Demand and Slutsky Equation: Varian: Intermediate Microeconomics, 8e, Chapters 6 and 8
Demand and Slutsky Equation: Varian: Intermediate Microeconomics, 8e, Chapters 6 and 8
() 1 / 51
Demand
() 2 / 51
Introduction
() 3 / 51
Changes in Income
A rise in income shifts the budget line out.
Normal good – increase in income increases demand (Figure 6.1):
∆x1
> 0.
∆m
Inferior good – increase in income decreases demand (Figure 6.2):
∆x1
< 0.
∆m
Examples of inferior goods: nearly any kind low quality good like gruel,
bologna, shacks.
() 4 / 51
() 5 / 51
() 6 / 51
Changes in Income (cont’d)
As income changes, the optimal choice moves along the income offer
curve or income expansion path.
The relationship between the optimal choice and income, with prices fixed,
is called the Engel curve.
() 7 / 51
Examples: Perfect Substitutes
Suppose that p1 < p2 : Consumer is specializing in consuming good 1 =⇒
horizontal income offer curve.
() 8 / 51
Examples: Perfect Complements
() 9 / 51
Examples: Cobb-Douglas Preferences
For u(x1 , x2 ) = x1a x21−a , the demand for good 1 x1 = am/p1
and the demand for good 2 is x2 = (1 − a)m/p2 .
(1−a)p1
The income offer curve is a straight line: x2 = ap2 x1 .
() 10 / 51
Examples: Homothetic Preferences
The consumer has homothetic preferences, if the demand for good goes
up by the same proportion as income. Or if (x1 , x2 ) (y1 , y2 ), then
(tx1 , tx2 ) (ty1 , ty2 ) for any positive value of t.
If the consumer has homothetic preferences, the income offer curves and
Engel curves are straight lines. Thus perfect substitutes, perfect
complements and Cobb-Douglas are homothetic preferences.
() 11 / 51
Examples: Quasilinear Preferences
The indifference curves shift in a parallel way. =⇒ It is tangent to the
budget line at a bundle (x1∗ , x2∗ ), then another indifference curve must be
tangent at (x1∗ , x2∗ + k) for any constant k.
Real-life example: choice between single good that is a small part of the
consumer’s budget (e.g. salt or toothpaste) and all other goods.
() 12 / 51
Changes in Price
Changes in price lead to a tilts or pivots of the budget line.
Ordinary good – decrease in price increases demand (see Figure 6.9):
∆x1
< 0.
∆p1
Giffen good – decrease in price decreases demand (see Figure 6.10):
∆x1
> 0.
∆p1
Intuituion behind Giffen good: Suppose you consume a little of meat and a
lot of potatoes. A reduction of price of potatoes gives you extra money for
meat. Then you might need less potatoes.
() 13 / 51
() 14 / 51
() 15 / 51
Changes in Prices (cont’d)
As price changes the optimal choice moves along the price offer curve.
The relationship between the optimal choice and a price, with income and
the other price fixed, is called the demand curve.
() 16 / 51
Examples: Perfect Substitutes
The demand function for good 1 is
m/p1 when p1 < p2 ;
x1 = any number between 0 and m/p1 when p1 = p2 ;
0 when p1 > p2 .
() 17 / 51
Examples: Perfect Complements
Consumed in fixed proportions =⇒ price offer curve is a straight line.
() 18 / 51
Examples: Discrete Goods
Reservation price rn – price where consumer is just indifferent between
consuming and not consuming unit n of good.
For the price r1 the utility from 0 and 1 units is the same:
u(0, m) = u(1, m − r1 ).
() 19 / 51
Examples: Discrete Goods (cont’d)
Special case: quasilinear preferences u(x1 , x2 ) = v (x1 ) + x2 .
() 20 / 51
Substitutes and Complements
Blue and red pencils are perfect subsitutes, what about pencils and pens?
Substitutes – increase in p2 increases demand for x1 :
∆x1
> 0.
∆p2
Left and right shoes are perfect complements, what about shoes and
socks?
Complements – increase in p2 decreases demand for x1 :
∆x1
< 0.
∆p2
() 21 / 51
The Inverse Demand Curve
Usually think of demand curve as measuring quantity as a function of price
– e.g. the Cobb-Douglas demand for good 1 is x1 = am/p1 .
() 22 / 51
The Inverse Demand Curve: Economic Interpretation
How many dollars is the consumer willing to give up for one additional unit
of good 1.
() 23 / 51
Summary
() 24 / 51
Slutsky Equation
() 25 / 51
Slutsky Equation
We want a way to decompose the effect of a price change into “simpler”
pieces.
