Soc Policy Adm - 2018 - Storbjörk - The New Privatized Market A Question of Ideology or Pragmatism Within The Swedish
Soc Policy Adm - 2018 - Storbjörk - The New Privatized Market A Question of Ideology or Pragmatism Within The Swedish
DOI: 10.1111/spol.12414
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
© 2018 The Authors. Social Policy & Administration Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd
KEYWORDS
1 | I N T RO DU CT I O N
Since the late 1980s, health and welfare systems in many Western countries have undergone dramatic changes
regarding modes of production and means of organization and steering. An umbrella term for many of these changes
is New Public Management (NPM). As Hood (1995) shows, NPM has been implemented with various motives and
different emphases in different countries. NPM typically relies on the effectiveness of market‐driven management
models also in the public sector, and on control of the output of public services, rather than of processes.
The spread of NPM is often attributed to the advent of new right governments in the 1980s and particularly to
the influence of Ronald Reagan and Margaret Thatcher, who sought to roll back state welfarism. NPM reforms were
first introduced in English‐speaking countries such as the United States, the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia, and
New Zealand.
However, Sweden has also been placed into the core of NPM countries (Common, 1998; Hood, 1991, 1995; James
& Manning, 1996; Pollitt, 1995). Hood (1995) called Sweden “the most obvious misfit” of NPM seen as an ideology‐
based reform. NPM is at first glance incompatible with a social democratic regime, with big government and a univer-
salistic welfare state. Research has ascribed the impact of market models in Sweden not only to a strengthened role
of the political right, but also to the development within Swedish social democracy itself. In the late 1980s and early
1990s, the Swedish welfare state was criticized for being too bureaucratic, centralized, and paternalistic. From the
1980s, the right, in line with the Anglo‐American trends, propagated market models and privatization in production
as a new welfare vision to shrink the scope and size of the public welfare state. The social democrats, who lost the
1976 elections and came back in 1982, regarded the shrinking legitimacy of the welfare system as their core political
problem. Reform seemed necessary. For the social democrats, municipal steering, with a separation of decisions about
allocations and needs assessment from the production of services (purchasing‐provider models), was an administrative
reform to promote service diversity, citizens' choice, lower costs, and better quality (Stenius, 1999). Already in 1984, the
party program proposed a welfare system built on decentralized decision making and freedom of choice for participating
citizens (still emphasizing universal rights to welfare) (Gingrich, 2011; Klitgaard, 2007). The social democrats also intro-
duced management by results into Swedish administration (Sundström, 2006). The development was further advanced
with different market‐type welfare reforms, also promoted by the social democrats (Green‐Pedersen, 2002).
Sweden had a large, and thus expensive, public sector and a strong central steering of comprehensive services.
As Hood (1995) points out, it had both economic motives and opportunities to effectively implement these new
administrative models. A public procurement legislation was introduced in 1992 (in force as of 1994), later revised
by the Swedish Public Procurement Act (LOU 2007:1091 and LOU 2016:1145), modeled on EU regulations. The
law stipulates that all public purchases above threshold levels be subject to a non‐discriminative procurement
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
778 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
process. Health care and social services are given more leeway, but for some reason, possibly judicial cautiousness,
Sweden has implemented public procurement more rigidly than other European countries also in these sectors
(Ahlberg & Bruun, 2010). In the social service sector, public procurement has often resulted in “framework agree-
ments” between suppliers and the contracting authorities. In 2008, the possibility was introduced to steer the service
system through service users' choice (Act on System of Choice in the Public Sector, 2008:962 [LOV]). This is,
however, a voluntary option for the municipalities, and has so far had little impact on the addiction treatment system
(Storbjörk & Samuelsson, 2018). From the 1990s and increasingly during the 2000s, purchaser‐provider models,
target and performance management, and economization have grown increasingly common in Swedish health and
welfare services (Bertling, 2015; Hartman, 2011; Sallnäs & Wiklund, 2018; Zaremba, 2013b).
Competition with an increasing role for non‐public provision of services—marketization—is a core feature of
NPM (Hood, 1995), and is the focus in this article. Non‐public service providers have had a strong position in Sweden
since the establishment of the alcohol treatment system in the early 1900s (Edman, 2016; Stenius, 1999). After the
Second World War, not‐for‐profit treatment providers were the dominant providers of care. They gradually became
only supplements to a growing municipal and county council public service sector in the heyday of the Swedish wel-
fare state. In the late 1980s the trend changed drastically. Purchaser‐provider models, procurement with competition
between providers, private sector management styles, and decentralized budget responsibility were introduced in
addiction treatment. It resulted in new steering models, but also in a growing number of non‐public providers, now
often incorporated enterprises (Oscarsson, 2000; Sallnäs & Wiklund, 2018; Stenius, 1999). The production of
services no longer took place within a corporatist arrangement, but moved onto a competitive quasi‐market.1
Critique (from the left) has repeatedly been raised against the development. Thus the “privatization of the century”
in 1980s addiction treatment was viewed as an attack against the universalism of the public sector‐dominant welfare
system (SoS‐rapport, 1991). But there were also leftist advocates of market models. After the economic crises in the
1990s, the benefits were emphasized of cost‐efficient public steering with competition and increased user involvement
(Edman, 2016; Oscarsson, 2000; Stenius, 1999). Consequently, market steering models for addiction treatment in the
1990s were already also established in social democratic local governments (Edman, 2016; Stenius, 1999).
