitcoin’s carbon
footprint. Accounting for less than 0.5% of the world’s electricity consumption, the
suggestion that Bitcoin could be solely responsible for a 2°C rise in average global
temperature in just 16 years defies logic, yet the Mora et al. (2018) study is cited ad
meter mining (Roeck and Drennen 2022) and more precise analyses of energy mix based
on mining location can improve the precision of rigorous GHG estimates (CBECI 2022).
Policymakers might also consider ways to compel miners to share their data to increase
189
Layer 2, commonly called the “Lightning Network,” is a protocol built on top of Bitcoin’s base layer
designed to alleviate the base layer’s scalability issues. Transactions on the Lightning Network occur off-
chain between two parties for very low fees and near-instantaneous settlement compared to the base layer.
A full explanation of this layer 2 protocol is outside the scope of this essay and it is so new that few
academic studies examining the network exist (Lin et al. 2020; Seres et al. 2020). A network explorer has
been developed by ACINQ, a Bitcoin technology company https://explorer.acinq.co/
162
In a systematic review of academic literature related to sustainable development
goals and cryptocurrencies, Mustafa et al. (2021) found most literature was
environmental impacts. They identified a “clear gap in the literature that focuses on the
development goals. The purpose of this study is to help fill that gap. Theoretically based
research, project simulations, and synthetic grid modeling are good tools for planning and
forecasting, but the field lacks rigorous empirical assessments of mining impacts.
This study is designed to use empirical data to describe Bitcoin mining’s role in
renewable energy development and grid stability efforts. ERCOT’s market structure and
the recent influx of new Bitcoin mining make Texas a great location to study these
relationships and test my research questions (3.4.1). I then describe how available data
can be used to test each question, and how certain data limitations may impact the
to Texas because of its low energy prices and friendly regulatory environment (Feng
2021; Sigalos 2021; Rutwitch and Feng 2022). The goal of this work is to provide
rich Texas to explore potential impacts in practice as opposed to modeling them. Rhodes
et al. (2021) did not consider potential negative effects of increased data center load
capacity. I try to capture those negative effects by looking at wholesale energy price
163
changes near new Bitcoin mining data centers. Bruno et al. (2022) “abstracted away from
the details of the miners’ operational decisions” (15). Menati et al. (2022) admitted “it is
rightfully possible that mining facilities apply more sophisticated load control strategies”
but assumed mining facilities consumed “a fixed amount of loads for all time steps” (6)
for the sake of simplicity in the model. But we should expect miners to respond to real-
time (RT) and day-ahead market (DAM) price signals and adjust their loads accordingly
to maximize profits. Pulling actual LMP data captures miner behavior and responses to
miners currently engage in grid stability efforts and what can be done to maximize
decisions that are hard to measure, there is a significant lag between the decision to build
a power plant and when that plant is registered in publicly available data, and
comprehensive data on power purchase agreements (PPAs) are limited.190 But the
high amounts of renewable energy. Of course, when drawing power from the grid, there
is no guarantee of what type of energy is being consumed. However, west to east export
190
PPAs are contracts between power generators (sellers) and large energy consumers (buyers) to help
finance and build renewable projects.
164
(ERCOT 2022), and low LMPs capture the costs of congestion (Singh et al. 2010;
of the eastern and western interconnections which bind the rest of the continental United
only, deregulated energy market. Generators sell energy on the wholesale market while
retail electricity providers (REPs) compete to buy this energy, and then sell/deliver it to
end-users with the “power to choose” their electric providers (Brown et al. 2020).192 One
feature of this system is relatively high price caps and low price floors compared to other
RTOs/ISOs.193 This allows a wide range of high and negative wholesale energy prices to
exist simultaneously across different locations which can be flagged to signal congestion
constraints.
Question 2: What do energy prices look like before and after Bitcoin mining data centers
come online?
also leads to substantially higher energy prices, miners and renewable producers stand to
gain as other local consumers pay more for their electricity. This question explores
191
Commuter traffic congestion pricing in Singapore is an instructive analogy for LMP pricing on electric
grids. Singapore’s electronic road pricing (ERP) system charges motorists a fee for driving in highly
congested areas. These fees adjust in real-time according to the amount of congestion. In the same way that
different ERP rates indicate different amounts of traffic across time and space, LMPs are a proxy for
congestion on electricity grids.
192
The Public Utility Commission of Texas’ “Power to Choose” system allows consumers to query
potential REPs on their powertochoose.org website. Consumers can pick plans that best suit their needs
depending on who services the area they live in.
193
The FERC manages price caps for other RSOs/ISOs through the issuance of formal orders. For example,
Order No. 831 set a $2000/MWh hard cap and further restrictions on any market prices above $1000/MWh
that do not apply to ERCOT because it is “not subject to the Commission’s jurisdiction under… the Federal
Power Act” (FERC 2022). ERCOT has had price caps as high as $9000/MWh in 2021.
165
miners and producers, or if a win-win-lose dynamic is more at play when considering
local stakeholders.
maximize efficiency leading to lower prices for most consumers relative to the U.S.
average (Stoft 2002; Hartley et al. 2019). Wholesale electricity price changes do not
“pass through” perfectly to retail and residential customers as REPs factor wholesale
price volatility into retail quotes by charging risk premiums (Brown et al. 2020). Still,
(marginal) costs in their prices (Hartley et al. 2019) and retail quotes decrease as
customer switching activity increases (Brown et al. 2020). For the purposes of this study,
this means immediate LMP changes are an imperfect proxy for the prices
retail/residential customers see. However, wholesale volatility does price into retail in
other ways, so a large sample of LMPs over longer periods of time should capture the
impacts of various exogenous shocks (i.e., increased base load due to Bitcoin mining).
West Texas sees a relatively high frequency of low and negative wholesale energy
prices, with limited periods of extremely high energy prices typically due to weather
events causing massive amounts of supply to come offline simultaneously. For example,
in 2021, average hourly prices in the West Load Zone (LZ) were single digit or negative
($/MWh) almost 20% of the time while prices over $50/MWh occurred less than 10% of
the time.194 Most of the extremely high pricing (>$100MWh) occurred during Winter
194
Average wholesale electricity prices in the United States vary by region, but prices above $50/MWh
would generally be considered higher than average. Average wholesale energy prices in the United States
166
Figure 3.5 Hourly Wholesale Energy Price Frequency in West Texas in 2021 (author)195
whether Bitcoin miners help stabilize the grid: 1) DR participation rates; and 2)
examining miner activity during tail-end events (e.g., major winter storms). In demand
response programs, consumers are compensated for scaling back consumption when
load. ERCOT has a separate, robust DR market with large amounts of publicly available
data about its participants. If in fact Bitcoin miners are uniquely suited to provide grid
specifically in those requiring highly flexible and controllable loads. Also, regardless of
during high energy pricing events. If miners are rational economic actors and mining is
were as low as $27/MWh in January 2021 and as high as $41/MWh in July 2021 (Thomas 2021; Wood
Mackenzie 2021).
195
Author generated from “Historical RTM Load Zone and Hub Prices” data files (ERCOT 2022)
167
both highly interruptible and highly responsive to real-time price changes, miners should
shut down their ASICs when electricity costs rise above certain breakeven prices.196
Bitcoin miners are not required to publicly disclose the precise location of their
operations. Cross referencing publicly available satellite imagery with returns from basic
internet keyword searches, YouTube videos, news articles, information from mining
company websites and quarterly earnings reports yielded 11 major mining sites across 8
20MW for inclusion in the sample. The level of fidelity on when each site is operating
and at what capacity varies depending on the amount of information available and the
responsiveness of each company to inquiries and requests for further information. The
conclusions which can be drawn regarding the impact(s) of each mining site vary to some
degree depending on that level of fidelity. What is/is not known about each location and
determine regional energy mixes. EIA-860 collects details on power plants and
196
Again, this price point depends on Bitcoin price, network hashrate, and ASIC efficiency
197
See Appendix B for details on information sources regarding capacity (size) and locations
168
generators including, but not limited to, their locations (lat-long), nameplate capacity, and
generation type. Any existing and proposed power generators that are grid-connected
with the ability to draw/deliver power to the grid and a nameplate capacity of 1 MW or
greater are required to fill out EIA-860.198 Precise coordinates allow me to plot generator
generators are relative to the locations of major Bitcoin mines. Nameplate capacities of
these generators show how much active power generation comes from renewable sources.
Recent LMP pricing data are publicly available on the ERCOT website and
ERCOT makes historical LMP data available to researchers by request. LMP data show
LMP name, time, and price, but ERCOT does not publish coordinates for their LMPs.
However, LMP names and locations are shown on ERCOT’s real-time market pricing
map. Exact coordinates can be determined and plotted on GIS since LMP settlement
points (SPs) are visible on publicly available satellite imagery.199 Finally, I create an
aggregate dataset of LMPs by settlement point name, location, and price organized into a
5-minute interval time series for years 2017-2022.200 Using GIS, I build regional
wholesale energy pricing profiles over time to determine whether proximity to a Bitcoin
198
Plants can consist of several generators at the same location, so each plant is assigned a unique
identification code and multiple generators can share the same plant code. I sorted by generator type first,
and then used plant codes to assign generators coordinates for entry into GIS.
199
NOTE: Brown et al. (2020) LMP nodal coordinate data used with permission. Brown et al. (2020) data
was then updated for 2022 since some LMPs are eliminated, several names and locations of LMPs are
changed, and some LMPs are added periodically.
200
Data stops October 2nd for the year 2022. Final locational time series data set includes only LMPs
common to each year. Descriptive statistics section includes all LMP pricing data from each year.
169
To examine miner participation in grid stability efforts, my quantitative data are
limited to what miners were willing to share.201 ERCOT established controllable load
resource (CLR) qualification requirements in 2020 and Lancium shared a limited data
sample (July-August 2022) of how their software works with Bitcoin mining to meet
CLR standards. I use a model for determining the dynamic breakeven price for Bitcoin to
show when miners were likely economically motivated by market conditions to curtail or
shutdown operations. Finally, qualitative data from news articles, quarterly earnings
reports, and interviews shed light on the pros and cons of ERCOT’s current DR market
3.5 Results
This section first shows where large, grid-connected Bitcoin mines are located in
Texas relative to different types of power generators and regional energy mixes across
the state (3.5.1). It also covers how often settlement points near these major Bitcoin
mines experience negative LMPs. I then examine whether the presence of an active
Bitcoin mine correlates with higher nearby wholesale energy prices relative to the rest of
the region/state (3.5.2). Finally, this section concludes with a look at how one data center
Growth
For the year 2021, Texas had a total of 928 unique plants with 1737 generators.202
Each individual plant has a unique location. A single plant can also host multiple
201
ERCOT publishes DR market participation by qualified scheduling entity (QSE) and load resource
names, but I was unable to determine which QSEs/load resources represent Bitcoin miners.
202
ERCOT manages most of the state’s energy balancing, but a few small regions to the north, west and
east do not fall under its balancing authority.
170
generators of varying types at the same location. EIA recognizes 18 forms of generator
technology that exist in Texas and most active generators (933) still use natural gas-based
technologies.203 416 generators in Texas fit the EIA definition for renewable technology
and 78% of these generators are wind (212) or solar (111).204 For decades the Permian
Basin has been a powerhouse for U.S. domestic oil and gas extraction and production, but
it is now one of the most popular locations for renewable projects. Of ERCOT’s six
major load zones (LZs) depicted in Figure 3.6, the West LZ has the highest percentage of
Most major Bitcoin mining facilities (8/11) are in the West LZ near this abundant
and expanding bastion of renewable energy. The three concentric rings around each red
dot seen in Figure 3.7 capture the local energy mixes within 25km, 50km, and 100km of
203
EIA recognizes: Battery, Hydroelectric, Coal (Steam), Hydroelectric, Flywheels, Landfill gas, 4 forms
of natural gas, nuclear, wind (onshore), 2 forms of petroleum, Solar PV, Wood/Biomass, and 3 forms of
“other” technology
204
Wind, solar PV, hydroelectric, wood/biomass, and landfill gas are considered renewable energy
technologies by the EIA. In Table 3.4 and GIS mapping, hydroelectric, wood/biomass, and landfill gas are
categorized as “other renew”
205
The two very small LZs, Lower Colorado River Authority and Rayburn Electric Coop, were included in
the South and North LZs for the sake of simplicity in GIS mapping. Table 3.4 includes active plants only
(EIA-860 tracks retired and proposed plants as well).
206
Some of Texas (gray areas in Figure 3.6) fall outside of the ERCOT region. ERCOT accounts for 75%
of the Texas land area and delivers 90% of electricity used across the entire state (ERCOT 2023).
171
each mining data center.207 Geographic proximity is only a proxy for the likely source of
a grid-connected data center’s power, so I consider both the quantity of nearby generators
by type (Table 3.5) and the local energy mix surrounding large mines (Table 3.6). Table
3.5 shows the number of generators within those rings by each power generation
technology type according to EIA data. EIA-860 also reports the precise nameplate
capacity for a more accurate depiction of the renewable energy mix within each ring. It
shows the wide range of clean and carbon-based mining occurring in the state. For
example, Lancium aptly titles their data centers in Fort Stockton and Abilene as “clean
campus” facilities, sourcing almost all power from 100% renewable sources nearby.
