Cai 2000
Cai 2000
DEBORAH A. CAI
University of Maryland
STEVEN R. WILSON
Purdue University
LAURA E. DRAKE
University of Maryland
This study explores culture’s effect on behaviors and outcomes in intercultural negotiation and
examines how those effects are moderated by role. Eighty U.S. and international students took
part in a previously developed negotiation task (Pruitt, 1981) and completed Hui and Triandis’s
(1986) individualism-collectivism (INDCOL) scale. Negotiation interactions were coded for
information sharing, offers, and distributive tactics. Findings show that a negotiation dyad’s
collectivism is positively associated with higher joint profit. The effects of culture on both com-
munication behaviors and joint outcomes, however, differ by role of the negotiator. In particular,
seller collectivism has larger and more consistent effects on communication behavior and joint
profit than buyer collectivism. Results support a “culture in context” perspective of negotiation
that takes into account negotiator qualities, contextual and structural features of the negotia-
tion, and mediating processes in addition to cultural values.
C
onflicts often contain potential for mutually beneficial outcomes
that go unrealized (Fisher, Ury, & Patton, 1991; Pruitt & Rubin,
1986); thus, scholars have identified communicative and cogni-
tive factors that impede joint gain (Neale & Bazerman, 1991; Pruitt, 1981;
Pruitt & Carnevale, 1993), such as distributive tactics (Pruitt & Lewis, 1975;
Deborah A. Cai (Ph.D., Michigan State University, 1994) is an assistant professor in the Depart-
ment of Communication at the University of Maryland, 2110 Skinner Building, College Park,
MD 20742, phone: (301) 405-6524, fax: (301) 314-9471, e-mail: [email protected]; Steven
R. Wilson (Ph.D., Purdue University, 1989) is an associate professor in the Department of Com-
munication, Purdue University, 1366 LAEB 2114, West Lafayette, IN 47907-1366, phone:
(765) 494-7547, e-mail: [email protected]; Laura E. Drake (Ph.D., Michigan State Uni-
versity, 1995) is an assistant professor at the Department of Communication, University of
Maryland, 2120 Skinner Building, University of Maryland, College Park, MD 20742, phone:
(301) 405-6530, e-mail: [email protected]. The research reported in this study was ap-
proved by the University Committee on Research Involving Human Subjects at Michigan
State University. We wish to thank Edward L. Fink and two anonymous reviewers for their
helpful feedback on earlier drafts of this article. Please direct correspondence to first author.
Human Communication Research, Vol. 26 No. 4, October 2000 591–617
© 2000 International Communication Association
592 HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
Putnam & Jones, 1982; Tutzauer & Roloff, 1988) or fixed-sum percep-
tions (Thompson & Hastie, 1990). With few exceptions (Brett & Okumura,
1998; see Graham, 1993), this research has not been replicated among
international participants. Consequently, we understand little about
culture’s influence on integrative bargaining (Cai & Drake, 1998; Weiss,
1996). To complicate matters, scholars historically have assumed that
culture directly affects negotiation behavior (Graham, 1985; Pye, 1982),
but recent research suggests that buyer-seller roles and norms of nego-
tiation can moderate effects of culture (Cai, 1998; Drake, 1995) and that
intercultural contexts bring about significantly different negotiation pro-
cesses than intracultural contexts (Adler & Graham, 1989). Thus, our chal-
lenge is to isolate the effects of culture from those of structure or context
when assessing integrative outcomes.
To this end, our paper pursues two goals. First, we examine how cul-
ture (here, individualism-collectivism) affects behavior in intercultural
negotiation. Although a few studies look at reaching integrative outcomes
among international partners (Adler & Graham, 1989; Brett & Okumura,
1998), none analyzes behaviors for reaching such outcomes. We look at
how cultural values affect communication behavior. Second, we examine
how the effects of culture on negotiation are moderated by role. After
defining individualism-collectivism, we offer a rationale for the relation-
ship between collectivism and high joint gain. Next, we examine culture’s
effect on communication processes. Finally, we suggest a basis for expect-
ing qualifying effects of structural and contextual features on outcomes.
