Computation and Modelling in Insurance and Finance Boelviken E. 2024 scribd download
Computation and Modelling in Insurance and Finance Boelviken E. 2024 scribd download
https://ebookultra.com/download/risk-analysis-in-finance-and-
insurance-second-edition-alexander-melnikov/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/career-opportunities-in-banking-
finance-and-insurance-2nd-ed-edition-thomas-p-fitch/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/risk-modelling-in-general-insurance-
from-principles-to-practice-1st-edition-roger-j-gray/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/synthetic-cdos-modelling-valuation-
and-risk-management-mathematics-finance-and-risk-1st-edition-c-c-
mounfield/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/insurance-statistics-
yearbook-2008-edition-2008-finance-et-investissement-assurance-et-
oecd/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/interest-rates-and-coupon-bonds-in-
quantum-finance-1st-edition-belal-e-baaquie/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/modelling-single-name-and-multi-name-
credit-derivatives-the-wiley-finance-series-1st-edition-dominic-okane/
ebookultra.com
https://ebookultra.com/download/careers-in-insurance-and-risk-
management-2009-edition-wetfeet/
ebookultra.com
Computation and Modelling in Insurance and Finance
Boelviken E. Digital Instant Download
Author(s): Boelviken E.
ISBN(s): 9780521830485, 0521830486
Edition: draft
File Details: PDF, 3.28 MB
Year: 2014
Language: english
i i
Focusing on what actuaries need in practice, this introductory account provides readers with
essential tools for handling complex problems and explains how simulation models can be created,
used and reused (with modifications) in related situations.
The book begins by outlining the basic tools of modelling and simulation, including a discussion
of the Monte Carlo method and its use. Part II deals with general insurance and Part III with life
insurance and financial risk. Algorithms that can be implemented on any programming platform are
spread throughout, and a program library written in R is included. Numerous figures and
experiments with R-code illustrate the text.
The authors non-technical approach is ideal for graduate students, the only prerequisites being
introductory courses in calculus and linear algebra, probability and statistics. The book will also be
of value to actuaries and other analysts in the industry looking to update their skills.
e r i k b ø lv i k e n holds the position of Chair of Actuarial Science at the University of Oslo and is
a partner in Gabler and Partners, Oslo.
i i
i i
i i
Editorial Board
Christopher Daykin (Independent Consultant and Actuary)
Angus Macdonald (Heriot-Watt University)
i i
i i
i i
E R I K B Ø LV I K E N
University of Oslo
i i
i i
i i
Published in the United States of America by Cambridge University Press, New York
www.cambridge.org
Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9780521830485
c Cambridge University Press 2014
This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception
and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements,
no reproduction of any part may take place without the written
permission of Cambridge University Press.
First published 2014
Printing in the United Kingdom by TJ International Ltd. Padstow Cornwall
A catalogue record for this publication is available from the British Library
Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication data
ISBN 978-0-521-83048-5 Hardback
Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of
URLs for external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication,
and does not guarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain,
accurate or appropriate.
i i
i i
i i
Contents
i i
i i
i i
vi Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents vii
i i
i i
i i
viii Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents ix
i i
i i
i i
x Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xi
i i
i i
i i
xii Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xiii
i i
i i
i i
xiv Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xv
i i
i i
i i
xvi Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xvii
i i
i i
i i
xviii Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xix
i i
i i
i i
xx Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xxi
i i
i i
i i
xxii Contents
i i
i i
i i
Contents xxiii
i i
i i
i i
xxiv Contents
i i
i i
i i
Preface
xxv
i i
i i
i i
xxvi Preface
passively. The exercises vary from the theoretical to the numerical. There is a good
deal of experimentation and model comparison.
I am grateful to my editor at Cambridge University Press, David Tranah, for
proposing the project and for following the work with infinite patience over a much
longer period than originally envisaged. Montserrat Guillen provided a stimulating
environment at The University of Barcelona where some parts were written. Ragnar
Norberg at London School of Economics was kind enough to go through an earlier
version of the entire manuscript. My friends at GablerWassum in Oslo, above all
Christian Fotland and Arve Moe have been a source of inspiration. Jostein Sørvoll,
then head of the same company, taught me some of the practical sides of insurance
as did Torbjørn Jakobsen for finance. I also thank Morten Folkeson and Steinar
Holm for providing some of the historical data. Many of the exercises were checked
by my students Eirik Sagstuen and Rebecca Wiborg.