However, the two Rockdale data centers demanding the highest power capacities of all
mining facilities in the state still pull from a disproportionately high non-renewable
energy mix. Wind, solar and other renewable sources generated 31% of electricity
ERCOT-wide in 2022 (Irfan 2023). 8 of the 11 Bitcoin mining data centers in this study
are in regions where renewables accounts for at least 60% of power capacity within
Figure 3.7 Example of Select Data Centers with Energy Mix Concentric Rings (author)
207
Figure 3.8 is just an example depicting three data centers, but this proximity-based data collection was
done for all Bitcoin mining facilities.
172
Table 3.5 Number of Power Plants Near Bitcoin Mining Facilities by Energy Technology
Technology Type Wind Solar Other Renew Total Renew All % Renew
Location Distance within
Ft. Stockton 25km 0 0 0 0 4 0%
West LZ 50km 3 4 0 7 14 50%
100km 6 18 0 24 49 49%
Pyote* 25km 0 0 0 0 4 0%
West LZ 50km 0 4 0 4 14 29%
100km 5 16 0 21 56 38%
Rockdale** 25km 0 0 0 0 2 0%
South LZ 50km 0 1 0 1 7 14%
100km 0 7 3 10 56 18%
*3 mining facilities in Pyote
**2 mining facilities in Rockdale
Table 3.6 Power Capacity Near Bitcoin Mining Facilities by Energy Technology (MW)
Technology Type Wind Solar Other Renew Total Renew Total All Types % Renew
Location Distance within
Ft. Stockton 25km 0 0 0 0 8.8 0%
West LZ 50km 292 700.2 0 992.2 1001 99%
100km 820.2 2779.6 0 3599.8 4236.5 85%
173
The most interesting finding relating to the geographic positioning of Bitcoin
mines has to do with their proximity to SPs with a high frequency of negative LMPs.
Negative LMPs are most frequent in the West LZ by a wide margin, consistent with
LMPs occurred an average of 6,394 times per SP (i.e., individual LMP location) across
Texas in 2021.209 Frequency of negative LMPs for SPs within 100km of Bitcoin mine
locations was much higher, indicating that most mining data centers are well-positioned
to provide demand during periods of depressed pricing (Table 3.7). The probability of a
negative LMP from the miner sample (SPs within 100km of a Bitcoin data center) was
56.3% higher than the ERCOT-wide average. Four of the eight locations (Fort Stockton,
Upton County, Pyote, and Afton210) saw negative wholesale energy prices at twice the
Only two of eight data center locations, Rockdale (South LZ) and Denton (North
LZ) are in regions with a below-average frequency of negative pricing. Denton’s negative
208
Of the five major load zones, the West LZ was responsible for 61% of negative LMPs, followed by the
South LZ with 26%.
209
LMP observations taken at 5-minute intervals throughout the entire year.
210
SPs around Afton have the highest frequency of negative LMPs of any SPs in the entire state.
174
LMP frequency is below the state SP average, but above the median. But SPs around
Rockdale certainly have negative pricing less often than the rest of the state. It is possible
that the combined power draw of the two large Bitcoin mining facilities in Rockdale has
reduced the frequency of negative LMPs. However, SPs around Rockdale have
historically had a lower frequency of negative LMPs relative to the rest of the state, even
before Riot Blockchain and Bitdeer built their mines. In 2018 well before either facility
was built, SPs within 100km of Rockdale saw negative LMPs an average of 422 times,
between 2017 and 2020 (Table 3.8). A massive jump in mean wholesale energy prices in
2021 can be mostly attributed to Winter Storm Uri. Dropping LMP observations during
the storm decreases the average 2021 LMP by ~$34/MWh.211 Still, average wholesale
prices increased significantly from 2020 to 2021 even after correcting for both Winter
Storm Uri and hot summer months. While a great deal of new Bitcoin mining came
online during this period, a 66% jump in Texas natural gas industrial prices in Q4 2021
accounts for this rise in wholesale energy prices (Webb 2022; EIA 2022).212 Persistent
elevated natural gas prices combined with increased demand during hot summer months
led to a continued increase in average wholesale energy prices in 2022 (Figure 3.8).213
211
Observations were dropped from February 12 th through February 18th
212
Jan.-Sep. ’21 average price (excluding February for Winter Storm Uri): $3.66/thousand cubic feet; Oct.-
Dec. ’21 Average price: $6.09/thousand cubic feet (EIA 2022)
213
ERCOT even asked Texans to keep thermostats set above 78 degrees to help keep energy demand down
during the hottest summer days (Ferman 2022).
175
Table 3.8. ERCOT Average Locational Marginal Prices
Time Period N Mean Median Min Max Variance Std. Dev.
2017 646 26.45 25.52 16.37 47.40 30.54 5.53
Summer 638 28.05 27.57 20.03 38.27 3.24 1.80
Figure 3.8 (right) ERCOT Average LMP and Natural Gas Price Over Time (author)
Historically, the West LZ where most major Bitcoin mining is now located had
higher wholesale energy prices relative to other regions in the state, particularly during
the winter months. Figures 3.9-3.12 compare ERCOT settlement point prices214 (SPP)
across load zones. Q4 2019 and Q1 2020 average SPPs in the West LZ were twice as
expensive as the other five major ERCOT load zones. More recently, this trend changed
significantly as VRE penetration has increased in the region. The West LZ had the lowest
average SPPs of all LZs in five of the last seven quarters (Q1 2021-Q3 2022). Still,
pricing differences between the West LZ and the rest of the state are small. The average
West LZ SPP was just $3/MWh and $4/MWh lower than the rest of the LZs for 2020 and
2022, respectively.215
214
Settlement point prices are another measure of real-time wholesale energy pricing. They are measured in
15-minute intervals and reflect what price energy settles or closes at, where LMPs are measured in 5-
minute intervals and represent the marginal cost of producing additional energy.
215
Data only available through Q3 2022.
176
Figures 3.9-3.12 Average Settlement Point Prices by Load Zone, 2019-2022 (author)
To examine wholesale energy pricing near large-scale Bitcoin miners, I took the
yearly means of LMPs within 25km, 50km, and 100km of each data center location from
2017-2022.216 Figures in Appendix B show these average LMPs compared to the ERCOT
wide averages for the same time periods. Comparisons of LMPs at different distances
allows us to see whether proximity to high demand mining data centers affects average
wholesale energy prices. Information about when data centers come online allows for
expect to see the 25km (red) and 50km (purple) trend lines to be higher than the 100km
(blue) on the charts after the point in time where mines become operational.
However, the level of fidelity regarding how much capacity is online and when
varies between the various locations. Mining companies are not required to report when
216
Again, LMP data stop October 2nd, 2022 and only include observations from LMPs common across the
entire timeframe for comparison purposes. 2021 data reflect dropped observations from Winter Storm Uri
(February 12th through February 18th)
177
they are online and how much power they draw.217 For those loads coming online late in
the time series, it is harder to draw ex-post conclusions about their pricing impacts.
average is still useful in assessing whether regional wholesale energy pricing played a
Appendix B. Overall, I find that proximity to Bitcoin mining data centers has no
correlation to changes in wholesale energy prices. Including LMPs falling within 100km
of an active data center lowers average price more than $1/MWh compared to the 25km
& 50km proximities at just three of eight locations, while average prices actually increase
with distance from the data center at two locations. Additionally, only three data centers
were built in regions with historically low wholesale energy costs. In fact, four data
centers were built at locations with higher locational marginal prices relative to the
ERCOT average since 2017. In 2022, LMPs around all five “green” data centers (>60%
renewable energy mix, see Table 2.6) are lower than the ERCOT average, whereas LMPs
Still, yearly averages may not effectively capture pricing dynamics when system
conserve power “by setting their thermostats to 78-degrees or above and avoiding the
217
ERCOT also does not make this information publicly available. Most of the information regarding when
facilities came online was pulled from publicly available sources: press releases, earnings reports, news
stories, and even Chapter 11 filings (Compute North). I reached out to each company to confirm the
data/information I found, comment on the study, and participate in a semi-structured interview. Few
responded at all, and only one company (Lancium) chose to confirm publicly available information and
share some additional data.
178
usage of large appliances (such as dishwashers, washers and dryers) during peak hours
between 3 p.m. and 8 p.m.” due to “unseasonably hot weather driving record demand
across Texas” (ERCOT 2022). Figure 3.13 shows average LMPs for all SPs within
100km of a Bitcoin mining facility during peak demand hours (3PM-8PM) from May
through August 2022. Five locations saw average LMPs at or below the ERCOT-wide
average, and seven locations averaged LMPs at or below the ERCOT-wide median
settlement point LMP. The breakeven price of energy for major high-efficiency miners
throughout most of this period was well below average wholesale energy prices across all
regions.218 The rational economic miner would turn off their equipment above this
breakeven price, but would still contribute to increased demand up until this price point.
Table 3.9 summarizes descriptive statistics and the results of a two-tail t-test comparison
between average LMPs for all ERCOT SPs and all SPs falling within 100km of a Bitcoin
mining data center during this same high demand period. The mean LMP for SPs near
Bitcoin mining facilities was slightly higher (~$2/MWh) than the ERCOT-wide average.
However, the median LMP for SPs near these data centers was lower than the ERCOT
median and t-test results indicate there is no meaningful difference between the two
group means.
218
The average breakeven price of energy for Bitcoin mining profitability with a S19 Pro miner was around
$125/MWh during this period. The breakeven price of energy for profitable Bitcoin mining is dynamic. It
depends on mining equipment and Bitcoin market/network conditions (i.e., ASIC model, market price, total
network hashrate). I elaborate on the breakeven price model in Appendix A.
179
Figure 3.13 Average LMPs During High Demand Hours, May-August ’22 (author)
Table 3.9 Statistical Comparison of LMPs: High Demand Summer '22 ($/MWh)
ERCOT ALL SPs SPs w/in 100km BTC
Mean $145.93 $147.90
Median $151.11 $146.38
Minimum $30.00 $121.32
Maximum $217.77 $178.15
Variance $1,351.31 $103.67
Observations 802 110
t Stat -1.22
P(T<=t) two-tail 0.22
t Critical two-tail 1.96
It is possible that companies hosting new loads in the early stages of coming fully
online are too small to impact nearby electricity prices. But the most interesting finding
of this study is that proximity to massive mining loads has almost no correlation to higher
average wholesale energy prices over the course of an entire year. Riot Blockchain hosts
the largest cryptocurrency mine in North America less than a mile from Bitdeer’s
170MW mine in Rockdale, Texas (Sigalos 2021). Both facilities were operational with a
combined capacity of at least 470MW when Bitcoin’s price hit all-time highs and all
Chinese-based hashrate fell offline in 2021, making it even easier and more profitable to
180
mine Bitcoin. Yet, LMPs within 25, 50, and 100km of Rockdale were just $1/MWh
higher than the ERCOT-wide average in 2021, continuing a trend for the region of LMPs
at or near ERCOT yearly averages. However, the average LMP for the 17 SPs within
100km of Rockdale were $15.69/MWh higher than the ERCOT-wide average during the
under a qualified scheduling entity (QSE). QSEs must meet certain qualification
requirements to submit schedules and bids for their load resources to participate in
various demand response programs. QSEs are often separate entities which act as
behalf (Menati et al. 2022). ERCOT makes data available on demand response
participation on day-ahead market disclosure reports. But data are sorted by “load
resource name” and/or QSE name (depending on the report). Load resource names are
made up of alphanumeric characters, but neither the type of load nor who owns that load
is clear from the load resource name. ERCOT provides a list of QSEs, but it is not clear
which QSE might represent a Bitcoin mining data center and mining companies were
generally unwilling to share this information with me for this research.219 Without the
ability to match bitcoin facilities to QSE or load resource names, there is little useful
quantitative data from ERCOT beyond statewide trends in demand response program
219
I reached out to each company owning a Bitcoin mining data center referenced in this paper and the
Texas Blockchain Council to try to match QSE and load resource names to mining operations. Several
companies did not respond to my requests for information at all, and those who did were unwilling to
provide the necessary information to tie ERCOT DAM data to their specific mining loads.
181
participation rates, which say nothing about Bitcoin mining impacts on grid flexibility
efforts.
ERCOT sheds some light on the unique ability of data centers to qualify as
load resources (NCLRs) with the capability to precisely follow and respond to security
constrained economic dispatch220 (SCED) base point instructions over short intervals.
commensurate with real-time grid operator instructions. NCLRs and other demand
(ERCOT 2022). In year-end reports on demand response for 2021 and 2022, Bitcoin
mining data centers were the “first substantial amount of conventional load to participate
in the AS market as a Controllable Load Resource” in 2020 (ERCOT 2021) and are still
This kind of flexibility benefits both grid operators and cryptocurrency miners
adjusting to real-time changes. Ancillary services are sold in day ahead markets and
delivered in real time. For example, ERCOT maintains certain load resources as
responsive reserve services (RRS) to restore grid frequency “within the first few minutes
of an event that causes a significant deviation from the standard frequency” (ERCOT
2005). If an RRS-participant load sells a day-ahead ancillary, they must be online and
available if called upon by ERCOT. If a black swan event occurs with a large mismatch
between the AS clearance price and a much higher real-time price, these load resources
cannot “sell back” the ancillary services they bought in the day-ahead market; they must
220
ERCOT (2023) defines SCED as “the real-time market evaluation of offers to produce a least-cost
dispatch of online resources”
221
ERCOT added three new CLRs in 2021 and sixteen in 2022
182
consume energy at the real-time price to stay compliant with their ancillary sale (Helman
2021).