Defining Individualism-Collectivism
tion tactics as they occur in the negotiation, we can examine the actual
relationship between culture, communication behavior, and integrative
outcomes.
Third, the work by Graham et al. assumes cultural values based on the
participants’ country of origin. Triandis, Bontempo, Villareal, Asai, and
Lucca (1988), however, argue that within-country variance may also be
significant. Therefore, results based on assumptions about national cul-
ture do not demonstrate how specific cultural values are related to be-
haviors and outcomes. Because we want to draw conclusions about the
effects of cultural values on communication behaviors and integrative
outcomes, we assess individualism-collectivism at the individual level.
Fourth, these prior studies draw generalizations for international ne-
gotiation based on country-by-country comparisons. Brett and Okumura
(1998) demonstrate, however, that intra- and intercultural dyads operate
differently in their ability to realize integrative potential by providing
evidence that interdependence between negotiators results in lower joint
outcomes for intercultural dyads than intracultural ones. Recognizing the
complexity of negotiator relationships, we examine the effects of both
parties’ collectivism on the use of bargaining tactics and the realization of
integrative outcomes during intercultural negotiation.
As these four points make clear, research to date has not explored rela-
tionships between cultural values (measured at the individual level) and
integrative outcomes. This study contributes to existing research in inter-
cultural negotiation by exploring these relationships.
Although it has been argued that individualist negotiators may stimu-
late each other to achieve higher joint gain (Brett & Okumura, 1998), we
provide four reasons to suspect that collectivism affects integrative negoti-
ating to achieve higher joint outcomes. First, collectivist negotiators may
have more concern for the opponent’s outcome because collectivist cultures
measure success in terms of maximizing group interests.2 Second, collectiv-
ist negotiators may engage less often in fixed-sum assumptions—the belief
that negotiators’ interests are necessarily related in zero-sum fashion (Th-
ompson & Hastie, 1990)—because collectivism is characterized by a greater
concern for the welfare of the group as a whole. Third, collectivist negotia-
tors may consider issues simultaneously rather than sequentially, because
collectivist cultures emphasize holistic over field independent thinking
(Gudykunst, 1987). Packaging issues allows negotiators to find integrative
solutions while incurring minimal concessions (Pruitt & Lewis, 1975;
Tutzauer & Roloff, 1988; Weingart, Thompson, Bazerman, & Carroll, 1990).
Finally, collectivistic negotiators may avoid distributive tactics, because col-
lectivist cultures value relational harmony (Kim & Wilson, 1994) and es-
chew forceful conflict styles (Kumagai & Straus, 1983; Lee & Rogan, 1991).
Based on the culture as shared value view, we predict that:
Cai et al. / CULTURE IN CONTEXT 595
H1: A negotiation dyad’s profit will increase as the dyad’s total collectivism
increases.
Culture in Context
Buyer-Seller Roles
Partner Collectivism
METHOD
Procedures
Three persons from different countries were scheduled for each time
slot to increase the likelihood of having two persons available to partici-
pate. When all three persons arrived, one was randomly selected to com-
plete only a questionnaire for use in another project with the provision
that the two “negotiators” always were from different countries of origin.
The two negotiators were separated so they could ask questions about
the instructions without giving away information to the opponent. Par-
ticipants completed a consent form briefly describing the task, then they
were given instructions randomly identifying their role as either buyer or
seller. Both participants received instructions manipulating cognitive fram-
ing.6 Next, participants completed a brief pretest to ensure they under-
stood the instructions. Participants then were moved to the negotiation
room and given 30 minutes to complete the negotiation task. All negotia-
tions were conducted in English. Sessions were videotaped from behind
a one-way mirror, and a tape recorder was placed on the negotiation table
to ensure sound quality. After completing the negotiation task, bargain-
ers completed a final contract spelling out the settlement points for each
issue. Dyads not finished negotiating were stopped at the 30-minute mark.
Participants again were separated and asked to complete two ques-
tionnaires assessing (a) satisfaction with their own performance and out-
comes and (b) individualism-collectivism (INDCOL) and demographic
information, including four questions assessing English ability (how long
they had been in the U.S., when they first learned English, how long they
had been conversing in English, and how competent they felt conversing
in English). Finally, participants were debriefed about the purpose of the
study but asked not to share this information with others.
