Principles of Corporate Finance 2021
Principles of Corporate Finance 2021
Undergraduate study in
Economics, Management,
Finance and the Social Sciences
This subject guide is for a 200 course offered as part of the University of London
undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social
Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 5 within the Framework for Higher Education
Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ). For more information,
see: www.london.ac.uk
This guide was prepared for the University of London by:
Dr Hongda Zhong, Assistant Professor of Finance, The London of Economics and Political
Science and Dr. J. Favilukis, Lecturer, The London School of Economics and Political Science
This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due
to pressure of work the authors are unable to enter into any correspondence relating to,
or arising from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or
unfavourable, please use the form at the back of this guide.
University of London
Publications Office
Stewart House
32 Russell Square
London WC1B 5DN
United Kingdom
london.ac.uk
The University of London asserts copyright over all material in this subject guide except where
otherwise indicated. All rights reserved. No part of this work may be reproduced in any form,
or by any means, without permission in writing from the publisher. We make every effort to
respect copyright. If you think we have inadvertently used your copyright material, please let
us know.
Contents
Contents
Introduction to the subject guide........................................................................... 1
Aims of the course.......................................................................................................... 1
Learning outcomes......................................................................................................... 1
Syllabus.......................................................................................................................... 2
Essential reading............................................................................................................ 2
Further reading............................................................................................................... 2
Online study resources.................................................................................................... 4
Subject guide structure and use...................................................................................... 5
Examination advice........................................................................................................ 6
Glossary of abbreviations used in this subject guide........................................................ 7
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment
projects.................................................................................................................... 9
Aim of this chapter ........................................................................................................ 9
Learning objectives......................................................................................................... 9
Essential reading............................................................................................................ 9
Further reading............................................................................................................... 9
Overview........................................................................................................................ 9
Introduction................................................................................................................. 10
Fisher separation and optimal decision-making............................................................. 10
Fisher separation and project evaluation....................................................................... 13
The time value of money............................................................................................... 14
The net present value rule............................................................................................. 15
Other project appraisal techniques................................................................................ 17
Using present value techniques to value stocks and bonds............................................ 21
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 23
Key terms..................................................................................................................... 23
Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 23
Chapter 2: Real options......................................................................................... 25
Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 25
Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 25
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 25
Further reading............................................................................................................. 25
Introduction................................................................................................................. 25
Decision tree, source of option value and early exercise................................................. 26
Three types of real options............................................................................................ 30
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 36
Key terms..................................................................................................................... 36
Sample examination questions...................................................................................... 37
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure............................................ 39
Aim of the chapter........................................................................................................ 39
Learning objectives....................................................................................................... 39
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 39
Further reading............................................................................................................. 39
Overview...................................................................................................................... 39
Basic features of debt and equity.................................................................................. 40
The Modigliani–Miller theorem..................................................................................... 41
Modigliani–Miller and corporate taxation...................................................................... 43
i
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
iii
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
iv
Introduction to the subject guide
This subject guide provides you with an introduction to the modern theory
of corporate finance. As such, it covers a broad range of topics and aims
to give a general background to any student who wishes to do further
academic or practical work in finance or accounting after graduation.
We begin with project valuation methods and then examine issues that
come under the broad heading of corporate finance. We will study how
key decisions made by firms affect firm value and empirical evidence on
these issues. The areas involved include:
• the capital structure decision
• dividend policy
• mergers and acquisitions
• raising equity
• risk management.
By studying these areas, you should gain an appreciation of:
• optimal financial policy on a firm level
• conditions under which an optimal policy actually exists
• how the actual financial decisions of firms may be explained in
theoretical terms.
Learning outcomes
At the end of this course, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain how to value projects, and use key capital budgeting
techniques (for example: NPV and IRR)
• understand and apply real option theory as an advanced technique of
capital budgeting
• understand and explain the relevance, facts and role of the payout
policy, and calculate how payouts affect the valuation of securities
• understand the trade-off firms face between tax advantages of debt
and various costs of debt
• calculate and apply different costs of capital in valuation
• understand and explain different capital structure theories, including
information asymmetry and agency conflict
• understand how companies issue new shares, and calculate related
price impact in security offerings
1
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
• discuss why merger and acquisition activities exist, and calculate the
related gains and losses
• understand risk, hedging, and numerous financial securities as tools to
manage risk.
Syllabus
Students may bring into the examination hall their own hand-held
electronic calculator. If calculators are used they must satisfy the
requirements listed in the General Regulations.
The up-to-date course syllabus for can be found in the course information
sheet, which is available on the course virtual learning environment (VLE)
page or on the LSE website: www.lse.ac.uk/study-at-lse/uolip/course-
information-sheets
Essential reading
There are a number of excellent textbooks that cover this area. However,
the following text has been chosen as the core text for this course due
to its extensive treatment of many of the issues covered and up-to-date
discussions:
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA,
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) 12th edition [ISBN 9781259253331].
At the start of each chapter of this guide, we will indicate the reading that
you need to do from Brealey, Myers and Allen (2016).
Detailed reading references in this subject guide refer to the editions of the
set textbooks listed above. New editions of one or more of these textbooks
may have been published by the time you study this course. You can use
a more recent edition of any of the books; use the detailed chapter and
section headings and the index to identify relevant readings. Also check the
VLE regularly for updated guidance on readings.
Further reading
Please note that as long as you read the Essential reading you are then free
to read around the subject area in any text, paper or online resource. You
will need to support your learning by reading as widely as possible and by
thinking about how these principles apply in the real world. To help you
read extensively, you have free access to the VLE and University of London
Online Library (see below).
As further material, we will also direct you to the relevant chapters in
two other texts. You may wish to look at the following two texts that are
standard for many undergraduate finance courses:
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA: McGraw Hill, 2011) 2nd edition [ISBN 9780077129422].
Copeland, T., J. Weston and K. Shastri Financial Theory and Corporate
Policy. (Reading, MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) 4th edition
[ISBN 9780321223531].
A full list of all Further reading referred to in the subject guide is presented
here for ease of reference.
2
Introduction to the subject guide
Journal articles
Allen, F. and R. Michaely ‘Dividend policy’ in Jarrow R.A., V. Maksimovic and
W.T. Ziemba (eds) Handbooks in Operational Research and Management
Science Volume 9 1995, pp.793–837.
Asquith, P. and D. Mullins ‘The impact of initiating dividend payments on
shareholders’ wealth’, Journal of Business 56(1) 1983, pp.77–96.
Ball, R. and P. Brown ‘An empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers’,
Journal of Accounting Research 6(2) 1968, pp.159–78.
Bhattacharya, S. ‘Imperfect information, dividend policy, and “the bird in the
hand” fallacy’, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1) 1979, pp.259–70.
Blume, M., J. Crockett and I. Friend ‘Stock ownership in the United States:
characteristics and trends’, Survey of Current Business 54(11) 1974,
pp.16–40.
Bradley, M., A. Desai and E. Kim ‘Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions
and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms’,
Journal of Financial Economics 21(1) 1988, pp.3–40.
Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘Takeover bids, the free-rider problem and the theory
of the corporation’, Bell Journal of Economics 11(1) 1980, pp.42–64.
Healy, P. and K. Palepu ‘Earnings information conveyed by dividend initiations
and omissions’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(2) 1988, pp.149–76.
Healy, P., K. Palepu and R. Ruback ‘Does corporate performance improve after
mergers?’, Journal of Financial Economics 31(2) 1992, pp.135–76.
Jarrell, G. and A. Poulsen ‘Returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence
from three decades’, Financial Management 18(3) 1989, pp.12–19.
Jarrell, G., J. Brickley and J. Netter ‘The market for corporate control: the
empirical evidence since 1980’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(1) 1988,
pp.49–68.
Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’,
American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency
costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976,
pp.305–60.
Jensen, M. and R. Ruback ‘The market for corporate control: the scientific
evidence’, Journal of Financial Economics 11(1–4) 1983, pp.5–50.
Lintner, J. ‘Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained
earnings and taxes’ American Economic Review 46(2) 1956, pp.97–113.
Masulis, R. ‘The impact of capital structure change on firm value: some
estimates’, Journal of Finance 38(1) 1983, pp.107–26.
Miles, J. and J. Ezzell ‘The weighed average cost of capital, perfect capital
markets and project life: a clarification’, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis (15) 1980, pp.719–30.
Miller, M. ‘Debt and taxes’, Journal of Finance 32 1977, pp.261–75.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the
theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp. 261–97.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a
correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp. 433–43.
Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics
5(2) 1977, pp.147–75.
Myers, S. and N. Majluf ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when
firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial
Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.187–221.
Poterba, J. and L. Summers ‘Mean reversion in stock prices: evidence and
implications’, Journal of Financial Economics 22(1) 1988, pp.27–59.
Ross, S. ‘The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling
approach’, Bell Journal of Economics 8(1) 1977, pp.23–40.
Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny ‘Large shareholders and corporate control,’ Journal of
Political Economy 94(3) 1986, pp.461–88.
3
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Books
Ravenscraft, D. and F. Scherer Mergers, selloffs, and economic efficiency.
(Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1987) [ISBN 9780815773481].
The VLE
The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to
enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a
sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience
with the University of London and you should access it regularly.
The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses:
• Course materials: Subject guides and other course materials
available for download. In some courses, the content of the subject
guide is transferred into the VLE and additional resources and
activities are integrated with the text.
• Readings: Direct links, wherever possible, to essential readings in the
Online Library, including journal articles and ebooks.
• Video content: Including introductions to courses and topics within
courses, interviews, lessons and debates.
• Screencasts: Videos of PowerPoint presentations, animated podcasts
and on-screen worked examples.
• External material: Links out to carefully selected third-party
resources
• Self-test activities: Multiple-choice, numerical and algebraic
quizzes to check your understanding.
• Collaborative activities: Work with fellow students to build a body
of knowledge.
• Discussion forums: A space where you can share your thoughts
and questions with fellow students. Many forums will be supported by
4
Introduction to the subject guide
Examination advice
Important: the information and advice given here are based on the
examination structure used at the time this guide was written. Please
note that subject guides may be used for several years. Because of this we
strongly advise you to always check both the current Regulations for relevant
information about the examination, and the VLE where you should be advised
of any forthcoming changes. You should also carefully check the rubric/
instructions on the paper you actually sit and follow those instructions.
This course will be evaluated solely on the basis of a three-hour examination.
Although the examiners will attempt to provide a fairly balanced coverage of
the course, there is no guarantee that all of the topics covered in this guide
will appear in the examination. Examination questions may contain both
numerical and discursive elements. Finally, each question will carry equal
weight in marking and, in allocating your examination time, you should pay
attention to the breakdown of marks associated with the different parts of
each question.
Remember, it is important to check the VLE for:
• up-to-date information on examination and assessment arrangements for
this course
• where available, past examination papers and Examiners’ commentaries
for the course which give advice on how each question might best be
answered.
6
Introduction to the subject guide
7
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
8
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
Learning objectives
At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• analyse optimal physical and financial investment in perfect capital
markets and derive the Fisher separation result
• justify the use of the NPV rules via Fisher separation
• compute present and future values of cash-flow streams and appraise
projects using the NPV rule
• evaluate the NPV rule in relation to other commonly used evaluation
criteria
• value stocks and bonds via NPV.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 2 (Present Values), 3 (How to
Calculate Present Values), 5 (The Value of Common Stocks), 6 (Why NPV
Leads to Better Investment Decisions) and 7 (Making Investment Decisions
with the NPV Rule).
Further reading
Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading, MA;
Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapters 1 and 2.
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 9 (Discounting and Valuation), 10
(Investing in Risk-Free Projects), 11 (Investing in Risky Projects).
Roll, R. ‘A critique of the asset pricing theory’s texts. Part 1: on past and
potential testability of the theory’, Journal of Financial Economics 4(2) 1977,
pp.129–76.
Overview
In this chapter we present the basics of the present value methodology
for the valuation of investment projects. The chapter develops the NPV
technique before presenting a comparison with the other project evaluation
criteria that are common in practice. We will also discuss the optimality of
NPV and give a number of extensive examples.
9
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Introduction
What do firms do? They use resources to produce outputs. Often there are
many different projects available, for example:
• an engine manufacturer can choose to supply engines to Airbus or to
Boeing
• a school can offer different courses to students
• and, similar to a firm, an individual can choose to supply labour to
different companies.
How do companies select projects? In this chapter, we answer this
fundamental question.
For the purposes of this chapter, we will consider a firm to be a package
of investment projects. The key question, therefore, is how do the
firm’s shareholders or managers decide on which investment projects to
undertake and which to discard? Developing the tools that should be used
for project evaluation is the emphasis of this chapter.
It may seem, at this point, that our definition of the firm is rather limited.
It is clear that, in only examining the investment operations of the firm,
we are ignoring a number of potentially important firm characteristics.
In particular, we have made no reference to the financial structure or
decisions of the firm (i.e. its capital structure, borrowing or lending
activities, or dividend policy). The first part of this chapter presents what
is known as the Fisher separation theorem. What follows is a statement
of the theorem. This theorem allows us to say the following: under
certain conditions (which will be presented in the following section), the
shareholders can delegate to the management the task of choosing which
projects to undertake (i.e. determining the optimal package of investment
projects), whereas they themselves determine the optimal financial
decisions. Hence, the theory implies that the investment and financing
choices can be completely disconnected from each other and justifies our
limited definition of the firm for the time being.
It is clear from Figure 1.1 that the specifics of the utility function of
the firm will impact upon the firm’s physical investment policy. The
implication of this is that the shareholders of a firm (i.e. those whose
utility function matters in forming optimal investment policy) must dictate
to the managers of the firm the point to which it invests. However, until
now we have ignored the fact that the firm has an alternative method for
investment (i.e. using the capital market).
Figure 1.1
The financial investment allows firms to borrow or lend unlimited
amounts at rate r. Assuming that the firm undertakes no physical
investment, we can define the firm’s consumption opportunities quite
easily. Assume the firm neither borrows nor lends. This implies that
current consumption (c0) must be identically m, whereas period 1
consumption (c1) is zero. Alternatively, the firm could lend all of its funds.
This leads to c0 being zero and c1 = (1 + r) m. The relationship between
period 0 and period 1 consumption is therefore:
c1 = (1 + r)(m – c0). (1.1)
This implies that the curve which represents capital market investments
is a straight line with slope –(1 + r). This curve is labeled CML on
Figure 1.2. Again, we have on Figure 1.2 plotted the optimal financial
investments for two different sets of preferences (assuming that no
physical investment is undertaken).
Figure 1.2
11
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Figure 1.3
12
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
where Π(I0) is the date 1 income from the firm’s physical investment.
Maximising this is equivalent to the following maximisation problem:
The prior objective is the NPV rule for project appraisal. It says that an
optimal physical investment policy maximises the difference between
investment proceeds divided by one plus the interest rate and the
investment cost. Here, the term ‘optimal’ is being defined as that which
leads to maximisation of shareholder utility. We will discuss the NPV rule
more fully (and for cases involving more than one time period) later in
this chapter.
The assumption of perfect capital markets is vital for our Fisher separation
results to hold. We have assumed that borrowing and lending occur at the
same rate and are unrestricted in amount and that there are no transaction
costs associated with the use of the capital market. However, in practical
situations, these conditions are unlikely to be met. A particular example
is given in Figure 1.4. Here we have assumed that the rate at which
borrowing occurs is greater than the rate of interest paid on lending (as
the real world would dictate). Figure 1.3 shows that there are now two
points at which the capital market lines and the production opportunities
frontier are tangential. This then implies that agents with different
preferences will choose differing physical investment decisions and,
therefore, Fisher separation breaks down.
Figure 1.4
13
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
such that:
(1.3)
14
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
You can see the present and future value concepts pictured in Figure 1.2.
If you recall, Figure 1.2 just plots the CML for a given level of initial funds
(m) assuming no funds are to be received in the future. The future value
of this amount of money is simply the vertical intercept of the CML (i.e.
m(1+r)), and obviously the present value of m(1+r) is just m.
The present and future value concepts are straightforwardly extended
to cover more than one period. Assume an annual compound interest rate
of r. The present value of $100 to be received in k year’s time is:
(1.4)
whereas the future value of $100 received today and evaluated k years
hence is:
FVK (100) = 100(1 + r)K (1.5)
Activity
Below, there are a few applications of the present and future value concepts. You should
attempt to verify that you can replicate the calculations.
Assume a compound borrowing and lending rate of 10 per cent annually.
a. The present value of $2,000 to be received in three years’ time is $1,502.63.
b. The present value of $500 to be received in five years’ time is $310.46.
c. The future value of $6,000 evaluated four years hence is $8,784.60.
d. The future value of $250 evaluated 10 years hence is $648.44.
Note that the cash flows to the project can be positive and negative,
implying that the notation employed is flexible enough to embody both
cash inflows and outflows after initiation.
Once we have calculated the NPV, what should we do? Clearly, if the NPV
is positive, it implies that the present value of receipts exceeds the present
value of payments. Hence, the project generates revenues that outweigh its
costs and should therefore be accepted. If the NPV is negative the project
should be rejected, and if it is zero the firm will be indifferent between
accepting and rejecting the project.
15
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Example
Consider a manufacturing firm, which is contemplating the purchase of a new piece of
plant. The rate of interest relevant to the firm is 10 per cent. The purchase price is £1,000.
If purchased, the machine will last for three years and in each year generate extra revenue
equivalent to £750. The resale value of the machine at the end of its lifetime is zero. The
NPV of this project is:
Activity
Assume an interest rate of 5 per cent. Compute the NPV of each of the following projects,
and state whether each project should be accepted or not.
• Project A has an immediate cost of $5,000, generates $1,000 for each of the next six
years and zero thereafter.