Lancium’s CLR software dynamically adjusts its power use to real time pricing
changes and/or grid operator instructions. This allows its Bitcoin mining data centers to
avoid high prices and turn down consumption during periods of high system-wide
demand. Figure 3.14 shows Lancium’s Fort Stockton active power consumption
compared to real-time energy prices in LZ West and Figure 3.15 shows the comparison to
consumption dramatically during periods of high real time prices during a hot week in
mid-July. 222 These large drops in power consumption typically correspond to increases in
Figure 3.14 Fort Stockton Electricity Use vs. LZ West Energy Prices (author)223
222
The breakeven price for Bitcoin mining profitability with a S19 Pro miner was around $125/MWh
during that week. This is based on a model for determining the breakeven price of energy depending on
mining equipment and Bitcoin market/network conditions (i.e., ASIC model, market price, total network
hashrate). I elaborate on this breakeven price model in Appendix A.
223
Figures 14 and 15 are author-generated from raw data provided directly to the author from Lancium.
Lancium provided their active power use during July and August 2022, only.
183
Figure 3.15 Fort Stockton Electricity Use vs. System Wide Demand
High degrees of flexibility and mining partnership with grid operators also enable
miners to rapidly offload power demand in response to certain grid conditions. Figure
3.16 shows how Fort Stockton miners dropped 50MW of power consumption within
seconds during an underfrequency event in January 2022. ERCOT CEO Brad Jones
touted the utility of Bitcoin mining in providing grid flexibility in March 2022 saying,
“cryptocurrency [mining] is very unique in that way in that all of the loads can come off.
Most other data centers, whether Microsoft or any other data center provider like
Amazon, they all have customers to serve every other day so they can’t just turn off – but
these cryptocurrencies can” (CNBC 2022). In February 2021, Winter Storm Uri led to
widespread power loss, several deaths, and economic losses exceeding $200 billion in
Texas (ASCE 2021). The following winter, virtually all industrial Bitcoin mining shut
184
down ahead of Winter Storm Landon to relieve pressure on the grid (Gkritsi 2022).224
The Texas Blockchain Council (TBC) worked directly with ERCOT to ensure Bitcoin
mining was part of the solution, and not a contributor to the problem in 2022. In a letter
to Texas Governor Gregg Abbot, TBC wrote “Just as important as the positive market
signals we send to generators is our unique ability to immediately shed load when
ERCOT demands it. This sort of demand response has and should continue to be a
3.6 Discussion
Power grids are complex systems wherein supply, demand, and pricing vary over
time and space. The results of this study rely on quantitative empirical data to describe
the state of the ERCOT grid relative to the presence of large Bitcoin mining data centers.
Most of these data centers are positioned in regions with a relatively high proportion of
224
While Winter Storm Uri was more severe than Landon, less than 100,000 Texans lost power during
Landon, and power was able to be restored much faster because there were no rolling blackouts leading to
grid failure.
185
renewable energy and a high frequency of negative wholesale energy prices (3.5.1). But
analysis (3.6.1). Time series data also indicate no correlation between these data centers
and wholesale energy prices, but policymakers should consider retail markets and other
factors impacting local communities (3.6.2). Lastly, some evidence from Fort Stockton,
Texas suggests Bitcoin mines are particularly well-suited to function as highly flexible
data centers. But more empirical data on widespread miner participation in demand
response programs is needed to conclude Bitcoin mining helps provide grid flexibility in
infrastructure in West Texas pre-dates the inflow of most new Bitcoin mining hashrate in
the state. Nearly all the mining power analyzed in this study came online after 2020. It is
still too early to conclude that the arrival of new Bitcoin mining causes further growth of
new renewable projects that would not have been developed otherwise. Future EIA Form
860 data on both “proposed” and “operable” generators could allow for a quantitative
study (e.g., difference in difference) comparing renewable growth trends before and after
the arrival of new Bitcoin mining. Of course, such studies would require more concrete
data on precisely when these data centers came online (as well as how much power they
between cryptocurrency miners and power plants were publicly available, hybrid project
research studies (Bolinger et al. 2021; 2022; Gorman et al. 2022) could be conducted as
well.
186
If anything, it is more likely that the causal link has run in the opposite direction:
saturation of renewables leads to congestion and a higher frequency of low and negative
wholesale energy pricing which entices Bitcoin miners to set up nearby. The results of
this study demonstrate that most Bitcoin miners in Texas choose areas with
disproportionately high levels of renewable energy relative to the rest of the state. It
stands to reason that the presence of flexible data centers in these regions provide a
consistent and reliable customer of excess renewable energy during low pricing events.
Former ERCOT CEO Brad Jones said, “crypto has found a way to come into our market
and take some of that excess wind in off-peak periods… we can use that cryptocurrency
to soak up the excess generation and really provide a home for more wind and solar to
Still, the largest mining data centers by capacity are in Rockdale, Texas; a region
low on renewable energy capacity. Grid-connected power consumption draws from the
energy mix of the region (Table 2.6). If cryptocurrency mining incentivizes further
power plants (Roeck and Drennen 2022; Millman 2022) and creates fewer new jobs than
growth unacceptable. The results of this study suggest energy-intensive data centers can
187
improve the economics of renewable projects as curtailment and congestion continue to
grow in regions with high VRE penetration like West Texas. An “all or nothing” policy
approach to cryptocurrency mining fails to recognize either the costs or benefits of its
This study yields little evidence to support claims that Bitcoin mining
significantly impacts nearby wholesale energy prices most of the time. Results suggest
exceptionally large data centers like Rockdale may contribute to higher nearby energy
prices during periods of high system-wide demand (Figure 3.13). But convincing causal
claims to that end would require demand data from these large data centers at the hourly
time interval. If these miners were to provide such data, researchers could identify
exactly when they curtail energy consumption relative to the dynamic breakeven price of
energy for Bitcoin miners, nearby wholesale energy prices, and system wide demand as
seen in seen in the analysis of Lancium data in section 3.5.3 (Figures 3.15 and 3.16).
Surprisingly, high regional wholesale energy prices relative to the rest of the state
do not appear to factor into miner decision-making calculus on where to locate their data
centers. For example, Fort Stockton, Upton County, and Pyote, Texas are all within
100km of one another. Regional LMPs were higher than the ERCOT-wide average prior
to new Bitcoin mines becoming operational, but lower than the ERCOT average in 2022
188
However, these results do not speak to the retail customer experience. Subsequent
studies might look specifically at whether retail electricity pricing is similarly unaffected
by nearby mining data centers by analyzing REP data (Hartley et al. 2019). Like
studies should look at localized cryptomining impacts beyond energy prices. Finally,
while cryptocurrency adoption is growing, the number of U.S. adults who use it is still
small (Faverio and Massarat 2022). A full cost-benefit analysis must consider that
response programs and ancillary services markets is limited but supports theoretical
QSE and/or load resource names, researchers have no way of quantitatively and
empirically assessing DR/AS participation rates. Still, the fact that cryptomining data
centers in Texas are the only loads to qualify for CLR certification supports claims that
these interruptible loads are uniquely suited to partner with grid operators in efforts to
boost grid flexibility in real time. Data shared from Lancium (Figures 3.14-3.16)
demonstrate how quickly these loads can reduce power consumption and aid in frequency
response. More hourly electricity consumption data sharing from mining companies
could show skeptics how natural, built-in economic incentives (i.e., high energy prices)
189
are in fact causing these data centers to scale back operations during periods of peak
demand.
There is also the question of whether the ERCOT demand response programs
costs to Texans when that money could be used to develop more transmission or battery
storage to cope with renewable intermittency. A report by the Tech Transparency Project
(2022) found “Bitcoin miners may collect as much as $170 million a year from programs
that pay large energy consumers for their willingness to shut down” (3). However, this
claim (and others made throughout the report) was unsubstantiated by empirical data and
no explanation was given for how this total yearly figure was calculated. Still, it is clear
from SEC filings that miners like Riot Blockchain (Rockdale, TX Bitcoin mine owner)
back to ERCOT in exchange for cash payments, rather than providing the power to our
customers during these peak times” (Riot Blockchain Inc 2021, 11). This occurs when
cryptominers like Riot Blockchain enter into contracts which lock in electricity prices at
specific rates ahead of time to avoid tail-end event volatility. While it received no
revenue from demand response in 2019 and just $9 million in 2020, Riot Blockchain
reported it was entitled to receive $125.1 million for its power sales during Winter Storm
A report on the costs and benefits pairing cryptocurrency mining with demand
response efforts finds a “win-win range of curtailed hours when both the utility and
crypto miner are better off than the status quo of no coordination and no demand
response” (Wright and Shaban 2022). This range depends on miner revenue factors like
190
cryptocurrency price, hashrate, and mining equipment efficiency, and grid conditions for
the utility (i.e., grid manager). Optimum hours of mining curtailment which maximize
utility wholesale value differ from that of the miner’s optimum level of curtailment hours
Wright and Shaban (2022) find wholesale energy prices correlate with grid emissions,
therefore emissions reductions are possible when grid managers issue “an emissions
intensity signal” to “modulate crypto load and contribute to reducing grid emissions.”
In sum, the results of this study suggest there is potential for Bitcoin and
critical to mutual success. Limited data shared from Lancium demonstrates how miners
react to price signals in real time and assist grid managers during underfrequency events
within seconds. Grid managers like ERCOT should be transparent with their customers
about the costs and benefits of demand response programs, and those costs/benefits
3.7 Conclusion
…the more demand to the degree that its flexible – that it can turn down whenever we
need the power for other customers – is fantastic. We can use that cryptocurrency to soak
up the excess generation and really provide a home for more wind and solar to come to
our state. And at the same time, it reduces their consumption during periods where we
get tight and we need the power for other customers. Now what we have to do in Texas is
figure this thing out. Its new. The solar is new, the batteries are new, and this
cryptocurrency is new. We have to find a way to utilize it within our system most
advantageously… we have to figure out ways to make sure we’re putting them at the right
location and that we can build out our transmission grid to accommodate them.
- Former ERCOT CEO Brad Jones (CNBC 2022)
191
This essay set aside normative arguments for or against the utility of
cryptocurrencies in favor of an objective exploration of how the world’s largest and most
energy-intensive cryptocurrency might serve as a tool in the energy transition. The scope
of this study is narrowly focused on a single energy grid – isolated from the Western and
from most states. Subsequent studies might consider how the specific structures of
ERCOT’s energy pricing, demand response programs, and ancillary services market work
in concert with PoW mining that may not be applicable to the rest of the United States.
centers as a panacea for renewable energy development and grid stability fail to capture
the nuance of what is at stake for grid operators and the customers who rely on it.
Academic studies suggesting the elimination of Bitcoin mining might help prevent the
world from a climate catastrophe are similarly biased and wildly misleading. In Texas,
cryptocurrency miners have demonstrated the ability to provide a constant customer for
impacting wholesale energy prices. Limited empirical work suggests they are capable of
functioning as interruptible data centers grid operators can partner with to make energy
grids more flexible under the right circumstances. Both are needed to facilitate a
transition to the green grid of the future which will power the net-zero economy.
term solutions to a reliable energy grid. But they are also expensive (Desing and Widmer
2022), time-consuming (Cohn and Jankovska 2020), and natural resource-intensive (Xu
et al. 2020). If managed properly, PoW- based cryptocurrency mining can serve as one of
192
many helpful solutions in the energy transition. Natural economic forces disincentivize
miners from using power when it is expensive and needed most. But a deregulated
market failures which regulators must compensate for. I propose three specific policy
data
Researchers need access to data for analysis and grid operators must insist on
the relationship between the grid and cryptocurrency mining requires a high degree of
mechanisms work in practice. With data transparency, researchers can produce more
studies that help citizens better understand the costs and benefits of incorporating more
cryptomining data centers along the power grid. Sharing detailed time series demand data
could allow studies like this one to include regressions drawing more causal relationships
between a data center’s load and nearby energy prices in real time.225
2. Grid operators in deregulated energy markets like ERCOT should establish shut off
criteria for non-essential loads like cryptocurrency miners – particularly during periods
of high demand.
Relying on the free market to regulate cryptocurrency miner demand works when
the breakeven price of energy for mining profitability is low. Economically rational
225
The data shared from Lancium (seen in Figures 3.15 and Figure 3.16) is a great example of this.
193
miners will turn off their equipment when energy prices are too expensive relative to the
revenue potential of mined Bitcoin. But the price of Bitcoin can surge rapidly, raising the
breakeven price of energy and creating a revenue incentive for miners to keep ASICs
running despite high prices and a high level of overall system demand. Without
participation in demand response, such miners could add to the risk of grid failure and
Thus far, the Texas Blockchain Council has voluntarily worked with ERCOT
managers to ensure large-scale miners shed load and relieve pressure on the grid when
needed. But there is no requirement for cryptominers to join the TBC or follow ERCOT
establish a ceiling price of energy or system demand above which cryptomining and other
non-essential uses of power are not permitted when economic conditions (i.e., the
3. Incentivize mining in regions with a high proportion of renewable energy for grid-
connected miners.