Negotiation Task
TABLE 1
Negotiators’ Payoff Schedules for Bargaining Simulationa
ment options for each appliance (marked “A” through “I”), each with
assigned profits for both parties. Participants read and were told explic-
itly, “You can approach the task in any fashion you choose. The only re-
strictions on your behavior are that you may not show your own profit
sheet to your counterpart and you may not ask to see your counterpart’s
profit sheet.”
Each negotiator could earn a maximum of $4,000 or a minimum of $0.
According to Table 1, an obvious compromise agreement would be E-E-E,
yielding for each negotiator an individual profit of $2,000 and a joint profit
of $4,000. A more integrative solution is possible if negotiators logroll,
because TVs are the most profitable appliance for the seller, whereas laptop
computers are most profitable for the buyer. A-E-I yields an individual
profit of $2,600 for each negotiator, for a joint profit of $5,200. To encour-
age integrative bargaining and remain consistent with prior research,
negotiators were instructed to achieve at least $2,200 profit across the three
appliances (Bazerman et al., 1985; Huber & Neale, 1986; Pruitt & Lewis,
1975). To induce concern about the other, participants were told that their
own company would incur long-term benefits from working with the
other company if an acceptable agreement was reached.
We chose Pruitt’s (1981) simulation to facilitate comparison of our find-
ings with the large body of prior research on integrative bargaining con-
ducted both with U.S. and international participants (see Graham, 1993;
Neale & Bazerman, 1991). In support of the task’s external validity, Neale
and Northcraft (1986) compared expert (real estate agents) and amateur
(undergraduates) negotiators using a similar version of this simulation.
Pairs of experts reached more profitable joint agreements than pairs of
amateurs, as would be expected if the task taps an important aspect of
skill at integrative bargaining.
600 HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
TABLE 2
Modified Individualism-Collectivism (INDCOL) Scalea
Independent Variables
validity of our 11-item solution, total scores from this solution were cor-
related with the total scores of the revised 33-item version of INDCOL
suggested by Hui and Yee (1994). We found the 33-item version to have
an alpha reliability of .72 and the correlation between this scale and our
11-item solution is .86 (p < .0001), which supports the comparability of
our index with their revised solution.
Dependent Variable
Joint profit was obtained based on the final contracts signed at the end
of the simulation. Of the 40 dyads, 34 (85%) reached agreement within 30
minutes. Because joint profit is a measure of integrativeness, and we
wanted to retain deadlocked dyads, it did not seem appropriate to assign
joint profits of $0 to dyads that did not reach agreement. Following pre-
vious studies (e.g., Pruitt & Lewis, 1975; Tutzauer, 1990), we treated the
six deadlocked dyads as if they had reached the least integrative solution
of a straight compromise agreement E-E-E, resulting in an individual profit
of $2,000 for each negotiator (see Table 1).
Communication Variables
Heuristic trial and error. In four 1-hour sessions, three new coders were
trained to recognize single- and multiple-item offers. Single-item offers
were defined as suggestions regarding the contract price for one appli-
ance only (e.g., “How about price B for TVs?”). Multiple-item offers were
defined as suggestions to combine the contract price for two or more ap-
pliances in a package offer (e.g., “Price C is okay for copy machines if I
can have price F for computers.”). Multiple offers often occurred as a
simple listing of prices (e.g., “How about D, E, and G?”). Single- and
multiple-item offers were coded separately for buyers and sellers.
The unit of analysis was the uninterrupted talking turn, all talk occur-
ring by one negotiator between the end of the opponent’s previous talk
and the beginning of the opponent’s next turn. Only turns in which offers
occurred were coded; all other turns received a “null” code. Unitizing
reliability was determined based on the match in coder performance across
8 (of 40) videotaped negotiations (187 offers). Using this method,
Guetzkow’s U reached .04 (agreement rate 96%). To establish categoriz-
ing reliability, units consensually recognized by coders were compiled
and listed. Coders then watched the same videotapes again, labeling each
unit as a single- or multiple-item offer. Agreement among coders produced
a global kappa of .96. Categorical kappas (103 single units, 50 multiple) were
.94 for single-item offers and .88 for multiple-item offers. For testing Hy-
pothesis 2, we report the use of multiple offers, but a sum of standardized
scores for single-item and multiple-item offers for each role was calculated
as an index of “heuristic trial and error” to address the research questions.