• Project B costs £1,000 immediately, generates cash flows of £600 in year 1,
£300 in year 2 and £300 in year 3.
• Project C costs ¥10,000 and generates ¥6,000 in year 1. Over the following years, the
cash flows decline by ¥2,000 each year, until the cash flow reaches zero.
• Project D costs £1,500 immediately. In year 1 it generates £1,000. In year 2 there is a
further cost of £2,000. In years 3, 4 and 5 the project generates revenues of £1,500
per annum.
16
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
cost of capital. The firm can raise funds via equity issues and debt issues,
and it is likely that the costs of these two types of funds will differ. Later
on in this chapter and in those that follow, we will present techniques by
which the firm can compute the overall cost of capital for its enterprise.
17
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
where Ci is the project cash flow in year i, and I is the initial (i.e. year 0)
investment outlay. Comparison of equation 1.7 with 1.6 shows that the
project IRR is the discount rate that would set the project NPV to zero.
Once the IRR has been calculated, the project is evaluated by comparing
the IRR to a predetermined required rate of return known as a hurdle
rate. If the IRR exceeds the hurdle rate, then the project is acceptable,
and if the IRR is less than the hurdle rate it should be rejected. A graphical
analysis of this is presented in Figure 1.5, which plots project NPV against
the rate of return used in NPV calculation. If r* is the hurdle rate used
in project evaluation, then the project represented by the curve on the
figure is acceptable as the IRR exceeds r*. Clearly, if r* is also the correct
required rate of return, which would be used in NPV calculations, then
application of the IRR and NPV rules to assessment of the project in Figure
1.5 gives identical results (as at rate r* the NPV exceeds zero).
Figure 1.5
Calculation of the IRR need not be straightforward. Rearranging equation
1.7 shows us that the IRR is a solution to a kth order polynomial in r.
In general, the solution must be found by some iterative process, for
example, a (progressively finer) grid search method. This also points to
a first weakness of the IRR approach; as the solution to a polynomial,
the IRR may not be unique. Several different rates of return might satisfy
equation 1.7; in this case, which one should be used as the IRR? Figure 1.6
gives a graphical example of this case.
18
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
Figure 1.6
The graphical approach can also be used to illustrate another weakness
of the IRR rule. Consider a firm that is faced with a choice between two
mutually exclusive investment projects (A and B). The locus of NPV-rate of
return pairings for each of these projects is given on Figure 1.7.
The first thing to note from the figure is that the IRR of project A exceeds
that of B. Also, both IRRs exceed the hurdle rate, r*. Hence, both projects
are acceptable but, using the IRR rule, one would choose project A as
its IRR is greatest. However, if we assume that the hurdle rate is the
true opportunity cost of capital (which should be employed in an NPV
calculation), then Figure 1.7 indicates that the NPV of project B exceeds
that of project A. Hence, in the evaluation of mutually exclusive projects,
use of the IRR rule may lead to choices that do not maximise expected
shareholder wealth.
Figure 1.7
19
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Example
Below are the equity values, debt values, and earnings (in billions) for several large US
retailers. Additionally provided is earnings growth for the past 10 years.
Walmart’s (WMT’s) equity value is excluded as this is the quantity we wish to estimate.
We can first calculate the market value of equity to earnings ratio for the average firm
in the industry (excluding Walmart), this is: [(17.48/1.1) + (24.08/1.1) + (82.08/6.01) +
(50.14/2.58)]/4 = 17.72
We now multiply this number by Walmart’s earnings to get Walmart’s equity value
estimate: 17.72*11.88=210.49. Walmart’s actual equity value was $192.48 billion.
that look otherwise similar may have very different value to earnings
ratios. We will learn how to adjust the multiples method for the effects of
leverage later.
The multiples method allows us to check whether the value of a
conglomerate is equal to the sum of its parts. To estimate the value of
each business division of a conglomerate we can calculate each division’s
earnings and multiply it by the average value to earnings multiple of stand
alone firms in the same sector. Adding up the value of all divisions gives
us an estimated value for the conglomerate, this estimate is on average
12 per cent greater than the traded value of the conglomerate. This is
called the conglomerate discount. The reasons for the conglomerate
discount are not fully understood. It is possible that conglomerates are
a less efficient form of organisation due to inefficient capital markets. It
is also possible that the multiples method is inappropriate here because
single segment firms are too different from divisions of a conglomerate
operating in the same industry.
The strength of the multiples approach is that it incorporates a lot of
information in a simple way. It does not require assumptions on the
discount rate and growth rate (as is necessary with the NPV approach)
but just uses the consensus estimates from the market. A weakness is
the assumption that the comparable companies are truly similar to the
company one is trying to value; there is no simple way of incorporating
company specific information. However, its strength is also its biggest
weakness. By using market information, we are assuming that the market
is always correct. This approach would lead to the biggest mistakes
in times of biggest money making opportunities: when the market is
overvalued or undervalued.
The lesson of this section is therefore as follows. The most commonly
used alternative project evaluation criteria to the NPV rule can lead to
poor decisions being made under some circumstances. By contrast, NPV
performs well under all circumstances and thus should be employed.
Stocks
Consider holding a common equity share from a given corporation. To
what does this equity share entitle the holder? Aside from issues such as
voting rights, the share simply delivers a stream of future dividends to
the holder. Assume that we are currently at time t, that the corporation is
infinitely long-lived (such that the stream of dividends goes on forever)
and that we denote the dividend to be paid at time t+i by Dt+i. Also
assume that dividends are paid annually. Denoting the required annual
rate of return on this equity share to be re, then a present value argument
would dictate that the share price (P) should be defined by the following
formula:
. (1.8)
The first term in 1.10 is the expected dividend yield on the stock, and the
second is expected dividend growth. Hence, with empirical estimates of
the previous two quantities, we can easily calculate the required rate of
return on any equity share.
Activity
Attempt the following questions:
1. An investor is considering buying a certain equity share. The stock has just paid a
dividend of £0.50, and both the investor and the market expect the future dividend to
be precisely at this level forever. The required rate of return on similar equities is 8 per
cent. What price should the investor be prepared to pay for a single equity share?
2. A stock has just paid a dividend of $0.25. Dividends are expected to grow at
a constant annual rate of 5 per cent. The required rate of return on the share
is 10 per cent. Calculate the price of the stock.
3. A single share of XYZ Corporation is priced at $25. Dividends are expected
to grow at a rate of 8 per cent, and the dividend just paid was $0.50. What is
the required rate of return on the stock?
Bonds
In principle, bonds are just as easy to value.
• A discount or zero coupon bond is an instrument that promises
to pay the bearer a given sum (known as the principal) at the end
of the instrument’s lifetime. For example, a simple five-year discount
bond might pay the bearer $1,000 after five years have elapsed.
• Slightly more complex instruments are coupon bonds. These not
only repay the principal at the end of the term but in the interim
entitle the bearer to coupon payments that are a specified percentage
of the principal. Assuming annual coupon payments, a three-year bond
with principal of £100 and coupon rate of 8 per cent will give annual
payments of £8, £8 and £108 in years 1, 2 and 3. 4
In our notation a coupon
In more general terms, assuming the coupon rate is c, the principal is P rate of 12 per cent, for
and the required annual rate of return on this type of bond is rb, the price example, implies that
c = 0.12; the discount
of the bond can be written as:4
rate used here, rb , is
called the yield to maturity
of the bond.
22
Chapter 1: Present value calculations and the valuation of physical investment projects
. (1.11)
Activity
Using the previous formula, value a seven-year bond with principal $1,000, annual
coupon rate of 5 per cent and required annual rate of return of 12 per cent.
(Hint: the use of a set of annuity tables might help.)
Key terms
capital market line (CML)
consumption
Fisher separation theorem
Gordon growth model
indifference curve
internal rate of return (IRR) criterion
investment policy
net present value (NPV) rule
payback rule
production opportunity frontier (POF)
production possibility frontier (PPF)
time value of money
utility function
23
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
24
Chapter 2: Real options
Learning objectives
At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain what real options are
• explain why real options are important in project valuation
• explain and calculate the source of option value
• explain three types of real options: options to abandon, to expand, and
to wait.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 10.4 (Real Options and Decision
Trees) and 22 (Real Options).
Further reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 20 (Understanding Options) and 21
(Valuing Options).
Introduction
In Chapter 1 we examined the use of present-value techniques in the
evaluation of investment projects. A key assumption is that if managers
decide to carry out a project, they never revise it subsequently. Clearly,
this is not realistic. Managers may terminate the project early if things
go wrong or may follow up with a new investment, if a trial is successful.
Analogously, movie directors may decide to film a sequel of a movie if the
original one performs well, but may decide not to if the first part performs
poorly.
In finance, we define real option as the right but not the obligation to
modify the project in the future. Real options are valuable if the future
is random, since they give us the flexibility to undertake projects only
when it is beneficial to do so. This flexibility can be in the form of an
opportunity to make more money or an opportunity to avoid losses. This
‘cherry-picking’ feature of real options is the main source of their value.
Note that in case of deterministic future, the flexibility provided by real
options, is meaningless. When there is no randomness, one can optimise
all future actions (what, when or how much to invest) upfront and simply
not deviate from this plan. Hence, there is no need for real options. In real
life, however, the future is non-deterministic in most cases and real options
are valuable.
25
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
In this chapter, we will consider decision trees – the key element to assess
real options. We will explore the source of real option value and analyse
whether it is optimal to exercise the option early.
Then we will go over the three main types of real options: option to
abandon, option to expand and option to wait.
Test Success
Invest $200,000 Pursue project
NPV=$2million
Failure
Stop project
Manager
Don’t test has a NPV=0
choice
NPV=0
In addition to this market risk, the cash flow in each year can be high,
medium or low in each market type. Table 2.1 summarises the probabilities
of each market type and the cash flow outcomes.
10
NPV
Berkeley
= − 50 + ∑ 11
(1 + 0.105) t
= 16.2
t=1
10
NPV
Cleveland
= − 50 + ∑ 6
(1 + 0.105) t
= −13.9
t=1
Hence, the unconditional NPV at year 0 is:
0.8*NPVB + 0.2*NPVC = 0.8*16.2 + 0.2*(–13.9) = 10.1
The NPV is positive, so we should build the coffee shop. But can we do
better? Yes, if we could hire a marketing research firm to learn the market
type before investing, in Year –1. The new timeline is shown in Figure 2.3:
Old Timeline
Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 10 CF
Year -1
Market Research Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF Year 10 CF
Figure 2.3: Coffee shop: time line with the market research.
27
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
If the research says that the market is Berkeley-type, we build the coffee
shop as the NPV is positive. On the other hand, if the market is Cleveland,
we withdraw as the NPV is negative. Thus, the new information creates
real option – we have the right but not the obligation to build the coffee
shop. The market research allows us to avoid losses in case of a Cleveland-
type market. Figure 2.4 depicts the decision tree.
Build
Berkeley
~Build
0.8
0.2 Build
Cleveland
~Build
Figure 2.4: Coffee shop: decision tree with the market research.
Let us now find out the value of the project with the market research. The
NPV at year –1 is:
Now, instead of –13.9 (NPVC), we simply do not build the coffee shop and
have a cash flow of 0 in the case of a Cleveland-type market. We discount
at the risk-free rate, because from year –1 to year 0, we just hold cash (no
risk). The project becomes more valuable with the real option: the NPV
without research at year –1 is 10.1/1.021 = 9.9 < 12.7.
How much are we ready to pay for the market research? We would be
willing to pay up to the additional benefit that we obtain due to the
research: 12.7 – 9.9 = £2.8,000. This is the first view of the source of option
value: the difference between the NPV with and without the real option.
An alternative view of the option value is to think of it as the marginal
effect of change in action. How does the research change our investment
decision? Without the option value, we cannot avoid losses in case of
Cleveland-type market. However, with the option to withdraw from the
project, we can avoid the negative NPV of building the shop. The NPV
of savings evaluated at year –1 is 0.2*(0 – 13.9)/1.021 = £2.8,000. This is
exactly the same as the previous figure!
Until now, we have assumed that we can only start the project at year 0,
even without research. In reality, however, market research takes time
(say one year, in this example) and without research, the project starts
immediately. The question is therefore, should we wait (start at year 0) or
should we start immediately (at year –1) without research? Recall option
theory:
• early exercise is never optimal for a US call option on a non-dividend
paying stock
• but early exercise may be optimal for a dividend paying stock.
28
Chapter 2: Real options
Year -1
Market Research Year 1 CF Year 2 CF ... Year 9 CF
Year 0 Investment
-50K
Year -1 Investment
-50K
Figure 2.5: Coffee shop: timeline with the market research and waiting.
As our lease runs for 10 years, we give up one year of cash flow by
waiting. Let us re-calculate the NPV with market research:
9
PV
Berkeley
= − 50 + ∑ 11
(1 + 0.105)t
= 12.1
t=1
Activities
1. Which of the following examples are applications of real options:
I) An investment in the IT business
II) The valuation of an option to purchase additional handset units for resale
III) The option to develop a new drug
IV) The decision to abandon a test facility
Select one:
a. I, II, III and IV
b. I, II, and III only
c. I only
d. I and II only
29
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Option to abandon
There are two main subcategories of this option: temporary abandonment
and permanent abandonment. To understand the temporary abandonment
option, consider the following example.
30
Chapter 2: Real options
317
0.5
264
0.5
0.5 238
220
0.5 238
0.5
198
0.5
178
Figure 2.6: Gold mine – gold price dynamics.
Let us first calculate the plain NPV without any real options. First, let us
find the expected price of gold in the first and the second period:
E0 [P1Gold] = 0.5*264 + 0.5*198 = 231
E0 [P2Gold] = 0.25*317 + 0.5 * 238 + 0.25*178 = 242.75
Then, the NPV is:
50 (231−230) 50 ( 242.75 − 230)
NVGold mine = 50(220 − 230) + + = 126
1.05 1 .05
2
The cash flows are calculated as the price of gold less the cost multiplied
with the amount produced.
4350
= (317 − 230)(50)
0.5
1700
0.5
0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50)
−500
0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50)
0.5
−1600
0.5
−2600 = (178 − 230)(50)
31
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
4350
= (317 − 230)(50)
0.5
1700
0.5
0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50)
0
0.5 400 = (238 − 230)(50)
0.5
0
0.5
0
Figure 2.8: Gold mine cash flows with abandonment option.
With 0.5*0.5 = 0.25 probability, the price continues to rise and the cash
flow is 1,700 in the first period, 4,350 in the second period. Analogously,
with 0.25 probability, the price goes ‘up and down’ and the cash flow is
1,700 in the first period, 400 in the second period. Using the same logic
for ‘down and up’ and ‘down and down’, the final NPV is:
[ [
1700 4350 [ 1700 400 [
NVGold mine = 0 + 0.25 + + 0.25 1 + 0.05 + +
1 + 0.05 (1 + 0.05)2 (1 + 0.05)2
[
+ 0.25 0 +
400
[ = 1978 > 126
(1 + 0.05)2
With the abandonment option, the project is much more valuable because
we can avoid the losses in case the price of gold is low. What is the source
of the option value? Just like in the coffee shop example, there are two
ways to calculate it. We can get it either as the difference between the two
NPVs (1978 – 126 = 1852), or, alternatively, as the NPV of the negative cash
flows that is saved by the abandonment option, which also gives 1,852.
Now let us consider permanent abandonment. Consider the following
example. Suppose we have set up our own company. Now we receive a
nonretractable offer from an outside investor, to buy our company for
$150 million at or before year 1. The company’s cash flow projection is
illustrated in Figure 2.9. The discount rate is 10 per cent. The questions we
need to answer are:
1. what is the value of the offer?
2. when should we abandon the company for good?
100 (.6)
90(.4)
0
70(.6)
50 (.4)
40(.4)
32
Chapter 2: Real options
100 (.6)
90(.4)
0
150 (.4)
Option to expand
As outlined at the beginning of this section, this option gives us the right
to expand an existing project if it turns out to be profitable. In that case,
we would be willing to invest more money in it.
33
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
to purchase a Turboprop plane for $550,000 that will generate the following
cash flows (see Figure 2.11).
960 (.8)
+150(.6)
220(.2)
-550
930(.4)
+30(.4)
140(.6)
Figure 2.11: Executive flying business – Turboprop plane.
Let us find the NPV of the Turboprop plane:
.6(150) + .4 (30) .6[.8(960) + .2(220)] + .4[.4(930) + .6(140)]
NPV = − 550 + + = 96.12
1.10 1.102
The project is positive NPV. But can we do better? Suppose we have another
option: purchase a Piston-engine (smaller) plane for $250,000 today and
another for $150,000 if demand is high. The latter has an implicit option to
expand if demand is high. The cash flows are depicted in Figure 2.12.
800(.8)
-150
{
100(.2)
+100(.6) or
410(.8)
0
180(.2)
-250
220(.4)
+50(.4)
100(.6)
Figure 2.12: Executive flying business – Piston engine.
First, let us find out whether we should buy a second plane when demand is
high. The upper node on Figure 2.12 shows the cash flows if we purchase the
second plane:
.8 * 800 + .2 * 100
− 150 = 450.
1.1
.8 * 410 + .2 * 180
This is greater than the cash flow without buying it: 450 > 1.1
so we decide to expand by purchasing a second Piston-engine plane. Then
the NPV of the resulting Piston-engine strategy is:
.6(−50) + .4(50) .6[.8(800) + .2(100) + .4[.4(220) + .6(100)]
NPV = − 250 + + = 117.11
1.10 1.102
As we see from this example, staged implementation is usually better:
NPVPISTON = $117,000,
NPVTURBO = $96,000. What is the source of option value? Suppose we ignore
the option to expand, then
NPVPISTON/NE = $52,000.