While most large-scale miners in Texas are in regions with relatively high
percentages of nearby renewable power generation, the largest mining operations in the
state are in regions which rely heavily on carbon-emitting energy sources (Table 3.6).
the form of a carbon tax on companies running data centers in these regions.
194
Lastly, this study focuses on grid-connected Bitcoin mining in a deregulated
energy market that lacks connection to the Western and Eastern Interconnections. This
effectively creates a unique situation where Texas is the only state which does not have
the ability to draw significant amounts of power from other states (Oxner 2022). The
external validity of the findings of this study may be limited as energy regulation and the
Subsequent studies might examine energy pricing around PoW cryptocurrency mining in
different types of energy markets and policymakers should consider the costs and benefits
generators sourcing power behind-the-meter could shed light on further opportunities for
195
Bibliography
Abbate, Janet. 1999. Inventing the Internet. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Abrahamson, Eric, and Charles, J. Fombrun. "Forging the Iron Cage: Interorganizational
Networks and the Production of Macro‐culture." Journal of Management
Studies 29, no. 2 (1992): 175-194.
Agarwal, Ajay, Genevieve Giuliano, and Christian L. Redfearn. "Strangers in our Midst:
the usefulness of exploring polycentricity." The Annals of Regional Science 48
(2012): 433-450.
Agranoff, Robert, and Michael McGuire. "Big Questions in Public Network Management
Research." Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 11, no. 3
(2001): 295-326.
Agranoff, Robert. “Inside Collaborative Networks: Ten Lessons for Public Managers.”
Public Administration Review 66 (2006): 56–65.
Aikema, David, Rob Simmonds, and Hamidreza Zareipour. "Data centres in the ancillary
services market." In 2012 International Green Computing Conference (IGCC), pp.
1-10. IEEE, 2012.
Akhtar, Tanzeel, and Sidhartha Shukla. “Bitcoin (BTC USD) Mining Is Back in China
despite Government Ban.” Bloomberg.com, Bloomberg, 17 May 2022,
https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2022-05-17/china-makes-a-comeback-
in-bitcoin-mining-despite-government-ban.
Aligica, Paul D., and Vlad Tarko. "Polycentricity: from Polanyi to Ostrom, and
beyond." Governance 25, no. 2 (2012): 237-262.
Alizadeh, Ali, Mohammad Reza Saghafi, Javad Rezaei, Alireza Fereidunian, and Hamid
Lesani. "Performance-based regulation framework for demand-side
management." In 2019 24th Electrical Power Distribution Conference (EPDC):
54-59. IEEE, 2019.
"An Interview with F.A. Hayek (1984)." Liberty In Our Time. May 1, 1984. Video,
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=s-k_Fc63tZI.
196
Andersson, Krister P., and Elinor Ostrom. "Analyzing Decentralized Resource Regimes
from a Polycentric Perspective." Policy Sciences 41 (2008): 71-93.
Ashraf, Aoyon. "Largest Bitcoin Mining Pool Blocks Internet Access From Mainland
China." CoinDesk. October 14, 2021.
https://www.coindesk.com/business/2021/10/14/largest-
bitcoin-mining-pool-blocks-internet-access-from-mainland-china/.
Atzori, Marcella. "Blockchain technology and decentralized governance: Is the state still
necessary?." Available at SSRN 2709713 (2015).
Baer, Greg. "Central Bank Digital Currencies: Costs, Benefits and Major Implications for
the U.S. Economic System." Bank Policy Institute. April 7, 2021.
https://bpi.com/central-bank-digital-currencies-costs-benefits-and-major-
implications-for-the-u-s-economic-system/.
Bai, Linquan, Fangxing Li, Hantao Cui, Tao Jiang, Hongbin Sun, and Jinxiang Zhu.
"Interval optimization based operating strategy for gas-electricity integrated
energy systems considering demand response and wind uncertainty." Applied
energy 167 (2016): 270-279.
Bayer, Dave, Stuart Haber, and W. Scott Stornetta. "Improving the Efficiency and
Reliability of Digital Time-stamping." In Sequences II: Methods in
Communication, Security, and Computer Science, pp. 329-334. Springer New
York, 1993.
Bayern, Shawn. "Dynamic common law and technological change: the classification of
Bitcoin." Washington & Lee Law Review Online 71 (2014): 22.
Benetton, Matteo, Giovanni Compiani, and Adair Morse. "When cryptomining comes to
town: High electricity-use spillovers to the local economy." Available at SSRN
197
3779720 (2021).
Biden, Joseph R. "FACT SHEET: President Biden Sets 2030 Greenhouse Gas Pollution
Reduction Target Aimed at Creating Good-Paying Union Jobs and Securing U.S.
Leadership on Clean Energy Technologies." The White House. April 22, 2021.
Bier, Jonathan. 2021. The Blocksize War: The Battle over Who Controls Bitcoin’s
Protocol Rules.
Blandin, Apolline, Ann Sofie Cloots, Hatim Hussain, Michel Rauchs, Rasheed Saleuddin,
Jason G. Allen, Bryan Zheng Zhang, and Katherine Cloud. "Global cryptoasset
regulatory landscape study." University of Cambridge Faculty of Law Research
Paper 23 (2019).
Böhme, Rainer, Nicolas Christin, Benjamin Edelman, and Tyler Moore. "Bitcoin:
Economics, technology, and governance." Journal of economic Perspectives 29,
no. 2 (2015): 213-238.
Brafman, Ori and Rod A Beckstrom. 2006. The Starfish and the Spider : The
Unstoppable Power of Leaderless Organizations. New York: Portfolio.
Brockland, Beth, Thea Garon, Andrew Dunn, Eric Wilson, and Necati Celik. "U.S.
Financial Health Pulse 2019 Trends Report." Financial Health Network (2019).
https://finhealthnetwork.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/06/2019-Pulse-Trends-
Report_updated.pdf.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Central Bank Digital Currency."
November 4, 2022. https://www.federalreserve.gov/central-bank-digital-
currency.htm.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. "Report on the Economic Well-
Being of U.S. Households in 2019 - May 2020." May 21, 2020.
https://www.federalreserve.gov/central-bank-digital-currency.htm.
Bolinger, Mark, Will Gorman, Joseph Rand, Ryan H. Wiser, Seongeun Jeong, Joachim
Seel, Cody Warner, and Bentham Paulos. "Hybrid power plants: Status of
installed and proposed projects." (2021).
Bolinger, Mark, Will Gorman, Joseph Rand, Seongeun Jeong, Joachim Seel, and Cody
Warner. "Hybrid Power Plants: Status of Operating and Proposed Plants." (2022).
Bordo, Michael. "The Imbalances of the Bretton Woods System between 1965 and 1973:
US Inflation, the Elephant in the Room." Centre for Economic Policy Research.
June 7, 2019. https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/imbalances-bretton-woods-system-
between-1965-and-1973-us-inflation-elephant-room.
198
Borri, Nicola, and Kirill Shakhnov. "Regulation spillovers across cryptocurrency
markets." Finance Research Letters 36 (2020): 101333.
Brown, David P., C H. Tsai, C K. Woo, J Zarnikau, and S Zhu. "Residential Electricity
Pricing in Texas's Competitive Retail Market." Energy Economics 92, (2020).
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2020.104953.
Browne, Ryan. "Bitcoin Production Roars Back in China despite Beijing’S Ban on
Crypto Mining." CNBC. May 18, 2022. https://www.cnbc.com/2022/05/18/china-
is-second-biggest-bitcoin-mining-hub-as-miners-go-underground.html.
Bruggers, James. "Overwhelmed by Solar Projects, the Nation’S Largest Grid Operator
Seeks a Two-year Pause on Approvals." Mountain State Spotlight. Inside Climate
News, February 2, 2022.
https://mountainstatespotlight.org/2022/02/02/overwhelmed-by-solar-
projects-the-nations-largest-grid-operator-seeks-a-two-year-pause-on-approvals/.
Bruno, August, Paige Weber, and Andrew Yates. "Can Bitcoin Mining Increase
Renewable Electricity Capacity?." (2022).
Buskens, Vincent. "The social structure of trust." Social networks 20, no. 3 (1998): 265-
289.
Buskens, Vincent. "The Social Structure of Trust." Social Networks 20, no. 3 (1998):
265-289.
Buterin, Vitalik. “DAOs, DACs, DAs and More: An Incomplete Terminology Guide”
Ethereum Foundation Blog (2014). https://blog.ethereum.org/2014/05/06/daos-
dacs-das-and-more-an-incomplete-terminology-guide/
California ISO. "What the Duck Curve Tells Us about Managing a Green Grid." 2021.
https://www.caiso.com/documents/flexibleresourceshelprenewables_fastfacts.pdf.
Calvo-Pardo, Hector F., Tullio Mancini, and Jose Olmo. "Machine learning the carbon
footprint of bitcoin mining." Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15, no. 2
(2022): 71.
199
Carlisle, Keith, and Rebecca L. Gruby. "Polycentric Systems of Governance: A
theoretical model for the commons." Policy Studies Journal 47, no. 4 (2019): 927-
952.
Carter, Nic. "How Much Energy Does Bitcoin Actually Consume?" Harvard Business
Review, May 21, 2021. https://hbr.org/2021/05/how-much-energy-does-bitcoin-
actually-consume.
Carter, Nic, and Shaun Connell. "Miners Are the Optimal Buyers: The Data Behind
Bitcoin-Led Decarbonization in Texas." Bitcoin Magazine, October 28, 2021.
https://bitcoinmagazine.com/business/bitcoin-mining-fits-texas-energy-grid.
Casey, Michael J., and Paul Vigna. The Truth Machine: The Blockchain and the Future
of Everything. St. Martin's Press, 2018.
Casey, Michael, Jonah Crane, Gary Gensler, Simon Johnson, and Neha Narula. "The
impact of blockchain technology on finance: A catalyst for change." (2018).
Castells, Manuel. 1996. The Information Age: Economy, Society and
Culture. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
Castro, Miguel, and Barbara Liskov. "Practical byzantine fault tolerance." In OsDI, vol.
99, pp. 173-186. 1999. https://pmg.csail.mit.edu/papers/osdi99.pdf
Catalini, Christian, and Joshua S. Gans. "Some Simple Economics of the Blockchain."
NBER Working Paper Series, (2019).
https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w22952/w22952.pdf.
Champagne, Phil. 2014. The Book of Satoshi: The Collected Writings of Bitcoin Creator
Satoshi Nakamoto. E53 Publishing LLC.
Chiles, Todd H., and John F. McMackin. “Integrating Variable Risk Preferences, Trust,
and Transaction Cost Economics.” The Academy of Management Review 21, no. 1
(1996): 73–99. https://doi.org/10.2307/258630.
200
“Notice on Further Preventing and Dealing with the Risk of Hype in Virtual Currency
Transactions.” People's Bank of China, April 1, 2021.
http://www.pbc.gov.cn/goutongjiaoliu/113456/113469/4348521/index.html?mc_cid
=b0a97b47fa&mc_eid=f1124a997c
Coase, Ronald H. 1987. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. University of Chicago Press.
Cohn, Julie, and Olivera Jankovska. "Texas CREZ Lines: How Stakeholders Shape
Major Energy Infrastructure Projects." Center for Energy Studies, Rice
University (2020).
Chen, Hao, Michael C. Caramanis, and Ayse K. Coskun. "The data center as a grid load
stabilizer." In 2014 19th Asia and South Pacific Design Automation Conference
(ASP-DAC), pp. 105-112. IEEE, 2014.
Chen, Junlong, Xiaomeng Wang, and Jiali Liu. "Corporate Social Responsibility and
Capacity Sharing in a Duopoly Model." Applied Economics Letters 28, no. 6
(2021): 512-517.
Church, Jeffrey, and Neil Gandal. "Network Effects, Software Provision, and
Standardization." The Journal of Industrial Economics (1992): 85-103.
Clayton, Jay. "Statement on Cryptocurrencies and Initial Coin Offerings." U.S. Securities
and Exchange Commission (2017).
Creutzig, Felix, Peter Agoston, Jan Christoph Goldschmidt, Gunnar Luderer, Gregory
Nemet, and Robert C. Pietzcker. "The underestimated potential of solar energy to
mitigate climate change." Nature Energy 2, no. 9 (2017): 1-9.
Croman, Kyle, Christian Decker, Ittay Eyal, Adem Efe Gencer, Ari Juels, Ahmed Kosba,
Andrew Miller. "On Scaling Decentralized Blockchains: (A Position Paper)."
In Financial Cryptography and Data Security: Revised Selected Papers 20 (2016):
106-125.
201
“Cryptocurrency Regulations by Country.” Thomson Reuters, 2022,
https://www.thomsonreuters.com/en-us/posts/wp-
content/uploads/sites/20/2022/04/Cryptos-Report-Compendium-2022.pdf.
"Crypto Mines Help ERCOT Keep Renewable Energy Operational, Says Interim CEO."
