Unit 4 Market Structures
Unit 4 Market Structures
Ans. The concept of a market is central to the understanding of the determination of price and quantity
of output of a commodity under consideration. In ordinary language, the term market refers to a public
place in which goods and services are bought and sold. In economics, it has a different meaning.
Different economists have tried to define market in different ways.
Cournot defines market as, “not any particular market place in which things are bought and sold, but the
whole of any region in which buyers and sellers are in such free intercourse with each other that the
prices of the same goods tend to equality easily and quickly”.
To Ely, “Market means the general field within which, the force determining the price of particular
product operate”. Stonier and Hague explain the term market as “any organisation whereby buyers and
sellers of a good are kept in close touch with each other”.
– BUYERS: There should be buyers of the product. If a country consists of people who are very poor,
there can hardly be market for luxuries like cars, VCR etc.
– SELLER: A commodity should be offered for sale in the market. Otherwise there is no question of
buying the commodity. Therefore, existence of sellers is a necessity for any market.
– CONTACT: Buyers and sellers should have close contact with each other.
The exchange of commodities between buyers and sellers occurs at a particular price which is mutually
agreeable to both the buyers and sellers. This is because, in a modern economy, most of the production
does not take place for self-consumption by the producers themselves. Thus, by the term market of a
good, it should not be taken to mean a place where the buyers and sellers meet each other and conduct
purchase and sale transactions.
– A Firm
– An Industry
A firm is a business unit engaged in the task of producing and selling of goods or services. It is identified
by the fact that it is only one unit of entrepreneurship. The entrepreneurship may not be provided by a
single individual. It may be exercised jointly by a board or a group of individuals in some defined
manner. However, the firm has a unified and coordinated authority of decision making. In essence,
these decisions relate to the objectives (such as, profit maximisation, or sales maximisation, etc.) and
other policy decisions (such as, what to produce) of the business unit.
An industry is a set of firms which are conceptually closely associated in the sense of having some
common type(s) of activities. A good example of an industry is a set of firms which are producing a
certain type of a manufactured good or providing a certain type of service. The good supplied by the
firms of the industry may be homogenous in the sense that the buyers believe that products of all firms
are perfect substitutes of each other.
There is no pre-determined number of firms which an industry must have. Their number can vary
according to the structure of the market. At one extreme, it may have only one firm in which case it is
called a monopoly or a one-firm industry. At the other extreme, an industry may have such a large
number of firms that each of them accounts for an extremely small portion of the total supply of the
industry and is not able to influence the price of the product. Between these two extremes, there can
be several other possibilities. There are various kinds of markets prevailing in the economy.
– PERFECT COMPETITION
– MONOPOLY
– MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION
– OLIGOPOLY
2. Oligopoly, in which a market is by a small number of firms that together control the
majority of the market share.
5. Oligopsony, a market in which many sellers can be present but meet only a few
buyers.
Ans.
Perfect Competition Market is a hypothetical market structure where in every seller takes the market
prices as the price of his own product, firms are incapable of influencing the market price either by
acting singly or in a group.
Perfect Competition in economic theory has a meaning diametrically opposite to the everyday use of the
term. In practice, businessmen use the word competition as synonymous to rivalry. In theory, Perfect
Competition implies no rivalry among firms. Perfect Competition, therefore, can be defined as a market
structure characterized by complete absence of rivalry among the individual firms. That is to say perfect
competition is a market structure where there is a perfect degree of competition and single price
prevails.
Main Features
Or
Q3. Explain price and output determination of a firm under perfect competition.
Ans.
(Note- First describe the characteristics of Perfect Competition firm given above)
Under perfect competition, the firms are unable to alter the price of the product by changing the
quantity of its own output. The prices of the input are given; therefore, cost conditions are also given. In
other words, under perfect competition, it can only decide to alter the quantity of its output without
changing price of the product.