Erik Bølviken
Oslo
i i
i i
i i
1
Introduction
i i
i i
i i
2 Introduction
in the computer. Risk in finance and insurance is future uncertain gains and losses,
designated in this book by letters such as X and Y. Typical examples are compen-
sations for claims in general insurance, pension schemes interrupted upon death
in life insurance and future values of shares and bonds in finance. There are also
secondary (or derived) products where values and payoffs are channelled through
contract clauses set up in advance. Such agreements are known as derivatives in
finance and reinsurance in insurance.
The mathematical approach, unanimously accepted today, is through probabilities
with risks X and Y seen as random variables. We shall know their values eventually
(after the event), but for planning and control and to price risk-taking activities
we need them in advance and must fall back on their probabilities. This leads to a
working process such as the one depicted in Figure 1.1. The real world on the left is
an enormously complicated mechanism (denoted M) that yields a future X.
We shall never know M, though our paradigm is that it does exist as a well-
defined stochastic mechanism. Since it is beyond reach, a simplified version M is
constructed in its place and used to study X. Its expected value is used for valuation
and the percentiles for control, and unlike in engineering we are rarely concerned
with predicting a specific value. Note that everything falls apart if M deviates too
strongly from the true mechanism M. This issue of error is a serious one indeed.
Chapter 7 is an introduction.
What there is to go on when M is constructed is listed on the right in Figure 1.1.
Learning from the past is an obvious source (but not all of it is relevant). In finance,
current asset prices bring market opinion about the future. This so-called implied
view is introduced briefly in Section 1.4, and there will be more in Part III. Then
there is the theory of arbitrage, where riskless financial income is assumed impos-
sible. The innocent-looking no-arbitrage condition has wide implications, which
are discussed in Chapter 14. In practice, some personal judgement behind M is
often present, but this is not for general argument, and nor shall we go into the
physical modelling used in large-claims insurance where hurricanes, earthquakes
or floods are imitated in the computer. This book is about how M is constructed
from the first three sources (historical data above all), how it is implemented in
the computer and how the computer model is used to determine the probability
i i
i i
i i
i i
i i
i i
4 Introduction
Section 1.5 (and in Chapter 3 too). By mastering it you are well equipped to deal
with much that comes your way and avoid getting stuck when pre-programmed
software doesn’t have what you need. What platform should you go for? Algo-
rithms in this book are written in a pseudo-code that goes with everything. Excel
and Visual Basic are standard in the industry and may be used even for simulation.
Much higher speed is obtained with C, Pascal or Fortran, and in the opinion of this
author people are well advised to learn software like those. There are other possi-
bilities as well, and the open-source R-package is used with the exercises. Much
can be achieved with a platform you know!
which is known as the pure premium and defines a break-even situation. A com-
pany receiving πpu for its services will, in the absence of all overhead cost and all
financial income, neither earn nor lose in the long run. This is a consequence of the
law of large numbers in probability theory; see Appendix A.2.
i i
i i
i i
Such a pricing strategy is (of course) out of the question, and companies add
loadings γ on top of πpu . The premium charged is then
π = (1 + γ)πpu , (1.2)
and we may regard γπpu as the cost of risk. It is influenced thoroughly by the
market situation, and in many branches of insurance is known to exhibit strong
fluctuations; see Section 11.5 for a simple model. There have been attempts to
determine γ from theoretical arguments, see Young (2004) for a review, but these
efforts are not used much in practice and will not be considered.
The loading concept separates the market side from the insurance process itself,
but another issue is whether the pure premium is known. Stochastic models for X
always depend on unknown quantities such as parameters or probability distribu-
tions. They are determined from experience or even assessed informally if histor-
ical data are lacking, and there is a crucial distinction between the true πpu with
perfect knowledge of the underlying situation and the π̂pu used for analysis and
decisions. The discrepancy between what we seek and what we get is a fundamen-
tal issue of error that is present everywhere (see Figure 1.1), and there is special
notation for it. A parameter or quantity with a ˆ such as ψ̂ means an estimate or an
assessment of an underlying, unknown ψ. Chapter 7 offers a general discussion of
errors and how they are confronted.
i i
i i
i i
6 Introduction
where is a small number (for example 1%). The amount q is known as the
solvency capital or reserve. Percentiles are used in finance too and are then often
called value at risk (or VaR for short). As elsewhere, the true q we seek is not the
same as the estimated q̂ we get.
i i
i i
i i
Chapter 15. The present section and the next one review the main concepts of
finance.
i i
i i
i i
8 Introduction
R; as will appear many times in this book. Whether the rate of interest r really is
risk free is not as obvious as it seems. True, you do get a fixed share of your deposit
as a reward, but that does not tell its worth in real terms when price increases are
taken into account. Indeed, over longer time horizons risk due to inflation may be
huge and even reduce the real value of cash deposits and bonds. Saving money with
a bank at a fixed rate of interest may also bring opportunity cost if the market rate
after a while exceeds what you get. These issues are discussed and integrated with
other sources of risk in Part III.