CNBC Television. March 18, 2022. Video,
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=gKnRfDeFgr0&t=2s.
De Filippi, Primavera, and Aaron Wright. Blockchain and the Law: The Rule of Code.
Harvard University Press, 2018. https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctv2867sp.
Denhardt, Robert B., and Janet Vinzant Denhardt. “The New Public Service: Serving
Rather Than Steering.” Public Administration Review 60, no. 6 (2000): 549–59.
Desing, Harald, and Rolf Widmer. "How much energy storage can we afford? On the
need for a sunflower society, aligning demand with renewable
supply." Biophysical Economics and Sustainability 7, no. 2 (2022): 3.
De Vries, Alex, and Christian Stoll. "Bitcoin's growing e-waste problem." Resources,
Conservation and Recycling 175 (2021): 105901.
Dietz, Thomas, Elinor Ostrom, and Paul C. Stern. "The Struggle to Govern the
Commons." Science 302, no. 5652 (2003): 1907-1912.
Dion, Derek A. "I'll gladly trade you two bits on Tuesday for a byte today: Bitcoin,
regulating fraud in the economy of Hacker-cash." U. Ill. JL Tech. & Policy (2013):
165.
Dittmar, Lars, and Aaron Praktiknjo. "Could Bitcoin emissions push global warming
above 2° C?." Nature Climate Change 9, no. 9 (2019): 656-657.
Ducas, Evangeline, and Alex Wilner. "The security and financial implications of
blockchain technologies: Regulating emerging technologies in
Canada." International Journal 72, no. 4 (2017): 538-562.
202
Campbell-Verduyn) Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains and
Global Governance (forthcoming).
Dwork, Cynthia, and Moni Naor. "Pricing via processing or combatting junk mail."
In Advances in Cryptology—CRYPTO’92: 12th Annual International Cryptology
Conference Santa Barbara, California, USA August 16–20, 1992 Proceedings 12,
pp. 139-147. Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 1993.
Dwivedi, Vimal, Alex Norta, Alexander Wulf, Benjamin Leiding, Sandeep Saxena, and
Chibuzor Udokwu. "A Formal Specification Smart-Contract Language for
Legally Binding Decentralized Autonomous Organizations." IEEE Access 9,
(2021): 76069-76082. https://doi.org/10.1109/ACCESS.2021.3081926.
De Vries, Alex. "Bitcoin's growing energy problem." Joule 2, no. 5 (2018): 801-805.
De Vries, Alex. "Renewable energy will not solve bitcoin’s sustainability problem." Joule
3, no. 4 (2019): 893-898.
De Vries, Alex, Ulrich Gallersdörfer, Lena Klaaßen, and Christian Stoll. "Revisiting
Bitcoin’s carbon footprint." Joule 6, no. 3 (2022): 498-502.
Dylan-Ennis, Paul J. "The Rise and Fall of Bitcoin Culture." Coindesk. October 17, 2022.
https://www.coindesk.com/layer2/2022/10/11/the-rise-and-fall-of-bitcoin-
maximalism/.
Economides, Nicholas, and Charles P. Himmelberg. "Critical Mass and Network Size
with Application to the US Fax Market." NYU Stern School of Business EC-95-
11 (1995).
Eggers, William, and John O'Leary. 2009. If We Can Put a Man on the Moon: Getting
Big Things Done in Government. Harvard Business School Press.
Electric Power Research Institute. "Strategies and Actions for Achieving a 50%
Reduction in U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions by 2030." November 10, 2021.
http://mydocs.epri.com/docs/public/EPRI-Whitepaper-Strategies-and-Actions-for-
US-GHG-Reduction.pdf.
Farrell, Joseph, and Garth Saloner. "Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation,
product preannouncements, and predation." The American Economic
Review (1986): 940-955.
203
ERCOT. "ERCOT Methodologies for Determining Ancillary Service Requirements."
2005. https://www.ercot.com/files/docs/2004/08/16/wms08192004_3.doc.
ERCOT Public. "Long-Term West Texas Export Study." ERCOT. January 14, 2022.
Faverio, Michelle, and Navid Masserat. "46% of Americans Who Have Invested in
Cryptocurrency Say It’S Done Worse than Expected." CNBC. Pew Research
Center, August 23, 2022. https://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2022/08/23/46-
of-americans-who-have-invested-in-cryptocurrency-say-its-done-worse-than-
expected/.
Feng, Coco, Che Pan, and Masha Borak. "Bitcoin Miners: China’s Cryptocurrency
Crackdown Pushes Companies Overseas." South China Morning Post, May 31,
2021. https://www.scmp.com/tech/policy/article/3135515/bitcoin-mining-
refugees-chinas-cryptocurrency-crackdown-pushes-miners.
Financial Stability Board. "Targets for Addressing the Four Challenges of Cross-Border
Payments." Bank of International Settlements. October 13, 2021.
https://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/P131021-2.pdf.
Fletcher, Emma. "Reports Show Scammers Cashing in on Crypto Craze." Federal Trade
Commission, June 3, 2022. https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/data-
visualizations/data-spotlight/2022/06/reports-show-scammers-cashing-crypto-
craze.
Florita, Anthony R., Kara Clark, Vahan Gevorgian, Maria Folgueras, and Erin
Wenger. Grid Frequency Extreme Event Analysis and Modeling. No. NREL/CP-
5D00-70029. National Renewable Energy Lab.(NREL), Golden, CO (United
States), 2017.
"Ford Would Replace Gold With Energy Currency and Stop Wars." New York Tribune,
December 4, 1921. https://chroniclingamerica.loc.gov/lccn/sn83030214/1921-12-
04/ed-1/seq-1/.
Foley, Sean , Bart Frijns, Alexandre Garel, and Tai-Yong Roh. "Who Buys Bitcoin? The
Cultural Determinants of Bitcoin Activity." International Review of Financial
Analysis 84, (2022). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2022.102385.
204
Fridgen, Gilbert, Marc-Fabian Körner, Steffen Walters, and Martin Weibelzahl. "Not all
doom and gloom: How energy-intensive and temporally flexible data center
applications may actually promote renewable energy sources." Business &
Information Systems Engineering 63 (2021): 243-256.
Fung, Archon, and Erik Olin Wright. Deepening democracy: Institutional innovations in
empowered participatory governance. Vol. 4. Verso, 2003.
Ghemawat, Pankaj, and Joan E. Ricart I Costa. “The Organizational Tension between
Static and Dynamic Efficiency.” Strategic Management Journal 14 (1993): 59–
73.
Gkritsi, Eliza. "Bitcoin Miners Powered Off as Winter Storm Battered North America."
CoinDesk. December 26, 2022.
https://www.coindesk.com/business/2022/12/26/bitcoin-miners-powered-off-as-
winter-storm-battered-north-america/.
Goldsmith, Stephen, and William D. Eggers. Governing by Network: The New Shape of
the Public Sector. Brookings Institution Press, 2004.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.7864/j.ctt12879qp.
Gorman, Will, Andrew Mills, Mark Bolinger, Ryan Wiser, Nikita G. Singhal, Erik Ela,
and Eric O’Shaughnessy. "Motivations and options for deploying hybrid generator-
plus-battery projects within the bulk power system." The Electricity Journal 33, no.
5 (2020): 106739.
205
Granovetter, Mark. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of
Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 3 (1985): 481–510.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/2780199.
Greenberg, Pierce, and Dylan Bugden. "Energy consumption boomtowns in the United
States: Community responses to a cryptocurrency boom." Energy Research &
Social Science 50 (2019): 162-167.
Griffith, Saul. Electrify: An optimist’s playbook for our clean energy future. MIT Press,
2022.
Gnyawali, Devi R., and Ravindranath Madhavan. "Cooperative networks and competitive
dynamics: A structural embeddedness perspective." Academy of Management
review 26, no. 3 (2001): 431-445.
Guo, Ye, and Chen Liang. "Blockchain Application and Outlook in the Banking
Industry." Financial Innovation 2, no. 24 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1186/s40854-
016-0034-9.
Hacker, Philipp, and Chris Thomale. "Crypto-securities regulation: ICOs, token sales and
cryptocurrencies under EU financial law." European Company and Financial Law
Review 15, no. 4 (2018): 645-696.
Hafner, Katie, and Matthew Lyon. "Casting the Net." Sciences-New York 36, no. 5
(1996): 32-37.
Hajdarbegovic, Nermin. "Bitcoin Miners Ditch Ghash.Io Pool Over Fears of 51%
Attack." Coindesk. January 9, 2014.
https://www.coindesk.com/markets/2014/01/09/bitcoin-miners-ditch-ghashio-pool-
over-fears-of-51-attack/.
206
Hale, Elaine, Brady Stoll, and Trieu Mai. "Capturing the Impact of Storage and Other
Flexible Technologies on Electric System Planning." National Renewable Energy
Laboratory, (2016).
Hall, Peter Geoffrey, and Kathy Pain, eds. The polycentric metropolis: Learning from
mega-city regions in Europe. Routledge, 2006.
Hardy, Cynthia, Stewart Clegg, and Walter R. Nord, eds. Handbook of Organization
Studies. Sage Publications, 1996.
Hardy, Cynthia, Nelson Phillips, and Tom Lawrence. "Distinguishing trust and power in
interorganizational relations: Forms and facades of trust." Trust within and between
organizations (1998): 64-87.
Harper, Colin. "The Cost of Sound Money: New Tool Tracks Bitcoin's Energy
Consumption." Bitcoin Magazine, July 4, 2019.
https://bitcoinmagazine.com/business/cost-sound-money-new-tool-tracks-bitcoins-
energy-consumption.
Hart, Herbert L. 1961. The Law as a Union of Primary and Secondary Rules. Oxford
University Press.
Hartley, Peter R., Kenneth B. Medlock III, and Olivera Jankovska. "Electricity reform
and retail pricing in Texas." Energy Economics 80 (2019): 1-11.
Helman, Udi. "Demand response in the US wholesale markets: Recent trends, new
models, and forecasts." Variable generation, flexible demand (2021): 211-257.
Henderson, M. Todd, and Max Raskin. "A regulatory classification of digital assets:
toward an operational Howey test for cryptocurrencies, ICOs, and other digital
assets." Colum. Bus. L. Rev. (2019): 443.
Hileman, Garrick, and Michel Rauchs. "2017 Global Blockchain Benchmarking Study."
207
Available at SSRN 3040224 (2017).
Ho, Benjamin. 2021. Why Trust Matters: An Economist's Guide to the Ties that Bind Us.
Columbia University of Press.
Holland, Frank. "Visa Says Crypto-linked Card Usage Hit $2.5 Billion in Its First
Quarter." CNBC. January 28, 2022. https://www.cnbc.com/2022/01/28/visa-says-
crypto-linked-card-usage-hit-2point5-billion-in-its-first-quarter.html.
Hsieh, Ying-Ying, Jean-Philipe Vergne, Philip Anderson, Karim Lakhani, and Markus
Reitzig. "Bitcoin and the Rise of Decentralized Autonomous Organizations."
Journal of Organizational Design 7, no. 14 (2018).
https://doi.org/10.1186/s41469-018-0038-1.
Hutton, Christopher. "New York Passes First Crypto-mining Ban in US." Washington
Examiner. November 23, 2022.
https://www.washingtonexaminer.com/policy/technology/new-york-
first-crypto-mining-united-states.
Insull, Samuel. "The Obligations of the Monopoly Must Be Accepted." Central Station
Electric Service, (1910): 118-122. ed. by William E. Keilly (Chicago: Private
Printing, 1915), https://energyhistory.yale.edu/library-item/samuel-insull-
obligations-monopoly-must-be-accepted-1910.
Irfan, Umair. "Clean Energy Is Taking over the Texas Grid. State Officials Are Trying to
Stop It." Vox. January 30, 2023. https://www.vox.com/science-and-
health/23577512/texas-clean-energy-wind-solar-natural-gas-ercot-blackout.
208
Indiana University, 1972.
Jiang, Shangrong, Yuze Li, Quanying Lu, Yongmiao Hong, Dabo Guan, Yu Xiong, and
Shouyang Wang. "Policy assessments for the carbon emission flows and
sustainability of Bitcoin blockchain operation in China." Nature
communications 12, no. 1 (2021): 1-10.
Jones, Chris. "Are There Too Many Cryptocurrencies?" Coin Telegraph. September 21,
2022. https://cointelegraph.com/news/are-there-too-many-cryptocurrencies.
Jones, Candace, William S. Hesterly, and Stephen P. Borgatti. "A general theory of
network governance: Exchange conditions and social mechanisms." Academy of
management review 22, no. 4 (1997): 911-945.
Jones, Benjamin A., Andrew L. Goodkind, and Robert P. Berrens. "Economic estimation
of Bitcoin mining’s climate damages demonstrates closer resemblance to digital
crude than digital gold." Scientific Reports 12, no. 1 (2022): 14512.
Kahrl, Fredrich, Hyungkwan Kim, Andrew D. Mills, Ryan H. Wiser, Cristina Crespo
Montañés, and Will Gorman. "Variable renewable energy participation in US
ancillary services markets: economic evaluation and key issues." (2021).
