0% found this document useful (0 votes)
28 views36 pages

2.3 Capital Regulation

Uploaded by

杨淇
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
28 views36 pages

2.3 Capital Regulation

Uploaded by

杨淇
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 36

Capital Regulation

Financial Intermediation

Sergio Vicente
0. Why do banks want high leverage?
Tax bene…ts

I Tax savings because interest on deposits are generally


tax-deductible whereas dividends to shareholders are not
Managerial preference for ROE

I Executive compensation based on ROE

I Leverage increases ROE, albeit at the expense of reducing


the market equity value because of increased risk

I Deposits/debt are cheaper (deposit insurance not


well-priced/implicit or explicit bail-out guarantees) and
therefore leverage increases the return on equity
D
rE = rL + (rE rD ) (1 τC ) > rL
E
Government safety nets

I Safety nets such as deposit insurance (or implicit bailouts)


subsidize deposits (or debt, in general)

I Safety nets prevents the appropriate pricing of risk entailed


by increasing leverage:

I If deposits were not insured, depositors would require a


higher return to compensate them for the risk of losing
deposits

I If there were not implicit guarantees, debt investors (those


that lend to banks) would require higher rates of return to
compensate them for the risk of not repayment

I Proper pricing would reduce the incentive to increase


leverage
Remark: Which value increases?

I Tax bene…ts increase the value of the bank


I The bank pay less taxes, which would otherwise go to the
Government

I Government safety nets increase the value of the bank


I The bank gets an implicit subsidy in the form of cheaper
deposits and debt that in the absence of guarantees
I The Government bears the cost by supporting the guarantees

I Leverage increases the value of bank’s equity, not the value


of the bank
I Leverage increases the value of equity at the expense of the
depositors, who get rewarded through a low rate (rate on
deposits) even though the rate of return on loans is higher
1. The case for capital regulation
1.1 Reducing risk: Skin in the game and risk-shifting
Two projects

I Consider the following two projects:

I Safe: Invest $100 and obtain $140 for certain

I Risky: Invest $100 and obtain $300 with probability 0.25 and
$0 otherwise
Expected value of projects

I What is the expected value of each project?

I Safe: 140 100 = $40

I Risky: 0.25 300 100 = $25


Pro…t of projects when …nanced with deposits

I Suppose that the bank is funded with deposits in its entirety,


rewarded at rD

I What is the pro…t from each project?

I Safe:

140 100 (1 + rD )
= 40 100 rD

I Risky:

0.25 [300 100 (1 + rD )]


= 50 25 rD
Observations

I Risky is more pro…table (75% of the times the downside is


paid by depositors/deposit insurance)

I The higher the interest rate on deposits, the lower the bank’s
pro…t (self-explanatory!)

I The e¤ect of interest rates on pro…ts is more accentuated for


the safe project (interest rates are not paid 75% of the times in
the case of the risky project)
Pro…t of projects with a funding mix of deposits and
capital
I Suppose that the bank is funded with deposits rewarded at rD
and (external) capital, rewarded at rE rD

I What is the pro…t from each project?

I Safe:
140 (100 k ) (1 + rD ) k (1 + rE )
= 40 100 rD k (rE rD )

I Risky:
0.25 [300 (100 k) (1 + rD )] k (1 + rE )
2 3
6 7
= 50 25 rD k 4 (rE rD ) + 0.75 (1 + rD )5
| {z } | {z }
Costlier capital Downside
Observation I

I Capital erodes pro…ts (because 75% of the times a share k


the downside is paid by equityholders–also, rE > rD leads to
an additional loss, but observe that even if rE = rD , capital
always erodes pro…ts as long as the failure event has positive
probability)

I Banks would be willing to set capital to zero, that is k = 0


Observation II

I Capital favors the safe project: The factor


0.75 (1 + rD )–the downside e¤ect– is only paid in the risky
project

I Safe project is preferable for


13.33 + 100rD
k k
1 + rD

I Remark: The higher rD , the higher the capital requirement to


induce safety (the reward on deposits is most often paid for
the safe project, making the risky project relatively more
interesting
Which capital requirement?
I There is a social cost of capital requirements (imposing
capital on banks reduces the extent of the main banking
function: the (qualitative asset) transformation of illiquid
loans into liquid deposits)

I Each additional unit of capital entails a (shadow, social) cost ρ

I Clearly, the optimal capital requirement is either k = 0 or


13.33 +100rD
k=k 1 +r D

I A capital requirement larger than k is wasteful because capital


is costly and the bank chooses the safe project for any such
capital requirements

I A capital requirement in between 0 and k is wasteful because


capital is costly and the bank chooses the risky project for any
such capital requirements
Social welfare function

I What is the social welfare from each project?

I Safe:
40
|{z} k ρ
| {z }
NPV Social cost of capital

I The rest of the elements in the bank’s pro…t function is


transfers among agents (as long as the Social Planner regards
equityholders and depositors equally, as we usually assume)

I Risky:
25 k ρ
|{z} | {z }
NPV Social cost of capital
Social welfare function
I What is the social welfare from each capital requirement?

I
13.33 +100rD
k= 1 +r D (induces the safe project, at a social cost):

13.33 + 100rD
40 ρ
1 + rD

I k = 0 (induces the risky project):

25

I As long as
65 (1 + rD )
ρ
13.33 + 100rD
a positive capital requirement improves welfare
Social cost of capital?

I In practice, hard to tell what the social cost of capital is

I Under which circumstances are deposits–and, more generally,


the banking function–valuable?

I Under which circumstances capital may be socially more


costly? (capital scarcity in recessions implies that capital is
more costly than in expansions?)