1.3.4 Log-returns
Economics and finance have often constructed stochastic models for R directly. An
alternative is the log-return
R 2 R3
X =R− + + ··· ,
2 3
where R (a fairly small number) dominates so that X R, at least over short
periods. It follows that the distributions of R and X must be rather similar (see
Section 2.4), but this is not to say that the discrepancy is unimportant. It depends
on the amount of random variation present, and the longer the time horizon the
more X deviates from R; see Section 5.4 for an illustration.
J
J
V0 = V j0 growing at the end of the period to V1 = (1 + R j )V j0 .
j=1 j=1
i i
i i
i i
Subtract V0 from V1 and divide by V0 , and you get the portfolio return
J
V0 j
R= w jR j where w j = . (1.8)
j=1
V0
w1 + · · · + w J = 1. (1.9)
Financial weights define the distribution on individual assets and will, in this book,
usually be normalized so that they sum to 1.
The mathematics allow negative w j . With bank deposits this corresponds to bor-
rowing. It is also possible with shares, known as short selling. A loss due to a
negative development is then carried by somebody else. The mechanism is as fol-
lows. A short contract with a buyer is to sell shares at the end of the period at an
agreed price. At that point we shall have to buy at market price, gaining if it is lower
than our agreement, losing if not. Short contracts may be an instrument to lower
risk (see Section 5.3) and require liquidity; i.e., assets that are traded regularly.
T k = kT or tk = kh
(1.10)
time scale for evaluation time scale for modelling
i i
i i
i i
10 Introduction
where R1 , . . . , RK are the returns. This defines R0:K on the right as the K-step return
R0:K = (1 + R1 ) · · · (1 + RK ) − 1 and also X0:K = X1 + · · · + XK ,
(1.11)
ordinary returns log-returns
where Xk = log(1 + Rk ) and X0:K = log(1 + R0:K ). The log-returns on the right
are accumulated by adding them. Interest is a special case (an important one!) and
grows from T 0 = 0 to T K according to
where r1 , . . . , rK are the future rates. This reduces to r0:K = (1 + r)K − 1 if all rk = r,
but in practice rk will float in a way that is unknown at T 0 = 0.
Often VK aggregates economic and financial activity beyond the initial invest-
ment v0 . Let Bk be income or expenses that surface at time T k , and suppose the
financial income or loss coming from the sequence B1 , . . . , BK is the same as for
the original asset. The total value at T K is then the sum
K
VK = (1 + R0:K )v0 + (1 + Rk:K )Bk , (1.13)
k=1
i i
i i
i i
the so-called implied rates. Consider an asset of value v0 that will be traded at time
T K for a price V0 (K) agreed today. Such contracts are called forwards and define
inherent rates of interest r0 (0 : K) through
V0 (K)
V0 (K) = {1 + r0 (0 : K)}v0 or r0 (0 : K) = − 1. (1.14)
v0
Note the difference from (1.12) where r0:K is uncertain, whereas now V0 (K) and
hence r0 (0 : K) is fixed by the contract and known at T 0 = 0. Forward rates can in
practice be deduced from many different sources, and the results are virtually iden-
tical. Otherwise there would have been market inconsistencies opening up money-
earning schemes with no risk attached; more on this in Chapter 14.
We are often interested in breaking the rate r0 (0 : K) down into its average value
r̄0 (0 : K) per period. The natural definition is
1 + r0 (0 : K) = {1 + r̄0 (0 : K)}K or r̄0 (0 : K) = {1 + r0 (0 : K)}1/K − 1, (1.15)
and as K is varied, the sequence r̄0 (0 : K) traces out the interest-rate curve or
yield curve, which is published daily in the financial press.
This is a popular criterion in all spheres of economic life and used for assets and
liabilities alike. It applies even when B0 , . . . , BK are stochastic (then the present
value is too). Individual payments may be both positive and negative.