Kaloudis, George. "China Can’t Seem to Stop Bitcoin Mining." CoinDesk. May 22,
2022. https://www.coindesk.com/layer2/2022/05/22/china-cant-seem-to-stop-
bitcoin-mining/.
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro. "Product introduction with network
externalities." The Journal of Industrial Economics (1992): 55-83.
Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro. “Systems Competition and Network Effects.” The
209
Journal of Economic Perspectives 8 no. 2 (1994): 93–115.
Kazek, Kelly. "Could Muscle Shoals Have Been a Hub Rivaling Detroit? Henry Ford
Thought So." Advance Local. January 17, 2013.
https://www.al.com/living/2013/01/post_89.html.
Khalif, David. "What Happens When All 21 Million Bitcoin Are Mined?" Nasdaq. June
8, 2022.
Kharpal, Arjun. "Crypto Firms Say Thousands of Digital Currencies Will Collapse,
Compare Market to Early Dotcom Days." CNBC. May 3, 2022.
https://www.cnbc.com/2022/06/03/crypto-firms-say-thousands-of-digital-
currencies-will-collapse.html.
Klingert, Sonja, and Sebastian Szilvas. "Spinning gold from straw-evaluating the
flexibility of data centres on power markets." Energy Informatics 3 (2020): 1-34.
Kloosterman, Robert C., and Sako Musterd. "The Polycentric Urban Region: Towards a
research agenda." Urban studies 38, no. 4 (2001): 623-633.
Kushner, David. "4. Dead End on Silk Road." The Best Business Writing (2014): 56-76.
Columbia University Press.
Kreiner, Kristian, and Majken Schultz. "Informal collaboration in R & D. The formation
of networks across organizations." Organization studies 14, no. 2 (1993): 189-
209.
Krause, Max J., and Thabet Tolaymat. "Quantification of energy and carbon costs for
mining cryptocurrencies." Nature Sustainability 1, no. 11 (2018): 711-718.
Lamport, Leslie, Robert Shostak, and Marshall Pease. "How to Time-stamp a Digital
Document." ACM Transactions on Programming Languages and Systems 4, no. 3
(1982): 382-401. https://lamport.azurewebsites.net/pubs/byz.pdf.
210
Larimer, Daniel. "DAC Revisited." Let's Talk Bitcoin (blog). November 2, 2013.
https://letstalkbitcoin.com/dac-revisited.
Larimer, Stan. “Bitcoin and the Three Laws of Robotics.” Let’s Talk Bitcoin (blog).
September 14, 2013. https://letstalkbitcoin.com/bitcoin-and-the-three-laws-of-
robotics.
LeClair, Dylan, and Sam Rule. "The Ethereum Merge: Risks, Flaws and the Pitfalls of
Centralization." Bitcoin Magazine, August 18, 2022.
https://bitcoinmagazine.com/business/centralization-risks-and-flaws-of-ethereum-
merge.
Li, Hanyue, Jessica L. Wert, Adam Barlow Birchfield, Thomas J. Overbye, Tomas
Gomez San Roman, Carlos Mateo Domingo, Fernando Emilio Postigo Marcos,
Pablo Duenas Martinez, Tarek Elgindy, and Bryan Palmintier. "Building highly
detailed synthetic electric grid data sets for combined transmission and distribution
systems." IEEE Open Access Journal of Power and Energy 7 (2020): 478-488.
Liao, Gordon Y. and John Caramichael (2022). “Stablecoins: Growth Potential and
Impact on Banking,” International Finance Discussion Papers 1334. Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
https://doi.org/10.17016/IFDP.2022.1334.
Lin, Jian-Hong, Kevin Primicerio, Tiziano Squartini, Christian Decker, and Claudio J.
Tessone. "Lightning Network: A second path towards centralisation of the bitcoin
economy." New Journal of Physics 22, no. 8 (2020): 083022.
"Liu He Presides over the 51st Meeting of the Financial Stability and Development
Committee of the State Council." China Government Network, May 21, 2021.
Litzenberger, Robert H., and Donald L. Tuttle. "Interest Rate Changes and the Required
Rate of Return on Risk Assets." Southern Economic Journal (1970): 45-50.
211
Loomes, Graham, and Robert Sugden. "Disappointment and dynamic consistency in
choice under uncertainty." The Review of Economic Studies 53, no. 2 (1986): 271-
282.
Lonnroth, Lars. "Bitcoin Mines Come to Rural Georgia Communities. They're Bringing
Opportunities — And Tensions." GPB News. April 7, 2022.
https://www.gpb.org/news/2022/04/07/bitcoin-mines-come-rural-georgia-
communities-theyre-bringing-opportunities-and.
Lopp, Jameson. "Bitcoin: The Trust Anchor in a Sea of Blockchains." Coindesk. July 23,
2016. https://www.coindesk.com/markets/2016/07/23/bitcoin-the-trust-anchor-in-a-
sea-of-blockchains/
Magaki, Ikuo, Moein Khazraee, Luis Vega Gutierrez, and Michael Bedford Taylor. "Asic
clouds: Specializing the datacenter." ACM SIGARCH Computer Architecture
News 44, no. 3 (2016): 178-190.
Marden, Peter. The Decline of Politics: Governance, globalization and the public sphere.
Ashgate, 2003.
Mark, Dino, Vlad Zamfir, and Emin Gun Sirer. “A Call for a Temporary Moratorium on
the Dao.” Hacking Distributed, https://hackingdistributed.com/2016/05/27/dao-call-
for-moratorium/.
Masanet, Eric, Arman Shehabi, Nuoa Lei, Harald Vranken, Jonathan Koomey, and Jens
Malmodin. "Implausible projections overestimate near-term Bitcoin CO2
emissions." Nature Climate Change 9, no. 9 (2019): 653-654.
McClung, Littell. “The Seventy-Five Mile City.” Scientific American 127, no. 3 (1922):
156–214. http://www.jstor.org/stable/24994004.
McMackin, John F., Todd H. Chiles, and Long W. Lam. “Integrating Variable Risk
Preferences, Trust, and Transaction Cost Economics – 25 Years on: Reflections in
Memory of Oliver Williamson.” Journal of Institutional Economics 18, no. 2
(2021): 253–68.
doi:10.1017/S1744137421000576.
212
currency 2 (2014): 25.
Menati, Ali, Kiyeob Lee, and Le Xie. "Modeling and analysis of utilizing cryptocurrency
mining for demand flexibility in electric energy systems: A synthetic texas grid
case study." IEEE Transactions on Energy Markets, Policy and
Regulation (2023).
Michael, George. Lone Wolf Terror and the Rise of Leaderless Resistance. Vanderbilt
University Press, 2012.
Millman, Oliver. "Bitcoin Miners Revived a Dying Coal Plant – then CO2 Emissions
Soared.", February 18, 2022.
https://www.theguardian.com/technology/2022/feb/18/bitcoin-miners-revive-
fossil-fuel-plant-co2-emissions-soared.
Mirza, Faisal Mehmood, and Olvar Bergland. "Pass-through of wholesale price to the end
user retail price in the Norwegian electricity market." Energy Economics 34, no. 6
(2012): 2003-2012.
Mookerjee, Ajay S. "What If Central Banks Issued Digital Currency?" Harvard Business
Review, October 15, 2021. https://hbr.org/2021/10/what-if-central-banks-issued-
digital-currency.
Mora, Camilo, Randi L. Rollins, Katie Taladay, Michael B. Kantar, Mason K. Chock,
Mio Shimada, and Erik C. Franklin. "Bitcoin emissions alone could push global
warming above 2 C." Nature Climate Change 8, no. 11 (2018): 931-933.
Morrison, Robbie, Natasha Mazey, and Stephen C. Wingreen. "The DAO controversy:
the case for a new species of corporate governance?" Frontiers in Blockchain 3
(2020): 25.
213
Theory 19, no. 4 (2009): 895-915.
Meijer, David, and Jolien Ubacht. "The Governance of Blockchain Systems from an
Institutional Perspective, a Matter of Trust or Control?" Association for
Computing Machinery 90, (2018): 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1145/3209281.3209321.
Meunier, Sebastien, and Danni Zhao-Meunier. "Bitcoin, distributed ledgers and the
theory of the firm." Available at SSRN 3327971 (2019).
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3327971
Millstein, Dev, Patrick Dobson, and Seongeun Jeong. "The potential to improve the value
of US geothermal electricity generation through flexible operations." Journal of
Energy Resources Technology 143, no. 1 (2021).
Murray, Alex, Scott Kuban, Matt Josefy, and Jon Anderson. "Contracting in the smart
era: The implications of blockchain and decentralized autonomous organizations
for contracting and corporate governance." Academy of Management
Perspectives 35, no. 4 (2021): 622-641.
Mulder, Machiel, and Bert Willems. "The Dutch retail electricity market." Energy
policy 127 (2019): 228-239.
Mustafa, Fairouz, Suman Lodh, Monomita Nandy, and Vikas Kumar. "Coupling of
cryptocurrency trading with the sustainable environmental goals: Is it on the
cards?." Business Strategy and the Environment 31, no. 3 (2022): 1152-1168.
Nadel, Steven, and Lowell Ungar. "Halfway there: Energy efficiency can cut energy use
and greenhouse gas emissions in half by 2050." Report u1907 american council
for an energy-efficient economy (2019).
Narula, Neha, Simon Johnson, Jonah Crane, Gary Gensler, and Michael Casey. "The
Blockchain Catalyst for Change." Centre for Economic Policy Research. June 16,
2018. https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/blockchain-catalyst-change.
Neumueller, Alexander. "A Deep Dive into Bitcoin’S Environmental Impact." University
of Cambridge Judge Business School. October 27, 2022.
https://www.jbs.cam.ac.uk/insight/2022/a-deep-dive-into-bitcoins-environmental-
impact/.
Niaz, Haider, Jay J. Liu, and Fengqi You. "Can Texas mitigate wind and solar
214
curtailments by leveraging bitcoin mining?." Journal of Cleaner Production 364
(2022): 132700.
NYDIG. "NYDIG Raises $100 Million from Strategic Partners Including Starr, Liberty
Mutual Insurance, and Other P&C Insurers; Launches Global Insurance Solutions
Business under Mike Sapnar." Cision PR Newswire. April 8, 2021.
O'Dwyer, Karl J., and David Malone. "Bitcoin mining and its energy footprint." (2014):
280-285.
Olsen, Karen Pardos, Yi Zong, Shi You, Henrik Bindner, Matti Koivisto, and Juan Gea-
Bermúdez. "Multi-timescale data-driven method identifying flexibility
requirements for scenarios with high penetration of renewables." Applied
Energy 264 (2020): 114702.
Oren, Shmuel, and Stephen Smith. "Critical Mass and Tariff Structure in Electronic
Communications Markets." Bell Journal of Economics 12, (1981): 467-487.
https://doi.org/10.2307/3003567.
O'Toole Jr, Laurence J. "Rational Choice and Policy Implementation: Implications for
interorganizational network management." The American Review of Public
Administration 25, no. 1 (1995): 43-57.
Ostroff, Caitlin, and Elaine Yu. "Cryptocurrency Companies Are Leaving China in
‘Great Mining Migration’." The Wall Street Journal, August 22, 2021.
https://www.wsj.com/articles/cryptocurrency-companies-are-leaving-china-in-
great-mining-migration-11629624602.
Ostrom, Elinor, and Gordon Whitaker. "Does Local Community Control of Police Make
a Difference? Some Preliminary Findings." American Journal of Political
Science (1973): 48-76.
Ostrom, Elinor, Roger B. Parks, and Gordon P. Whitaker. "Do We Really Want to
Consolidate Urban Police Forces? A reappraisal of some old assertions." Public
Administration Review (1973): 423-432.
215
Ostrom, Elinor, and Gordon P. Whitaker. "Community Control and Governmental
Responsiveness: The case of police in black neighborhoods." Improving the
Quality of Urban Management 10, no. 4 (1974): 303-34.
Ostrom, Elinor. "Size and Performance in a Federal System." Publius 6, no. 2 (1976): 33-
73.
Ostrom, Elinor. "A Long Polycentric Journey." Annual Review of Political Science 13
(2010): 1-23.
OSTP (2022). “Climate and Energy Implications of Crypto-Assets in the United States.”
White House Office of Science and Technology Policy. Washington, D.C.
September 8, 2022.
Oxner, Reese. "Texas Could Connect to National Power Grids Without Losing
Autonomy, Former Grid Regulator Says." The Texas Tribune, February 15, 2022.
https://www.texastribune.org/2022/02/14/texas-national-power-grids/.
Pankhurst, Richard. “The Trade of Northern Ethiopia in the Nineteenth and Early
Twentieth Centuries.” Journal of Ethiopian Studies 2, no. 1 (1964): 49–159.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/41965707.
Parr, John. "Perspectives on the City‐region." Regional Studies 39, no. 5 (2005): 555-566.
Patki, Tapasya, Natalie Bates, Girish Ghatikar, Anders Clausen, Sonja Klingert, Ghaleb
Abdulla, and Mehdi Sheikhalishahi. "Supercomputing centers and electricity
service providers: A geographically distributed perspective on demand
management in europe and the united states." In High Performance Computing:
31st International Conference, ISC High Performance 2016, Frankfurt, Germany,
June 19-23, 2016, Proceedings, pp. 243-260. Springer International Publishing,
2016.