That’s what analysis is all about – break up into simple pieces to
determine behavior of whole.
With this analytical tool, we will be able to answer the following questions:
• Does a reduction in price always increase the demand for the good?
What if we have a Giffen good?
• Does an increase in wage induce people to work more? What if the
wage increases from $10 to $100 an hour? What if it increases from
$100 to $10.000 an hour?
() 26 / 51
Slutsky Equation (con’t)
Break up price change into a pivot and a shift.
These are hypothetical changes. We can examine each change in isolation
and look at sum of two changes.
() 27 / 51
The Pivoted Line
The pivoted line has the same slope (relative prices) like the final budget
line, but the purchasing power is adjusted so that the original consumption
bundle (x1 , x2 ) is just affordable.
How much we have to adjust the income to keep (x1 , x2 ) just affordable?
() 28 / 51
The Pivoted Line (con’t)
Let m0 be the income that will make (x1 , x2 ) just affordable and p10 the
final price of good 1. Then
m0 = p10 x1 + p2 x2 .
m = p1 x1 + p2 x2 .
∆m = x1 ∆p1 .
()
∆m = 20 × 0.1 = $2.00. 29 / 51
Slutsky Substitution Effect
() 30 / 51
() 31 / 51
Sign of the Substitution Effect
The bundles on the pivoted budget line to the left of X (with less of
good 1 than x1 ) were affordable at the old prices.
If the consumer chooses the best bundles he can afford, then X must be
preferred to all the bundles on the pivoted line inside the original budget
set (revealed preference).
() 32 / 51
Example: Calculating the Substitution Effect
Now the price of milk falls to p10 = $2 per quart. The demand for milk is
10 + 120/(10 × 2) = 16 quarts per week.
() 33 / 51
Income Effect
This measures the change in demand for good 1 when we change the
income from m0 to m and keep the prices constant at (p10 , p2 ):
∆x1n = x1 (p10 , m) − x1 (p10 , m0 ).
Income effect is negative for normal goods (a rise in price reduces the
income which reduces the demand) and positive for inferior good.
() 34 / 51
() 35 / 51
The Total Change in Demand
Total change in demand is substitution effect plus the income effect. This
equation is called Slutsky indentity:
If good is normal, the substitution effect and the income effect are
negative. The total effect is negative.
If good is inferior, the substitution effect is negative and the income effect
is positive. The total effect is ambiguous (see Figure 8.3).
() 36 / 51
() 37 / 51
The Rates of Change
If we want to express Slutsky identity in terms rates of change, it is
convenient to define negative income effect:
∆x1m = x1 (p10 , m0 ) − x1 (p10 , m) = −∆x1n .
() 38 / 51
The Law of Demand
The Law of Demand – If the demand for a good increases when income
increases, then the demand for that good must decrease when its price
increases.
Follows directly from the Slutsky equation:
• If demand increases when income increases, it is a normal good.
• If we nave a normal good, then the total effect of a price change is
negative.
() 39 / 51
Examples: Perfect Complements
Substitution effect is zero: The entire change in demand is due to income
effect.
() 40 / 51
Examples: Perfect Substitutes
Income effect is zero: The entire change in demand is due to substitution
effect.
() 41 / 51
Examples: Quasilinear Preferences
Quasilinear preferences imply that shift in income causes no change in
demand: The entire change in demand is due to substitution effect.
() 42 / 51
Application: Rabating a Tax
In 1974, OPEC instituted an oil embargo against the US and was able to
stop oil shipments for several weeks.
Critics: Consumers will use the rebated money to purchase more gasoline.
() 43 / 51
Application: Rabating a Tax (cont’d)
Original budget constraint: px + y = m
The consumer will choose less gasoline and more of other goods (see
Figure 8.7).
() 44 / 51
() 45 / 51
Application: Voluntary Real Time Pricing
Electricity producers have extreme capacity problem: easy to produce up
to capacity, impossible to produce more.
Increasing capacities is expensive =⇒ reducing the use of electricity
during peak demand is attractive.
Peak demand due to weather is easy to forecast (in hot weather in Georgia
– 30 % of usage due to air conditioning).
How to set up pricing system so that people have incentives to reduce
consumption in peak demand.
() 46 / 51
Application: Voluntary Real Time Pricing (cont’d)
One solution: Real Time Pricing (RTP)
() 47 / 51
() 48 / 51
The Hicks Substitution Effect
Hicks substitution effect a change in demand for a good due to a change
in the relative prices while keeping the utility of the consumer constant.
() 49 / 51
The Sign of Hicks Substitution Effect
Negative – proof by revealed preferences:
() 51 / 51