The quantities dk = 1/(1 + r)k (or dk = e−rk if interest is continuously com-
pounded) are known as discount factors; they devaluate or discount future income.
In life insurance, r is called the technical rate. The value to use isn’t obvious, least
of all with payment streams lasting decades ahead. Market discounting is an alter-
native. The coefficient dk in (1.16) is then replaced by
1 1
dk = = or dk = P0 (0 : k), (1.17)
{1 + r̄0 (0 : k)} k 1 + r0 (0 : k)
where P0 (0 : k) comes from the bond market; see below. Instead of choosing the
technical rate r administratively, the market view is used. The resulting valuation,
i i
i i
i i
12 Introduction
known as fair value, holds obvious attraction, but also the disadvantage that such
discount sequences fluctuate randomly, bringing uncertainty even if there was none
at the start; see Section 15.3.
With more than one payment a numerical method such as bisection is needed to
determine y; see Appendix C.4.
A special case is the zero-coupon bond or T-bond, for which B0 = · · · = BK−1 =
0. It is unit faced if BK = 1. Now the only transaction occurs at maturity T K , and
in a market operating rationally its yield y is the same as the forward rate of interest
r̄0 (0 : K). The price of unit-faced T-bonds will be denoted P0 (0 : K), which is what
is charged today for the right to receive one money unit at T K and relates to the
forward rate of interest through
1 1
P0 (0 : K) = = . (1.19)
1 + r0 (0 : K) {1 + r̄0 (0 : K)}K
Why? Because anything else would have allowed riskless financial income, which
is incompatible with free markets. The prices P0 (0 : K) will be used a lot in Chap-
ters 14 and 15.
1.4.6 Duration
The timing of bonds and other fixed payment streams is often measured through
their duration D. There are several versions which vary in detail. One possibility is
i i
i i
i i
K
Bk (1 + r)−k
D= qk T k where qk = K . (1.20)
−i
k=0 i=0 Bi (1 + r)
so that D = T K , a sensible result! A bond with fixed coupon payments and a final
(much larger) face has duration between T K /2 and T K .
Vk = (1 + Rk )Vk−1 , k = 1, 2, . . . , (1.21)
where the link of Rk to the individual assets is through (1.8) as before. If R jk is the
return of asset j in period k, then
J
Rk = w j R jk , (1.22)
j=1
and the weights w1 , . . . , w J define the investment strategy. One way is to keep them
fixed, as in (1.22) where they do not depend on k. This is not achieved automati-
cally since individual investments meet with unequal success, which changes their
relative value. Weights can only be kept fixed by buying and selling. Restructuring
financial weights in such a way is known as rebalancing.
The opposite line is to let weights float freely. Mathematically this is more con-
veniently expressed through
J
Vk = Vk j where Vk j = (1 + Rk j )Vk−1, j , j = 1, . . . , J,
j=1
emphasizing assets rather than returns. For more on investment strategies, consult
Section 15.5.
i i
i i
i i
14 Introduction
and two different sources of risk that might themselves demand extensive mod-
elling and simulation are integrated. There will be more on this in Section 15.6.
Here the target is a more modest one. A simple Monte Carlo algorithm and nota-
tion for such schemes will first be presented and then four simple examples. The
aim is to introduce a general line of attack and indicate the power of Monte Carlo
for problem solving, learning and communication.
i i
i i
i i
0.04
100
Million US$
80
0.02
40
0.01
20
0.0
0
Figure 1.2 Simulations of term insurance. Left: 100 parallel runs through insurance portfolio.
Right: Annual density function obtained from m = 10 000 simulations.
where p j is the probability of survival. A simulation goes through the entire port-
folio, reads policy information from file, draws those who die (whom we have to
pay for) and adds all the payments together. In Algorithm 1.1 take K = J, ak = 1
and X ∗j is either 0 or s j ; details in Section 3.4.
The example in Figure 1.2 shows annual expenses for J = 10 000 policies for
which s j = 1 for all j (money unit: one million US$). All policy holders were
i i
i i
i i
16 Introduction
Figure 1.3 Density functions of the total claim against portfolio of fire risks (seven/eight Danish
kroner (DKK) for one euro).
i i
i i
i i
15
% Interest % Interest
10
10
5
5
0
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30
Years ahead Years ahead
Figure 1.4 Simulations of the annual rate of interest from the Vasic̆ek model.