Cai et al. / CULTURE IN CONTEXT 603
Transforming Variables
TABLE 3
Descriptive Statistics for Communication Tactics a
Single Offers 2.03 0.93 -.34 93% 2.19 0.80 -.02 97%
Multiple Offers 1.69 0.99 .17 87% 1.71 1.04 .22 87%
Ask Numerical 1.04 0.06 1.66 32% 1.04 0.06 1.39 37%
Ask Directional 1.02 0.03 1.32 27% 1.02 0.05 2.42 20%
Give Numerical 0.45 0.56 .46 40% .51 0.58 .24 45%
HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
Give Directionale 0.76 0.51 -.84 70% 2.43 2.43 1.10 77%
a
At the level of individual tactics, significant differences between buyer and seller were found only for giving directional information, t (39) = 4.37,
p < .0001, using a two-tailed paired t-test. No other buyer-seller differences were significant. Comparisons were performed on transformed variables.
b
For both buyer and seller, n = 40. Descriptive statistics reported are based on transformed variables.
c
Standard error of skewness (after transformation) = .37.
d
Percentage of buyers or sellers who used the tactic at least once.
e
Sellers’ giving directional information was not transformed.
Cai et al. / CULTURE IN CONTEXT 605
RESULTS
TABLE 4
Correlations Between Total Profit, Buyer Collectivism, Seller Collectivism, and
Communication Processesa
a
Correlations performed on transformed variables.
b
Buyer role, seller role, total profit, and buyer collectivism, n = 40. Seller collectivism, n = 38.
*p < .10 (one-tailed).
**p < .05 (one-tailed).
tively associated with joint profit (b = 13.72, p < .05, one-tailed). The rela-
tionship between buyer collectivism and joint profit, although positive,
was not statistically significant (b = 11.52, p = .13), and the interaction
term also was not significant (b = 1.26, p = .11). Thus, for RQ1a, the re-
gression analysis demonstrates joint profit is only associated with seller
collectivism regardless of the level of buyer collectivism, and for RQ3,
buyer and seller collectivism do not interact to affect joint profit. These
findings become easier to interpret when examining the effects of buyer
and seller collectivism separately on communication tactics.
Cai et al. / CULTURE IN CONTEXT 607
Hypothesis 2 and Research Question 1b. We know, then, that seller collectiv-
ism is significantly associated with joint profit, and that the degree of asking
information by the seller and the degree of buyer and seller distributive
tactics affect joint profit. Next, we examine how culture influences the use of
these tactics. Hypothesis 2 posits that during intercultural negotiation,
negotiator’s collectivism will be (a) positively associated with the frequency
of asking for information, (b) positively associated with offers that package
multiple issues, and (c) negatively associated with the frequency of using
distributive tactics. Further, RQ1(b) asks whether the effects of seller collec-
tivism on seller’s negotiation tactics are different than the effects of buyer
collectivism on buyer’s negotiation tactics.
608 HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
The second and third data columns of Table 4 provide Pearson correla-
tions between buyer and seller collectivism and the use of communication
tactics. For H2a, seller collectivism has a significant positive relationship
with the degree of asking for information by the seller (r = .41, p < .05, one-
tailed). Buyer collectivism, however, is not associated with the buyers’
asking for information (r = -.09, ns). As for making offers that package
multiple issues (H2b), once again seller collectivism is significantly and
positively associated with multiple offers by sellers (r = .33, p < .05, one-
tailed), but buyer collectivism is not associated with multiple offers by
buyers (r = .06, ns). Similarly, for H2c, seller collectivism has a signifi-
cantly negative association with the seller’s frequency of using distribu-
tive tactics (r = -.29, p < .05, one-tailed), but buyer collectivism is not sig-
nificantly related to the buyer’s use of distributive tactics (r = -.20, ns).
