Input Output Models
Input Output Models
Sandip Sarkar
Department of Economics and Finance, BITS Pilani KK Birla Goa Campus, Goa, India.
1 Preliminaries
We assume that there are n (n > 1) industries such that each industries output is used
by other industries as inputs. Furthermore, a part of the output may also goes to the
market as final demand in an open sector (say domestic demand). Wassiely Leontief was
interested in the following question:
Question 1. What level of output each of the n industries produce, in order that it will
be just sufficient to satisfy the total demand of the product?
Assumption 2. Each industry uses a fixed input ratio or factor combinations in the
production process.
The three assumptions enables us to ensures that in order to produce one unit of
the j th commodity, the input required for the ith commodity is a constant, which will be
denoted as aij . Thus for production of one unit of good ‘j ’ we need a1j units of good 1 as
input. We also need a2j of good 2, a3j of good 3,.., anj of good n as inputs for producing
good j.
Note that we always denote aij is how much the ith commodity is used for producing 1
unit of the j th commodity. We assume that prices are given and consider dollar as the unit
∗ Email id: [email protected]
1
of the output. Hence, aij is the value of commodity i required as input required to produce
1 unit of commodity j. For example, if steel industry (industry s) produces output worth
1000$ and uses 100$ of coal (industry c) as inputs, then acs = 100/1000 = 0.1. You can
consider acs either as unit free, or consider in dollar. For example, 0.1 dollar (10 cents)
of coal is required to produce 1 dollar worth steel. Or you may also interpret that 10%
of the output of steel is required for the purchasing coal as inputs. For an n industry
economy the input coefficients can be arranged in a matrix as follows:
a11 a12 a13 · · · a1n
a21 a22 a23 · · · a2n
A= .
.. .. ..
(1)
.. . . ··· .
an1 an2 an3 · · · ann
Formally aij is defined as the amount of input from industry i required to produce 1
dollar worth of steel. The j th column of the matrix A may also be interpreted as inputs
of different commodities required for production of 1 unit of commodity j (or 1 dollar
worth of commodity j). The elements in the principal diagonal of the matrix A (i..e, aii is
nothing but the input demand for good i required for producing 1 unit of good i). Thus
it is the portion of the output that is used as inputs for itself.
2
x1 = a11 x1 + a12 x2 + ... + a1n xn + d1 (2)
In terms of matrix notation we can rewrite the above set of equations as follows:
(I − A)x = d (4)
x∗ = (I − A)−1 d (5)
We now illustrate how we can solve for x∗ in the following numerical example.
d1 x1
d2 x2
1
More specifically, d = . and x = . . Note that the order of LHS and RHS of equation 4 is
.. ..
dn xn
n × 1. Other formulations like x(I − A) will have matrix conformability error.
3
Problem 1. Consider the flowchart below of an input-out model for three industries:
railways, coal, and electricity. We denote railways these three industries as industry 1,
2, and 3, respectively. Write the input matrix, Leontief matrix, and solve for x∗ .
3 Hawkins-Simons condition
Note that all elements of the vector x∗ must be non-negative. Otherwise such solutions
is not economically feasible. Now, non-singularity of the Leontief matrix, ensures ex-
istence of x∗ . However, we need to incorporate additional restrictions to ensure that
∀i ∈ {1, 2, .., n}: we have x∗i ≥ 0 are non-negative. Hawkins-Simons provides a condition
which is necessary and sufficient for non-negative x∗i . The condition is formally stated
below:
1. n×n matrix B such that all off-diagonal elements are negative, i.e, bij ≤ 0 whenever
i ̸= j.
2. n × 1 vector d, such that all the elements are non-negative (i.e., ∀i ∈ {1, 2, .., n} we
have di ≥ 0).
4
3. For any vector x∗ we have Bx∗ = d.
All elements of x∗ is non-negative if and only if the leading principal minors of the
matrix B are positive.
Note that if we define B = I − A, then it is easy to check that all the off-diagonal
elements are negative. Thus Hawkins-Simon condition provides a necessary and sufficient
condition for all elements of x∗ defined in 5 to be non-negative.
In linear algebra, a minor of any matrix M is the determinant of some smaller square
matrix, by cutting cutting down the ith row and j th column of the matrix, where i and j
not necessarily the same. If i = j, the the underlying minor is referred as the principal
b11 b12 b13
minor. For example, for any B = b21 b22 b23 , the simultaneous deletion of three ith
b31 b32 b33
b11 b12 b11 b13
row and column, we have the following three principal minors: , , and
b21 b22 b31 b33
b22 b23
.
b32 b33
Since these matrices are of order 2 × 2 we refer this as first order principal matrix.
Similarly, we can generate first order principal minors by deleting any two rows and
columns, where b11 , b22 , and b33 . The third order principal minor for matrix B is |B|
itself.
The set of principal matrices that are naturally ordered are referred as the leading
principal minors. For the matrix B, we have the following three leading principal minors:
b11 b12
B = b11 B2 = and B3 = |B|.
b21 b22
Problem 2. Find all the principal minors and the leading principal minors of the fol-
x11 x12 x13 x14
x21 x22 x23 x24
lowing 4 × 4matrix: X =
x31 x32 x33 x34
x41 x42 x43 x44
5
Here is the solution for the leading principal minors.
NB: For Hawkins-Simion condition we need to concentrate only on Leading
principal minors.
Recall that the Hawkins-Simon condition states that the output vector (i..e, x∗ ) is positive
whenever all the leading principal minors of the Leontief matrix (i.e., |I −A|) are positive.
For the sake of interpretation we consider a n = 2, and thus we have
1 − a11 −a12
I −A= (6)
−a21 1 − a22
Now the first leading principal minor is 1 − a11 , and 1 − a11 > 0 =⇒ a11 < 1. The
second leading principal minor is |I − A| > 0 =⇒ (1 − a11 )(1 − a22 ) − a12 a21 > 0. The
last condition can be further expressed as
6
Now we already have (1 − a11 a22 ) ≥ 0, hence, we must have
Economically a11 means that the direct use of the first commodity as input for the
first commodity itself. Interestingly a12 a21 is the indirect use of the first commodity as
input for the first commodity. This is because the first industry is giving a fraction a12 to
second industry. In return the first industry gets a21 as inputs from the second industry.
Thus a part of the output send to industry 2 comes back to industry 1, and eventually
we have the indirect usage of first commodity as a21 a12 .
Equation 8 implies that the amount of first commodity used as direct and indirect
inputs in producing a dollar worth of the output must be less than 1 dollar. Thus what
Hawkins-Simon condition requires is certain practicability and visibility restrictions in
the production process..
These are the only inputs required for each of these three inputs. Suppose there is no
external demands for fishing boats. Find the gross output for each industries, provided the
external demands for fish and timbers are df and dt , respectively. Illustrate the Hawkins-
Simons condition in this regard.
7
x0 = a01 x1 + a02 x2 + ... + a0n xn
(I − A)x = 0n (10)