‘small’ portfolio (J = 1000) on the left and a ‘large’ one (J = 100 000) on the right.
The uncertainty is now much larger than in the first example. Note that the density
function on the left is strongly skewed, but this asymmetry is straightened out as
the portfolio grows, and the distribution becomes more Gaussian. The central limit
theorem tells us this must be so.
starting at Y0 = r0 −ξ. Here ξ, a and σ are fixed parameters and {εk } independent and
identically distributed variables with mean 0 and standard deviation 1. The model
is known as an autoregression of order 1 and is examined in Section 5.6. Here the
objective is simulation, which is carried out by taking ak = a in Algorithm 1.1 and
adding ξ to the output Y1∗ , Y2∗ . . . so that Monte Carlo interest rates r1∗ , r2∗ , . . . are
produced.
i i
i i
i i
18 Introduction
Figure 1.4 shows simulated scenarios on an annual time scale under Gaussian
models. The parameters are
Rk = eξ+σεk − 1, k = 1, 2, . . . , (1.26)
i i
i i
Discovering Diverse Content Through
Random Scribd Documents
I
Representation of Employees
The chairman shall appoint three tellers, who shall take charge of
the ballot box containing the nomination votes, and, with the aid of
the secretary, they shall make out the list of the duly nominated
candidates, which shall be announced by the chairman. The meeting
shall then proceed to elect representatives by secret ballot, from
among the number of candidates announced, the same tellers
having charge of the balloting. If dissatisfied with the count, either
as respects the nomination or election, any twenty-five employees
present may demand a recount, and for the purposes of the recount
the chairman shall select as tellers three from the number of those
demanding a recount, and himself assist in the counting, and these
four shall act, in making the recount, in place of the secretary and
the tellers previously chosen. There shall be no appeal from this
recount, except to the president of the company, and such appeal
may be taken as hereinafter provided, at the request of any twenty-
five employees present and entitled to vote.
1. District divisions.
To facilitate the purposes herein set forth, the camps of the company
shall be divided into five or more districts, as follows: the Trinidad
District, comprising all mines and coke oven plants in Las Animas
County; the Walsenburg District, comprising all mines in Huerfano
County; the Cañon District, comprising all mines in Fremont County;
the Western District, comprising all mines and coke oven plants
located on the Western Slope; the Sunrise District, comprising the
iron mines located in Wyoming.
The first district conferences held in each year shall select the
following joint committees on industrial relations for each district,
which joint committees shall be regarded as permanent committees
to be intrusted with such duties as are herein set forth, or as may be
assigned by the conferences. These joint committees shall be
available for consultation at any time throughout the year with the
Advisory Board on Social and Industrial Betterment, the president,
the president’s executive assistant, or any officer of the operating
department of the company.
(a) Joint Committee on Industrial Coöperation and Conciliation: to be
composed of six members.
(b) Joint Committee on Safety and Accidents: to be composed of six
members.
(c) Joint Committee on Sanitation, Health and Housing: to be
composed of six members.
(d) Joint Committee on Recreation and Education: to be composed
of six members.
There shall be on the part of the company and its employees, a strict
observance of the Federal and State laws respecting mining and
labor and of the company’s rules and regulations supplementing the
same.
1. Executive supervision.
The Advisory Board shall meet at least once in every six months, and
may convene for special meetings upon the call of the chairman
whenever he may deem a special meeting advisable.
The Advisory Board shall have power to consider all matters referred
to it by the chairman, or any of its members, or by any committee or
organization directly or indirectly connected with the company, and
may make such recommendations to the president as in its opinion
seem to be expedient and in the interest of the company and its
employees.
Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside the
United States, check the laws of your country in addition to the
terms of this agreement before downloading, copying, displaying,
performing, distributing or creating derivative works based on this
work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes
no representations concerning the copyright status of any work in
any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you
provide access to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work
in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in
the official version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or
expense to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or
a means of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original
“Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must
include the full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in
paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.
1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED,
INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF
MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.
Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of
other ways including checks, online payments and credit card
donations. To donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.
Our website is not just a platform for buying books, but a bridge
connecting readers to the timeless values of culture and wisdom. With
an elegant, user-friendly interface and an intelligent search system,
we are committed to providing a quick and convenient shopping
experience. Additionally, our special promotions and home delivery
services ensure that you save time and fully enjoy the joy of reading.
ebookultra.com