Peters, B. Guy, and John Pierre. "Governance without government? Rethinking public
administration." Journal of public administration research and theory 8, no. 2
(1998): 223-243.
Pina, André, Carlos Silva, and Paulo Ferrão. "The impact of demand side management
strategies in the penetration of renewable electricity." Energy 41, no. 1 (2012):
128-137.
216
Poon, Joseph, and Thaddeus Dryja. "The Bitcoin Lightning Network: Scalable off-chain
instant payments." (2016). https://lightning.network/lightning-network-paper.pdf
Poteete, Amy R., Marco A. Janssen, and Elinor Ostrom. Working Together. Princeton
University Press, 2010.
Potomac Economics. "2021 State of the Market Report for the ERCOT Electricity
Markets." Independent Market Monitor for ERCOT, May 1, 2022.
Pranata, Andasmara Rizky, and Pardis Moslemzadeh Tehrani. "The Legality of Smart
Contracts in a Decentralized Autonomous Organization (DAO)." Regulatory
Aspects of Artificial Intelligence on Blockchain (2022): 112-131.
Prasad, Eswar S. The future of money: How the digital revolution is transforming
currencies and finance. Harvard University Press, 2021.
Price, Rob. "DAO Hacked, Ethereum Crashing in Value." Business Insider. June 17,
2016. https://www.businessinsider.com/dao-hacked-ethereum-crashing-in-value-
tens-of-millions-allegedly-stolen-2016-6.
"Proof of Work Is a ‘Feature Not a Flaw’: CleanSpark CEO." Bloomberg. October 14,
2022. Video, https://www.bloomberg.com/news/videos/2022-10-14/proof-of-work-
is-a-feature-not-a-flaw-cleanspark-ceo.
Provan, Keith G., and Jule B. Gassenheimer. "Supplier commitment in relational contract
exchanges with buyers: A study of interorganizational dependence and exercised
power." Journal of Management Studies 31, no. 1 (1994): 55-68.
Provan, Keith G., and Robin H. Lemaire. "Core Concepts and Key Ideas for
Understanding Public Sector Organizational Networks: Using research to inform
scholarship and practice." Public Administration Review 72, no. 5 (2012): 638-648.
217
Systems.” Administrative Science Quarterly 40, no. 1 (1995): 1–33.
https://doi.org/10.2307/2393698.
Provan, Keith G., and H. Brinton Milward. "Do Networks Really Work? A framework
for evaluating public‐sector organizational networks." Public Administration
Review 61, no. 4 (2001): 414-423.
Provan, Keith G., and Patrick Kenis. "Modes of Network Governance: Structure,
management, and effectiveness." Journal of Public Administration Research and
Theory 18, no. 2 (2008): 229-252.
Radmilac, Andjela. "2021 Was the Year of Institutional Crypto Adoption." CryptoSlate.
January 19, 2022. https://cryptoslate.com/2021-was-the-year-of-institutional-
crypto-adoption/.
Radmilac, Andjela, and James Van Straten. "Research: Miners Sent 57K Bitcoin to
Exchanges in 2022; Selling Pressure Decreasing." CryptoSlate. December 18,
2022. https://cryptoslate.com/how-many-bitcoins-have-miners-sold-to-exchanges-
in-2022/.
Rand, Joseph, Ryan H. Wiser, Will Gorman, Dev Millstein, Joachim Seel, Seongeun
Jeong, and Dana Robson. Queued up: Characteristics of power plants seeking
transmission interconnection as of the end of 2021. Lawrence Berkeley National
Lab.(LBNL), Berkeley, CA (United States), 2022.
Redman, Jamie. "Bitcoin Miners Discovered 53,240 Blocks This Year, Foundry Led the
Pack, Hashrate Tapped an All-Time High." Bitcoin.Com. December 23, 2022.
https://news.bitcoin.com/bitcoin-miners-discovered-53240-blocks-this-year-
foundry-led-the-pack-hashrate-tapped-an-all-time-high/.
Richardson, George B. "The Organisation of Industry." The Economic Journal 82, no.
327 (1972): 883-896. https://doi.org/10.2307/2230256.
Rhodes, Joshua D., Thomas Deetjen, and Caitlin Smith. "Impacts of Large, Flexible Data
Center Operations on the Future of ERCOT." Lancium. June 1, 2021.
https://lancium.com/wp-
content/uploads/2022/06/Lancium_Flexible_Data_Center_Whitepaper_4.2022.pdf.
218
Ring, Peter Smith, and Andrew H. Van de Ven. "Structuring cooperative relationships
between organizations." Strategic Management Journal 13, no. 7 (1992): 483-498.
Rodrigues, Usha. "Law and the Blockchain." Iowa Law Review 104, no. 2018-07 (2018).
https://doi.org/https://ssrn.com/abstract=3127782.
Simpson, Thomas W. "Computing and the Search for Trust." Trust, Computing, and
Society ed. Richard H. Harper, (2013): 95-119.
https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781139828567.009.
Singh, Kanwardeep, Narayana Prasad Padhy, and Jaydev Sharma. "Influence of price
responsive demand shifting bidding on congestion and LMP in pool-based day-
ahead electricity markets." IEEE Transactions on Power Systems 26, no. 2 (2010):
886-896.
Singh, Madhusudan and Shiho Kim. “Chapter Four - Blockchain technology for
decentralized autonomous organizations.” Adv. Comput. 115 (2019): 115-140.
Rogers, Bruce D., and C. McCurdy Lipsey. "Metropolitan Reform: Citizen evaluations of
performances in Nashville-Davidson county, Tennessee." Publius 4, no. 4 (1974):
19-34.
Rothstein, Bo. Social Traps and the Problem of Trust. Cambridge University Press, 2005.
Rutwich, John, and Emily Feng. "How the U.S. Benefits when China Turns Its Back on
Bitcoin." NPR. February 24, 2022. Podcast,
https://www.npr.org/transcripts/1081252187?ft=nprml&f=147666959.
Sageman, Marc. "A strategy for fighting international Islamist terrorists." The Annals of
the American Academy of Political and Social Science 618, no. 1 (2008): 223-
231.
Saul, Josh. "America’s Bitcoin Miners See Georgia as the New U.S. Hot Spot."
Bloomberg. February 7, 2022. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2022-
219
02-07/america-s-bitcoin-btc-miners-have-georgia-on-their-minds#xj4y7vzkg.
Santana-Viera, Victor, Jesus Jimenez, Tongdan Jin, and Jose Espiritu. "Implementing
factory demand response via onsite renewable energy: a design-of-experiment
approach." International Journal of Production Research 53, no. 23 (2015): 7034-
7048.
Savery, Lawson. "Influence and Trust of Members Within Small Firms." Management
Decision 20, no. 1 (1982): 32-37.
Saylor, Michael, Nic Carter, and Darin Feinstein. "Response to the Huffman Letter."
Bitcoin Mining Council. May 2, 2022. https://bitcoinminingcouncil.com/wp-
content/uploads/2022/05/Bitcoin_Letter_to_the_Environmental_Protection_Agen
cy.pdf.
Seel, Joachim, Dev Millstein, Andrew Mills, Mark Bolinger, and Ryan Wiser. "Plentiful
electricity turns wholesale prices negative." Advances in Applied Energy 4 (2021):
100073.
Shan, Rui, and Yaojin Sun. "Bitcoin mining to reduce the renewable curtailment: a case
study of CAISO." Available at SSRN 3436872 (2019).
Shaner, Matthew R., Steven J. Davis, Nathan S. Lewis, and Ken Caldeira. "Geophysical
constraints on the reliability of solar and wind power in the United
States." Energy & Environmental Science 11, no. 4 (2018): 914-925.
Sigalos, Mackenzie. "TECH Bitcoin Mining Is now Easier and More Profitable as
Algorithm Adjusts after China Crackdown." CNBC. July 3, 2021.
https://www.cnbc.com/2021/07/03/bitcoin-mining-difficulty-drops-after-hashrate-
collapse-in-china-.html.
Sigalos, MacKenzie. "The FBI Likely Exploited Sloppy Password Storage to Seize
Colonial Pipeline Bitcoin Ransom." CNBC. June 8, 2021.
https://www.cnbc.com/2021/06/08/fbi-
likely-exploited-sloppy-password-storage-to-seize-colonial-ransom.html.
220
Simon, Herbert A. "New Developments in the Theory of the Firm." The American
economic review 52, no. 2 (1962): 1-15.
Simon, Herbert A. "Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political
science." American political science review 79, no. 2 (1985): 293-304.
Simsek, Zeki, Michael H. Lubatkin, and Steven W. Floyd. "Inter-firm networks and
entrepreneurial behavior: A structural embeddedness perspective." Journal of
Management 29, no. 3 (2003): 427-442.
Sørensen, Eva. “Democratic Theory and Network Governance.” Administrative Theory &
Praxis 24, no. 4 (2002): 693–720.
Sørensen, Eva, and Jacob Torfing. “Network Governance and Post-Liberal Democracy.”
Administrative Theory & Praxis 27, no. 2 (2005): 197–237.
Sørensen, Eva, and Jacob Torfing. "Enhancing Public Innovation Through Collaboration,
Leadership and New Public Governance." New Frontiers in Social Innovation
Research (2015): 145-169.
Standaert , Michael. “Despite Pledges to Cut Emissions, China Goes on a Coal Spree.”
Yale E360, 24 Mar. 2021, https://e360.yale.edu/features/despite-pledges-to-cut-
emissions-china-goes-on-a-coal-spree.
Steinberg, Daniel, Dave Bielen, Josh Eichman, Kelly Eurek, Jeff Logan, Trieu Mai, Colin
McMillan, Andrew Parker, Laura Vimmerstedt, and Eric Wilson. Electrification
and decarbonization: exploring US energy use and greenhouse gas emissions in
scenarios with widespread electrification and power sector decarbonization. No.
NREL/TP-6A20-68214. National Renewable Energy Lab.(NREL), Golden, CO
(United States), 2017.
221
Stoft, Steven. Power system economics: designing markets for electricity. Vol. 468.
Piscataway: IEEE press, 2002.
Stoll, Christian, Lena Klaasen, and Ulrich Gallersdorfer. “The Carbon Footprint of
Bitcoin.” MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, 2018.
Sun, Wei, Haitao Jin, and Fengjun Jin. "Spatial Analysis of Global Bitcoin Mining."
Scientific Reports 12, (2022). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-022-14987-0.
Tan, Evrim, Stanislav Mahula, and Joep Crompvoets. "Blockchain Governance in the
Public Sector: A Conceptual Framework for Public Management." Government
Information Quarterly 39, no. 1 (2022).
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.giq.2021.101625.
Tellez, Anthony. "Fidelity Buys 7.4% Of Bitcoin Mining Company Marathon Digital
Holdings Across Multiple Funds." Forbes, August 4, 2021.
https://www.forbes.com/sites/anthonytellez/2021/08/04/fidelity-buys-74-of-
bitcoin-mining-company-marathon-digital-holdings-across-multiple-
funds/?sh=34859fb926f2.
Temple, James. "The $2.5 trillion reason we can’t rely on batteries to clean up the
grid." Technology Review (2018).
Texas Section of the American Society of Civil Engineers. "Reliability and Resilience in
the Balance – Winter Storms Report." ASCE. February 16, 2022.
https://www.texasce.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/02/Reliability-Resilience-in-
the-Balance-REPORT.pdf.
Tummers, Lars, and Eva Knies. "Measuring public leadership: Developing scales for four
key public leadership roles." Public Administration 94, no. 2 (2016): 433-451.
222
Form”. Victoria University of Wellington Law Review 51 (2). Wellington, New
Zealand: 313-56. https://doi.org/10.26686/vuwlr.v51i2.6573.
Uberti, David. "How the FBI Got Colonial Pipeline’s Ransom Money Back." Wall Street
Journal, June 11, 2021. https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-the-fbi-got-colonial-
pipelines-ransom-money-back-11623403981.
United States, Executive Office of the President [Joseph Biden]. Executive order 14067:
Ensuring Responsible Development of Digital Assets. 9 Mar. 2022.
Uzzi, Brian. "The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic
performance of organizations: The network effect." American sociological
review (1996): 674-698.
Van Dijk, Jan AGM. "The One-dimensional Network Society of Manuel Castells." New
Media & Society 1, no. 1 (1999): 127-138.
Van Hove, Leo. "Electronic Money and the Network Externalities Theory: Lessons for
real life." Netnomics 1, no. 2 (1999): 137-171.
Van Kersbergen, Kees, and Frans Van Waarden. "‘Governance as a bridge between
disciplines: Cross-disciplinary inspiration regarding shifts in governance and
problems of governability, accountability and legitimacy." European Corporate
Governance (2009): 64-80.
Vazquez, Jennifer, and Donald Larry Crumbley. "Flared Gas Can Reduce Some Risks in
Crypto Mining as Well as Oil and Gas Operations." Risks 10, no. 6 (2022): 127.
Victoria, Marta, Nancy Haegel, Ian Marius Peters, Ron Sinton, Arnulf Jäger-Waldau,
Carlos del Cañizo, Christian Breyer et al. "Solar photovoltaics is ready to power a
sustainable future." Joule 5, no. 5 (2021): 1041-1056.