The last few years have seen the rise of a highly polarized public debate—with partly new arguments—on the role
of for‐profit providers in the Swedish welfare system. The vast majority of all health and social services in Sweden
remain tax‐funded. However, compared to the 1980s or 1990s, market models no longer appear as neutral roads
to better quality and lower costs. Whereas the total costs for all social services offered by the municipalities
increased by 14% between 2009 and 2013, the costs for such care produced by private enterprises increased by
57% during the same period (Statistics Sweden, 2015, p. 9).
Criticism, again primarily from the left, has pointed to opportunist and revenue‐seeking big, multinational, providers
entering the welfare sector, and that this has had a negative effect on the quality of services for citizens in a weak posi-
tion; there have been no demonstrated cost savings, but rather a draining of tax money (Agerberg, 2014; Government,
2016; Löfven, 2013; SOU, 2002; Zaremba, 2013a). In 2016, an inquiry set up by the Social Democratic–Green govern-
ment (SOU, 2016) noted the increasing share of for‐profit providers in the 2000s. While most of these providers are
small, some are multinational, and some have a very high profit level. The report, supported by social democrats, and
the green and left parties, suggested a profit level ceiling (7%) for private, for‐profit enterprises in the publicly financed
service sector as an attempt to limit the impact of certain for‐profit actors. In the discussion following the report, the
right‐wing and liberal parties defended for‐profit provision of care with similar arguments as in the 1990s: private alter-
natives promote efficiency in service production, improve the quality, staff commitment, and choice for patients
(Stenius & Storbjörk, 2003). The attitudes towards private, for‐profit provision again seem to differ along ideological
lines. Within economy and in “leading‐edge” NPM countries, scholars and officials are now talking about the death of
this management model (Dunleavy, Margetts, Bastow, & Tinkler, 2006). This can partly be linked to the critique of a
new type of privatization and the lack of demonstrated improved economy or outcomes (Hood & Dixon, 2015; Pollitt
& Sorin, 2011). In general, NPM reforms have had a substantial impact on the welfare systems, but are yet poorly stud-
ied. The few studies conducted internationally on performance measurement in addiction treatment indicate some
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 779
improved process outcomes such as shorter waiting lists or larger treatment volumes (Hull & Ritter, 2014; McLellan,
Kemp, Brooks, & Carise, 2008). But the new market models have also led to unintended negative consequences such
as increased fragmentation of treatment systems and less treatment for the most severe cases (Bjerge, 2012; Moore
& Fraser, 2013; Nesvåg & Lie, 2010). The impact on the Swedish addiction treatment system has not been thoroughly
researched (Creutzer, 2014; Wiklund, 2011). Sallnäs and Wiklund (2018) note a clear increase of for‐profit actors during
the 2010s, and a recent study on NPM from the service users' point of view indicates improved choice for a small group
of substance users, but also limited professional discretion and service user involvement (Storbjörk & Samuelsson,
2018). Given the lack of effect studies, decision makers are not well‐equipped to choose adequate steering models.
In the decentralized Swedish addiction treatment system, the main responsibility for organizing, funding, and
providing services, which are based on local needs assessments, is located in the 290 municipalities' social services
administrations. In this, the municipalities are assisted by 21 county councils (responsible for medical addiction treat-
ment). All of them have independent political decision‐making bodies and independent rights to raise and distribute
taxes, and to organize services as they wish (e.g., purchase or deliver in‐house). However, it is only the municipal
social services that have the right to exercise authority in individual treatment decisions, which implies that some
activities cannot be contracted out (see Blomqvist, Palm, & Storbjörk, 2009 on the overall Swedish addiction treat-
ment system). The municipalities have varying political majorities elected every four years. They are also of varying
size, with different and more or less predictable needs for addiction treatment (see Table 2).
Analysis of the municipalities' purchases of addiction treatment services, as opposed to in‐house service produc-
tion, can tell us the extent to which the use of private as opposed to in‐house addiction services over time has been
linked to ideological characteristics within decision‐making bodies—if the recurring leftist critique in the national discus-
sion is mirrored at the local level. Or are other conditions more decisive in a pragmatic choice of service production, fac-
tors such as the size of the community (small municipalities not being able to produce their own treatment, see SOU,
2011), the affluence of its inhabitants, or a general societal norm enforced by legislation on procurement and central
steering? This small and relatively delineated sector of the welfare system (e.g., compared to schools) has previously
been neglected in this respect. Addiction treatment has, as noted, historically had a large share of non‐public service
providers and a tradition of municipal purchasing of primarily residential services. It is also a fairly marginal means‐tested
welfare sector that is not of obvious interest for the middle class as service users. In both these respects it is similar to
child/youth care. But even with its limitations, addiction treatment holds an important position in the Swedish debate
on the distribution of common goods to deserving or undeserving citizens—on the practice of universalism. Based on
the decentralized care system and a large number of local‐level political majorities operating under similar conditions
in one country, our study adds to the knowledge of the role of party politics in the marketization of public services.
1.1 | Aims
This article examines the degree of purchased interventions, particularly for‐profit provision, in this specialized part of
the welfare system since the 1970s and with a special emphasis on 1999–2014. We have charted and analyzed
national and local developments, and more specifically, we analyze: (1) the national development of purchases of
addiction services (size in SEK and share of purchased in‐ and outpatient services from different types of provider)
relative to the total expenses (all in‐house and purchased activities); (2) whether political majorities (left or right‐wing)
have an impact on these developments at local levels; and (3) whether: (i) population size; or (ii) local‐level economy
has an impact on local‐level purchases, i.e., whether pragmatism rules over ideology.