Hence, we can calculate the value of the option to expand as the difference
between the two NPVs, analogously to before: 117,000 – 52,000 = $65,000.
Alternatively, we can calculate it again as the present value of the marginal
changes. The option value comes from the ability to invest $150,000 for a
34
Chapter 2: Real options
second Piston plane and get incremental cash flow of 800 – 410 = 390 with
probability 0.8, and of 100 –180= –80 with probability 0.2. This opportunity
exists with probability 0.6. Hence, the present value of this investment is
[(390*0.8 – 80*0.2)/1.1 – 150]*0.6/1.1 = $65,000. This is again the same as
the previous option value.
Option to wait
As outlined at the beginning, this option gives us the flexibility to delay
investment. Even when the project currently has a positive NPV, it may be
more valuable if we wait for a better timing. Recall the stock option: you
can exercise now and pocket profits (if any) or you have the option to
exercise later, hoping for even larger profit. We can decompose the option
value into intrinsic value and time premium: option value = intrinsic
value + time premium. The intrinsic value is the profit if you exercise now.
For example, for a call option, it is max(Stock Price – Strike Price,0). The
time premium is the value of being able to wait (shown in Figure 2.13).
The black curve is the intrinsic value, and the gap between the dotted
and black curves is the value of the option to wait (the time premium).
Essentially, the time premium is the additional benefit of the stock option
that gives us the flexibility to exercise with larger profits in the future.
Option
Price
Intrinsic
Option value
Value
Time Premium
Stock Price
Harvest year 0 1 2 3 4 5
Net FV ($1000s) 50 64.4 77.5 89.4 100 109.4
% change in value 28.8 20.3 15.4 11.9 9.4
Table 2.2: Tree harvest: future values.
35
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Harvest year 0 1 2 3 4 5
NPV ($1000s) 50 58.5 64.0 67.2 68.3 67.9
Table 2.3: Tree harvest: NPVs.
Hence, it is optimal to harvest in year 4 (highest NPV).
Activities
4. Are the following statements true or false?
a. The option to expand increases NPV
b. High abandonment value decreases NPV
c. If a project has positive NPV, the firm should always invest immediately
5. An abandonment option, in effect (select one):
a. Limits the flexibility of management’s decision-making.
b. Applies only to new projects.
c. Limits the profit potential of a proposed project.
d. Limits the downside risk of an investment project.
Key terms
Decision tree
Early exercise
Option to abandon
Option to expand
Option to wait
Option value
36
Chapter 2: Real options
37
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
38
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
Learning objectives
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• outline the main features of risky debt and equity
• derive and discuss the Modigliani–Miller theorem
• analyse the impact of taxes on the Modigliani–Miller propositions.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 19 (How Much Should a Firm
Borrow?).
Further reading
Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading,
MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 15.
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 14 (How Taxes Affect Financing Choices)
and 16 (Bankruptcy Costs and Debt Holder-Equity Holder Conflicts).
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the
theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp.261–97.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a
correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp.433–43.
Warner, J. ‘Bankruptcy costs: some evidence’, Journal of Finance 32(2) 1977,
pp.337–47.
Overview
In the preceding chapters of this guide we studied capital budget – the
choice of investment projects assuming the firm has required capital
to implement these projects. In particular, we have considered how a
manager should evaluate projects given projected future cash flows and
possible future actions that the manager may take.
Thus far, however, we have said nothing about how the firm can raise the
required investment capital, typically the mix of securities actually issued
by corporations. Should firms aim to use a large proportion of debt in
their financing or, conversely, should they employ equity financing in the
main? In this chapter and the next we examine the firm’s decision over
which types of claim to issue. The most important result we will find is
that, under a certain set of assumptions, the firm is indifferent about the
39
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
mix of debt and equity that it uses in its financing. This result is the first
Modigliani–Miller theorem (MM1). We go on to explore deviations
from the MM1 assumptions and how this affects the debt–equity choice
through the introduction of taxation effects, costly bankruptcy and
information asymmetries.
B [Xt , B] –
0 B Xt
40
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
The holders of corporate equity receive the residual cash flow accruing to
the firm after payments to debt-holders. However, despite having a claim
that is junior to that of debt-holders, equity-holders elect the board of a
firm and have voting rights over corporate activities and are hence the true
owners of the corporation. Equity also comes in many forms, but we will
focus on the characteristics of common stock.1 1
Other types of equity
include preferred stock
Stock-holders receive cash income in the form of dividend payments. and warrants.
These payments, unlike payments to service debt, are not deductible from
corporation tax obligations. Given the residual nature of the equity claim,
the payoff to equity is as given in Figure 3.2.
Payoff
[Xt – B, 0]+
0 B Xt
Figure 3.2: Equity holders payoff.
When the firm’s cash flow (X) is at or less than the face value of debt (B),
equity-holders receive nothing. However, they receive every dollar of cash
flow greater than B. This gives the kinked payoff function shown in Figure
6.2, which (anticipating future developments) is of precisely the same
form as that of a European call option.
41
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
42
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
L now chooses to repurchase half of its equity (costing E/2) and funds
the repurchase with the issue of new debt. Hence, the face value of debt
outstanding becomes B1 = B + E/2. Assuming that none of our investor’s
equity was repurchased, their payoff would be 2α(X – B1(1 + rd)) after the
repurchase. This is obviously different to that prior to the capital structure
change.
However, our investor can restore their original payoff profile using the
following strategy. Sell one-half of their equity stake and use the proceeds to
buy debt. The payoff from the new position is α(X – B1(1 + rd)) + α(1 + rd)E/2
= α(X – B(1 + rd)). Hence our investor can, without cost, undo any change
the firm makes in its capital structure. This implies that investors will be
indifferent to such changes, and hence the valuation of a firm will not
depend on the specific debt–equity ratio it chooses (i.e. the MM irrelevance
proposition is valid).
Example
Consider an entrepreneur with a project which requires an initial investment of $100m
and which will have perpetual cash flows of $20m forever or $5m forever with equal
probability. Assume that all investors are risk neutral and require a 10 per cent expected
rate of return. We can show that the entrepreneur is indifferent between raising $100m
with debt, equity, or a mix of debt and equity.
• Debt: the entrepreneur must promise investors a coupon such that in expectations
they receive interest of 100*.1 = $10m every year. Since in the bad state of the
world investors will receive no more than $5m, it must be the case that .5*c + .5*5
= 10 and c = 15. The entrepreneur will receive the remainder: 0 in the bad state of
the world and 20 – 15 = 5 in the good state of the world. In expectation, the present
value of this is .5*5/.1 = $25m.
• Equity: the entrepreneur must promise investors a fraction α of future equity
payouts. In expectation, outside equity investors will receive α*(.5*5 + .5*20) =
12.5α each year. The present value of this is 12.5α/.1 = 125α. This must equal to the
amount they put in: 100 = 125α and α = 80 per cent. The entrepreneur receives the
remainder of the equity, (1 – α)*12.5 = $2.5m every year. The present value of this
is $25m.
• Mix: the entrepreneur raises $50m through debt. They must promise investors a
coupon such that in expectations they receive interest of 50*.1 = $5m every year.
Since even in the bad state of the world the firm can pay $5m, they promise them a
coupon of $5m. The total equity payout is the remainder: 0 in the bad state of the
world and 20 – 5 = $15m in the good state of the world; this is equal to .5*15 =
$7.5m in expectation. The entrepreneur promises equity investors a fraction α of
future equity payouts. In expectation outside equity investors will receive 7.5α, per
year, or 7.5α/.1 = 75α in present value. This must equal to the $50m they have
contributed, resulting in α = 66.7 per cent. The entrepreneur is left with (1 – α)*75
= $25m.
The entrepreneur is indifferent to the choice of capital structure because capital structure
does not affect total cash flows produced by the firm.
calculation of a firm’s corporation tax bill, and similarly investors are taxed
differentially on their income from interest and from capital gains. Hence,
the choice of firm capital structure will affect the after-tax stream of
payments to all stakeholders and hence change the value of the firm.
To start, consider a world in which investors are not taxed at all on their
personal incomes. However, firm profits are taxed. Interest payments to
debt, however, are made prior to the calculation of the corporation tax
bill, whereas dividend payments must be paid out of after-tax income.
As suggested above, the fact that debt service payments are made out of
pre-tax cash flow and payments to equity out of post-tax cash flow will
cause the breakdown of the irrelevance proposition. Debt is now a more
favourable security to issue than equity.
To illustrate, consider an infinitely lived, levered firm. Assume that the
firm earns net cash flow Xt in period t, and that interest of rdB must be paid
every period. Finally, assume that the probability of defaulting on the debt
is always zero.3 In period t, the following funds are paid to investors in the 3
For this to hold we
firm: must have Xt > rd B in
every period t.
Ct = rd B + (1 – τc )(Xt – rdB) = (1 – τc) Xt + τcrd B, (3.1)
where τc is the corporation tax rate. The first term on the right-hand side
of equation 3.1 is precisely the payment made by an unlevered firm with
cash flow Xt in period t. The second term is the gain made by the levered
firm in saving on its corporation tax bill through using debt in the capital
structure. This is known as the tax shield advantage of debt finance.
As our firm is infinitely lived, its market value is calculated as the present
value of the perpetual stream of payments to investors. Discounting and
adding up the stream of payments represented by the first term on the
right-hand side of equation 3.1 gives us the value of an unlevered firm
(VU), with identical cash flows to our levered firm. Discounting the stream
of payments represented by the second term on the right-hand side of
equation 3.1 gives τcD, where D is the market value of debt. Hence the
value of the levered firm can be written as:
VU = VL + τcD. (3.2)
The value of a firm increases linearly with the market value of its debt
and, as such, firms should aim to have as high a leverage as possible.
Note that, when the corporation tax rate is zero, the MM proposition is
satisfied once more. In the following section, we show how firm valuation
is affected by the introduction of personal taxes on investor income as well
as taxes on corporate profits.
Example
Consider the same entrepreneur as in the previous example but now living in a world
where corporate taxes are 15 per cent. We can show that the entrepreneur wishes to
raise as much money as possible through debt.
• Debt: the coupon payment offered to creditors is c = $15m, exactly as before. The
entrepreneur will receive the remainder, but must pay taxes on it. This is 0 in the bad
state of the world and (20 – 15)*(1 – .15) = 4.25 in the good state of the world. In
expectation the present value of this is .5*4.25/.1 = $21.25m.
• Equity: the entrepreneur must promise investors a fraction α of future equity
payouts. In expectation, outside equity investors will receive α*(.5*5 + .5*20)
(1 – .85) = 10.625α each year. The present value of this is 10.625α/.1=106.25α.
This must equal to the amount they put in: 100 = 106.25α and α = 94.12%. The
entrepreneur receives the remainder of the equity, (1 – α)*10.625 = $.625m every
year. The present value of this is $6.25m.
44
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
• Mix: the coupon payment offered to creditors is $5m, exactly as above. The total
equity payout is the remainder: 0 in the bad state of the world and (20 – 5)*
(1 – .15) = $12.75m in the good state of the world; this is equal to .5*12.75 =
$6.375m in expectation. The entrepreneur promises equity investors a fraction α of
future equity payouts. In expectation outside equity investors will receive 6.375 α, per
year, or 6.375α/.1 = 63.75α in present value. This must equal to the $50m they have
contributed, resulting in α = 78.43%. The entrepreneur is left with (1 – α)*63.75 =
$13.75m.
The entrepreneur is best off raising money with 100 per cent debt, next best off with a
50/50 mix, and worst off raising money with 100 per cent equity.
Figure 3.3 makes the point quite well. When debt levels become too large,
the costs of financial distress outweigh tax shield gains and imply a finite
optimal leverage ratio. This is in contrast to the case when bankruptcy is
costless as firm value then increases without bound as leverage rises.
Example
Consider the same entrepreneur as in the previous example who still faces a 15 per
cent corporate tax, but now also a drop of 40 per cent in all future income in case of
bankruptcy. We can show that the entrepreneur wishes to raise money through a mix of
45
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
debt and equity because using all equity results in losses of tax shields while too much
debt results in paying bankruptcy costs.
• Debt: the entrepreneur must promise investors a coupon such that in expectations
they receive interest of 100*.1 = $10m every year. In the bad state of the world
the firm is unable to fully pay its creditors and the firm will default. At this point, the
creditors will take over the firm, but 20 per cent is lost to bankruptcy costs so their
annual payout is 5*(1 – .4) = 3. It must be the case that .5*c + .5*3 = 10 and c
= 17. The entrepreneur will receive the remainder, after taxes. This is 0 in the bad
state of the world and (20 – 17)*(1 – .15) = 2.55 in the good state of the world. In
expectation the present value of this is .5*2.55/.1 = $12.75m.
• Equity: the firm cannot be bankrupt since it carries no debt, therefore the solution is
identical to the previous example. The entrepreneur receives $6.25m.
• Mix: note that in the previous example the coupon payment was just low enough
for the firm to not default (in the bad state of the world equity is left with zero but
creditors are fully paid, this is not default). Since no bankruptcy costs are paid, the
solution is identical to the previous example. The entrepreneur receives $13.75m
The entrepreneur is best off raising money by a mix of debt and equity so that they can
take advantage of the tax benefits of debt without having leverage so high as to suffer
bankruptcy costs.
The idea that firm value is maximised by some intermediate leverage which
balances out the tax benefit of debt and the costs of financial distress is
called trade-off theory. However trade-off theory is out of favour because
empirically the costs of bankruptcy appear to be too low to observe the low
amounts of debt firms typically have in their capital structure. The average
leverage ratio for large US firms is 1/3. Estimates of direct costs have been
estimated as 7.5 per cent of market value for small firms by Ang (1982)
but only 2.9 per cent for firms listed on AMEX and NYSE by Weiss (1990).
Indirect costs are likely to be somewhat larger, but are harder to estimate.
Hence, in total, in period t, the firm pays out the following amount:
Ct = (Xt – rD B) (1 – τc)(1 – τe) + rDB(1 – τd). (3.5)
46
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
Note that the first term in equation 3.6 is precisely the cash-flow stream
accruing to equity-holders in an unlevered firm (with identical cash flows to
the levered firm). Hence, discounting this stream of funds at the appropriate
rate yields a present value of VU. The second term is the extra money paid
out, as the firm has debt in its capital structure. This should be discounted
at the after-tax rate of return on debt (i.e. (1 – τd)rD). The sum of the present
values of these two terms is clearly the value of the levered firm. Hence we
can write:
(3.7)
This generalises equation 3.2 to the personal (as well as corporate) taxation
case. Note that equation 3.2 can be retrieved as a special case of equation
3.7, when both personal tax rates are set to zero. The second term on the
right-hand side of 3.7 is the taxation gain of debt. It is increasing in the
corporate tax rate and the tax rate on equity income and decreasing in the
tax rate on debt income. Note that, if (1 – τc)(1 – τe) > (1 – τd), then the tax
advantage is negative, such that the optimal capital structure choice is to be
all equity. If the preceding inequality is reversed, though, the tax advantage
is clearly positive and, as such, optimal capital structure involves a firm
issuing as much debt as possible.
Investors are willing to hold debt as long as, after adjusting for risk
premiums, the return after personal income taxes offered by debt is weakly
higher than the return after personal taxes on equity income offered by
equity, that is, as long as:
If the rate of return offered on debt is lower than rE /(1 – τc), firms have still
incentives to issue more debt as, at this point, it is still profitable to issue
47
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Summary
In this chapter we have presented a fundamental analysis of the capital
structure of a firm. Initially we show that, under the MM assumptions,
capital structure does not affect firm value. We then present relaxations of
the MM assumptions and demonstrate how the MM result is altered. With
the introduction of corporate taxation it becomes clear that firm value is
increasing with the level of debt in the capital structure. Also allowing for
costly bankruptcy, we find that an optimal, finite capital structure may result.
When personal taxes and corporate taxes are included, then the prescriptions
for optimal capital structure are unclear. The optimum depends on the
particular constellation of corporate and personal taxation rates.
In the next chapter we will explore the same relationships but from the
perspective of returns rather than values. In the following chapter we will
examine how conflicts between debt and equity-holder interests will also
imply that the MM result is violated. The analysis presented focuses on
simple cases in which the choices of equity-holders (those who dictate the
firm’s investment policy) are not aligned with the interests of debt-holders.
Key terms
bankruptcy costs
capital structure
corporate taxes
leverage
Miller equilibrium
Modigliani–Miller irrelevance theorem
personal taxes
tax shield of debt
48
Chapter 3: The choice of corporate capital structure
Notes
50
Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition
Learning objectives
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• write down the relationship between debt, equity, the unlevered return
on the firm, and the levered return on the firm
• understand what happens to equity returns, and the weighted average
cost of capital as leverage increases with and without taxes
• draw a link between Modigliani–Miller’s 1st and 2nd propositions
• find the equity beta of a firm by unlevering and relevering the equity
beta of a comparable firm with different capital structure.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 18 (Does Debt Policy Matter?) and
20 (Financing and Valuation).
Further reading
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 13 (Corporate Taxes and the Impact
of Financing on Real Asset Valuation), 14 (How Taxes Affect Financing
Choices) and 15 (How Taxes Affect Dividends and Share Repurchases).
Miles, J. and J. Ezzell ‘The weighed average cost of capital, perfect capital
markets and project life: a clarification’, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis (15) 1980, pp.719–30.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporation finance and the
theory of investment’, American Economic Review (48)3 1958, pp.261–97.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a
correction’, American Economic Review (5)3 1963, pp.433–43.
Overview
In Chapter 1 we learned how to calculate the value of a project by
computing the present value of the project’s future cash flows. This was
done by discounting the cash flows by the appropriate discount rate. In
this chapter we will see how this discount rate changes as the capital
structure of the firm changes.