Vincent, Olusegun, and Olaniyi Evans. "Can Cryptocurrency, Mobile Phones, and
Internet Herald Sustainable Financial Sector Development in Emerging Markets?"
Journal of Transnational Management 24, no. 3 (2019): 259-279.
https://doi.org/10.1080/15475778.2019.1633170.
Walton, Robert. "Biden Decarbonization Goals Could Triple Reliance on Electric Grid:
EPRI."
223
Utility Dive. January 14, 2022. https://www.utilitydive.com/news/biden-decarbonization-
goals-could-triple-reliance-on-electricity-grid-epri/617188/.
Wang, Wenbo, Dinh T. Hoang, Peizhao Hu, Zehui Xiong, Dusit Niyato, Ping Wang,
Yonggang Wen, and Dong I. Kim. "A Survey on Consensus Mechanisms and
Mining Strategy Management in Blockchain Networks." IEEE Access 7, (2019):
22328-22370. https://doi.org/10.1109/ACCESS.2019.2896108.
Wang, Shuai. W. Ding, J. Li, Y. Yuan, L. Ouyang and F. -Y. Wang. 2019. "Decentralized
Autonomous Organizations: Concept, Model, and Applications," in IEEE
Transactions on Computational Social Systems 6, no. 5 (2019): 870-878. doi:
10.1109/TCSS.2019.2938190.
Webb, Shelby. "ERCOT's Shift in Operations May Mean a Rise in Prices." Houston
Chronicle, July 4, 2022.
https://www.houstonchronicle.com/business/energy/article/ERCOT-shift-
in-operations-may-mean-rise-in-prices-17281676.php.
Weber, Warren E. "Government and private e-money-like systems: Federal reserve notes
and national bank notes." (2015).
Werbach, Kevin. "Trust, But Verify: Why the blockchain needs the law." Berkeley
Technology Law Journal 33, no. 2 (2018): 487-550.
Wierman, Adam, Zhenhua Liu, Iris Liu, and Hamed Mohsenian-Rad. "Opportunities and
challenges for data center demand response." In International Green Computing
Conference, pp. 1-10. IEEE, 2014.
Wright, Turner. "Crypto Miner in Texas Shuts down 99% of Operations as Winter Storm
Approaches." Coin Telegraph. February 2, 2022.
https://cointelegraph.com/news/crypto-
miner-in-texas-shuts-down-99-of-operations-as-winter-storm-approaches.
224
Wright, Aaron. “The Rise of Decentralized Autonomous Organizations: Opportunities
and Challenges.” Stanford Journal of Blockchain Law & Policy (2021).
https://stanford-jblp.pubpub.org/pub/rise-of-daos
Wright, Steve, and Hassan Shaban. "Coordination between Utilities and Crypto Miners
— When Does It Make Sense?" Utility Dive. August 11, 2022.
https://www.utilitydive.com/news/coordination-between-utilities-and-crypto-
miners-when-does-it-make-sense/629407/.
Xia, Wengfeng, Yonggang Wen, and Kok-Chuan Toh. "Toward Green Data Centers as
an Interruptible Load for Grid Stabilization in Singapore." IEEE Communications
November 2015, (2015): 192-198.
Xie, Rain. "Why China had to ban cryptocurrency but the US did not: a comparative
analysis of regulations on crypto-markets between the US and China." Wash. U.
Global Stud. L. Rev. 18 (2019): 457.
Xu, Chengjian, Qiang Dai, Linda Gaines, Mingming Hu, Arnold Tukker, and Bernhard
Steubing. "Future material demand for automotive lithium-based
batteries." Communications Materials 1, no. 1 (2020): 99.
Xu, Muyu, and David Stanway. “Explainer: The Power Crunch in China's Sichuan and
Why It Matters.” Reuters, Thomson Reuters, 26 Aug. 2022,
https://www.reuters.com/world/china/power-crunch-chinas-sichuan-why-it-matters-
2022-08-26/.
Yanagawa, Noriyuki, and Hiromi Yamaoka. Digital innovation, data revolution and
central bank digital currency. No. 19-E-2. Bank of Japan, 2019.
Yeung, Karen, and David Galindo. "Why do public blockchains need formal and
effective internal governance mechanisms?." European Journal of Risk
Regulation 10, no. 2 (2019): 359-375.
Yoo, Christopher S., "Paul Baran, Network Theory, and the Past, Present, and Future of
Internet" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Carey Law. 2040.
https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/2040
Zhang, Laney. China: National Development and Reform Commission Issues Notice
225
Restricting Cryptocurrency Mining. 2022. Web Page.
https://www.loc.gov/item/global-legal-
monitor/2022-02-08/china-national-development-and-reform-commission-issues-
notice-restricting-cryptocurrency-mining/.
226
Appendix A: A Basic Model of Bitcoin Mining Economics and Demand Response
Profitability
Hypothesis #1: In a perfectly free market, energy pricing serves as the primary driver of
H1a: Miners turn on when the price of energy is below their breakeven price; or
H1b: Miners will turn off when the price of energy is below their breakeven price
provided they can make more money participating in demand response / ancillary
services
Bitcoin Price ($USD/BTC): Each block that is mined yields a mining reward or block
subsidy – a certain amount of Bitcoin awarded to the miner. The value of this reward
Electricity Price ($USD/kWh): Mining requires electricity. Miners pay for power
Network Hashrate (TH/s): the amount of computing power across the network
of the amount of “guesses” being generated to solve a block. Related to mining difficulty
(below)
Hardware (ASIC) Hashrate (TH/s): the rate at which individual hardware miners –
227
Hardware efficiency (W/Th): The amount of power each individual ASIC needs per
hash solved
Difficulty (numerical internal score): Bitcoin’s built in “goal” is to have blocks mined
ten minutes apart. The difficulty of solving a block adjusts commensurate with the
amount of hashrate or mining effort dedicated to solving blocks. Difficulty can be found
in block headers
Transaction Fees (BTC): All BTC transactions include a fee to be paid to miners.
Setting higher fees can incentivize miners to include transactions in blocks faster than
Miners will turn off during hour “t” if: 𝑃𝐵 (𝑡) < 0 | 𝑃𝐵 (𝑡) < 𝑃𝐷𝑅 (𝑡)
Given:
How do we find 𝑃𝐵 (𝑡)? “The profit/loss for mining Bitcoin during hour t”
“The difference between BTC revenue per MWh in hr. t and electricity cost per MWh in
hr. t”
228
The per MWh profit/loss for mining Bitcoin during hour t is the individual miner’s share
of the block reward for the hashing they contributed relative to the overall network
hashrate multiplied by the price of Bitcoin, divided by the power consumed (ASIC
wattage)
𝐻𝐴
𝐵𝑇𝐶(𝑡) ∗ 𝑏𝑟 ∗ 𝑏ℎ ∗
𝐻𝑁 (𝑡)
𝐵(𝑡) =
𝑊𝐴
algorithm)
Now for our second important term: 𝑃𝐷𝑅 “Profit/loss from participating in DR or AS”
Bitcoin mining data centers could participate in wholesale markets, AS, or as an ERS
be brought on-line in a timely manner, to balance the variability that cannot be covered
226
https://www.ercot.com/files/docs/2021/12/02/18_2022_ERCOT_Methodologies_for_Determining_Mini
mum_AS_Requirements.pdf
229
1. Regulation Service: Regulation Service is capacity that can be deployed every 4
seconds to maintain frequency (i.e. balance supply & demand) between 5-min
dispatch intervals.
started or interrupted within 30 minutes to cover net load (load – wind - solar)
forecast errors, replace loss of generation capacity, address risk of net load
Grid managers need AS on the supply side: responsive generation resources to come
online or scale back production to adjust for changes in demand. But AS is also needed
consumption227
2. Load Resources - Customers who are capable of changing their load in response
in both AS and real-time (RT) markets. In the ERCOT markets, the value of a
generating plant. Load Resources in SCED submit bids to buy power "up to"
227
https://www.ercot.com/services/programs/load/eils
230
their specified level, and are instructed by ERCOT to reduce Load if wholesale
market prices equal or exceed that level. Load Resources that are scheduled or
frequency relay)
– QSE submits a “Bid to Buy” which represents the energy price above
System.
system. This is known as Voluntary Load Response. Depending on how the retail
contract with their Load Serving Entity (LSE) is structured, these customers may
have the opportunity to benefit financially during periods when wholesale market
228
https://www.ercot.com/services/programs/load/laar
229
https://www.ercot.com/services/programs/load/vlrp
231
Appendix B: Section 3.5.2 Detailed Results
Core Scientific’s Denton facility is the major Bitcoin mining data center in the study from
the North LZ. The exact location is visible on Google Maps imagery and the address is
public knowledge available online (Gaudet 2022). SEC Filings confirm 22MW were
operational with plans to scale to 300MW.230 Core Scientific filed for bankruptcy in
December 2022 (Yerak et al. 2022). Average LMPs around the facility were lower than
the ERCOT average both before and after the data center came online. LMPs within 25
230
Form 10-Q; Commission File #001-40046
232
Rockdale Average LMPs
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 5yr.
25/50km 23.57 28.60 28.57 19.85 35.60 61.92 33.02
100km 24.23 28.75 28.69 20.15 35.63 59.83 32.88
ERCOT avg. 26.45 30.10 29.56 20.55 34.32 59.59 33.43
the largest bitcoin mining facility in North America. Riot Blockchain’s website provides
Bitdeer is less transparent about their facility, but timing of when their active capacity
came online is available in SEC filings. The Bitdeer location is a former aluminum
smelting plant (according to several media reports) and is clearly visible on Google Maps
imagery. Despite the amount of active Bitcoin mining, LMPs around Rockdale are very
Lancium Inc. publicly announced breaking ground on the “Abilene Clean Campus” data
center in November 2022, but it is not active. It is included in the study to determine
whether prices or grid energy mix factors into miner location decision-making. The exact
location of the data center is available on their website. In the case of Abilene, local
233
LMPs are consistently lower than the ERCOT-wide average and almost all generators
within 100km of the Abilene Clean Campus site are renewable (Tables 3.5 and 3.6).
Argo Blockchain’s Helios data center is located in Afton, Texas. It publicly announced
of May 2022 when Argo was acquired by Galaxy Digital Holdings (Galaxy 2022). The
data center is co-located to a wind farm and Youtube videos provide imagery which can
be matched to lat-long on Google Maps for the exact location. Most of the nearby
generator capacity (64% within 100km, 100% within 50km) is renewable (Table 3.6) and
nearby LMPs have consistently been lower than the ERCOT average, before and after the
234
Pyote Average LMPs
Poolin, a subsidiary of Bitmain, runs North America’s “first fully operational hydro
cooling data center” in Pyote, Texas according to Bitmain’s website. The exact location
is unknown, but Pyote is a very small town so the estimated location is rather precise.
The amount of active capacity is unknown, but a Poolin job listing for a “data center
facilities manager” in Pyote says the position would involve managing one of two
300MW data centers there. A report from the Washington Post indicates Layer1
Technologies opened a mining plant in Pyote in 2020, though active capacity and precise
location are unknown (Brown 2021). Genesis Digital Assets posts location imagery and
construction status updates on their data center in Pyote on their website. It will have a
capacity of up to 300MW when complete. Exact dates for active capacity is unknown, but
it was active in some capacity as early as August 2022 according to their website. LMPs
235
near Pyote have been more expensive than the rest of ERCOT before 2021, but are just
Compute North began launching the first large data center in this study in 2018. Details
on the timeline of the launch and capacity of this facility were available when the
Compute North website was active prior to filing for bankruptcy in September 2022
(Texas Southern District 2022). Some details are still available in a Texas Monthly news
article (Gallaga 2021). Foundry Digital LLC confirmed 11MW were still active at the
time of their purchase of the Big Spring facility in November 2022 (Foundry 2022).
LMPs near Big Spring have been consistently lower than the ERCOT average.
236
Fort Stockton Average LMPs
All details and data on Lancium’s Fort Stockton facility from this study were confirmed
by an active employee of Lancium and used with permission. Like Lancium’s Abilene
campus, the energy mix near Fort Stockton is predominantly from renewable generators.
But unlike the Abilene facility, LMPs near Fort Stockton were higher than the ERCOT
average when Lancium broke ground on the facility, indicating nearby wholesale energy
237
Upton County Average LMP
The location of Compute North’s Upton County facility can be seen on Google Maps.
Details on the timeline of the launch and capacity of this facility were available when the
Compute North website was active prior to filing for bankruptcy in September 2022
(Texas Southern District 2022).Though the facility had a capacity of 280 MW, only
40MW were active as of Q2 2022 according to their exclusive client for this site,
Marathon Digital (Gkritsi and Ashraf 2022). LMPs around the facility actually dropped
238
ProQuest Number: 30318955
This work may be used in accordance with the terms of the Creative Commons license
or other rights statement, as indicated in the copyright statement or in the metadata
associated with this work. Unless otherwise specified in the copyright statement
or the metadata, all rights are reserved by the copyright holder.
ProQuest LLC
789 East Eisenhower Parkway
P.O. Box 1346
Ann Arbor, MI 48106 - 1346 USA