We used Swedish official statistics to compile all providers of institutional care run as nationally approved Homes for
Care and Housing (Hem för vård eller boende [HVB]). Our data series cover 1976, 1984, 1990, 1997, 2003, and 2016.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
780 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
The first four years have been investigated in previous work by Stenius (1999, pp. 92–93, 113) and were
complemented for 2003 by Storbjörk for a national inquiry (SOU, 2004). We applied a manual reading of annual cat-
alogs listing and describing the institutions. For the purpose of this article, corresponding information was extracted
in March 2016 from the national HVB register that now holds the data. A manual categorization sought to replicate
previous analyses by singling out units treating alcohol problems. For 1976–97, units were included if they claimed to
treat alcohol misusers. There were few drug units in 1976. Since the 1980s, alcohol and drug treatment have more or
less merged into one integrated addiction treatment system (Bergmark, 1998). The categorization for 2003 and 2016
excluded units claiming that they only treated problems with illicit drugs or pharmaceuticals. In 2016, only two units
were excluded because of a sole focus on illicit drugs. Across the time series, units were excluded if they had fewer
than five beds, provided family care, were shelters and other pure housing facilities, and institutions for youth (up to
the age of 25). We counted the number of institutions and beds by type of provider. Our HVB series cover 40 years
of institutional care for adults.
In March 2016, we ordered data from Statistics Sweden, which holds information on all municipalities' annual
accounts (Statistics Sweden, 2015, 2016). The statistics run from 1998, and we used data on each municipality's
(social service) total expenditure and purchases of addiction treatment for adults from various types of providers in
1999, 2004, 2009, and 2014. As of 2004, it was possible to distinguish between purchased institutional and outpa-
tient care. We analyze the overall expenditure (measured and presented as Swedish krona, SEK) and costs for pur-
chasing care (instead of producing and delivering it in‐house), in total, by type of provider, and by activity and
year. We report amounts (SEK) and percentage of purchased care of the overall costs. The data was analyzed in cur-
rent prices, but Figure 2, reporting on the development over time, used the 2014 monetary value.
Data on local government—whether the municipalities had left‐wing and/or social democratic governance; right‐
wing governance; or coalition governance—following the elections in 1994–2014 were collected from the Swedish
Association of Local Authorities and Regions (SALAR). Excel files were downloaded from the SALAR website (SALAR,
2016) and complemented by email correspondence. We focus on the difference between municipalities with
left‐wing and right‐wing governance across the entire period. Although governed by politicians, social services
administrations are dominated by treatment professionals and civil servants, and some agreements may be in force
across elections. Therefore, organizations change slowly, and stable ideologies appear the most interesting for our
study. Additionally, initial analyses of the effects of single elections prior to the studied years showed few correla-
tions. Lastly, we used official data provided online by Statistics Sweden on population size and median income
(2014 monetary value) in the adult population of each municipality for each studied year. The municipal divisions
have changed slightly over the years. We used the division in force in 2016.
We charted developments in figures and frequency tables, and used multiple regression models to analyze the
extent to which local‐level purchases of care could be attributed to local government (ideology), population size,
wealth, and the total budget for addiction care, in 1999, 2004, 2009, and 2014 when controlling for all other
variables. This is a total population study including all Swedish municipalities, but significant levels are indicated
for the convenience of the reader (few correlations are significant due to the low number of municipalities).
3 | RESULTS
3.1 | National development: Growing role for private enterprises and new focus on
outpatient care
This section charts national developments. We start off by charting the share of public versus private (non‐governmental
organization [NGO] and for‐profit) provision of institutional care (HVB), and move on to analyzing purchases of addiction
services by exploring the municipalities' total expenditure and purchases of addiction care since 1999, as well as the
distribution across different types of providers of the purchased care.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 781
FIGURE 1 Institutional alcohol care 1976–2016, percentage of beds by type of provider (bars) and total number of
institutions and beds (lines) [Colour figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
782 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
government, while critical of the role of for‐profit provision, is a minority government, and has a history of ambiv-
alence towards market‐type reforms.
FIGURE 2 Total costs for municipal addiction care and purchased care in 1999–2014a, in total and by type of care,
SEK billion (2014 monetary value)
Note. a 1999–2009 adjusted by Consumer Price Index (CPI), compiled by Statistics Sweden, to represent the
monetary value in 2014.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 783
prerequisites are fulfilled (see more in Blomqvist et al., 2009). Interestingly, NGOs play quite an important part in pro-
viding purchased outpatient care, but their role has diminished from 26% to 18%. The biggest changes occurred
between 1999 and 2004, and between 2009 and 2014 (first chart of Figure 3).
3.2 | The role of ideology and pragmatics in local‐level purchases of care in 1999–2014
3.2.1 | Some effect of ideology, but purchasing is the “new normal”
Sweden had a social democratic national government in 1982–91. Figure 4 charts the subsequent national political
power bases: a (black arrow) center–right‐wing government for one three‐year term of office, followed by
(grey arrow) social democratic rule that changed on both national and local (bars) levels in 2006 when an alliance
of center–right‐wing parties gained power for two terms. As of 2014, Sweden has been governed by a social
democratic–green minority coalition.
Since 1999, the proportion of municipalities that do not purchase any care (≤5% of the treatment was pur-
chased) has decreased from 12% to 3%, and the decreasing standard deviations indicate greater similarity across
municipalities over time (Table 1). The most drastic drops are found in 1999–2004 and in 2009–2014. The middle
period appears stable. A redistribution (not shown in the table) from purchased institutional to purchased outpatient
care also took place: the share of municipalities not purchasing institutional care (≤5%) increased from 10% to 17% in
2004–14, whereas those not purchasing outpatient care decreased from 50% to 39%. This redistribution was most
prominent between 2009 and 2014.