We will see that as the firm increases its leverage, its equity becomes more
risky. The required rate of return on equity therefore increases. However
the overall return on the firm’s assets (WACC) does not change if there are
51
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
This is the rate of return which should discount the total cash flow coming
from the firm (that is, the cash flows to debt and equity) in order to
calculate the total value of the firm (that is, the value of debt plus equity).
Expression (4.3) is known as the weighted average cost of capital
(WACC). From the expression, it is clear that WACC is the average cost of
equity and cost of debt weighed by their respective composition in the
total asset value.
Now we introduce corporate income tax. If interest payment to the debt
holders is tax deductible, then the cost of borrowing through debt becomes
cheaper, as it lowers the tax bill of the company. Hence, the average cost of
capital should therefore lower.
Consider a firm with pre-tax annual cash flows Xt. Its value today is V0
and its value next year, after X1 has been paid out, is V1. If this firm has
outstanding debt with market value B0, then its equity is valued E0=V0–
B0. Suppose that the appropriate returns on debt and equity are rd and re
respectively.
52 Recall from the previous chapter that if this firm has perpetual outstanding
debt with face value B then rdB will be distributed to the creditors in the
Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition
form of a dividend, and the rest (Xt – rdB)(1 – τC) will be distributed to
equity holders after corporate taxes. Define the free cash flow (FCF) as the
after-tax cash flow available to be distributed by a similar but all equity
firm. In this case, the firm’s FCF each year is Xt(1 – τC). Let us calculate the
discount rate r, which would make the discounted present value of the FCF
equal to V0, the combined value of the debt and equity.
By definition of a return:
V0 = [Xt(1 – τc) + V1]/(1 + r). (4.4)
which can be rewritten as:
r = (Xt(1 – τc) + V1 – V0)/V0. (4.5)
We wish to solve for the r in equation 4.5 as a function of the return on
debt, return on equity, and the tax rate.
Note that the expected increase in value between years 0 and 1 is:
(Xt – rdB0) (1 – τc) + rdB0+ V1 – V0 = [X1(1 – τc) + V1 – V0] + τcrdB0 (4.6)
where the first term is the payment to equity holders, the second term is the
payment to creditors, and the third term is the value of all assets remaining
in the firm. The formulation on the right of 4.6 merely rearranges terms on
the left hand side. Note that this increase in expected value must be split
between the return to equity holders and the return to debt holders:
Finally, substitute equation 4.5 for the left hand side, and note that
V0 = E0 + B0 to find the WACC:
WACC = r = ( E E+ B
0
0
0
( re + (1 – τC)
( E B+ B
0
0
0
( rd (4.8)
Thus, the WACC is the discount rate at which the FCF needs to be
discounted in order to calculate the firm’s value. The FCF is the cash flow
to a hypothetical all equity firm, while the WACC accounts for the firm’s
leverage.
When corporate taxes are zero, equation 4.8 collapses to 4.3, however in
the presence of taxes, WACC decreases as leverage increases. The intuition
is similar to the Modigliani–Miller 1st proposition. For every extra dollar of
debt in its capital structure, the firm receives τcrd back as a tax refund. This
tax refund is a riskless payment, therefore the firm appears less risky and
the average rate of return it pays to raise money decreases. Because of the
refund, effectively, the firm is paying (1 – τc)rd instead of rd to raise money
through debt.
Example
Walmart has an expected equity return of re = 8.5%. Walmart has AA debt
which matures in 2023 and has a yield of 5.9%. Walmart’s tax rate is 35%
so Walmart is paying (1 – τc )rd =(1 – 0.35) * 5.9 = 3.835% to raise money
through debt.
Walmart’s outstanding debt has a value of $22.7 billion. Walmart has 4,269
million shares outstanding with a price of $55.69 per share, implying an
equity market capitalization of 4.269 * 55.69 = $237.7 billion. Walmart’s
weight of debt in the capital structure is 22.7/(237.7 + 22.7) = 8.7% and
its weight of equity is 237.7/(237.7 + 22.7) = 91.3%. Walmart’s WACC is
0.087 * 3.835 + .913 * 8.5 = 8.09%.
53
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
where B/E is the debt to equity ratio in the firm’s capital structure, re is
the return on the firm’s equity, rd is the return on the firm’s debt, and ru is
the unlevered return, or the return on a hypothetical firm that is financed
by all equity (or unlevered) but otherwise similar to the firm we are
considering.
As leverage increases, the expected return on equity grows because equity
becomes riskier. Equity is riskier because it is a residual payment, it is paid
last after all other claims (such as debt) have been settled. When leverage
is high, equity is only a small portion of the firm, but must take the brunt
of most of the firm’s losses. This makes the equity of a highly levered firm
very risky.
Let us illustrate this fact by a simple example which shows how higher
leverage can boost earnings per share, increase volatility and expected
return to equity.
Outcomes
A B C D
Operating income ($) 500 1,000 1,500 2,000
Earnings per share 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0
Return on shares (%) 5 10 15 20
Table 4.1: Professor Miller’s firm without leverage.
Column C is the average outcome, i.e. average earnings per share (EPS)
are 1.5 and average return on shares is 15 per cent. Now, assume Professor
Miller raises the leverage to 50 per cent debt at 10 per cent interest:
Data
Number of shares 500
Price per share ($) 10
Market value of shares ($) 5,000
54
Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition
Outcomes
A B C D
Operating income ($) 500 1,000 1,500 2,000
Interest ($) 500 500 500 500
Equity earnings ($) 0 500 1,000 1,500
Earnings per share ($) 0 1 2 3
Return on shares (%) 0 10 20 30
Table 4.2: Professor Miller’s firm with leverage.
Looking at column C of Table 4.2, which is the expected outcome, we
can see that higher leverage increases average EPS and return on shares:
the average EPS are 2, and the average return on shares is 20 per cent.
However, it also increases the variance of returns, thus making returns
also more risky. Figure 4.1 illustrates the result from Tables 4.1 and 4.2
graphically. The dashed line shows the EPS as a function of operating
income for Table 4.1 and the black line for Table 4.1. For the same range
on the x-axis (say, 500 to 1,500), the black graph gives a wider set of
values on the y-axis (0 to 2.5) compared to the dotted one (0.5 to 1.5).
This is evidence of higher variance (risk):
All equity
1.00
Expected
0.50 operating
income
0.00
Operating
500 1000 1500 2000 income, dollars
55
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
the average rate at which the firm raises money, the WACC, is equal to the
rate at which an all equity (or unlevered) firm raises money, ru. The WACC is
independent of capital structure, analogous to the MM 1st proposition in the
absence of taxes. The relationship between equity, debt, WACC and leverage
in the absence of taxes is illustrated graphically in Figure 4.1.
r
rE
rA = WACC
rD
D
E
Figure 4.2: Weighted average cost of capital without tax.
We will now derive a more general version of the MM 2nd proposition, in
the presence of taxes. Consider a firm that lives for one period. It has both
debt and equity in its capital structure and its value is V0 = E0 + B0 today
and V1 = E1 + B1 next period. Also note that from the definition of return,
E1 = (1 + re)E0 and B1 = (1 + rd)B0 as there are no intermediate payments.
This firm will have a cash flow X1 which it will distribute to its debt and
equity holders in period 1. Also consider a similar firm that is all equity
owned. This unlevered firm has value V0U today; for this firm B = 0.
Since next period the cash flows will be distributed first to creditors, and
then to equity-holders (after taxes), we can write the value of the firm as
the value of the total distributions:
V1 = (X1 – B1)(1 – τC) + B1 = X1 (1 – τC) + τCB1 = V1U + τC B1, (4.10)
where the first term is the payout to equity-holders and the second term is
the payout to creditors. The last equality uses the fact that the value of the
unlevered firm next period is just equal to its after-tax cash flows.
From the definitions of debt and equity we know that:
V1 = E1 + B1 = (1 + re)E0 + (1 + rd)B0. (4.11)
Setting equations 7.10 and 7.11 equal to each other and substituting
V1U = (1 + ru)V0U and B1 = (1 + rd)B0 we get the following equation:
Now, we can rearrange the terms of this to solve for the return on equity:
Finally, we can use the fact that V0U = V0 – τCB0 = E0 + B0 – τC B0 (this is just
the present value of equation 4.10) to rewrite this as:
re = ru + (1 – τC)(B0 / E0)(ru – rd). (4.14)
even though extra leverage makes equity more risky for the same
arguments as before, tax shield reduce some of this risk. This can also be
seen by comparing the equity return in Figure 4.2 to that of Figure 4.3
which has the same returns in the presence of taxes.
r
rE
After-tax WACC
(1 – Tc) rD
D
E
Figure 4.3: Weighted average cost of capital with tax.
The MM 2nd proposition gives us a relationship between the unlevered
return on a firm, and the return on the debt and equity of a similar but
levered firm. The WACC is the average rate of return the firm pays to raise
money, it is defined as a function of the returns on debt and equity. We
can combine the MM 2nd proposition (equation 4.14) with the definition
of WACC (equation 4.8) to find the WACC as a function of the unlevered
return on the firm:
WACC = ru(1 – τC (B0 / V0)). (4.15)
Activity
Combine equations 4.14 and 4.8 to derive equation 4.15.
We can split up the risk investors of a firm face into two types of risk. The
first is business risk, this depends on the risk of the firm’s underlying assets
and activities. All similar firms should have similar business risk regardless
of capital structure. The second is financial risk, this is additional risk that
the firm faces due to its choice of capital structure. The return on an
unlevered firm ru is based on the firm’s business risk, since this firm has no
leverage. WACC is the return on the levered firm, this combines business
and financial risk. From equation 4.15, it is evident that without taxes
financial risk is irrelevant. The WACC of any firm is equal to the return on
an unlevered firm, regardless of the amount of leverage. This is analogous
to the 1st proposition of MM: the value of any firm is equal to the value of
an unlevered firm, regardless of the amount of leverage. In the presence of
taxes, the WACC decreases as we add leverage because of additional tax
shields. With more leverage, the firm becomes safer, its borrowing rate
decreases (equation 4.15), and its value increases. The MM 1st and 2nd
propositions are flip sides of the same coin.
Example
Consider two firms with the same unlevered return on asset ru = 4.5 per cent. The
corporate tax rate is 35 per cent.
Firm A has no debt. Current pre-tax earnings are $23 million with no growth prospects.
57
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Firm B has AAA-rated long-term debt with 4 per cent yield to maturity and market value
$50 million. Current pre-tax earnings are $8.75 million with no growth prospects.
What are the WACC, equity return, total firm value, and equity value for each firm?
The FCF of firm A is 23*(1 – .35) = $23.98 million. We use ru = 4.5% as the discount
rate and find an unlevered firm value of VU = 23.98/.045 = $332.2 million.
Since this firm is debt free, its equity value and its total value are the same as the
unlevered value. Again, because this firm is unlevered, its WACC and its equity return are
both equal to ru.
The FCF of firm B is 8.75*(1 – 0.35) = $5.69 million. We use ru = 4.5% as the discount
rate and find an unlevered firm value of VU = 5.69/ 0.045 = $126.4 million.
Using the MM 1st proposition, we can calculate the levered value as the unlevered value
plus the present value of tax shields where the present value of tax shields is given by τcB:
V = 126.4 + 0.35*50 = $143.9 million. The equity value is the total firm value minus
the value of the debt: 143.9 – 50 = $93.9 million.
We can use the MM 2nd proposition (4.14) to calculate the return on equity:
We can now calculate the WACC either through equation 4.8 or 4.15. Both give the same
answer. First using equation 4.8:
WACC = (E/(E + B))re + (1 – τC)(B/ (E + B))rd
By plugging equation 4.16 into equation 4.14 (MM 2nd proposition) and
then rearranging terms, we can rewrite the return on equity as:
re = rf + [βu+ (1 – τC )(B/E)(βu – βd )](rm – rf) (4.19)
58
Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition
Example
Firm A is looking to do an IPO with a debt to value ratio of 0.7. The average equity beta of
similar, publically traded firms is 0.85 and the average debt to value ratio is 0.22. The tax
rate is 35 per cent. What rate of return should we use to discount Firm A’s expected equity
cash flows?
Using equation 4.21 backwards with the capital structure of the comparables, we find
that the unlevered (asset) β of this industry is:
βu = βe/(1 + (1 – τC)(B/E)) = 0.85/(1 + (1 – 0.35)*.22/(1 – 0.22)) = 0.718
Now we can use equation 4.21 forwards, with the target leverage of firm A:
βe = βu(1 + (1 – τC)(B/E)) = 0.718*(1 + (1 – 0.35)* 0.7/(1 – 0.7)) = 1.81
With a 4 per cent historical risk-free rate and a 6 per cent historical market premium, the
required equity return is: 4 + 1.81*6 = 14.86%.
Summary
In this chapter we derived relationships between the return on a firm’s
equity, a firm’s debt and a firm’s total assets. We saw that if there are no
taxes, increasing leverage makes equity riskier and increases expected
returns. However, the return on the firm’s total assets does not change
because more weight is given to the safe debt return. However, in the
presence of taxes, the increase of expected equity returns with leverage
was smaller, due to a tax refund. The return on the firm’s total asset
actually declined with leverage in the presence of taxes, because tax
refunds make the firm safer. This is analogous to firm value rising with
leverage in the presence of taxes, as we saw in the previous chapter.
59
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Key terms
business risk
financial risk
leverage
tax shields
weighted average cost of capital (WACC)
unlevered (asset) return
unlevered β
60
Chapter 4: Leverage, WACC and the Modigliani-Miller 2nd proposition
Year –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 +1 +2
A –11 0 1 2 21 22 23 23
B 5 13 7 4 15 13 3 10
4. Both firms pay out nearly 100 per cent of their after-tax cash flows
to the owner. A has no debt. B has AAA-rated long-term debt with 4
per cent yield to maturity and market value of 50 million. The asset
(unlevered) β for firms in the same industry as A and B is 0.5. The
corporate tax rate is 35 per cent, assume no personal taxes. The
historical risk-free rate is 3 per cent and the historical return on the
stock market is 6 per cent.
a. For each firm calculate the WACC, the firm (enterprise) value, and
the equity value. Give justification for your calculation.
b. What changes to capital structure would you make for firm A?
Firm B?
61
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
62
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
Learning objectives
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• understand the concept of agency costs and governance problems in
general
• discuss the intuition behind the agency costs of debt, equity and free
cash-flows
• calculate the agency cost of debt in stylised settings
• discuss the effects of asymmetric information on capital structure
• explain the intuition behind the pecking order theory of finance.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 13 (Agency Problems, Management
Compensation, and the Measurement of Performance) and 19 (How Much
Should a Firm Borrow?).
Further reading
Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading,
MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 15.
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 16 (Bankruptcy Costs and Debt
Holder – Equity Holder Conflicts), 17 (Capital Structure and Corporate
Strategy), 18 (How Managerial Incentives Affect Financial Decisions) and
19 (The Information Conveyed by Financial Decisions).
Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’,
American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency
costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976,
pp.305–60.
Masulis, R. ‘The impact of capital structure change on firm value: some
estimates’, Journal of Finance 38(1) 1983, pp.107–26.
Miller, M. ‘Debt and taxes’, Journal of Finance 32, 1977, pp.261–75.
Modigliani, F. and M. Miller ‘The cost of capital, corporate finance and the
theory of investment’, American Economic Review 48(3) 1958, pp.261–97.
Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics
5(2) 1977, pp.147–75.
Myers, S. and N. Majluf ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when
firms have information that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial
Economics 13(2) 1984, pp.187–221.
63
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Overview
In Chapter 3 we introduced the capital irrelevance proposition first put
forward by Miller and Modigliani (1958). We also explored cases in which
the capital structure of a firm did matter in its valuation due to relaxations
of the MM assumptions (e.g. the introduction of corporation tax and
bankruptcy costs). In this chapter we will focus on two classes of problem in
which MM1 does not hold. In the first, firms are subject to agency problems
between outside stakeholders and insiders (managers). The second class of
problem allows the possibility that insiders to the firm are better informed
about its quality than the market or potential external investors.
64
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
Jensen and Meckling argue that the agency cost of outside equity is
decreasing in the leverage ratio of the firm (where leverage is the ratio of
debt to equity values). The argument runs as follows: assume that the firm
repurchases some of the equity held by outsiders, funding this with a debt
issue – hence, leverage is increased. Also, the proportion of outstanding
equity held by the manager is now increased. Thus, as his share of the
residual value of the firm is increased, the manager chooses to supply
more effort, leading to increased firm value. Then, as leverage rises,
agency costs of outside equity fall.
Example
In this example we will see that when issuing outside equity, a project’s owner is worse
off because they use too little effort. On the other hand, when using debt, they use
optimal effort.
Consider an entrepreneur with a project that next year pays $20 million with probability
p and $10 million with probability 1 – p. This project requires an initial investment of
$11 million.
The entrepreneur can pick the probability of success p to be any number they want
between 0.25 and 0.75. However, choosing a higher p requires effort e, which the
entrepreneur dislikes. The disutility function of effort is e = k * p, where k = 4. The
required discount rate is zero and everyone is risk neutral. The utility function of the
entrepreneur is U = E[X] – k * p.
Suppose the entrepreneur finances the project with equity by promising a share α of
equity to outside investors in return for paying them the $11 million necessary for the
initial investment.
In that case the expected payoff of the entrepreneur is:
(1 – α)(20p + 10(1 – p)) = (1 – α)(10p + 10)
And the utility of the entrepreneur is:
U = (1 – α)(10p + 10) – k * p = 10(1 – α) + [10(1 – α) – k] * p
Note that to maximise their utility, the entrepreneur will choose p to be as large as
possible if
[10 * (1 – α) – k] > 0.