A firm is said to be in equilibrium when its profits are maximum, which in lieu depends on the cost and
revenue conditions of the firm. The concepts of cost and revenue vary in short run and long run. Thus a
competitive firm has four equilibrium states differing on the basis of period of operation as follows:
Under the short run period, the following are the major assumptions;
– Price of product is given in the market at which a firm can sell any quantity
1. (Profit) π= TR less TC or
2. at a point where MR equates MC.
Since a perfectly competitive firm is a price taker, it is faced with a straight line demand curve i.e. AR is
parallel to X axis as its Marginal Revenue (MR).
Given the assumption of profit maximization by the firm, it will be in equilibrium when there is no scope
for either increasing its profit income or reducing its loss by changing the quantity of output. It cannot
improve its economic position by changing the output.
Equilibrium of a Firm using TR and TC Curves
Therefore, in short run since prices are given, the TR curve is a straight line through the origin O as
shown in the figure. Its slope is positive and equal to the price of the product and Average Revenue (AR).
In the short run, a firm has to incur both fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are there even when the
output is reduced to zero. As a result, total cost (TC) curve starts from Y-axis at a positive distance from
origin O. Assuming that fixed costs are OF, the TC curve starts from point F on the Y-axis. The short run
average cost curve (SAC) is U-Shaped. The total cost curve in the figure is represented by TC.
Thus, OM is the equilibrium output of the firm in the short run under perfect competition. At any other
output, its total profit is less than PE. It is also noted that if the output is reduced to OM’ or increased to
OM”, the profit of the firm is reduced to zero. Further, for output less than OM’ or greater than OM”, TC
exceeds TR and results in a loss for the firm. The conditions of profit maximisation (or loss minimization)
can be translated into what are known as marginal conditions. Thus profit, = TR - TC is maximized if
As regards the supply side, the set of four cost curves of the firm, namely, the AFC, the AVC, the MC and
the ATC. Out of these, the supply curve of the firm is that portion of the MC curve which lies above AVC
curve and is upward sloping. The actual equilibrium of the firm is determined by the intersection of its
supply and demand curves. An explanation of this phenomenon is provided below.
In the short run, the firm cannot avoid fixed costs. They have to be incurred even if production is
reduced to zero. However, the variable costs are directly related to the quantity of output. The
implication is that, in the short run, the firm cannot avoid losses by not producing. Therefore, it decides
to continue production even at a loss, provided the loss does not exceed its fixed costs. It means that
the firm would decide to produce if its average price (that is, per unit price of the good) equals or
exceeds its AVC.
On account of the law of variable proportions, the average variable cost curve is U-shaped. Marginal
cost represents a change in the total cost so that it is related only to the variable costs and not fixed
costs. And since AVC curve is U-shaped, MC curve is also U-shaped. It lies below AVC curve when the
latter is downward sloping. However, MC curve starts rising when the rate of fall in AVC curves slows
down, intersects it at its lowest point, and rises above it.
A firm attains its best possible position (that is, the position of maximum profit or minimum loss) when
its MC curve cuts its MR curve from below. At the same time, price per unit of the product must be able
to recover at least the average variable cost. When the price exceeds AVC, the firm is able to recover a
part of its fixed costs also with a resultant reduction in its losses. In case the price equals the average of
total cost, the firm is able to recover its full costs (including the component of ‘normal profit’). And if the
price is still higher, it earns an abnormal profit.
Thus, in determination of short term equilibrium of the firm, two conditions should be satisfied:
1. When the price is OP0 , the corresponding MR0 curve cuts MC curve at two points, A and B. At point A,
none of the above-stated two conditions of equilibrium is satisfied. At point B, MC curve cuts MR 0 curve
from below but the second condition is not satisfied. AR is still less than AVC. Therefore, the firm incurs
a loss greater than its fixed cost if it decides to produce when the price is OP0 . The firm, therefore,
decides to close down but it cannot leave the industry.
