Portfolio Performance Measurement Review of Litera
Portfolio Performance Measurement Review of Litera
Abstract
This study provides a review of the main measures of portfolio performance. We discuss their
weaknesses and distinguish between traditional performance measures and more recent condi-
tional performance measures. We show that the conditional approach addresses one major short-
coming of the traditional approach (risk stability assumption). Conditional measures allow ex-
pected returns and risk to vary with the state of the economy. We also propose new avenues for
future research and some improvements to the existing measures.
Keywords
Portfolio Performance, Traditional Measures, Conditional Performance Measures, Asset Selection,
Market Timing, Jensen Alpha, Conditional Alpha
1. Introduction
The main goal of portfolio performance evaluation is to measure value creation provided by the portfolio man-
agement industry. In recent years, the demand of “reliable and admissible” performance measures has increased
as investment in mutual and exchange traded funds has exploded in popularity among small investors across the
globe. This research produces a census of the main measures of portfolio performance that has been proposed in
the literature. We discuss their limits and provide a classification based on their properties and objectives. It is
worth mentioning that we do not cover all existing measures (a complete survey is virtually impossible) but our
analysis provides an exhaustive list of the main established measures of financial performance. We distinguish
between traditional (unconditional) performance measures and conditional performance measures. The tradi-
tional measures were mainly influenced by the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). Their major shortcoming
How to cite this paper: Marhfor, A. (2016) Portfolio Performance Measurement: Review of Literature and Avenues of Fu-
ture Research. American Journal of Industrial and Business Management, 6, 432-438.
http://dx.doi.org/10.4236/ajibm.2016.64039
A. Marhfor
is the assumption that risk is constant over the entire evaluation period. On the other hand, conditional measures
relax this hypothesis by allowing portfolios risk and market premiums to vary over time with the state of the
economy (Ferson and Schadt [1]). Recent empirical findings reveal that conditional performance techniques im-
prove investors’ perception of the portfolio management industry [2]. In this paper, we also propose some im-
provements to the existing approaches and identify new avenues for future research.
433
A. Marhfor
At equilibrium, RAP = RM (return of the benchmark: market portfolio). When RAP > RM, the manager generates
higher performances.
N t =1
where THR is a threshold return (a specified required rate of return) and D is a Dummy variable set to 1 if the
return of the portfolio is below THR and 0 otherwise. According to SR, only returns that fall below a specified
required rate of return are taken into consideration. In fact, the Sharpe standard deviation is replaced by a new
standard deviation measure which considers only returns below THR.
where αP is Jensen’s alpha; βP is the portfolio beta; and εPt is an error term. Jensen’s alpha reflects good securi-
ties picking skill of a portfolio manager. A positive and significant alpha indicates that a portfolio manager has
beaten the market with his/her good assets selection skills. Like TR, Jensen’s alpha is sensitive to the choice of
the market index (Roll [7] critique). In reality, the market portfolio is unobservable because it should include
434
A. Marhfor
every single possible available asset. Furthermore, Jensen’s alpha does not allow a comparison of portfolios with
different levels of risk (Cogneau and Hubner [9]). Finally, this measure does not reflect managers’ market tim-
ing skills. In the literature, many adjustments have been proposed to distinguish between managers’ stock pick-
ing skills and market timing skills.
(R − R ft )
2
where Mt is the quadratic term. The latter assesses managers’ ability to increase (reduce) exposure to
the market risk in a bull (bear) market. A positive and significant coefficient on the quadratic term indicates that
managers have market timing skills because their portfolios returns are higher than market index returns in all
cases (bull or bear market). The term δ P ( RMt − R ft ) is always positive when δP is positive . In fact, when
2
the portfolio manager is able to predict when stocks will outperform bonds (high exposure to the market) and
when bonds will outperform stocks (low exposure to the market), we can say that he has a good market timing
skills.
where D is a dummy variable set equal to 1 when the market return is above the risk-free rate and 0 otherwise.
Intuitively, a positive and significant coefficient on the added term suggests that we should expect higher portfo-
lio returns (good market timing skills) because the term (δ D ( R
P t Mt )
− R ft ) is always positive when managers
have high exposure to the market during a bull market period.
Empirical results of studies using traditional performance measures suggest that fund managers do not have
investment ability to outperform passive investments strategies. Their management activities generate more
negative alphas than positive alphas. In addition, Jagannathanand and Korajczyk [12]; and Ferson and Schadt [1]
used T & M and H & M models to assess passive investments strategies performance. Their findings indicate
that a passive investment strategy can generate positive market timing coefficients and negative stock picking
coefficients (negative Jensen’s alpha). Theoretically, a passive strategy should generate non significant coeffi-
cients which indicate that T & M and H & M models are misspecified. One potential explanation of theses puz-
zling findings is that risk is assumed to be constant over time by all traditional performance measures. This
might seem like a very strong assumption because it is well established in the literature that investors’ expecta-
tions and second moments vary over time. Another explanation is that there are other factors (e.g. Size, Book-to-
market ratio…) that may explain changes in portfolios returns. As a result, portfolios risk exposures should be
allowed to vary over time in order to capture active portfolio management strategies and additional factors
should be included into Jensen’s traditional formula.
435
A. Marhfor
where SMB is the size factor (small minus big) and HML is the book-to-market factor (High minus low). These
factors measure the historic excess return of small cap stocks over big cap stocks and value stocks over growth
stocks.