In sum, Hypothesis 2 receives partial support in that seller collectiv-
ism has significant effects on the seller’s use of all three communication
behaviors that previous research has associated with integrative outcomes,
but buyer collectivism has no such effects. Further, the answer to RQ1,
which asks whether the effects of individualism-collectivism are depen-
dent on negotiator role, is affirmative. Seller collectivism affects the seller’s
use of all three communication behaviors, but buyer collectivism only
marginally affects the buyer’s use of distributive tactics.
Summary
DISCUSSION
Summary of Findings
NOTES
1. Three studies by Graham and his colleagues actually examine transcriptions or video-
tapes for communication behaviors (Graham & Andrews, 1987; Graham et al., 1992, 1994). No
coding scheme is used in the Graham and Andrews study; the other two studies compare
national cultures on frequencies of behaviors. Although both perceptual and behavioral mea-
sures are used in Graham et al. (1992), correlations between these measures are not reported.
2. This assumption continues to be problematic for prediction because a negotiator’s
concerns may center on whether the opponent is perceived as an in-group or out-group
member. Even within highly collectivist cultures, concern for others’ needs may be con-
fined only to those who are in-group members. Competition and distributiveness may be
directed toward out-group members (Triandis et al., 1988). Negotiators’ perceptions of in-
group versus out-group membership are rarely measured and probably vary widely de-
pending on contextual and structural features of the negotiation. For instance, when negoti-
ating in the U.S., non-U.S. negotiators may perceive an opponent who is not North American
as an in-group member. However, expatriates new to the U.S. and intending to seek citizen-
ship may perceive the same opponent as an in-group member and perceive all opponents not
from the U.S. as members of the out-group. In the present analysis, this problem was ad-
dressed partially by creating “future relationship” concerns within the induction. We assumed
that collectivism and its emphasis on relational harmony would foster in-group feelings to-
ward an opponent with whom the negotiator would have an ongoing business relationship.
Showing concern for the opponent’s goals is one means of fostering that relationship.
614 HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
We also examined the scatterplot and stem and leaf plot of standardized residuals and ob-
served no structured pattern of residuals. Both the skew and kurtosis of the residuals was
small and not significant. Thus, we concluded the regression met the necessary statistical
assumptions.
REFERENCES
Adler, N. J., Brahm, R., & Graham, J. L. (1992). Strategy implementation: A comparison of
face-to-face negotiations in the People’s Republic of China and the United States. Strate-
gic Management Journal, 13, 449–466.
Adler, N. J., & Graham, J. L. (1989). Cross-cultural interaction: The international compari-
son fallacy? Journal of International Business Studies, 20, 515–537.
Adler, N. J., Graham, J. L., & Gehrke, T. S. (1987). Business negotiations in Canada, Mexico,
and the United States. Journal of Business Research, 15, 411–429.
Bazerman, M. H., Magliozzi, T., & Neale, M. A. (1985). The acquisition of an integrative
response in a competitive market. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes,
35, 294–313.
Brett, J. N., & Okumura, T. (1998) Inter- and intracultural negotiation: U.S. and Japanese
negotiators. Academy of Management Journal, 41, 495–510.
Cai, D. A. (1998). Culture, plans, and the pursuit of negotiation goals. Journal of Asian Pacific
Communication, 8, 103–123.
Cai, D. A., & Donohue, W. (1997). Determinants of facework in negotiation: An intercultural
perspective. Asian Journal of Communication, 7, 85–110.
Cai, D. A., & Drake, L. E. (1998). The business of business negotiation. In M. E. Roloff (Ed.),
Communication yearbook 21 (pp. 153–189). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Campbell, N. C. G., Graham, J. L., Jolibert, A., & Meissner, H. G. (1988). Marketing negotia-
tions in France, Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Journal of Market-
ing, 52, 49–62.
Drake, L. E. (1995). To err is human: Cultural orientation as a source of judgment errors
and integrative processes in international negotiation. Dissertation Abstracts Interna-
tional, 56, 07A.
Emerson, R. M. (1962). Power dependence relations. American Sociological Review, 62, 31–41.