2. If the price happens to be higher and equal to OP1 (that is, equal to the least possible average variable
cost), the firm decides to produce. In this case, not only MC curve cuts MR 1 curve from below (a point
C); AR1 is also equal to AVC. Thus, we find that either the firm does not produce at all, or it produces at
least equal to OM1 .
3. In the third case, price (OP2) exceeds AVC but is still less than ATC. MR2 and MC curves intersect each
other at point D. The firm produces OM2 . It still incurs a loss but less than its fixed costs because it is
able to recover a portion of the latter.
4. In case the price rises to OP3 , the firm is able to recover its full cost including fixed costs. Its MC curve
cuts MR3 curve from below at point E and AR3 = ATC. All the conditions of its equilibrium are satisfied. It
produces OM3 .
5. If the price rises even further, say, P4 , the point of intersection of MR4 and MC curves moves to F. The
firm is able to recover not only its total cost but is able to earn an abnormal profit also. It produces OM 4.
In the short run, existing firms can close down but they cannot leave the industry and new ones cannot
enter it. Therefore, when our firm is incurring a loss, it continues production so long, its’ loses do not
exceed fixed costs. Similarly, if it earns an abnormal profit, they are not wiped out by new firms entering
the industry.
Since the firm can vary all its inputs in the long run, it follows that it has the option to close down and
leave the industry. Similarly, new firms can also enter the industry. This condition, termed ‘free entry
and exit of firms’ has two implications.
– The firm is not compelled to operate when incurring a loss. It can leave the industry
– No firm is able to earn an abnormal profit (that is, a profit in excess of the ‘normal‘one). It can only
earn ‘normal profit’ which forms a part of its costs and is incorporated in its LRAC curve. This happens
because abnormal profit earned by existing firms attracts new firms. And as they enter the industry,
supply increases, price comes down and abnormal profit is wiped out.
Two conditions have to be satisfied for the firm to be in state of long run equilibrium.
– AR AC, so that the firm does not incur a loss and close down. In practice, however, on account of
free entry and exit of firms, AR cannot exceed AC and is equal to the latter
Determination of long run equilibrium of the firm under perfect competition is explained in Fig. in which
output is measured along X-axis and costs are measured along Y-axis.
The firm is a price taker. For it the price of its product is given and fixed.
Its AR curve runs parallel to X-axis and MR curve coincides with it.
For the purpose of explaining the determination of firm’s equilibrium, we are considering three
alternative prices given to the firm by the industry.
In long run equilibrium, the firm produces an ‘optimum’ output at the least possible average cost. It is
this position where the firm is operating under ‘constant returns’ to scale. Consequently, its MC = AC. At
the same time, MC = MR and AR = AC , so that we get AC = AR = MC = MR.
Q4. Explain how the equilibrium of the industry is determined under Perfect Competition?
Or
Q4. Explain price and output determination of industry under perfect competition.
Answer:
An industry comprises all the firms which are producing goods which the buyers consider substitutes of
each other. As such the determination of price of such a product is the result of interaction between
total demand for the output of all the firms taken together and their supply
On the demand side, the important fact to be noted is that a change in its supply affects the price of the
product also. The industry is not a price taker. Though the contribution of an individual firm in total
supply is so insignificant that it cannot make any noticeable difference to the price of the product, this is
not so with the industry. The change in supply made by the firms taken together alters the aggregate
supply to such an extent that it cannot sell more without lowering the price. This results in a downward
sloping demand curve for the industry.
The fact of a negatively sloped demand curve for the industry can also be understood as follows. A firm
can sell more of its output by attracting customers from its competing firms. In the process, the total
sales of the industry need not increase. But an industry can sell more when the existing buyers buy more
of its product and/or new buyers enter the market and buy its product. Now it follows that existing
buyers are already equating their marginal utility with the price. They would buy more only if price falls.
Similarly, for the new buyers, the existing price is higher than the marginal utility of the product. And,
therefore, they would also buy more of the good only if the price is reduced. Accordingly, the demand
curve for the product of the firm must have a negative slope indicating that more of the product can be
sold only by reducing its price.