It is first and foremost municipalities with a tradition of left‐wing and coalition governments that do not purchase
care. Right‐wing municipalities generally have high percentages of purchased care (relative to the overall costs;
medians) across the study period. In 2014, all municipalities, including left‐wing municipalities, present higher average
percentages of purchased care than during previous years. The shift was quite remarkable between 2009 and 2014,
following a period with bourgeois national government, revised procurement law (LOU), and a new system of choice
law (LOV). On the other hand, the differences grew again in shares of purchased care between the left‐ and right‐
wing municipalities: bourgeois municipalities purchased more once again. Smaller municipalities more often report
that they do not purchase any services. The standard deviations are smaller for larger municipalities, indicating
greater similarity in levels of purchasing in more populated municipalities. The dispersion is also smaller across the
richest municipalities. Better‐off municipalities bought more services in 1999, but the pattern was reversed in
2014, when the poorest municipalities reported the highest average purchase levels. In terms of total expenditure
on addiction care per inhabitant, those municipalities that spent the least reported higher levels of non‐purchase. This
pattern remained stable across the time series.
Table 2 used linear multiple regression to study the correlations between municipal characteristics and local
purchase of care (0–100% of total expenditure was purchased relative to the total net costs) in total for all addiction
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
784 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
FIGURE 4 Municipal local governments (bars) following the general elections in 1994–2014 percentage of
municipalities, and national government (arrows)
services (Models A) and for institutional care separately (Models B). Models C analyzed purchases from for‐profit
providers specifically, as the proportion of bought from (incorporated) enterprises of all purchases.
Compared to municipalities with a stable left‐wing local government, right‐wing municipalities bought more
care in 1999, 2009, and 2014 (Models A). Larger municipalities generally purchased less care—maybe finding it rea-
sonable to produce more themselves? Richer municipalities purchased more treatment in 1999–2009 but this rela-
tionship altered in 2014 when the poorer municipalities bought more treatment than the wealthier municipalities.
Municipalities with greater overall expenses for addiction services purchased less treatment than the municipalities
spending the least in 1999, also when controlling for population size and wealth, but the tendency was reversed
thereafter. The pattern is mixed for purchases of institutional care (Models B) that fluctuates more on the local
level depending on needs. Right‐wing municipalities purchased more institutional care than did left‐wing municipal-
ities in 2004 and 2014, richer municipalities purchased less than the poorest municipalities, and municipalities
spending more on addiction services per inhabitant also purchased more institutional care than did those spending
the least. Models C, lastly, shows that right‐wing local governments in 1999, 2004, and 2009 bought more from
enterprises than left‐wing municipalities, while in 2014 left‐wing municipalities bought more than did bourgeois
municipalities.
Due to highly skewed distributions, we used multiple logistic regression (instead of multiple linear regression)
to analyze the associations between municipal characteristics and purchasing of outpatient services (Table 3,
Models D). Purchasing more than 5% of the outpatient care was coded as 1 (purchasing ≤5% coded 0). Right‐wing
local governments were more inclined than left‐wing governments to purchase outpatient services in 2004; there
was no difference between the two in 2009; and in 2014 the condition was reversed with right‐wing municipalities
having lower odds than left‐wing municipalities to purchase outpatient services. Larger municipalities, population‐
wise, would more often purchase outpatient care over the entire time period. This was most pronounced in
2014. Richer municipalities had higher odds of purchasing outpatient care than their less well‐off counterparts.
In 2004 and 2009, municipalities that spent the most on addiction services also purchased more outpatient care
as compared to those spending the least. In 2014, it was those spending the least that were more inclined to pur-
chase outpatient care.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 785
TABLE 1 Purchased care by municipal characteristics in 1999, 2004, 2009, and 2014; percentage not purchasing
(bought less than 5%), and central tendencies for percentage of purchased care of total costs for addiction services
1999 2004 2009 2014
≤ 5% Median SD ≤ 5% Median SD ≤ 5% Median SD ≤ 5% Median SD
Total 12% 41 25 6% 42 22 7% 40 23 3% 45 20
a
Local conditions (n)
Government 1994–2014
Left‐wing 40 10 45 21 8 44 25 8 37 21 5 45 19
Left + coalition 46 18 33 29 9 36 20 13 40 24 7 44 20
Shifting 123 11 41 23 7 42 24 8 44 23 2 44 19
Right + coalition 57 9 39 25 5 37 20 4 40 23 2 50 20
Right‐wing 24 13 50 30 0 46 19 0 41 24 4 53 23
Populationa
0–9,999 78 20 35 29 11 45 28 16 38 29 6 50 24
10,000–14,999 58 15 47 28 8 44 23 3 48 22 2 49 22
15,000–39,999 92 8 41 22 4 39 20 6 40 22 4 47 17
40,000–69,999 32 4 40 21 0 39 12 0 37 15 0 41 16
70,000–999,999 30 0 35 13 4 42 15 4 36 15 0 41 16
Wealth/median incomea
Lowest percentile/poor 97 15 39 25 10 40 26 9 39 25 5 50 22
Middle percentile 97 13 40 26 5 43 22 6 39 23 3 42 20
Highest percentile/rich 96 7 42 23 3 43 19 7 43 21 2 45 16
Total net expenditure per
inhabitantsa
Lowest percentile 96 18 48 30 11 43 27 9 38 24 6 48 24
Middle percentile 97 10 41 23 4 43 21 9 42 24 2 47 18
Highest percentile 96 6 36 20 3 41 18 4 40 21 2 43 16
a
Note. n refers to 2014.