Suppose outside investors believe that the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.75, then their
expected payoff is:
α(10 * 0.75 + 10) = 17.5α
In order for outside investors to break even, their expected payoff must equal their
investment 17.5α = 11 implying α = 62.9%. However, that would imply that
[10(1 – α) – k] = 3.71 – k = 3.71 – 4 < 0 and the entrepreneur would choose
p = 0.25, therefore cannot be an equilibrium.
Suppose outside investors believe that the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.25, then their
expected payoff is:
α(10 * 0.25 + 10) = 12.5α
In order for outside investors to break even, their expected payoff must equal their
investment 12.5α = 11 implying α = 88%.
Indeed [10(1 – α) – k] = 1.2 – k = 1.2 – 4 < 0, thus the entrepreneur will choose
p = 0.25, consistent with the beliefs of the outside equity investors.
The entrepreneur’s utility with equity financing is:
U = 10(1 – α) + [10(1 – α) – k] * p = 10(1 – 0.88) + [10(1 – 0.88) – 4] * 0.25 =
1.2 – 0.7 = 0.5
65
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Suppose instead that the entrepreneur financed their investment with debt by promising
a face value F to creditors in return for $11 million to cover the initial investment. In this
case, because the payoff of the project in the bad state of the world is below the initial
investment cost, then the company would go bankrupt with probability 1 – p. In the bad
state of the world, the creditors would receive the full $10 million payoff from the project
and the value of the entrepreneur’s equity would be zero. In the good state of the world,
which occurs with probability p, the creditors would receive the face value of the debt F,
and the residual payoff to the entrepreneur would be 20 – F.
The utility of the entrepreneur with debt financing is therefore
U = (1 – p) * 0 + p * (20 – F) – k * p = (20 – F – k) * p
To maximise their utility, the entrepreneur will choose p to be as large as possible as long
as (20 – F – k) > 0.
Suppose that creditors believe that the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.25, then their
expected payoff is:
(1 – p) * 10 + p * F = 7.5 + 0.25F
In order to break even, their expected payoff must equal their initial investment of $11
million, implying F = 14. However, this implies that (20 – F – k) > 0, in which case the
entrepreneur would choose p = 0.75, and therefore this cannot be an equilibrium.
Suppose that creditors believe that the entrepreneur will choose p = 0.75, then their
expected payoff is:
(1 – p) * 10 + p * F = 2.5 + 0.75 * F
In order to break even, creditors’ expected payoff must equal their initial investment of
$11million, implying that F = 11.33. Indeed, (20 – F – k) > 0 if F = 11.33, and the
entrepreneur chooses p = 0.75 consistent with the beliefs of creditors.
The entrepreneur’s utility with debt financing is:
U = (20 – F – k) * p = (20 – 11.33 –4) * 0.75 = 3.5
Note that the utility of the entrepreneur with debt financing is much higher than with
equity financing. In this example the MM proposition did not hold because one type
of security (debt) provided higher utility to the entrepreneur than the other (equity). As
we increase the proportion of debt used to finance the firm, the entrepreneur chose
to exert more effort, which increased the expected value of the project. Increasing
leverage reduced the agency cost of outside equity because it aligned the payoff to the
entrepreneur with their cost of effort. With a fraction α of outside equity, the entrepreneur
only loses (1 – α) of wealth for every dollar of wealth that the project loses when effort
is low.
Activity
First, show that in the above example, if the entrepreneur could commit to using the
optimal amount of effort, then they could get maximum utility even when using equity.
Next, show that in the above example if the entrepreneur is less averse to effort, for
example k = 3, then two possible equilibria can arise in the equity financing case. Thus
market beliefs may play an important role.
66
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
Example
Assume that a firm that is financed by both debt and equity. A manager runs the firm in
the interest of current equity-holders (i.e. the manager sets investment policy in order
to maximise the expected shareholder payoff). The manager is faced with the choice
between two investment projects, A and B. These projects are assumed to have zero cost
and are mutually exclusive. The cash flows to projects A and B are given in Table 5.1.
Table 5.1
Clearly, both projects have positive expected NPV. Project A has the lowest risk and the
higher expected NPV (50), whereas project B is the riskier and its expected NPV is 45.1
1
When we say that
project B is riskier, we
mean that it has higher
cash-flow variance than
We assume that debt-holders have a claim of 50 that must be repaid out of
project A.
the cash flow to the chosen project. Given this debt claim, which project
will the manager choose?
Let us start our analysis with Project A. From the cash flows of the project,
we see that, with a debt obligation of 50, only in state 3 will equity-
holders get any pay-off, this pay-off being 60 – 50=10. This implies that
the expected pay-off from Project A to shareholders is 10*0.25 = 2.5. The
expected pay-off to debt-holders from A is equal to (0.25*40) + (0.5*50)
+ (0.25*50) = 47.5.
Moving on to the analysis of Project B, again equity-holders only get
some cash in state 3 and their expected pay-off is 0.25*(80 – 50) = 7.5.
The pay-off to debt-holders from Project B is (0.25*20) + (0.5*40) +
(0.25*50) = 37.5. Hence, from the equity-holders point of view, Project
B maximises expected pay-off as 7.5>2.5 and, as a result, this will be the
project chosen by the manager. Note that the choice of this project implies
that debt-holders are worse off and firm value lower than in the case
where Project A is chosen.
When the face value of debt is 50, the firm invests in the project with
the lower expected NPV and higher risk, as this project maximises the
expected return to equity. What would happen if the debt repayment
outstanding were 30 instead of 50? In this case the expected payoffs to
equity-holders are 20 from project A and 17.5 from project B. Therefore,
the manager will choose project A. This choice also implies that debt-
holders are happy as project A maximises their expected payoff (they get
30 rather than the 27.5 that they would expect to receive if project B were
chosen). Note that, when the face value of debt is lower, the manager
switches and chooses the low-risk, high-expected-return project. This, in
turn, implies that, when face value of debt is lower, firm value is higher.
67
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Example
In this example we will see that when issuing debt, a project’s owner is worse off because
they choose to take on too much risk. On the other hand, when using outside equity, they
choose the optimal amount of risk.
Consider an entrepreneur with a choice of one of two projects. Project A pays $5
million or $15 million with equal probability. Project B pays 0 or $18 million with equal
probability.
Each project requires an initial investment of $3 million. The entrepreneur will have the
freedom to choose the project after they raise financing.
The required discount rate is zero and everyone is risk neutral. There are no taxes or
bankruptcy costs.
Note that the expected value of project A is 0.5*5 + 0.5*15 = 10 while the expected
value of project B is 0.5*0 + 0.5*18 = 9 so project A is better. Project A is also less
volatile; in this example investors are risk neutral but typically they would prefer less
volatile projects.
Consider debt financing. For any face value of debt F shareholders receive the residual
after creditors have been paid. From project A their expected payout is:
0.5*(5 – F) + 0.5*(15 – F) = 10 – F if F < 5
0.5*0 + 0.5*(15 – F) = 7.5 – 0.5F if 5 < F < 15.
From project B their expected payout is:
0.5*(18 – F) = 9 – 0.5F if F < 18.
Comparing these two equations we can see that project B is preferred by equity-holders
for any F > 2, this can also be seen graphically in Figure 8.1. Project B is preferred
because equity-holders have a limited downside but care very much about the upside.
On the other hand, creditors expected payout from project A is:
F if F < 5
0.5*5 + 0.5*F = 2.5 + 0.5F if 5 < F < 15.
From project B their expected payout is:
0.5*F if F < 18.
Comparing these two equations we can see that project A is preferred by creditors for any
F, this can also be seen graphically in Figure 8.1. Project A is preferred because creditors
have no upside, and care only about limiting losses in the downside.
Since the necessary initial investment is 3, the face value of debt will have to be at least
3. This leads equity-holders to choose project B. Knowing this, creditors will ask for a face
value of debt such that they receive their initial investment back in expectation:
3 = 0.5*F and F = 6.
With this F, the initial entrepreneur’s payout is:
0.5*(18 – 6) = $6 million
Suppose the entrepreneur could credibly commit to choose project A. In that case
creditors would ask for a smaller face value of debt, F = 3, because even in the bad
scenario, project A will be more than enough to repay the initial investment. The payout
to equity-holders would be:
10 – F = $7 million.
The shareholders would be better off if they could ex-ante commit to invest in A because
A has higher NPV. However, as we saw earlier, with F = 3 they are ex-post better off
choosing B. Since the creditors have no reason to trust them, creditors will assume B will
be chosen and ask for F = 6.
68
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
Now consider using outside equity to finance this project. Outside equity-holders
are promised a fraction α of the project and the entrepreneur receives the rest. The
entrepreneur’s payoff from choosing A is:
(1 – α)[0.5*5 + 0.5*15] = (1 – α)*10,
and from choosing B it is:
(1 – α)[0.5*0 + 0.5*18] = (1 – α)*9.
Clearly the entrepreneur always chooses A. Knowing this, outside equity-holder will ask
for α such that their expected payoff 10α is equal to their initial investment of 3. This
implies that α = 30% and the entrepreneur’s share is worth (1 – 0.3)*10 = 7. This is just
as good as the commitment case and better than the debt financing case.
In this example the MM proposition did not hold because one type of security was better
than another. Debt financing caused the entrepreneur to choose a very risky project (risk
shift) because their downside was limited. As a result, creditors asked for a very high
interest rate to protect their investment and the entrepreneur was worse off for this.
Equity financing did not face this problem because the entrepreneur was just receiving
a fixed share of total profits, therefore it was in their interest to maximise total profits
both ex-ante and ex-post. Commitment was a possible substitute to equity, but it may be
difficult to implement in a real world situation.
10
Project A
Shareholder value
Project B
0
0 5 10 15 20 25
F
10
8
Creditor value
6
4
Project A
2
Project B
0
0 5 10 15 20 25
F
Figure 5.1: Payoff to the shareholder and to the creditor.
Jensen and Meckling argue that the agency costs of debt are increasing in
the level of debt outstanding and hence in corporate leverage. Combining
the two agency costs then allows us to argue that an optimal (in the sense
of maximising firm value) capital structure might exist. We contended
that the agency cost of outside equity was decreasing in leverage, whereas
the agency cost of debt increased with leverage. Firm value would be
maximised where total agency costs are minimised, and this leads to the
optimal leverage ratio shown on Figure 5.2.
Cost Total
cost
Cmin
Agency cost
of debt Agency cost
of equity
0 D/E* D/E
69
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Activity
Compute the expected payoff to equity-holders if the required debt repayment is 90. Will
the manager accept or reject the project?
70
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
The preceding intuition can be formalised with the following model, which
is a simplified version of that contained in Ross (1977). Assume a
population of firms, each of which has future cash flow that is uniformly
distributed.2 Firm quality varies, as the upper bound of the cash flow 2
If cash flow is
distribution (call this parameter t) varies across firms (i.e. a high-quality uniformly distributed
firm may have cash flow distributed on [0, t1] and a low-quality firm might on [a, b] it means that
the probability density
have cash flow distributed on [0, t2] where t1 exceeds t2). Managers of firms
of cash flow is constant
know the value of t for their own firms, but the market as a whole does not. from a to b and zero
Managerial utility is increasing in date 0 firm value and date 1 firm value, elsewhere. This implies
that the probability
but is decreasing in the expected cost of bankruptcy. In line with the prior
distribution function of
argument, managers will try to use debt to signal their quality. However, cash flow is F(x)=(x–a)/
non-zero debt levels imply that bankruptcy is possible. Hence, we can (b–a) for x between a
write the managerial optimisation problem as follows: and b.
(5.1)
To compute the optimal level of debt, we compute the first order condition
of 5.2 with respect to B. After rearrangement this yields:
.
(5.3)
Finally, we assume that in equilibrium, the market’s beliefs about firm
quality (based on a firm’s debt level) are correct. Hence, we have the
condition f (B(t)) = 2t where we have also acknowledged the dependence
of the debt level, B, on firm quality through managerial actions.
Differentiating this condition yields:
f’(B)B’(t) = ½. (5.4)
Substituting f’(B) from 5.4 into 5.3 yields the following differential
equation:
. (5.5)
. (5.7)
72
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
. (5.8)
Equation 5.8 gives us the key results from the Ross (1977) model. Debt level
(B) is increasing in firm quality (t). Clearly then, firms with higher debt levels
will have greater date 0 market values and MM1 is violated once more.
In more loose terms, the arguments in Ross (1977) are that debt is a
costly signal (due to the possibility of bankruptcy it entails), and hence its
use implies higher-quality firms. From an empirical standpoint, evidence
that supports this notion can be found in Masulis (1983). This paper
demonstrates that firms which swap debt for equity (hence increasing
leverage) experience positive stock price returns whereas firms swapping
equity for debt experience negative stock returns. The stock price reactions
are interpreted as implying that leverage-increasing transactions are good
news whereas leverage-decreasing transactions are bad news, consistent
with the asymmetric information story.
73
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Valuation
Assets State A (cheap oil) State B (expensive oil)
Assets in place £130m £220m
NPV of the project’s cash flows £10m £40m
The positive NPV project requires an initial investment of K = £600m irrespective of the
state of nature. In order to fund its project, PUI must raise £600m in equity. Assume that
managers maximise the wealth of the existing shareholders and that the states are equally
likely.
a. If managers must issue equity prior to knowing the price of oil, how many shares
should the firm issue and at which price will they sell for?
In each state, the post-issue firm value will be equal to the sum of the value of the
assets in place, the NPV of the project, and the capital (K = $600m) contributed by
the new equity-holders. In state A, the post-issue firm value is thus £740m. In state B,
the post-issue firm value is thus £860m. As both states are equally likely, the expected
post-issue firm value is thus £800m (derived as 50%*£740m + 50%*£860m). The
74
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
fraction of the value of the firm that the new shareholder should be getting is hence
£600m/£800m = 75%. The value of the firm’s equity prior to the share issue is thus
£600m, and the share price is thus £200m/20m = £10. As ex-post, all the shares
have an equal claim, the firm must thus issue 60 million new shares (derived as
£600m/£10).
b. If the manager knew the state of the world before investing, in which state (A or B)
would the manager raise equity and invest in the project? In order to answer this
question, let us assume that the capital can be raised under the terms found in part a)
of this example and that the market does not know the state of the world.
Let us derive the ex-post payoffs to the existing shareholders in each state of nature
when the manager raises equity and invests in the project and when the manager
abstains from raising any equity and does not invest in the project. These payoffs can
be found in the following table:
Summary
In this chapter we have examined theoretical models (and examples),
which imply that firm value does depend on the financing choices it
makes and on capital structure choices in particular. First, we examined
arguments based on agency costs and then looked at a model of
asymmetric information. The empirical evidence for these models is
75
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Key terms
agency costs of debt
agency costs of free cash flows
agency costs of outside equity
asset substitution problem
asymmetric information
capital structure
debt-overhang problem
event study
governance problems
overinvestment
pecking order theory
risk-shifting problem
separation of ownership and control
signalling
underinvestment
76
Chapter 5: Asymmetric information, agency costs and capital structure
77
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
78
Chapter 6: Equity financing
Learning objectives
At the end of this chapter, and having completed the essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain venture capital and equity issuance in the public market
• perform valuation with multiple financing rounds
• explain the calculate ownership structure in initial public offerings and
seasoned equity offerings
• explain and evaluate the winners’ curse problem.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 15 (How Corporations Issue
Securities).
Further reading
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 3 (Equity Financing)
Rock, K. ‘Why new issues are underpriced’, Journal of Financial Economics 15
(1–2) 1986, pp.187–212.
Introduction
Corporate finance is mostly about how firms raise money to conduct
their activities. Broadly speaking, there are two categories of financing
securities: debt and equity. Financing a project through debt results in a
liability to creditors that can take the form of a bank loan, notes payable
or bonds issued to the public. This is an obligation that must be serviced,
independent of the project’s success as debt holders are senior to equity
holders. Debt comes with benefits for the firm (tax shield, less information
sensitive claim), but it might also cause conflicts of interest (recall the
debt overhang problem in Chapter 5), and as a result, some positive NPV
projects might not get financed.
Equity financing is usually in the form of selling company shares to
investors. It is less risky than debt with respect to cash flow commitments,
but causes a dilution of share ownership and control. Moreover, equity
holders are junior claimholders compared to debt holders. In Chapters
3–5, we focused on debt financing. Now we will turn to equity financing.
In this chapter, we will consider three main topics. First, we will see how
start-up companies finance themselves. We will talk about the main stages
of equity financing and their characteristics. Then, we will analyse how
79
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
firms issue new shares. Our main focus will be IPO (initial public offering)
and SEO (seasoned equity offerings). Finally, we will consider one of the
most prominent features in IPO market – underpricing – and one of its
explanations.
80
Chapter 6: Equity financing
for the next financing stage, the VC can cut financing or even withdraw
from the project. This creates strong incentives for entrepreneurs to be
more efficient in order to get to the next financing stage. Essentially,
staged financing creates real options for the VC by providing them with
the flexibility to adjust funding decisions in the future. If the new firms
are unsuccessful, the VC has the option to abandon the project. If the
firms turn out to be successful, the VC has the option to expand profitable
projects by injecting more money.
How does one calculate the ownership structure with multiple rounds of
equity finance? Let us take a simple example. You have just started your
own company (say, a website or a social network) by investing $K. For
simplicity, there were no sunk costs related to setting up the company,
so the company is also worth $K. After some time, you realise you need
new funding to expand the operations, for example to buy new servers
or hardware. You present your business plan to a couple of potential
investors, and one of them, impressed by your presentation, decides to
contribute $L to the company. Now, the firm is worth $K+$L, and your
K
fraction of the firm is s = . After some more time, your website
K+ L
gets even more popular and attracts the attention of a VC. The VC decides
to contribute $X to your startup. After contribution, the startup is worth
$V=$K+$L+$X.