Fisher, R., Ury, W., & Patton, B. (1991). Getting to yes: Negotiating agreement without giving in
(2nd ed.). Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Folger, J. P., Hewes, D. E., & Poole, M. S. (1984). Coding social interaction. In B. Dervin & M.
Voigt (Eds.), Progress in communication sciences (Vol. 6, pp. 115–161). Norwood, NJ: Ablex.
Graham, J. L. (1983). Brazilian, Japanese, and American business negotiations. Journal of
International Business Studies, 14, 47–61.
Graham, J. L. (1985). Cross-cultural marketing negotiations: A laboratory experiment. Mar-
keting Science, 4, 130–146.
Graham, J. L. (1993). The Japanese negotiation style: Characteristics of a distinct approach.
Negotiation Journal, 9, 123–140.
Graham, J. L., & Andrews, J. D. (1987). A holistic analysis of Japanese and American busi-
ness negotiations. Journal of Business Communication, 24, 63–77.
Graham, J. L., Evenko, L. I., & Rajan, M. N. (1992). An empirical comparison of Soviet and
American business negotiations. Journal of International Business Studies, 23, 387–415.
Graham, J. L., Kim, D. K., Lin, C. Y., & Robinson, M. (1988). Buyer-seller negotiations around
the Pacific Rim: Differences in fundamental exchange processes. Journal of Consumer Re-
search, 15, 48–54.
616 HUMAN COMMUNICATION RESEARCH / October 2000
Graham, J. L., Mintu, A. T., & Rodgers, W. (1994). Explorations of negotiation behaviors in
ten foreign cultures using a model developed in the United States. Management Science,
40, 72–95.
Gudykunst, W. B. (1987). Cross-cultural comparisons. In C. Berger & S. Chaffee (Eds.), Hand-
book of communication science (pp. 847–891). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Huber, V. L., & Neale, M. A. (1986). Effects of cognitive heuristics and goals on negotiator
performance and subsequent goal setting. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision
Processes, 38, 342–365.
Hui, C. H., & Triandis, H. C. (1986). Individualism-collectivism: A study of cross-cultural
researchers. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 17, 225–248.
Hui, C. H., & Yee, C. (1994). The shortened individualism-collectivism scale: Its relationship
to demographic and work-related variables. Journal of Research in Personality, 28, 409–424.
Hunter, J. E. (1980). Factor analysis. In P. R. Monge & J. N. Cappella (Eds.), Multivariate
techniques in human communication research (pp. 229–257). New York: Academic Press.
Janosik, R. J. (1987). Rethinking the culture-negotiation link. Negotiation Journal, 3, 385–395.
Kelley, H. H. (1966). A classroom study of dilemmas in interpersonal negotiation. In K.
Archibald (Ed.), Strategic interaction and conflict (pp. 49–73). Berkeley: Institute of Inter-
national Studies, University of California.
Kim, M. S., & Wilson, S. R. (1994). A cross-cultural comparison of implicit theories of re-
questing. Communication Monographs, 61, 210–235.
Kumagai, F., & Straus, M. A. (1983). Conflict resolution tactics in Japan, India, and the USA.
Journal of Comparative Family Studies, 14, 377–392.
Lee, H. O., & Rogan, R. G. (1991). A cross-cultural comparison of organizational conflict
management behavior. International Journal of Conflict Management, 2, 181–199.
Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. (1985). The effects of framing and negotiator overconfi-
dence on bargaining behaviors and outcomes. Academy of Management Journal, 28, 34–49.
Neale, M. A., & Bazerman, M. H. (1991). Cognition and rationality in organizations. New York:
Free Press.
Neale, M. A., Huber, V. L., & Northcraft, G. B. (1987). The framing of negotiations: Contex-
tual versus task frames. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 39, 228–241.
Neale, M. A., & Northcraft, G. B. (1986). Experts, amateurs, and refrigerators: Comparing
expert and amateur negotiators in a novel task. Organizational Behavior and Human Deci-
sion Processes, 38, 305–317.
Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Negotiation behavior. New York: Academic Press.