The exact location and slope of the demand curve varies from product to product and also for the same
product from one time interval to the other. There can also be several reasons on account of which its
demand curve may shift in its slope and location. However, there is no theoretical basis for predicting
these changes. Therefore, even while recognising that demand curve for a product can and often does
shift over time, the economists assume that it retains its position when we move from short term to
long term. In other words, demand curve for the industry is always drawn with a negative slope without
specifically providing for a change in either its exact slope or its exact location.
When an industry changes the quantity of its supply, there is a corresponding change in the price of its
product also. It follows, therefore, that when it is in equilibrium, there is no tendency on its part to
change the quantity of its output. We also know that the price of the industry’s product is determined
by intersection of its demand and supply curves. Having seen the nature of industry’s demand curve, we
may look into the nature of its supply curve which is obviously the summation of individual supply
curves of the firms constituting it. That is to say, we get the industry’s supply curve by adding the
quantities which its firms are ready to sell at alternative prices. Since the supply curve of a firm, in the
short run, is that upward sloping portion of its marginal cost curve which lies above its average variable
cost curve, therefore, the supply curve of the industry also is upward sloping.
DD is demand curve and SS is
supply curve. The intersection
of both curves at E is the
equilibrium of a competitive
industry.
The slope of the demand curve of industry remains negative even in the long run, implying that it can
sell more of the product only by reducing the price and vice versa.
However, the long run supply curve of the industry cannot be derived by horizontal summation of the
supply curves of the individual firms. The reason is that in the long run, existing firms can leave the
industry and new ones can join it. Moreover, it is possible that due to various reasons, the industry may
suffer from some internal/ external diseconomies or enjoy some economies. These factors can shift the
position of the long term supply curve of the industry. Another fact which complicates the derivation of
long run supply curve of the industry is that while in the short run, individual firms may incur losses or
enjoy abnormal profit, in the long run, these possibilities tend to be wiped out. When the industry is in
equilibrium, its individual firms are also simultaneously in such equilibrium that they neither make an
abnormal profit nor incur a loss.
Thus, long run supply curve of the industry is derived by taking into account all these determining
variables. It is not derived by adding those portions of the MC curves of the individual firms which lie
above the AC curves of the firms. Instead it is the locus of the pairs of those points which represent
quantities of its output and the least average cost at which its firms can produce it.
Economists believe that the factors at work in the long run may result in one of the three situations,
namely, that of diminishing, constant, and increasing returns, indicating the shift in the average cost of
its firms. These three cases are explained below.
In Fig. 4.6, the supply curve of the industry is SS’ and its demand curve is DD1 . The two intersect at
point E1 with OM1 and E1M1 as equilibrium output and price respectively. At the same time, all the
firms of the industry are also at equilibrium such that for each firm, its MC = MR = AC = AR and it
operates at the least possible average cost. As a result, there is no incentive for any firm to leave the
industry or enter it.
Fig. 4.6 also depicts the alternative equilibrium position if demand curve happens to be differently
located. It is seen that shifting of the demand curve does not result in a change in price. It only results in
a change in the quantity of supply.
Diminishing Returns
Let us assume that when existing firms of an industry expand their output, their average cost of
production increases. Similarly, let us assume that if new firms enter the industry, they also face higher
average product cost. This implies that the expansion of the industry generates more diseconomies than
economies and the net result is an increase in the average cost of production. The supply curve of the
industry, therefore, slopes upwards and implies that the industry will be ready to sell more only if the
price offered increases.
Increasing Returns
In this case, the average cost of production of the industry declines with its expansion and its supply
curve has a negative slope.
What is Monopoly? How price and output determination is done in monopoly?
Answer
Q. Explain the concept of Discriminating Monopoly. What are the various degrees of discrimination.
Explain.
Q Explain Monopolistic Competition. Discuss its salient features.
Answer
Explain equilibrium of the firm under monopolistic competition.
Answer
Oligopoly refers to a market wherein only a few firms account for most or all of total production.