4 | DISCUSSION
This article set out to study what the Swedish addiction treatment system—a market—looks like in terms of division
of labor between different types of providers, development over time, and whether one could distinguish any effects
on purchasing services as opposed to producing treatment within the public administration that could be linked to
ideological differences between municipalities with left and right ideologies, or if other, more pragmatic factors were
at play. Our analysis elaborates on statistical associations. In this discussion we therefore outline some possible
explanations to be tested in future studies.
Within Swedish institutional addiction treatment (HVB), where we have the longest statistics series, NGOs pro-
duced most of the treatment in the 1970s, while in 1984 municipalities had become the largest producer group. In
1990, NGOs and municipalities had about equal shares, but a third provider type appeared: the for‐profit incorpo-
rated enterprises. During the social democrat government (1994–2006), purchases from the public sector diminished,
and the for‐profit providers became the largest group. In 2009 and 2014, with right‐wing governments, the role of
NGOs diminished and the role of private enterprises continued to increase. Production of purchased institutional
treatment is today a matter primarily for incorporated enterprises. A closer scrutiny of the national HVB register
reveals that in 2014 at least three multinational investment or venture capital enterprises are represented among
the institutions. Even if there were only about 10 such institutions in the whole country, their presence means that
786
TABLE 2 Multiple linear regression: percentage of purchased care in 1999, 2004, 2009, and 2014, in total and institutional care separately (of total net costs), and percentage
purchased from for‐profit enterprises (of all purchases), by municipal characteristic. Unstandardized coefficients
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 787
TABLE 3 Logistic multiple regression models: purchasing outpatient care (more than 5%) in 1999, 2004, 2009, and
2014; odds ratios
MODELS D
Outpatient care
2004 2009 2014
a new economic actor—strong in terms of offering diverse interventions and handling procurement processes—has
demonstrated its interest in addiction treatment (see also Sallnäs & Wiklund, 2018). The growing size of the institu-
tions and the decreasing number of providers may indicate that bigger enterprises are buying smaller ones (SOU,
2016). The declared goal in the 1990s was to increase producer diversity (Edman, 2016). The recent development
could be a sign of concentration in service production and thus an opposite development.
The total national net costs for Swedish municipal addiction treatment, both outpatient and inpatient care, has
increased substantially between 1999 and 2014 (56%; Figure 2). The cost increase is steady over time with no visible
impact of changes of government ideologies. The increase is most pronounced in outpatient care (85%, as compared
to 30% for institutional care; Figure 2). The total costs for purchased care was high in 1999 (relative to the total net
costs), dropped in 2004, and the share of purchased services has since remained stable, around and just above 40%.
Yet the total amount (SEK) has increased in recent years. The costs for purchases of institutional care (since 2004),
where private enterprises have since the late 1990s been the biggest and are now the dominant provider, have also
been rather stable during the 2000s. Private enterprises have had an especially dominant position within the
expanding purchased outpatient care during the 2000s.
To summarize: nationally, the total turnover has increased, and particularly for outpatient treatment. The share of
services purchased appears stable, but the increased total expenditure implies that more money is spent also on pur-
chased care; the market is growing. In addition, the distribution of producers within purchased care has changed. For‐
profit providers are now the dominant provider group that municipalities buy from. It is not possible to distinguish
any breaches in the general growth of the market, nor in the growing share of for‐profit providers. However, there
are some signs that the market has recently entered a new phase with an increasing role for for‐profit providers in
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
788 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
outpatient treatment (a market that is also increasing in financial turnover), new kinds of private providers associated
with clear profit interests, a shrinking role for NGOs and, as a consequence, a new, ideological debate.
Research has showed how procurement and marketization have challenged the previous corporative and munic-
ipal social work logic (Alvehus & Andersson, 2017; Forkby & Höjer, 2008; Freidson, 2001; Meagher & Szebehely,
2013; Sallnäs & Wiklund, 2018). While social workers purchasing addiction services often stress previous experi-
ences, established collaboration with providers, and clients' wishes, LOU stresses the non‐discrimination of producers
and tender‐based ranking order (Storbjörk & Samuelsson, 2018; Storbjörk & Stenius, in press). The Norwegian gov-
ernment has chosen to protect the NGO engagement in community matters and the tradition of NGO–public sector
cooperation by preventing incorporated enterprises from entering procurement processes and addiction treatment
markets (Bogen & Backer Grønningsæter, 2016). We believe that the increasingly centralized and formalized procure-
ment practices in Sweden at least partly explain why we see bigger players on the addiction treatment arena while
NGOs have difficulties managing in this new landscape (Storbjörk & Stenius, in press). All in all, we cautiously
hypothesize that a “New Privatized Market” is emerging in Swedish addiction treatment.
Moving to the local‐level analyses that proved valuable for understanding the role of ideology in developments
over time, we note that today only a very small minority of municipalities adhere solely to in‐house services. Purchas-
ing addiction care has become the norm, in right‐wing as well as left‐wing municipalities, while it was less so in the
late 1990s. One explanation could be the somewhat slow but firm implementation of public procurement legislations
leading to greater conformity. The difference in purchasing behavior between small and big municipalities has also
diminished over time. It is possible that almost mandatory procurement protocols, guided by overarching EU
directives, weaken the role of local ideology in the organization of care.
Our analysis shows that during the social democrat national government (1999 and 2004), the gap in purchasing
behaviors between left‐wing and right‐wing municipalities disappeared. The fact that the left started buying more
implies that purchasing services became normalized rather than being an ideological question (Table 1). On the other
hand, between 2004 and 2014, with a right‐wing government and at a time when the market also slightly changed,
we see again a widening gap. The right‐wing municipalities today buy more than the left‐wing ones (confirmed in the
multiple regression analyses of Table 2). The picture becomes more complicated when we move on to purchases of
out‐ and inpatient treatment. Right‐wing municipalities bought more outpatient treatment and less inpatient care
than the left‐wing municipalities 15 years ago, and previously bought more from private enterprises, whereas today
the ratio is reversed. We can only speculate about the reasons: one hypothesis is that a bourgeois ideology was more
decisive for purchasing care before public procurements had become the “new normal”, with left‐wing local
governments just lagging behind.