Pruitt, D. G., & Carnevale, P. J. (1993). Negotiation in social conflict. Pacific Grove, CA:
Brooks-Cole.
Pruitt, D. G., & Lewis, S. A. (1975). Development of integrative solutions in bilateral nego-
tiation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 31, 621–633.
Pruitt, D. G., & Rubin, J. Z. (1986). Social conflict: Escalation, stalemate, and settlement. New
York: Random House.
Putnam, L. L., & Geist, P. (1985). Argument in bargaining: An analysis of the reasoning
process. Southern Speech Communication Journal, 50, 225–245.
Putnam, L. L., & Jones, T. S. (1982). Reciprocity in negotiations: An analysis of bargaining
interaction. Communication Monographs, 49, 171–191.
Putnam, L. L., & Wilson, S. R. (1989). Argumentation and bargaining strategies as discrimi-
nators of integrative bargaining outcomes. In M. Rahim (Ed.), Managing conflict: An in-
terdisciplinary approach (pp. 121–144). New York: Praeger.
Putnam, L. L., Wilson, S. R., & Turner, D. B. (1990). The evolution of policy arguments in
teachers’ negotiation. Argumentation, 4, 129–152.
Putnam, L. L., Wilson, S. R., Waltman, M. S., & Turner, D. B. (1986). The evolution of case
arguments in teachers’ bargaining. Journal of American Forensic Association, 23, 63–81.
Cai et al. / CULTURE IN CONTEXT 617
Pye, L. W. (1982). Chinese commercial negotiating style. Santa Monica, CA: Rand.
Roloff, M. E., Tutzauer, F. E., & Dailey, W. O. (1989). The role of argumentation in distribu-
tive and integrative bargaining contexts: Seeking relative advantage but at what cost? In
M. A. Rahim (Ed.), Managing conflict: An interdisciplinary approach (pp. 109–119). New
York: Praeger.
Salacuse, J. W. (1991). Making global deals. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Schwartz, S. H. (1990). Individualism-collectivism: Critique and proposed refinements. Jour-
nal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 21, 139–157.
Thomas, K. W., & Pondy, L. R. (1977). Toward an “intent” model of conflict management
among principal parties. Human Relations, 30, 1089–1102.
Thompson, L. L. (1991). Information exchange in negotiation. Journal of Experimental Social
Psychology, 27, 161–179.
Thompson, L. L., & Hastie, R. (1990). Social perception in negotiation. Organization Behavior
and Human Decision Processes, 47, 98–123.
Triandis, H., Bontempo, R., Villareal, M. J., Asai, M., & Lucca, N. (1988). Individualism and
collectivism: Cross-cultural perspectives on self in-group relationships. Journal of Per-
sonality and Social Psychology, 54, 323–338.
Trompenaars, F. (1993). Riding the waves of culture. London: The Economist Books.
Tutzauer, F. (1990). Integrative potential and information exchange as antecedents of joint
benefit in negotiation dyads. International Journal of Conflict Management, 1, 153–173.
Tutzauer, F., & Roloff, M. E. (1988). Communication processes leading to integrative agree-
ments: Three paths to joint benefits. Communication Research, 15, 360–380.
Weingart, L. R., Thompson, L. L., Bazerman, M. H., & Carroll, J. S. (1990). Tactical behavior
and negotiation outcomes. International Journal of Conflict Management, 1, 7–31.
Weiss, S. E. (1996). International negotiations: Bricks, mortar, and prospects. In B. J. Punnett
& O. Shenkar (Eds.), Handbook for international management research (pp. 209–265). Cam-
bridge, MA: Blackwell.
Wilson, S. R., Cai, D., Campbell, D., Donohue, W., & Drake, L. (1995). Cultural and commu-
nication processes in international business negotiation. In A. M. Nicotera (Ed.), Conflict
in organizations: Communication processes (pp. 197–229). Albany, NY: SUNY Press.
Wilson, S. R., & Putnam, L. L. (1990). Interaction goals in negotiation. In J. Anderson (Ed.),
Communication Yearbook 13 (pp. 374–406). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Winer, B. J. (1971). Statistical principles in experimental design (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw -Hill.