As an original investor (OI), you hold 0 < s < 1 fraction of the pre-
contribution firm. What fraction of the post-contribution company do you
(OI) and the VC own? The VC simply owns $X in something worth $V, so
x
his fraction is VCfrac = . The OI owns a fraction s of whatever is left
v
in the company, excluding the VC’s share: OIfrac= s *[1 –
x
(
v ]
(
. As the OI
attracts more and more funds from outside investors, the value of the firm
keeps growing, but your fraction decreases, everything else equal. Let us
illustrate the staged financing with an example where we will see how to
calculate the fraction of the company that belongs to different investors in
each stage.–
Assets Liabilities
Cash from new equity 2.0 New equity from venture capital 2.0
Other assets 2.0 Your original equity 2.0
Value 4.0 Value 4.0
Table 6.1: First stage market value balance sheet ($K).
2
Your fraction:
4 = 50%
2
VC1 fraction: (Recall that if the VC contributes X to a start-up
4 = 50%
worth V, his fractions is simply X/V. Here X=2 and V=4)
Suppose we expand the business and in one year the market value
increases to $20K. A new VC2 contributes $8K.
81
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Assets Liabilities
Cash from new equity 8.0 New equity from 2nd stage 8.0
Fixed assets 2.0 Equity from 1st stage ??
Other assets 18.0 Your original equity ??
Value 28.0 Value 28.0
82
Chapter 6: Equity financing
Example. VC monitoring
Suppose there is a firm that next period generates a cash flow of 10 if
an equity holder monitors or 0 otherwise. The cost of monitoring is 4. If
you are a small investor with 20 per cent stake, then you do not monitor
because:
• The payoff from monitoring is 20%*10 – 4 = –2 (if you monitor,
then the firm value is 10, and you get 20 per cent of the total firm
value. On the other hand, you exert monitoring effort of 4 – the full
cost of monitoring. Hence, the net payoff to you as the monitoring
shareholder is: 20%*10 – 4 = –2).
• On the other hand, your payoff from not monitoring is simply 0 as
the firm value without monitoring is 0. Since your payoff from not
monitoring exceeds the one from monitoring (0>–2), you do not
monitor.
If every investor holds less than 20 per cent, then no one monitors. In
public companies, this is almost always true, so we have the free-riders
problem.
On the other hand, if you are a large investor with a 70 per cent stake,
then you will monitor because:
• you anticipate that no one else monitors
• your payoff from monitoring is: 70%*10 – 4 = 3
• payoff from not monitoring is 0<3. Thus, you are better off monitoring.
VCs are usually large investors with a big stake in the company; hence,
they have the incentives to monitor.
Now, let us talk about how VC funds raise money for their investments.
VCs belong to the private equity industry and are usually organised in
limited partnership structure. There are two types of partners: general
partners (GPs) and limited partners (LPs). GPs are responsible for choosing
and monitoring the portfolio of firms. They contribute mainly skill and
around 2 per cent of the total capital of the VC. LPs provide capital for
the partnership. They do not directly make investment decisions but
contribute the majority of capital: around 98 per cent. To understand the
fund structure, let us consider the following example. Suppose you have
brilliant skills in choosing successful start-ups, but do not have enough
money to invest in all of them. However, some outside investors (for
example your friends) have large amounts of money and are looking
for high return projects. One possibility is to set up a VC, where you are
the GP and your wealthy investors are the LPs. A typical fund structure
is depicted in Figure 6.1. The institutional investors are the LPs – they
contribute funds to the VC and expect larger than usual returns. The VCs
are the GPs – they buy the equity of a portfolio of start-ups.
83
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Institutional Investors
Funds Returns
VCs
Cash Equity
Portfolio Firms
Example. VC compensation
Suppose you are the GP of a VC. You open a fund with 1 per cent
contribution of $1M (as GP). LPs contribute $99M. Ten years later, you
manage to increase the fund value by $100M. Assume 2 per cent annual
fixed fees and 20 per cent carry. What are the payoffs to GP and LP?
The payoff to you as a GP consists of three components. First, since you
hold 1 per cent of the fund (as you contributed $1M out of the original
$100M), now you get 1 per cent of the new value of the fund: $200M.
Second, you get the fixed fees of 2 per cent for each of the 10 years. Third,
you are entitled to the carry which is 20 per cent of the fund profits. All in
all, you get:
1%*(200M) (stake in the fund) + 2%*100M*10 (fixed fees) + 20%*(200M –
99M – 2M – 20M) (carry) = 37.8M
The payoff to LPs is their original stake plus the rest of the profits:
99M + 80% * (200M – 99M – 2M – 20M) = 162.2M
Note the huge return to the GP: $37.8M on $1M investment. This is due to
the effective leverage taken on by the LP fund structure.
84
Chapter 6: Equity financing
Finally, let us consider how VCs exit the portfolio of firms. There are
two ways: M&A and IPO. In M&A, the company is acquired by another
(potentially bigger) company. For example, recall the 2014 acquisition of
WhatsApp by Facebook. In an IPO, a company’s equity becomes available
to the general public for the first time. We will discuss this in detail in the
next section.
Activities
You founded your own IT firm five years ago. Initially you invested $2 million of your own
money and in return you received 20 million shares in the company. Last year you sold
10 million shares of stock to angel investors. Now you decide to obtain funding from a
VC which would invest $50 million and would receive 20 million newly issued shares in
return. What is the post-money valuation of your IT firm?
Select one:
a. $52 million
b. $125 million
c. $50 million
d. $100 million
85
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
costs are usually in the range of seven to 11 per cent. This is the fee that
investment bankers (usually big reputable banks) charge for their services.
They agree to buy the shares from the company and to place them to
the general public. However, the most dramatic monetary cost is the IPO
underpricing. A prominent feature of almost all IPOs is that the IPO price
is typically lower than the day one closing price. This is a cost to existing
shareholders as they could have sold the shares at a higher price than the
IPO price.
Second, there are disclosure requirements. Public companies are legally
obliged to file honest reports. This information is publicly available, and
can be used by the company’s competitors. Thus, disclosure requirements
may make public firms more vulnerable to competitors. Lastly, companies
that go public lose freedom as there is now oversight by the regulator.
A prominent feature of most US IPOs is the seven per cent underwriting
fee puzzle (see Figure 6.2). As we see, after 1988, 7 per cent is the
predominant underwriting fee for most IPOs in the USA.
100.0%
90.0%
80.0%
70.0%
Percentage of IPOs
60.0%
Below 7%
50.0% 7%
Above 7%
40.0%
30.0%
20.0%
10.0%
0.0%
85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98
Year
88
Chapter 6: Equity financing
Activities
Big Burger Corporation has 1 million shares outstanding. It wishes to issue 500,000 new
shares using rights issue. The current stock price is $500 and the subscription price is
$470/share. What is the value of a right?.
Select one:
a. $25/right
b. $20/right
c. $4/right
d. $50/right
89
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
industries. Thus, holding shares of firms that recently went public, for a
long period after the IPO, proofs to be a bad investing strategy.
Russia
Argentina
Austria
Canada
Denmark
Chile
Norway Small underpricing
Netherlands
France
Turkey
Spain
Portugal
Nigeria
Belgium
Israel
Hong Kong
Mexico
UK
Italy
USA
Finland
S. Africa
New Zealand
Philippines
Iran
Australia
Medium underpricing
Poland
Cyprus
Ireland
Germany
High
Indonesia
Sweden underpricing
Singapore
Switzerland
Sri Lanka
Brazil
Bulgaria
Thailand
Taiwan
Japan
Greece
Korea
Malaysia
India
China
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140
90
Chapter 6: Equity financing
information, the winner of the auction tends to overpay for the item.
How does this relate to an IPO? Analogously, in an IPO, uninformed
investors tend to overpay for bad firms. To the contrary, informed investors
participate in an IPO only if the firm is good. Now, assume you are
uninformed investor and your average evaluations are correct. If you bid
the average estimates in an IPO, and the IPO is a good deal, you get small
(or no) allocation in the issue because informed investors also participate.
However, when the IPO is bad, informed investors withdraw and you are
the only buyer. You end up with a big allocation in a bad firm, for which
you paid a higher price than the fair one (since the average between a
good and a bad deal is larger than a bad deal). Thus, on average, when
you win a lot of allocation, it means it is a bad IPO – winner’s curse
problem. Moreover, your expected return is negative. Hence, in order
to break even, you bid at a discount which means that the day 1 closing
price should be higher than the IPO price. This leads to IPO underpricing.
In some sense, the IPO underpricing is a form of a ‘bribe’ to attract the
uninformed investors to the offering. Let us consider an example which
shows us why uninformed investors need a lower-than fair price at the IPO
to break even.
91
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Dog Jewel
(40% Probability) (60% Probability)
Informed 0 500
Uninformed 1,000 500
Table 6.3 Shares rationing.
We need participation by uniformed investors; otherwise the IPO will not
go through. They must earn an average 1–day return of 0 per cent. What is
the required return from a ‘Jewel’ for uniformed investors to participate in
the IPO?
Assume is the day 1 return from ‘Jewel’. Then the expected day 1 return
for an uninformed investor is:
.4($1000)(1 – .20) + .6(500)(1 + Rj) + .6(500)(1 + 0) = 1000 (1 + 0)
The first term on the left-hand side of the equation above is the return on
allocated shares in a bad IPO, the second the return on allocated shares in
a good IPO, and the last the return on unused cash. The right-hand side is
the return from not participating in the IPO. Solving yields . What is the
expected return on the IPO then?
E(RIPO) = .4*(–20%) + .6*(26.67%) = 8%
This is the average day 1 return (underpricing)!
Key terms
Initial public offerings
IPO underpricing
Private equity
Rights offerings
Seasoned equity offerings
Staged financing
Venture capital
Winner’s curse problem
92
Chapter 6: Equity financing
93
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
94
Chapter 7: Dividend policy
Learning objectives
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• show that dividend policy (and share repurchases) are irrelevant to
firm valuation under the Modigliani–Miller assumptions
• discuss the stylised facts of dividend policy provided by Lintner
• present the clientele model of dividends
• discuss the effects of asymmetric information and agency costs on
dividend behaviour.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 17 (Payout Policy).
Further reading
Allen, F. and R. Michaely ‘Dividend Policy’ in Jarrow, R.A., V. Maksimovic and
W.T. Ziemba (eds) Handbooks in Operational Research and Management
Science: Volume 9: Finance. (Amsterdam: North Holland, 1995).
Bhattacharya, S. ‘Imperfect information, dividend policy, and “the bird in the
hand” fallacy’, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1) 1979, pp.259–70.
Blume, M., J. Crockett and I. Friend ‘Stock ownership in the United States:
characteristics and trends’, Survey of Current Business 54(11) 1974,
pp.16–40.
Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading,
MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2005) Chapter 16.
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 15 (How Taxes Affect Dividends
and Share Repurchases) and 19 (The Information Conveyed by Financial
Decisions).
Healy, P. and K. Palepu ‘Earnings information conveyed by dividend initiations
and omissions’, Journal of Financial Economics 21(2) 1988, pp.149–76.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency
costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976,
pp.305–60.
Lintner, J. ‘Distribution of incomes of corporations among dividends, retained
earnings and taxes’, American Economic Review 46(2) 1956, pp.97–113.
Myers, S. ‘Determinants of corporate borrowing’, Journal of Financial Economics
5(2) 1977, pp.147–75.
Ross, S. ‘The determination of financial structure: the incentive signalling
approach’, Bell Journal of Economics 8(1) 1977, pp.23–40.
95
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Overview
The dividend is a cash payment (usually made on an annual or semi-
annual basis) to the owners of corporate equity and is the basic financial
inducement for individuals to hold shares. In Chapter 1, when analysing
discounted cash-flow techniques, we demonstrated how to price an
equity share, given knowledge of the future dividend stream that would
accrue to the share. Such an analysis might be undertaken by an investor
in order to assess the ‘value’ of an equity share. The current chapter
analyses dividends from the opposite perspective, that of the manager
of a corporation who must decide on the level of dividends to pay out.
In a similar vein to the analysis of capital structure in Chapters 5 and 6,
the fundamental question we wish to answer is: what dividend policy is
optimal for management in that its adoption results in maximum firm
value?
96
Chapter 7: Dividend policy
buy a share of the company any time before t=3, you will be eligible for a
dividend as at t=5 the transaction will be settled and you will be holding
shares in the company. However, if you buy the share at, say, t=4, you will
not receive the dividend as you will only become an official shareholder at
t=4+2=6, which is after the record date. In relation to this, the first day
the stock trades without the dividend, is called the ex-dividend date (t=4
in our example). The day before the ex-dividend day, is called the cum-
dividend date (t=3 in our example). Figure 7.1 illustrates the timeline of a
typical dividend payment. If you buy the share on or after the ex-dividend
date, you will not receive the declared dividend. If you buy the share on or
before the cum-dividend date, you will receive the dividend.
97
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
• no agency costs
• investment outcomes independent of financing decisions.
The assumptions that give us MM1 actually yield a far more powerful
result than just the irrelevancy of debt policy. They imply that the entire
financial policy followed by a firm is irrelevant for its valuation; all that
matters is the firm’s portfolio of investment projects. Hence, capital
structure, dividend policy and risk management activities (among other
things) are all ineffectual in altering firm value. We have restated the
theorem and application of its logic to dividend policy, below.
Consider a firm that has fixed its investment policy. In each period, it is left
with a net cash flow, which is simply the difference between operating
income and investment costs. A straightforward corporate dividend
policy would just be to pay out this net cash flow to the holders of equity.
However, consider a firm that desires to pay a dividend in excess of its
net cash flow. In order to do this, the firm can raise funds by issuing
new equity. Alternatively, the firm could borrow money which, assuming
perfect capital markets, is a transaction with NPV of zero. Conversely, a
firm wishing to pay a smaller dividend might spend the balance of its net
cash flow on repurchasing equity. The key idea here is that a firm can
choose whatever payout policy it desires, funding the policy through share
issues/repurchases; hence, dividend policy is irrelevant.
From the individual investor’s point of view we can show that dividend
policy is irrelevant too. To do this we can use a similar argument to that
employed in our argument that shareholders are indifferent to capital
structure changes; shareholders are indifferent to dividend policy as,
through appropriate purchases or sales of shares, they can replicate any
dividend policy they wish. Hence, investors will not value a firm paying a
particular dividend policy different to any other firm such that firm
value does not depend on dividends. We will pick up this theme in the
following section.
Activity
A firm has current share price of £2.50 and will pay a £0.15 per share dividend
tomorrow. What is the share price immediately after dividend payment?
98
Chapter 7: Dividend policy
Consider the cash position of an individual who originally held five shares
in our firm. The value of their shareholding was originally $250. After
the dividend payment, they have cash of $50, and the value of their
shareholding is $200. Hence, the dividend has just altered the composition
of their wealth rather than changing its dollar amount.
What happens if, instead, the firm decides to use the cash it had originally
earmarked for dividend payment for a share repurchase instead? As
mentioned above, the total dividend amount was $20,000. As the
original share price was $50, this implies that the firm can repurchase
$20,000/$50 = 400 shares. As a result, after the share repurchase, there
are 1,600 shares outstanding, and the firm is again worth $80,000 in total.
Therefore, the post-share repurchase share price must be $80,000/1,600
= $50. Note that a share repurchase (at a fair price) does not alter share
prices.
Again, consider the position of our individual who originally owned
five shares. The firm repurchases 400 shares, which is one-fifth of all
equity. Now, assume that one share of this individual’s holding of five
is repurchased. The repurchase thus gives them $50 and, after the
repurchase, their four remaining shares are worth $200 in all. As a result,
in this case also, their $250 invested in equity has been changed into
$50 of cash and $200 still in equity. This is identical to the case where
dividends were paid.
Thus, the individual is indifferent between dividends and share
repurchases. The manner in which the firm chooses to distribute cash does
not matter to them and, as a result, they will not discriminate (in value
terms) between stocks that do and do not pay dividends.
where Dt is the time t dividend per share, EPSt is earnings per share at t, α
is the target payout ratio, and λ is the parameter governing the degree of
dividend smoothing. In line with facts 1 and 2, equation 7.1 embodies a
target payout, which is a simple proportion of earnings. Also, the change
in dividends appears on the left-hand side of 7.1 in line with fact 3.
Note that, if λ was equal to one, then the dividend change at time t would
always ensure that dividends were at precisely their target level (i.e. we
would have Dt = α EPSt). However, for values of λ less than one, dividends
change towards their target level gradually. This reflects the smoothing of
dividends that Lintner’s stylised facts indicate.
The other major source of empirical observations on the effects of dividend
policy has been the event study literature, which has also emphasised the
vast importance of changes in dividends. A wide range of studies for equity
from many different countries has demonstrated that dividend cuts lead to
drops in stock price on average, whereas dividend increases on average
lead to stock price rises.1 The interested reader can consult Healy and 1
No change in dividends
Palepu (1988), among other writers. is (as one might expect)
Clearly then, putting together the empirical evidence from interviews and associated with little or
no effect on stock prices
event studies yields an impressive case for the relevance of dividend policy.
on average.
The results of Lintner (1956) indicate that corporate managers do not
perceive dividend policy as irrelevant. Rather, they seem to follow similar
plans in their payout policy. Further, the event study evidence tells us that
the market interprets unexpected dividend increases as good news for a
stock, whereas unexpected dividend cuts are regarded as bad news.
Hence, we have a case for arguing that the dividend version of the MM
theorem is invalid. However, we have not yet come up with reasons for
why it is invalid. In the following two sections we will explore three sets
of reasons (similar to those put forward to explain the relevancy of capital
structure): namely, the existence of taxation, asymmetric information and
agency costs.