Bigger and wealthier municipalities vary less in their purchasing behavior than smaller and poorer municipalities.
(Note: there was no relation between size and political majority.) The impact of size seems feasible in that a small
municipality has less possibility to produce treatment, and the demand for treatment can be more difficult to foresee.
Bigger municipalities buy in general relatively less treatment, and produce more themselves, regardless of political
majority (SOU, 2011). However, towards the end of the study period, if one controls for political majority, they actu-
ally buy more institutional and outpatient treatment. The pattern is most clear for outpatient care. One hypothesis for
the latter, in line with our emerging market thesis above, is that private providers establish themselves where they
can find sufficient local markets (Tables 2 and 3). Sallnäs and Wiklund (2018) explain the expansion of for‐profit
providers in outpatient care by the fact that this field is not strictly controlled by supervisory bodies. It is thus easy
to establish such units.
Wealthier municipalities also buy consistently less inpatient and more outpatient services than their less wealthy
counterparts. Addiction problems may be less of an issue in wealthier areas, given that the treatment population in
Sweden is highly marginalized (Storbjörk & Room, 2008). It could also reflect that the overall resources are rationally
steered towards outpatient care in a population with less need for intensive interventions. Notably, budgetary issues
combined with the questioning of the effectiveness of institutional care also lead many municipalities to implement
internal guidelines prioritizing outpatient care over institutional treatment (Storbjörk & Samuelsson, 2018).
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 789
5 | C O N CL U S I O N S
The share of public provision of addiction services which can be locally decided has remained fairly stable during the
last 15–20 years. However, the surrounding landscape has changed. Procurement law entails that who municipalities
buy from is primarily determined by market forces. Competent bidders are advantaged. Incorporated enterprises
have gained an increasing role among those providing purchased care, also within the expanding outpatient
treatment. New kinds of multinational enterprises have entered the market. The role of NGOs has diminished. This
points to a new type of privatized production, different from that of the 1980s.
Which has been more important for this development: ideology or pragmatism? It is clear that very small and
very big municipalities, and poor and rich ones, have somewhat different purchasing behaviors. Differences can be
explained by pragmatic reasons, such as the possibility to plan for unexpected new needs, the feasibility of launching
public municipal production for a local market, the possibility to have long‐standing relations with non‐public
providers, and the attractiveness of a big local market for private providers.
On the role of ideology, our data seem to confirm the picture presented in earlier research. The left‐wing
governments or municipalities do not consistently present any clear alternative in their purchasing behavior. The
acceptance of arguments favoring market incentives from the left was also mirrored in a rapid privatization of a large
addiction treatment clinic in Stockholm in the early 2000s (Stenius & Storbjörk, 2003). Our analysis shows that in
1994–2006 the share of purchased care in left‐wing municipalities grew and reached the level of right‐wing munic-
ipalities. Purchases did not seem to be a very ideological question. Thereafter, when the government again became
bourgeois, and the role of for‐profit providers reached a higher level, the purchasing behavior diversified once more
and became relatively more important in right‐wing municipalities than in left‐wing ones. But the difference is not
dramatic. To some extent, it looks as though the left has only slowed down the privatization development, not
stopped it.
Hood (1995) argues that NPM as party politics may suit both left‐ and right‐wing sides, with arguments that can
attract the floating middle‐ground voters. Addiction treatment, of small interest to middle‐class voters, has some-
times been caught up in reforms for larger welfare areas such as elder care. Also, non‐public provision has a very long
tradition in Swedish addiction treatment. All these conditions, the legislative changes and EU directives, and previous
ambivalence within the social democratic party impede their and their allies' chances to develop feasible alternatives
to market models. The path of the present government is to try to regulate this market. The recent proposal (SOU,
2016) to cut profit returns marks an attempt to eliminate outright speculation in the welfare market.
5.1 | Limitations
The study is limited to services provided by the municipal social services, which hold the major responsibility for
addiction treatment. The role of the regional‐level health care system, responsible for medical treatment, has
increased somewhat over the years, but the annual accounts available for the regional county councils are limited
to “specialized psychiatric care” and do not allow us to distinguish dependence care from the much broader field
of general psychiatry.
ACKNOWLEDGEMEN TS
The funding agency, Riksbankens jubileumsfond (The Swedish Foundation for Humanities and Social Sciences) had
no further role in the study design, analysis, or preparation of this article. The authors wish to thank Sandra Norman
for her participation in the statistical analysis during her internship at our unit.
AUTHOR CONTRIBUTIONS
Jessica Storbjörk designed and performed the statistical analyses of data. Both authors interpreted the results. Both
authors contributed substantially to drafting the article, responding to reviewers' comments, and writing the final
version of the article.
ENDNOTES
1
A quasi‐market, in this case, refers to the entrance of for‐profit providers to a market thereby characterized by a mix of
for‐profit and not‐for‐profit actors; public funding and purchases; demands decided by politically agreed budgets and pro-
fessional needs assessments rather than by the actual service users (who are weak actors, i.e., the public serve as the
customer) (see Sallnäs & Wiklund, 2018 for a thorough description of the Swedish social services' quasi‐market in
practice).
2
No earmarked state subsidies have been available for municipal addiction treatment services since then, apart from some
small scale projects and a Government initiative (Contract for life) that sought to facilitate more aftercare following com-
pulsory treatment in 2005–07.