I These are open questions, but the bottom line is that capital
requirements favors banks’safety but it entails a social
cost

I Capital regulation should deal with this tradeo¤


"appropriately"
Risk-shifting generally

I More generally, banks choose their risk level facing a


risk-return tradeo¤

I The bank would typically choose an ine¢ ciently high level


of risk, as compared to the social optimum

I This is due to the fact that the bank does not internalize
the losses associated with a failure: limited liability bounds
the losses to 0
Role for regulation

I Capital requirements improve social welfare because of an


ine¢ ciency: the bank does not internalize the cost
in‡icted on society when failing

I Limited liability and (inappropriately priced, because of


deposit insurance) debt-type funding induce this ine¢ ciency

I By reducing the wedge between the bank’s private


bene…t and society’s goals –hence an alignment of private
and social preferences-, capital requirements improve upon
social welfare
1.2 Preventing bank failures: Capital as a bu¤er
Capital as a bu¤er
I Consider a bank with:

I Stochastic returns with distribution:


R F Rlow , Rhigh

I Debt with face value D

I The bank becomes insolvent when R < D, that is, with


probability F (D )

I If the bank buys-back debt with equity, so that new debt


becomes D 0 = D K , now the bank becomes insolvent when
R < D 0 , that is, with probability F (D 0 ) < F (D )

I By reducing debt to D 0 , the bank can now (additionally!)


survive the events in which its returns R fall in the interval
[D 0 , D ], hence increasing the probability of bank’s survival
Capital as a bu¤er: An example
I Consider a bank with:

R Unif [0, 300]

I Bank raises k and 100 k in capital and in debt/deposits,


respectively

I Bank defaults if R < (100 k) (1 + rD ) D̂ (k )

I The probability of insolvency is given by:

D̂ (k ) (100 k ) (1 + rD )
PI (k ) Pr R < D̂ (k ) = =
300 300

I The probability of insolvency is decreasing in k (for rD = 0.05:


PI (0) = 0.35 , PI (20) = 0.28, PI (100) = 0)
The bu¤er case for capital requirements

I Capital reduces the probability of insolvency, but simply


by changing the nature of funding to the bank (from debt
to equity)

I Essentially, there is no risk reduction, but simply a change in


the type of investor that su¤er the losses (from debt-holders
–i.e. depositors- to equity-holders –i.e. the bank’s owners)

I Which is the gain from simply changing who su¤ers the loss?

I By reducing the likelihood of insolvency, there is a gain if


insolvency per se is socially costly because of panics,
contagion, side e¤ects,. . .

I Remind that capital is costly!


Why are defaults socially costly?
I Disruption costs (bail-ins)

I Investors may run on their investments (contagion)

I Investors may not invest at all (credit crunch, freeze,. . . )

I Tax-payers money (bail-outs)

I Shadow cost of public funds (less public investment, less


redistribution, distortionary taxes,. . . )

I Redistribution of bank losses to society at large


I Remark: A bail-out is a transfer which, as such, does not carry
any social cost per se for a utilitarian social welfare maximizer;
however, we may think that it is costly to transfer resources
from the average citizen to bank’s equityholders on equality
grounds
Are equityholders ready to absorb losses?

I Equityholders are investors whose return depends on the


bank earnings: If earnings are high, their return is high; if
pro…ts are low, their returns are low

I Bank insolvency is a state that equityholders (must!)


consider when investing, in which case their equity value gets
wiped out

I Unlike debtholders (especially depositors), who expect to get


their promised return back, equityholders are ready to
asume this loss
1.3 Reducing debt-overhang
Debt overhang

I Debt overhang: A …rm may pass on a positive NPV


investment instead of issuing equity to fund it because by
funding it may reduce the value of equity (since a large
share of the value created accrues to debtholders)

I This is typically the case when the …rm has a large share of
debt

I Food for thought: How leveraged are …nancial institutions?


An example of debt-overhang
The problem

I $70 owed to bondholders

I Payo¤ distribution: $100 w.p 0.5 and $0 otherwise

I The expected value of this gamble is $50

I Opportunity invest $20 to turn the project payo¤ into $75 w.p
1

I Should the …rm do it?


To invest or not to invest?

I A positive NPV investment:

$75 $50 $20 = $5


|{z} |{z} |{z}
New project value Old project (expected) value Cost

I Equity value from not investing:

0.5 (100 70) = $15

I Equity value from investing:

75 70 20 = $15
Why is a positive NPV opportunity missed?

I Most of the value of this (positive NPV) investment accrues


to the debtholder so that the …rm does not have an incentive
to invest
Aside: renegotiating debt

I Should debtholders accept a (50%) haircut to reduce their


debt claim from $70 to $35?

I Value of debt from no renegotiation:

0.5 70 = $35
Aside: renegotiating debt

I Value of debt from renegotiation:

I If the …rm does not invest, it would now get:

0.5 (100 35) = $32.5

I If the …rm invests, it would now get:

75 20 35 = $20

I Hence, the value of debt from renegotiation is smaller:

0.5 35 = $17.5 < $35


What about renegotiation with conditional aid to invest?
I Consider the following renegotiation package: Debtholders
provide $20 to invest and reduce their debt claim from $70 to
$55 (if you want, think of $55.0001)
I Notice that debtholders would then collect $55 for certain,
therefore getting–after subtracting the investmentof $20–a
return of $35

I Equity value from not investing:


0.5 (100 70) = $15

I Equity value from investing now:


75 55 = $20 > $15

I By letting the …rm cash the NPV of the project, the


investment can be undertaken

You might also like