100
Chapter 7: Dividend policy
Payout policy
High Medium Low
Dividend 100 50 0
Capital gain 0 50 100
After tax payoffs
Individuals 50 65 80
Corporations 90 77.5 65
Institutions 100 100 100
Equilibrium price 1,000 1,000 1,000
Table 7.1
Clearly, given the after-tax payoffs to each group, individuals will hold low
payout stocks, corporations will hold high payout stocks, and institutions
are indifferent. Assume that in equilibrium the total holdings of each
group are as given in Table 7.2.
Payout policy
High Medium Low
Individuals 0 0 320m
Corporations 110m 0 0
Institutions 500m 730m 220m
Total 610m 730m 540m
Table 7.2
Note that in Table 7.1 we displayed the equilibrium price of each equity
share as 1,000. Why is this the case? To see this, assume that the price of
low payout stock is 1,050, whereas the price of all other stock is 1,000.
This would imply that high and medium dividend level firms have an
incentive to switch to low dividend policies (to take advantage of the high
share prices). Such actions would increase the supply of low dividend
stocks and hence depress their price.
A reinforcing effect comes from the demand side. The return that
individuals get from holding low payout stock is 80/1,050 = 7.62%.
This exceeds the returns they would gain from holding medium and high
payout stocks (which are 6.5 per cent and 5 per cent respectively), and
hence individuals continue to demand low dividend stocks. Institutions, on
the other hand, only get a return of 9.52 per cent from holding low payout
stock (100/1,050 = 9.52 per cent), whereas they get a return of 10 per
cent on other types of equity. Thus, institutions rationally sell their low
dividend equity. This further depresses the price. It is only when the price
of low dividend stock is 1,000 that equilibrium is reached.
The clientele model leads to the same main result as MM. Firm values (or 3
The dividend yield on
stock prices) are unaffected by dividend policy. There are obviously a stock is the ratio of
dividend payment to
underlying differences to these theories though. For example, the clientele
stock price. Evidence for
theory implies that investors in high tax brackets should hold portfolios this prediction is given
with low dividend yields and vice versa.3 in Blume, Crockett and
Friend (1974).
101
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Let us elaborate more on the timing of dividend and the tax deferral of
capital gain. Suppose a company has a current share price of 100 and has
an additional income at 5 per cent every year. The company can choose
between two dividend policies: in policy A, it pays 5 per cent dividend
every year so that the share price stays constant at 100. In policy B, it does
not pay any dividend, but reinvests the additional income in the firm so
that the share price grows by 5 per cent per year. Suppose both dividend
and capital gain tax rates are 40 per cent. As a shareholder of the company
with an investment horizon of 10 years, are we indifferent between the
two payout methods? No, because we can defer capital gain tax under
policy B. How? Recall dividends are immediately taxable upon payment,
and investors can only use after-tax dividend to reinvest. Then, the
dividend on the reinvestment is again taxed in the next round of payout
after it generates some new profits. However, if the capital is returned
in the form of repurchase, such a repeated taxation problem would not
appear. Investors are only taxed once upon the liquidation of their shares.
This is the crucial difference between the two payout methods. Thus,
even if the tax rates are the same, paying dividends still incurs higher tax
liability. Let us see why this is the case by calculating the gain under the
two different policies. If the company chooses policy A, we as shareholders
receive after tax dividend of 3 = 5 * (1 – 40%) in year 1. Then, we
reinvest the dividend and get 3 per cent after tax return every year. After
10 years, our proceeds are 100 * 1.0310 = 134.4. If the firm chooses policy
B, we do not pay any taxes over the next 10 years as we receive zero
dividends. After 10 years, we sell the stock at a price of 100 * 1.0510 =
162.9. After paying tax of 40% on the capital gain (162.9 – 100), our final
proceeds are 162.9 – (162.9 – 100) * 40% = 137.7 which is higher than
the gain under policy A.
empirical predictions fit quite nicely with those empirical results discussed
earlier in the chapter.
Summary
We started this chapter by arguing that, like capital structure, dividend
policy should not affect firm value. Subsequent to this, however, we
pointed out several sources of real world imperfection that might lead to
optimal dividend policies (in the sense of firm value maximisation). Such
imperfections included taxation, information asymmetries and agency
costs.
We also explored some of the empirical results on dividend policy.
Empirical evidence shows that equity prices tend to rise after unexpected
dividend increases and fall after unexpected dividend cuts (with bond
prices following a similar pattern). This, we argued, seemed most
supportive of dividend models based on asymmetric information.
The dividend puzzle is far from resolved, however. Much research
work remains to be done in the area to clarify our understanding of the
fundamental determinants of corporate dividend policy. Lintner’s stylised
facts and results from event studies have given us a good empirical basis
103
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Key terms
agency costs
asymmetric information
capital structure
clientele model
dividend policy
frictionless markets
Lintner’s stylised facts
Modigliani–Miller irrelevance theorem
personal taxes
share repurchases
target dividend payout level
taxes on capital gains
taxes on dividends
104
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
Learning objectives
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading,
you should be able to:
• discuss motivations for merger activity
• analyse simple numerical examples of efficient takeover activity
• detail the argument of Grossman–Hart (1980) regarding the
impossibility of efficient takeovers
• present ways in which this analysis can be modified to permit
takeovers to occur.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapter 32 (Mergers).
Further reading
Bradley, M., A. Desai and E. Kim ‘Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions
and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms’,
Journal of Financial Economics 21(1) 1988, pp.3–40.
Copeland, T. and J. Weston Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. (Reading,
MA; Wokingham: Addison-Wesley, 2004) Chapter 18.
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapter 20 (Mergers and Acquisitions).
Grossman, S. and O. Hart ‘Takeover bids, the free-rider problem and the theory
of the corporation’, Bell Journal of Economics 11(1) 1980, pp.42–64.
Healy, P., K. Palepu and R. Ruback ‘Does corporate performance improve after
mergers?’, Journal of Financial Economics 31(2) 1992, pp.135–76.
Jarrell, G., J. Brickley and J. Netter ‘The market for corporate control: the
empirical evidence since 1980’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2(1) 1988,
pp.49–68.
Jarrell, G. and A. Poulsen ‘Returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence
from three decades’, Financial Management 18(3) 1989, pp.12–19.
Jensen, M. ‘Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers’,
American Economic Review 76(2) 1986, pp.323–29.
Jensen, M. and W. Meckling ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency
costs and capital structure’, Journal of Financial Economics 3(4) 1976,
pp.305–60.
Jensen, M. and R. Ruback ‘The market for corporate control: the scientific
evidence’, Journal of Financial Economics 11(1–4) 1983, pp.5–50.
105
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Overview
The post-Second World War period has seen an unprecedented amount
of corporate activity resulting in the combination of two or more firms
under a single corporate banner and legal status. Such activity comes in
many forms and is initiated for varying reasons. This chapter gives an
introduction to the concepts underlying merger/takeover/acquisition
activity and provides a basic review of the theory of takeover activity, and
supplies empirical evidence on returns to takeovers.
In line with the arguments presented throughout this guide, we argue
that merger activity should be judged in terms of the value it delivers.
Mergers should be undertaken if they are positive NPV transactions. A
mathematical way of stating this is that:
VXY > VX + VY, (8.1)
that is, the value of the merged firm created from firms X and Y (VXY)
exceeds the sum of pre-merger values of X and Y (i.e. VX + VY). Such value
may come about through the exploitation of scale economies or elimination
of inefficiencies. We will give a classification of merger and acquisition
behaviour based on the source of value in the following section.
Merger motivations
Following Grinblatt and Titman (2002), we will split merger and takeover
activity into three distinct sub-groups:
• financial activity
• strategic activity
• conglomerate activity.
1. Financial mergers: these are takeovers or acquisitions that are
initiated to take advantage of corporate inefficiencies that lead to the
under-valuation of firms. This allows an acquiring firm to buy assets
cheaply, implement strategies that increase the value of the acquired
firm and then sell on the acquired assets at a profit (if so desired).
Such activity yields a positive net present value. Opportunities
for financial mergers are likely to come about due to managers of
1
This is because, if
a takeover occurs,
acquired firms following their own, rather than shareholders’, goals
incumbent management
and hence not maximising firm value. In this way, the market for are likely to lose their
corporate control is said to exert discipline on a firm’s management.1 jobs. Hence, assuming
The merger wave of the 1980s may be thought of as largely comprised management would prefer
of such activity. An active market for corporate control (in the form to retain their jobs, the
of hostile takeovers) is therefore an important force that mitigates possibility of takeover
limits managerial scope for
the problems arising from the separation of ownership and control in
inefficiency.
modern corporations.
106
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
107
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
share price is the total firm value post-takeover divided by the new total
number of shares outstanding. The new number of shares is calculated
as a pre-takeover number of shares plus new shares offered to the target
shareholders. Note that, unlike in cash deals, stock deals typically do not
involve the transfer of resource from the firm to the target shareholders.
The owners of the target company merely join those of the acquiring
company and also become shareholders of the post-takeover firm.
Example 1:
Consider two firms, X and Y, that compete in the same product market.
Corporation X currently has one million shares outstanding, each with
value $2. Firm Y has 500,000 shares on offer and share price $10. Firm Y
is contemplating a takeover of corporation X, as it knows that corporation
X is being run inefficiently. Firm Y estimates that, if it takes corporation X
over, it could increase firm X’s net cash flow by $300,000 per year. Assume
that these firms are infinitely lived. The relevant cost of capital for firm X
is 10 per cent.
Given the prior information, it is clear that, if firm Y does take over
corporation X, the increase in X’s value would be the present value of a
perpetuity paying $300,000 each year. This present value is $3m, which
represents the gain from the merger.4 It is clear that, given that the merger 4
Make sure you can
creates value, it is socially desirable. However, the terms by which the derive this PV for
yourself.
merger actually occurs will dictate the net payoffs to the shareholders of X
and Y. For the merger to occur, both net payoffs must be positive.
Assume, for example, that the merger is to occur by firm Y agreeing to
purchase every share in firm X at a price of $3 per share. This implies that
(as there are one million shares in firm X in issue) X’s shareholders get a
total payout of $3m, which exceeds the value of their initial shareholding
(i.e. $2m). Hence firm X’s shareholders are happy to participate in the
merger, as their payoff is $1m. Firm Y’s shareholders are paying $3m for a
firm which, under their management, will be worth $2m + $3m = $5m.
Hence their gain is also positive at $2m, and they are happy to participate.
Note that, quite obviously, the sum of the gains to X and Y shareholders is
the total value creation of $3m.
Another way in which this merger could have been financed is if firm Y
offered to issue a certain amount of new shares and gave these to the
shareholders of firm X instead of cash. Consider the following offer as an
example. One new share in firm Y is exchanged for every four existing firm
X shares. Note that this freshly issued equity will be a claim on the value of
the merged enterprise and hence priced as such.
The value of the merged firm will be the sum of the pre-merger values of X
and Y plus the value created of $3m. The pre-merger value of X is $2m
and that of Y is $5m. Hence the total value of the firm after the merger is
$10m. After the merger there are 0.75m shares in issue. This comprises
the original 0.5m shares in firm Y plus the 250,000 new shares issued.5 5
One new share was
Hence the share price of the merged enterprise is: offered for every four old
X shares. As there were
$ (8.2) originally one million X
shares outstanding, this
implies 250,000 new Y
shares must be issued.
The original shareholders of Y hold two-thirds of the equity of the merged
enterprise, which has a value $6.67m. The value of their original position
is $5m and hence they gain to the tune of $1.67m. The old X shareholders
own one-third of the equity of the merged enterprise, which is worth
$3.33m. Their gain is hence $1.33m, as the value of firm X pre-merger
was $2m. Both sets of shareholders are winners therefore, and hence the
108
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
merger goes ahead. Again, note that the sum of the gains is $3m, the total
value created.
Example 2:
Suppose you are the treasurer of Company A and you are investigating the
possible acquisition of Company B. You have the following basic data:
Company A B
Next year’s expected earnings per share £5.00 £1.50
Next year’s expected dividends per share £3.00 £0.80
Number of shares 1,000,000 600,000
Stock price £90 £20
You estimate that investors currently expect a steady growth of about 6 per
cent in B’s earnings and dividends. Under new management this growth
rate would be increased to 8 per cent per year, without any additional
capital investment required.
Let us first calculate the gain from the acquisition. To find the appropriate
discount rate (r) for the common stock of Company B, we use the
perpetual growth model of stock valuation:
0.80 = 20 ⇒ r = 0.10
r – 0.06
Under the new management, the value of the merged firm (call it AB)
would be the value of Company A before the merger plus the value of B
after the merger, or:
( 0.10$0.80
PVAB = (1,000,000 * $90) + 600,000 *
( = $114,000,000.
– 0.08
109
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
110
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
Assumptions
Our assumptions here are as follows:
• the firm is subject to a takeover bid from an external takeover raider
• firm value will improve, if the bid succeeds: the value increase is
common knowledge
• the equity of the target firm is held by many, small shareholders
• the raider incurs administrative takeover costs of c.
Assume that the current firm value is y, and let the firm value if the
takeover were to succeed be y + z. The takeover is efficient as the
following condition holds:
z > c. (8.3)
The raider must gain at least 50 per cent of the shares to implement the
takeover. Note, however, that as shareholders are assumed to be identical,
if any one shareholder finds it profitable to tender their shares to the
raider then all will. The raider offers a premium p over the current firm
value to equity-holders for their shares. Hence, for the bid to be profitable
for the raider we must have:
z > p + c, (8.4)
that is, the improvement in firm value must exceed the cost of takeover
and the premium paid to original equity-holders.
Consider the position of a single, small shareholder. As their shareholding
is minor relative to the sum of all equity, they do not consider their
decision to be pivotal. Assume that they believe that the bid will be
successful. Then they will only sell their shares to the raider if:
p > z, (8.5)
that is, it is only in the shareholder’s interest to tender if the premium they
get outweighs the money they would make by hanging on to their equity
and profiting from the value improvement associated with the takeover.
If the shareholder believes that the takeover bid will fail, then they will
be indifferent between offering their shares to the raider and not offering
them.
Our key result can be derived from a comparison of equations 8.4 and
8.5. They are clearly contradictory, implying that the raider cannot
simultaneously succeed with the bid and make a profit. Hence, profitable
takeover activity cannot occur.
A crucial assumption here is that all shareholders are small in size.
This then implies that none of them perceive themselves to be pivotal
to the success of the takeover bid. This results in all small shareholders
attempting to free-ride on the value improvement offered by the raider
and, ultimately, the bid then fails.
Another way to see the result is as follows. A premium that allows the
raider to make a profit must satisfy the following condition:
p ∈ (0, z – c). (8.6)
However, a premium in this region implies that shareholders are better off
not selling to the raider and hanging on to their equity as:
y + p < y + z – c < y + z. (8.7)
111
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
The first term in equation 8.7 is the money they get for selling to the
raider, and the final term is the value of their shareholding if they do not
sell (conditional on the bid being successful).
Dilution
Grossman and Hart (1980) first pointed out the free-riding problem we
discussed in the preceding section. In the same paper they also indicated a
solution to the free-riding problem. This solution was dilution.
Dilution is the ability of a raider to extract value from the target, if they
successfully complete the takeover. This might be done by placing themself
in charge and paying themself an astronomical salary, selling the firm’s
output to another corporation they own at a very low price, and other
diverse means. Hence, if the takeover is successful and the raider dilutes
the firm, the firm’s market value ends up being less than y + z (to use the
notation of the previous section).
To make the prior argument concrete, assume the raider can appropriate
an amount φ of firm value if the takeover is successful. Hence, if
shareholders believe the bid will be successful, they will be willing to
tender their shares if offered a premium (over current value) that satisfies
the following condition:
p > z – φ. (8.8)
The raider makes money if equation 8.4 holds, and this leads to the
following condition for profitable takeover activity to occur:
z – c > p > z – φ | φ > c. (8.9)
112
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
Hence, shareholders require a premium that exceeds the size of the value
improvement. The condition that must hold for the large shareholder to
profit is:
z > (1 – α)p + c, (8.11)
that is, the value improvement must exceed the cost of takeover, plus the
premium the large shareholder must pay to buy the remaining (1 – α) of
firm equity. Both equations 8.10 and 8.11 are satisfied when the following
condition holds:
αz > c. (8.12)
Hence, large shareholders can implement efficient takeovers, when the
proportion of the value improvement that accrues to their original holding
exceeds the takeover cost.
Thus our analysis tells us that large shareholders are important in that
their existence allows the free-rider problem to be circumvented. This is
exploited in Shleifer and Vishny (1986) who also relax the assumption
of perfect information. In their analysis, the value improvement is only
known by the large shareholder, and this provides another reason for
the existence of takeover activity in the model. The role of the large
shareholder is emphasised in some of the empirical predictions from their
model. They show, for example, that firm values increase with the size of
the large shareholding. The intuition for this is that a larger shareholding
means more efficient takeover decisions and hence a firm with larger
future values and hence greater current market value.
Empirical evidence
Are mergers and acquisitions value-enhancing? This section reviews
empirical evidence from two types of studies: accounting and event studies.
The first type, accounting studies, examine financial results
(accounting data) to draw inferences about the underlying economic
impact of mergers and acquisitions. These studies tend to investigate
whether acquirers outperform their non-acquirer peers. Alternatively, these
studies compare the performance of the combined firm following a merger
or an acquisition with the performance obtaining prior to the transaction.
Performance tends to be measured by net income, operating margin, or
return on equity or assets.
The second type, event studies, do not directly measure performance.