ORCID
Jessica Storbjörk http://orcid.org/0000-0002-1757-9974
RE FE R ENC ES
Agerberg, M. (2014). NPM var en syndabock ingen hade hört talas om [NPM was a scapegoat nobody had heard of].
Läkartidningen.se 2014–04‐29. Retrieved from http://www.lakartidningen.se/Aktuellt/Nyheter/2014/04/NPM‐var‐
ensyndabock‐ingen‐hade‐hort‐talas‐om/ (accessed May 15, 2018).
Ahlberg, K., & Bruun, N. (2010). Upphandling och arbete i EU. Stockholm: Sieps.
Alvehus, J., & Andersson, T. (2017). Styrning och professionellt inflytande i offentliga organisationer [Steering and professional
discretion in public organizations]. Stockholm: SKL.
Bergmark, A. (1998). Expansion and implosion: The story of drug treatment in Sweden. In H. Klingemann, & G. Hunt (eds),
Drug treatment systems in an international perspective: Drugs, demons, and delinquents (pp. 33–47). Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage.
Bertling, U. (2015). Ansvarsförskjutning och skamstruktur—konsekvenser av ekonomistyrning? Socialmedicinsk tidskrift, 92(4),
433–444.
Bjerge, B. (2012). Structural reforms as new public management policy: Three dilemmas in Danish substance misuse treat-
ment. In M. Hellman, G. Roos, & J. von Wright (Eds.), A welfare policy patchwork: Negotiating the public good in times of
transition (pp. 181–201). Helsinki: Nordic Centre for Welfare and Social Issues.
Blomqvist, J., Palm, J., & Storbjörk, J. (2009). “More cure and less control” or “more care and lower costs”? Recent changes in
services for problem drug users in Stockholm and Sweden. Drugs: Education, Prevention & Policy, 16(6), 479–496.
Bogen, H., & Backer Grønningsæter, A. (2016). En ideell forskjell? Om ideelle aktører i spesialisthelsetjenesten. Oslo:
Forskningsstiftelsen Fafo.
Common, R. K. (1998). Convergence and transfer: A review of the globalisation of new public management. International
Journal of Public Sector Management, 11(6), 440–450.
Creutzer, M. (2014). New Public Management inom missbruksvården: Beroendeläkare i lära hos SAS [NPM within addiction
treatment: Dependence doctors apprenticed to SAS (Scandinavian Airlines)]. Alkohol & Narkotika, 108(4), 14–17.
Dunleavy, P., Margetts, H., Bastow, S., & Tinkler, J. (2006). New Public Management is dead—Long live digital‐era gover-
nance. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 16(3), 467–494.
Edman, J. (2016). Depoliticising the political: Market solutions and the retreat of Swedish institutional drug treatment from
state management. International Journal of Drug Policy, 32(June), 93–99.
Forkby, T., & Höjer, S. (2008). Ritual eller strategi—Upphandlingar och ramavtal inom den sociala ungdomsvården.
Socialvetenskaplig tidskrift, 15(2), 115–134.
Freidson, E. (2001). Professionalism: The third logic. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Gingrich, J. R. (2011). Making markets in the welfare state: The politics of varying market reforms. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Government. (2016). Uppdrag till Statskontoret om statlig styrning av offentlig sektor [Assignment to the Swedish Agency for
Public Management] (Regeringsbeslut 2016–02‐04). Stockholm: Regeringen, Finansdepartementet.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS 791
Green‐Pedersen, C. (2002). New Public Management reforms of the Danish and Swedish welfare states: The role of different
social democratic responses. Governance, 15(2), 271–294.
Hartman, L. (Ed.). (2011). Konkurrensens konsekvenser: Vad händer med svensk välfärd? Stockholm: SNS Förlag.
Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all seasons? Public Administration, 69(1), 3–19.
Hood, C. (1995). The “New Public Management” in the 1980s: Variations on a theme. Accounting, Organizations and Society,
20(2), 93–109.
Hood, C., & Dixon, R. (Eds.) (2015). A government that worked better and cost less? Evaluating three decades of reform and
change in UK central government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hull, P., & Ritter, A. (2014). The potential role of pay‐for‐performance in alcohol and other drug treatment funding: A literature
review (14 Feb 2014). Sydney: University of New South Wales, National Drug and Alcohol Research Centre, Drug Policy
Modelling Program.
James, O., & Manning, N. (1996). Public management reform: A global perspective. Politics, 16(3), 143–149.
Klitgaard, M. B. (2007). Why are they doing it? Social democracy and market‐oriented welfare state reforms. West European
Politics, 30(1), 172–194.
Löfven, S. (2013). DN debatt “Välfärdens yrken måste få sin frihet och status åter” [For debate: Welfare professions must get
their freedom and status back]. Dagens Nyheter, November 29.
McLellan, T., Kemp, J., Brooks, A., & Carise, D. (2008). Improving public addiction treatment through performance
contracting: The Delaware experiment. Health Policy, 87(3), 296–308.
Meagher, G., & Szebehely, M. (Eds.) (2013). Marketisation in Nordic eldercare: A research report on legislation, oversight, extent
and consequences. Stockholm: Stockholm University, Department of Social Work.
Moore, D., & Fraser, S. (2013). Producing the “problem” of addiction in drug treatment. Qualitative Health Research, 23(7),
916–923.
Nesvåg, S., & Lie, T. (2010). The Norwegian substance treatment reform: Between New Public Management and conditions
for good practice. Nordic Studies on Alcohol and Drugs, 27(6), 655–666.