( )
RPt − R ft = α cp + β 0 p ( RMt − R ft ) + B1′p zt −1 × ( RMt − R ft ) + ε pt (11)
where αcp is the conditional alpha; B1′p is the vector measuring the sensitivity of beta to the vector of public in-
formation variable (zt−1); β0p is the average beta of portfolio P; zt−1 is the difference between the realization of the
macroeconomic variables (public information) and their unconditional average (zt−1 – E(z)). The conditional
measure (Equation (11)) proposed by Ferson and Schadt [1] assumes that beta is a linear function of predeter-
mined public macroeconomic variables (zt−1) at period t − 1. In fact, using a Taylor series expansion, the portfo-
lio beta can be written as follows:
β p ( zt −=
1) β 0 p + B1′p zt −1 (12)
In the literature, most studies use four predetermined macro-variables: market dividend yield, Treasury bill
rate of returns, liquidity premiums and default risk premiums. A four-factor conditional model can be written as
follows:
(
RPt − R ft = α cp + β 0 p ( RMt − R ft ) + B1′p zt −1 × ( RMt − R ft ) ) (13)
+ β 2 p ( SMBt ) + β 3 p ( HMLt ) + β 4 p (UMDt ) + ε pt
Conditional models allow risk exposures to vary over time based on lagged public information variables. The
intuition behind such models is that managers use lagged public information (e.g. an increase in market dividend
yield) to change their risk exposure. For instance, an increase in market dividend yield at t − 1 may be a good
reason for portfolio managers to increase their exposure to the market in the future. This may be possible with a
portfolio beta above 1 so that future returns will be much higher if indeed we have a bull market. The opposite is
also true. Ferson and Schadt [1] approach takes into consideration such possibilities. In fact, the underlying in-
( (
tuition behind the additional term B1′p zt −1 × RMt − R ft )) is to remove from αcp (conditional alpha) the effect of
any investment strategy that can be replicated using public information. In some studies (e.g. Christopherson et
al. [15]), even the alpha follows a conditional process as in Equation (12).
436
A. Marhfor
information (macro and microeconomic). On the other hand, under Ferson and Schadt’s [1] framework, risk is
only a function of one-period lag public information (Coggins et al. [16]).
where D1 is a dummy variable equal to 1 during a bull market and 0 otherwise; D2 is a dummy variable equal to
1 during a bear market and 0 otherwise; AMB is the market timing factor (Above market returns minus Below
market returns). A positive and significant β2 and β3 indicate that managers have market timing skills.
F should for instance play the role of a smooth transition continuous function bounded between 0 and 1. The
switch from one regime to another (e.g. from bear to bull market) depends on the past values of a market index
time series data. A positive and significant δP suggests that portfolio managers are able to predict and understand
when the market enters a different regime.
437
A. Marhfor
( )
RPt − R ft = α cp + β 0 p ( RMt − R ft ) + B1′p Et −1 × ( RMt − R ft ) + ε pt (16)
4. Conclusion
This research revisits and extends the main measures of portfolio performance. We show that early traditional
performance measures do not control for risk-time variations associated with the state of economy and do not
consider multiple risk factors. The early portfolio empirical results in the finance literature suggest that the av-
erage performance net of expenses is negative. On the other hand, when we control for risk-time variations and
include additional risk factors, the average performance of funds looks better [1]. In this paper, we do not only
provide an exhaustive list of portfolio performance measures, but we also propose new avenues for future re-
search and some improvements to some existing measures.
References
[1] Ferson, W. and Schadt, R. (1996) Measuring Fund Strategy and Performance in Changing Economic Conditions.
Journal of Finance, 51, 425-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1996.tb02690.x
[2] Sharpe, W.F. (1966) Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Business, 1, 119-138. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/294846
[3] Markowitz, H. (1952) Portfolio Selection. Journal of Finance, 7, 77-91.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1952.tb01525.x
[4] Sortino, F. (1994) Performance Measurement in a Downside Risk Framework. Journal of Investing, 3, 59-65.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/joi.3.3.59
[5] Modigliani, F. and Modigliani, L. (1997) Risk-Adjusted Performance. Journal of Portfolio Management, 23, 45-54.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/jpm.23.2.45
[6] Treynor, J. (1965) How to Rate Management of Investment Funds. Harvard Business Review, 41, 63-75.
[7] Roll, R. (1977) A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory’s Tests’ Part I: On Past and Potential Testability of the Theory.
Journal of Financial Economics, 4, 129-176. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(77)90009-5
[8] Jensen, M.C. (1968) The Performance of Mutual Funds in the Period 1945-1964. Journal of Finance, 23, 389-416.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1968.tb00815.x
[9] Cogneau, P. and Hubner, G. (2009) The more than 100 Ways to Measure Portfolio Performance—Part 1: Standardized
Risk-Adjusted Measures. Journal of Performance Measurement, 14, 56-69.
[10] Treynor, J. and Mazuy, K. (1966) Can Mutual Funds Outguess the Market? Harvard Business Review, 44, 131-136.
[11] Henriksson, R.D. and Merton, R.C. (1981) On the Market Timing and Investment Performance II: Statistical Proce-
dures for Evaluating Forecasting Skills. Journal of Business, 54, 513-534. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/296144
[12] Jagannathan, R. and Korajczyk, R. (1986) Assessing the Market Timing Performance of Managed Portfolios. Journal
of Business, 59, 217-236. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/296326
[13] Fama, E.F. and French, K.R. (1992) The Cross-Section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance, 47, 427-465.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04398.x
[14] Carhart, R.S. (1970) On the Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance. Journal of Finance, 52, 57-82.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1997.tb03808.x
[15] Christopherson, J.A., Ferson, W. and Glassman, D.A. (1998) Conditioning Manager Alpha on Economic Information:
Another Look at the Persistence of Performance. Journal of Portfolio Management, 5, 4-12.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/11.1.111
[16] Coggins, F., Beaulieu, M.C. and Gendron, M. (2009) Mutual Fund Daily Conditional Performance Evaluation. Journal
of Financial Research, 32, 95-122. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01244.x
438