Instead, these studies attempt to measure the value created by the merger
or acquisition through abnormal stock returns around the announcement
date of a tender offer. Hence, event studies rely on financial markets being
efficient.
Accounting studies
The empirical evidence from accounting studies is mixed. Ravenscraft and
Scherer (1987) investigate more than 5,000 mergers occurring between
1950 and 1975, calculate and compare the post-merger performance of
acquiring firms with that of non-acquiring firms in the same industries,
with performance being measured as return on assets, and report that
performance is 1 to 2 per cent less for acquiring firms.
113
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Event studies
Empirical evidence from event studies suggests that shareholders from
target firms gain from takeovers. This should not come as a surprise as
target shareholders require a premium in order to induce them to sell their
shares to the acquiring firm. Jensen and Ruback (1983) report that target
share prices increase, on average, by about 16 to 30 per cent around the
date of the announcement of a tender offer. Empirical evidence reported
by Jarrell, Brickley and Netter (1988) suggests that these returns increased
substantially during the 1980s to an average of about 53 per cent.
Jensen and Ruback (1983) furthermore report that the average return to
shareholders from target firms in negotiated mergers is, however, only
about 10 per cent.
The empirical evidence from event studies on returns to shareholders of
bidding firms tends to be quite mixed: returns to bidders are, on average,
small, time-varying, but may be positive or negative. For instance, Jarrell
and Poulsen (1989) show that the announcement return to bidder in
tender offers dropped from a statistically significant 5 per cent gain in
the 1960s to an insignificant 1 per cent loss in the 1980s. The means of
payment used for the transaction is furthermore shown to have a major
effect on returns to bidders. For instance, Travlos (1987) finds that the
average return on the two days around the announcement of a cash offer
is only marginally different from zero (+0.24 per cent). In contrast, in
acquisitions financed by an exchange of equity, stock prices of bidding
firms fall, on average, by about 1.5 per cent. The means of payment may
hence act as a signal for the quality of the bidder. Consistent with the
pecking order theory reviewed in Chapter 6 (Myers and Majluf (1984)),
bidders offer stock when they believe that their stock is overvalued. A
stock offer may furthermore indicate that the bidder was unable to get any
financial backing from a bank or another financial institution.
Adding the bidder and target returns generates positive returns, implying
that, on average, there is a net gain to shareholders around the time of the
merger or acquisition. For instance, Bradley, Desai and Kim (1988) provide
evidence suggesting that successful tender offers increase the combined
value of the merging firms by an average of 7.4 per cent or $117m (stated
in 1984 dollars). The empirical evidence from event studies hence suggests
that mergers and acquisitions are, on average, value enhancing.
Summary
In this chapter we have given you an overview of the facts involved in,
and theory surrounding, mergers and takeovers. The main lesson of
this chapter is that mergers that should go ahead (i.e. efficient merger
activity) are those that are positive NPV transactions. See equation 8.1.
114
Chapter 8: Mergers and takeovers
Key terms
asymmetric information
bidders
capital structure
clientele model
conglomerate mergers
corporate governance
dilution
disciplinary takeover
efficient takeovers
event studies
financial mergers
free-riding
frictionless markets
Grossman–Hart model
large shareholders
mergers and acquisitions
strategic mergers
targets
takeover premium
toehold
115
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
116
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
Learning objectives
At the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain why and how companies manage risk
• explain and evaluate the cost of hedging
• explain covered and uncovered interest rate parity, and analyse the
associated arbitrage possibilities.
Essential reading
Brealey, R., S. Myers and F. Allen Principles of Corporate Finance. (Boston, MA;
London: McGraw-Hill, 2016) Chapters 26 (Managing Risk).
Further reading
Grinblatt, M. and S. Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy. (Boston,
MA; London: McGraw-Hill, 2011) Chapters 21 (Risk Management and
Corporate Strategy), 22 (The Practice of Hedging), and 23 (Interest Rate
Risk Management)
Introduction
In the previous chapters, we have analysed:
• valuation and investment decisions
• dividend decisions
• financing decisions.
One of the most important roles of a CFO in running a business is to
manage the potential risks associated with the operations. In this chapter,
we study risk management and hedging. In particular, we would like to
understand which risks should be hedged, and how to find the appropriate
instruments to hedge these risks. We are going to talk about why and how
firms manage risks. We will consider three main reasons why firms hedge
their risks:
• bankruptcy costs
• cost of financial distress
• risk averse managers.
Then we will analyse several possible instruments to reduce risks:
• insurance
• future contracts
117
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
• forward contracts
• swaps.
We will elaborate on each of those and see how they can be beneficial to
reduce future uncertainty. However, managing risks via hedging is typically
not for free. We will talk about the two main costs of hedging:
• transaction costs
• risk premium.
Finally, we will briefly talk about one application of futures for hedging in
the foreign exchange market – the carry trade, and the resulting covered
and uncovered interest rate parity.
118
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
Bankruptcy costs
How do we reduce bankruptcy costs? One way to achieve this target is
by reducing the probability of default. Sometimes, however, the financial
market for the risk may not exist. For example, suppose you are a UK
company, and you want to hedge against unfavourable outcomes for
your activities in case London becomes a less important financial centre.
However, a contract that pays off in this case might simply not exist. A
possible way to hedge is then for the company to establish a subsidiary
outside the UK, thereby diversifying its activities.
Another obvious non-hedging approach to reduce the default probability
is to avoid any kind of leverage altogether. In the extreme case, when the
firm has no debt, there is zero probability of default. Would this be optimal
for the company? Not necessarily. Recall companies can increase their
value by taking debt because of the interest tax shield. Hence, they can
find it optimal to take on leverage to improve valuation indicators even
though this increases default risk. There are two main types of leverage
( debts
that companies manage: financial leverage assets
( , and operating
(
fixed costs
leverage total costs .
(
Alternatively, firms use financial contracts to lower the default probability
and thus, bankruptcy costs. By using financial arrangements with
other entities, a company can shift resources from good outcomes
to bad outcomes, thereby reducing the cash flow risk. The firm’s
aggregate performance (including the payment associated with the
financial arrangements) in the good state would be lower, but the firm’s
performance in the bad state would be less devastating. Hence, these
financial arrangements reduce the probability of bankruptcy in the bad
state. Let us illustrate the last point with a simple example which shows
how hedging activities can decrease the default probability.
120
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
State 1 State 2
Firm A 50 100
Firm B 100 50
Table 9.1: Cash flows in the different states.
The firm value (for both A and B) without hedging (since the probability
of each state is 50 per cent) is 0.5*100 + 0.5*50*(1 – 20%) = 70
But can the firms do better than that? Can they write a contract that
allows them both to avoid bankruptcy and the loss of 20 per cent in the
bad state? Yes. Suppose the two firms can sign the following contract: in
state 1, firm B gives firm A 25; in state 2, firm A gives firm B 25. The new
cash flows are shown in Table 9.2.
State 1 State 2
Firm A 75 75
Firm B 75 75
121
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
State 1 State 2
Unhedged Asset Cash flow 60 100 + 20
Hedged Asset Cash flow 80 80 + 20
State 1 State 2
Unhedged Asset Cash flow 60 100
Hedged Asset Cash flow 80+20 80
Table 9.4: Cash flows with negative correlation.
Thus, if the firm hedges, it has an expected cash flow of 0.5*(80 + 20) +
0.5*80 = 90. If it does not hedge, the expected cash flow is only 80: 0.5*60
+ 0.5*100 = 80. Hence, there are gains from hedging as the expected cash
flow from hedging is larger than that from not hedging. Where does the
benefit come from? It is due to the fact that with hedging, the company
does not forego the positive NPV project and gets the full NPV of 20 with a
probability of 50%: 0.5*20 = 10 = 90 – 80.
122
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
Activity
Which of the following firms may be more likely to hedge risks? Give a brief explanation:
a. Private firms where investors are not diversified.
b. Opaque firms with significant asymmetric information problems.
c. Intangible firms that are more exposed to costs of financial distress.
d. All of the above described firms.
123
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
• forward contracts
• swaps.
Futures, forward contracts and swaps belong to the asset class of
derivatives. Derivatives are financial agreements/instruments/contracts
whose returns are linked to, or derived from, the performance of
underlying assets such as equity, bonds, currencies or commodities. We
are already familiar with some basic derivatives: call and put options.
Remember, the call option gives you the right, but not the obligation to
buy the underlying asset in the future for a price fixed today; the put
option gives you a similar right but to sell the asset. The value of both
these simple derivatives is derived from the price of the underlying asset.
For the remainder of this section we are going to discuss each type of
financial contract used for hedging in more detail.
Let us start with insurance. We already briefly talked about the main
features of this type of hedging, so let us summarise the key points.
In an insurance contract, the firm pays a fixed amount (the insurance
premium) in exchange for the insurance company paying the variable
cash flow (the loss) instead of the firm. This exchanges a variable cash
flow for a fixed one. Insurance is against (mostly idiosyncratic) risk. By
selling many policies, the insurance company diversifies much of the risk
internally as it pools many idiosyncratic risks that cancel each other out.
Moreover, because of the law of large numbers, the insurance company is
able to predict the fraction of insurance events for the pool. Essentially, the
probability is no longer uncertain but deterministic. The only risk which
is left in the insurance company is the systematic risk, which is passed to
shareholders through the securities market, where the security holders
diversify the risk.
Forwards and futures are another way of hedging the future uncertainty.
They are agreements to sell an asset at a future date at a fixed price set
today. The transaction price set today is called the forward/future price.
For example, an airline company might be worried that in a year’s time the
price of oil might be too high, hence increasing costs. To hedge this risk,
the firm can buy a one-year futures contract, fixing the oil price today. This
allows the company to get rid of the uncertainty related to future prices.
Many assets have future markets including agricultural commodities (e.g.
corn and soybeans), non-agricultural commodities (e.g. gold or fuel oil)
and financial assets (e.g. 30-year government bonds or Swiss Francs).
In practice, most contracts are not physically settled, i.e. the actual
commodity is not usually delivered (sometimes delivery is not allowed for
commodities like wind, for example). Traders usually reverse their position
before the contract expires to have a net exposure of 0. For example, if
you enter in a long oil futures contract maturing in one year, you can enter
into a short futures contract with the same notional any time before the
maturity, which would cancel your long position.
Although quite similar, futures and forward contracts have some
differences. Most importantly, futures contracts are standardised and are
traded on exchanges. This means that the counterparty of your futures
contract is the exchange. This decreases the counterparty risk. To the
contrary, forward contracts are not standardised and are traded over-
the-counter. This means that there is no intermediary between the long
and the short side of the contract and that the risk of the counterparty
defaulting is much higher.
124
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
Futures prices are closely related to spot prices observed in the future. In
particular, future prices are one possible predictor of expected spot prices
in the future. Is this predictor good enough? Not always. Why? Because of
the risk premium. We will elaborate more on this in the next section.
Lastly, let us discuss swaps as a way to hedge risks. A swap is an exchange
of one set of cash flows (e.g. cash flows on a floating rate loan) for
another of equivalent market value (e.g. cash flows on a fixed rate loan).
Essentially, they are a sequence of futures contracts. Let us illustrate the
mechanics of swaps with a simple example that shows how swaps can be
beneficial in hedging mismatch between assets and liabilities.
Example. Swap
There are two firms: CRST and Hanson. CRST receives LIBOR (London
Interbank Offered Rate), which is floating, but CRST a fixed liability. Thus,
it is exposed to the risk that the floating rate might decrease and hence
the company will have insufficient assets to cover its fixed-rate liability.
Hanson, on the other hand, receives fixed rate but is liable for LIBOR.
Thus, it is exposed to the risk that the floating rate might increase and
hence Hansen will have insufficient assets to cover its floating-rate liability.
Can the two firms sign a contract that allows both of them to hedge the
floating versus fixed risk mismatch?
Yes! CRST and Hanson can enter into an interest rate swap: CRST agrees
to pay a floating rate to Hanson and Hanson agrees to pay a fixed interest
rate (called the swap rate) to CRST. This way, both of them get rid of the
uncertainty associated with the future LIBOR. The swap rate is always set
such that the transaction has zero NPV. Suppose, in our example, the swap
rate is 8 per cent. Figure 9.1 illustrates the mechanics of the contract.
CRST receives LIBOR and pays it immediately to Hansen as a part of the
swap contract. In return, CRST gets the fixed 8 per cent swap rate which
allows CRST to pay the fixed 8 per cent liability to the lender. Analogously,
Hansen receives the fixed rate of 8 per cent and pays it as a part of the
swap contract. In return, it receives LIBOR from CRST which allows
Hansen to cover the LIBOR liability:
LIBOR
Swap rate = 8%
8%
LIBOR
Lender Lender
125
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
value in bad times, negative b). Consider, for example, an owner selling
gold through a futures contract. Gold is a good hedge against bad times, so
has a negative b. Hence, rC< rF and (1 + rF) / (1 + rC) > 1 which means (Future
price > E0 (spot price). The seller of a gold futures contract loses the benefit
of gold to appreciate in value in bad times by fixing the futures price today.
He requires compensation for this; hence, the future price is above the
expected spot price.
To conclude, the risk premium is an important cost of hedging. Depending
on the b of the asset, this premium may be positive or negative, causing
the future price to be different than the expected spot price.
127
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
The company can use a currency forward contract to lock down the FX
tomorrow. Suppose ABC can sign a currency forward contract on the £/$
exchange rate. How many contracts (face value) does the company need?
What is the forward price?
If ABC borrows in pounds, it needs to buy back £8.16M. The forward price
must make sure that the company is indifferent between borrowing in
pounds and in dollars, i.e. that £8.16M = $10.6M in a year’s time. Namely,
the forward price must be £1=$1.3. As today £1=$1.25<$1.3, the forward
price implies the pound will appreciate, making borrowing in pounds less
attractive.
What if the forward price is larger than $1.3, say, £1=$1.4? That is an
arbitrage. Take the following strategy: today, borrow $1.25, convert into
£1 and invest at the UK risk-free rate of 2%. Simultaneously, sign a forward
contract for £1.02 at the observed forward price of £1=$1.4. In a year’s
time, the investment returns £1.02, we use the forward contract to convert
it into dollars: 1.02*1.4 = $1.428. We use part of this money to repay the
dollar debt with 6 per cent interest: $1.25*1.06 = $1.325. The rest is the
arbitrage profit: $1.428-$1.325 = 0.103.
This example shows that the forward price should be uniquely linked
to the spot exchange rate and to the interest rates in the two countries.
Whenever this relationship is violated, we can construct an arbitrage.
Let us generalise this relationship, based on the logic in the ABC example.
Consider two ways to borrow $1 today:
1. Directly borrow $1 today and repay $(1+r$) in a year.
2. Borrow £fx£/$ today which is equivalent to $1 at today’s FX (foreign
exchange) rate. Need to repay £fx£/$ * (1+r£) in a year.
You can lock down the liability in dollars by entering a one-year forward
contract today. The dollar liability in a year will be £
By the no-arbitrage argument we saw before, it must be that the two ways
of borrowing are equivalent, i.e. (1+r$)=£fx£/$ * (1+r£)/F£/$. This is the
‘covered interest rate parity’.
−1 1.02
In the ABC example, 1.06 = 1.25 . If covered interest rate parity
1.3
fails, then there is an arbitrage opportunity. In reality it holds very well.
Finally, what if we do not lock down the exchange rates in the future
through future contracts? If we believe the forward rate F should equal the
expected FX rate in a year, then the formula is called ‘uncovered interest
rate parity’: (1 + r$) = fx£/$ * (1 + r£) / E[fx£/$]. Note the use of the uncertain
instead of the deterministic E[fx£/$] in the formula F£/$.
If we hold the positions in foreign currency and close them using random
future spot exchange rate, then typically there is a non-zero return. In
other words, the uncovered interest rate parity fails in reality: currency
with higher interest rate tends to appreciate. Based on this, traders have
developed a strategy called the carry trade: borrow low interest currency,
buy government bond in high interest rate currency; then exchange
it back to low interest currency and pay back the debt. There are two
sources of profit in the strategy: from the interest rate spread and from
the currency appreciation. For instance, in 2016–2017, the exchange
rate increased, i.e. the pound depreciated against the dollar, although the
pound interest rate was lower than the dollars. Hence, if you borrowed
in pounds and invested in dollars over that period, you would not only
gain because of the interest rate difference, but also because the dollar
would be worth more in terms of pounds It is important to note, however,
128
Chapter 9: Risk management and hedging
that the non-zero return is stochastic, hence the carry trade is not an
arbitrage opportunity – there is some risk. Historically, the carry trade has
experienced occasional very large losses when the exchange rates moved
dramatically over short periods of time.
Activities
1. Which of the following statements about futures contracts is false?
Select only one:
a. Futures contracts are generally more illiquid than forward contracts and are
traded anonymously on an exchange at a publicly observed market price.
b. Traders are required to post collateral, called margin, when selling or buying
commodities through futures contracts.
c. Both the seller and the buyer can get out of the contract at any time by selling it
to a third party at the current market price.
d. Futures prices are not prices that are paid today. They are prices agreed today, but
to be paid in the future.
2. In September 2004, the spot exchange rate for the Euro against the US Dollar was
$1.7188/€. At the same time the one-year interest rate in the USA was 4.85 per cent
and the one-year interest rate in Europe was 3.15 per cent. Based on these rates,
what is the one-year forward exchange rate that is consistent with no arbitrage?
Choose the closest answer.
Select one:
a. $1.6/€.
b. $1.9/€.
c. $1.7/€.
d. $1.5/€.
Key terms
Carry trade
Covered interest rate parity
Forward contracts
Future contracts
Hedging
Insurance
Swaps
Uncovered interest rate parity
129
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
130
Notes
Notes
131
FN2191 Principles of corporate finance
Notes
132