Oscarsson, L. (2000). Den socialtjänstbaserade missbrukarvården under 1990‐talet—Förutsättningar, utveckling och behov.
In M. Szebehey (Ed.), Välfärd, vård, omsorg (SOU 2008:38, forskarantologi) (pp. 57–106). Stockholm: Fritzes.
Pollitt, C. (1995). Justification by works or by faith? Evaluating the New Public Management. Evaluation, 1(2), 133–154.
Pollitt, C., & Sorin, D. (2011). The impacts of the New Public Management in Europe: A meta‐analysis. Brussels: European
Commission.
SALAR. (2016). Maktfördelning för tidsperioden 1994–2014 [Distribution of political power in 1994–2014]. Sveriges Kommuner
och Landsting (SKL) [Swedish Association of Local Authorities and Regions (SALAR)]. Retrieved from http://skl.se/
demokratiledningstyrning/valmaktfordelning/valresultatmaktfordelning2014/valresultatochmaktfordelningsam
manstallning19942014.370.html (accessed March 14, 2016).
Sallnäs, M., & Wiklund, S. (Eds.) (2018). Socialtjänstmarknaden—Om marknadsorientering och konkurrensutsättning av individ‐
och familjeomsorgen [The social services market—On marketization and competition in the social services]. Stockholm: Liber.
SoS‐rapport. (1991). Privat och offentligt i vården—En analys av utvecklingen under 1980‐talet inom barn‐, ungdoms‐ och
missbrukarvården (SoS‐rapport 1991:27). Stockholm: Socialstyrelsen.
SOU. (2002). Vårdens ägarformer—Vinst och demokrati [Profit or not‐for‐profit in the Swedish health system] (SOU 2002:31).
Stockholm: Fritzes.
SOU. (2004). Tvång och förändring—Rättssäkerhet, vårdens innehåll och eftervård [Coercion and change: Legal security, treatment
contents and follow‐up care] (SOU 2004:3). Stockholm: Fritzes.
SOU. (2011). Bättre insatser vid missbruk och beroende. Individen, kunskapen och ansvaret. Slutbetänkande av
Missbruksutredningen, volym 2 av 2 [Better interventions for misuse and dependence: Individual, knowledge and responsibili-
ties. Final report of misuse commission, vol. 2] (SOU 2011:35). Stockholm: Fritzes.
SOU. (2016). Ordning och reda i välfärden: Betänkande av välfärdsutredningen [Bringing order into welfare: Report by the welfare
inquiry]. (SOU 2016:78). Stockholm: Wolters Kluwer.
Statistics Sweden. (2015). Finansiärer och utförare inom vård, skola och omsorg 2013 [Financiers and providers within health
care, education, and social services 2013] (Statistiska meddelanden OE 29 SM 1501). Örebro: Statistics Sweden.
Statistics Sweden. (2016). Annual accounts for municipalities and county councils [Räkenskapssammandrag (RS)]. Statistics
Sweden. Retrieved from http://www.scb.se/oe0107‐en (accessed March 16, 2016).
Stenius, K. (1999). Privat och offentligt i svensk alkoholistvård: Arbetsfördelning, samverkan och styrning under 1900‐talet. Lund:
Arkiv.
14679515, 2019, 5, Downloaded from https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/spol.12414 by Universidad Los Andes Columbia Sistema De Bibliotecas, Wiley Online Library on [05/10/2024]. See the Terms and Conditions (https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/terms-and-conditions) on Wiley Online Library for rules of use; OA articles are governed by the applicable Creative Commons License
792 STORBJÖRK AND STENIUS
Stenius, K., & Storbjörk, J. (2003). Dynamiken bakom en gränsomdragande reform. Den snabba avknoppningen av
Maria‐enheten [The dynamics behind a rebordering reform. The abrupt privatization of the Maria unit]. Socialvetenskaplig
tidskrift, 10(4), 366–387.
Storbjörk, J., & Room, R. (2008). The two worlds of alcohol problems: Who is in treatment and who is not? Addiction Research
and Theory, 16(1), 67–84.
Storbjörk, J., & Samuelsson, E. (2018). Brukarinflytande på vårdmarknaden—En paradox i missbruks‐ och beroendevården?
[Service user involvement in the care market: A paradox in addiction care?] In M. Sallnäs, & S. Wiklund (Eds.),
Socialtjänstmarknaden—Om marknadsorientering och konkurrensutsättning av individ‐ och familjeomsorgen [The social ser-
vices market—On marketization and competition in the social services] (pp. 85–115). Stockholm: Liber.
Storbjörk, J., & Stenius, K. (in press). Why research should pay attention to effects of marketization of addiction treatment
systems. Journal of Studies on Alcohol and Drugs.
Sundström, G. (2006). Management by results: Its origin and development in the case of the Swedish state. International
Public Management Journal, 9(4), 399–427.
Wiklund, S. (2011). Individ‐ och familjeomsorgens välfärdstjänster. In L. Harman (Ed.), Konkurrensens konsekvenser: Vad
händer med svensk välfärd? (pp. 111–145). Stockholm: SNS Förlag.
Zaremba, M. (2013a). Patienten och prislappen 1. Vad var det som dödade Herr B [The patient and the prize tag 1. What
killed Mr B]? Dagens Nyheter, February 17.
Zaremba, M. (2013b). Patientens pris. Ett reportage om den svenska sjukvården och marknaden. Stockholm: Weyler.
How to cite this article: Storbjörk J, Stenius K. The new privatized market: A question of ideology or prag-
matism within the Swedish addiction treatment system? Soc Policy Admin. 2019;53:776–792. https://doi.org/
10.1111/spol.12414