Death of Democracy Ebook
Death of Democracy Ebook
Contents
Introduction 5
CHAPTER 1
Death of democracy and the rise of the techno-autocracy 9
CHAPTER 2
Globalisation: the cracking sound? 21
CHAPTER 3
A big deal 31
CHAPTER 4
Price and prejudice 47
CHAPTER 5
Of rabbits, bankers and what matters 59
CHAPTER 6
Technology — saviour or curse? 63
End Notes 73
Introduction
In this short book, through a series of essays, we argue that there is more than
the rise of populism afoot. New politico-economic models are being formed
that could replace the old democratic model.
The authoritarian command economy of the Soviet Union failed, but now
there is an even more potent rival to the traditional democratic model: a
techno-autocracy where the market economy flourishes (under some state
direction), but social and political freedoms are restricted. China is the prime
example of this. China now threatens to rival the old democracies of North
America, Europe and Japan, not only economically, but also as a future poli-
tical model. There are still many tin-pot dictatorships (often elected!) who
haven’t a clue how to deliver economic well-being to the masses. Examples
are the Philippines’ Duterte and Turkey’s Erdogan. But techno-autocracies
like China are far removed from the tin-pot dictatorship model and are both
economically savvy and socially oppressive.
Even Russia, which threatens the old geopolitical order as much as China,
provides a reasonably successful alternative social model for its citizenry,
which continues to vote for it in droves. Russia has seen its poverty rate halve
to below 14% in less than a decade, on par with the US. Population decline
has been reversed. Its automobile ownership is now equal with Poland and
5
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
How and why is this happening? In this book, we consider several develop-
ments. The first is the attack on globalisation, free trade and internationalism
by populism and nationalism, as most strikingly trumpeted by the US
President, as the leader of the ‘free world’. In Europe, many governments in
the east stand for no further integration and aim to block the free movement
of labour, while in the west scepticism with the great post-war European
project has multiplied. At least three EU members, Hungary, Poland, and the
Czech Republic are attacking the rule of law and civic society in ways that
makes nonsense of their right to be in the EU, which in turn is powerless to
kick them out. And the UK is taking the seminal step of breaking with the
European Union after over 50 years of membership.
Global population growth is happening in areas of the world that have scant
hope of providing their burgeoning populations with decent living standards.
This threatens increasing numbers of failed states and massive movements
of labour across the globe from those areas with fast growing populations
(Africa) to those with falling populations (Europe), and all the attendant
tensions and conflict that could involve.
And third, there are the new disruptive technologies of AI, robots, big data
and blockchain. These technologies are no longer the preserve of the old
6
7
CHAPTER 1
Democracy is under attack. This calls into question the global leadership of the
world’s most significant rich economies which are all democratic. From within
they are under siege from populism. Externally, their status is being under-
mined by alternative social systems which are delivering improved economic
well-being, but at the expense of increased surveillance and more oppression.
This is new. Dictatorship has always stood in the opposite corner of the ring
to democracy. Over the past two centuries, dictatorships never came close
to rivalling the economic dividends of the ballot box. Now, in relatively few,
but highly significant cases, dictatorships have developed integrated political,
social and economic models that can do so.
China doubles real living standards every 13 years. It now takes the US
and Europe 50 years and Japan even longer (Figure 1). Russia has seen its
poverty rate halve to below 14% in less than a decade and population decline
has been reversed. Its automobile ownership is now on par with Poland and
Hungary. And individual connectivity to the internet is around 75%, level
with the EU and ahead of the US. All of which makes the rich democracies,
struggling with the aftermath of crisis, look bad.
Mar-06
Mar-09
Mar-12
Mar-15
Dec-03
Dec-06
Dec-09
Dec-12
Dec-15
Sep-04
Jun-05
Sep-07
Jun-08
Sep-10
Jun-11
Sep-13
Jun-14
Sep-16
Jun-17
9
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
And it’s no better if we look at how this economic strength feeds into the
capacity of both Russia and China to assert themselves geopolitically and
diminish the power of rich countries — especially the US and Europe. It’s
here the similarities between the alternative systems of Russia and China
ends. The Russians may be happy with their development model. But no-one
else envies it. The Chinese model is, in contrast, exportable (in whole or part)
and will be. For that reason, we will focus on the Chinese alternative system.
There was a time when the western liberal mantra and our humbler belief
was that rising living standards create the demand for civic society and rule
of law. And that civic society is a basic building block for an economy to
achieve rich country status.
So the two trends were self-reinforcing: as societies got richer they became
more civic. Becoming more civic empowered the creativity that allowed
them to become rich.
Right now, all major rich countries are democracies and enjoy the rule of law.
But this increasingly appears to be less of a rule that governs the future than a
historical accident that typified the past. China is conceivably the laboratory
test that will prove or disprove this.
10
Chapter 1
The political architecture to make this social contract work is being moder-
nised and consolidated at a stunning rate. Take the latest National People’s
Congress (NPC) which ….
2. did away with the separation of Party and State (put in place by Deng
Xiao Ping to prevent the recurrence of Mao’s personalised dictatorship);
The political architecture is only as solid as its ability to deliver the goods.
If things go well, all is well. But if things go wrong economically, the cracks
will spread quickly.
Western democracies with all their lasagna-like political and bureaucratic layers
have an ability to absorb shocks and cushion discontent, without ever really
tackling the causes of either. But autarkies and dictatorships are much more
fragile, which is why they are more sensitive to social discontent than rich
countries’ elected leaders. And interestingly, the new techno-autarkies, thanks
to their sophisticated technical abilities, are better equipped at sussing out social
discontent and not only suppressing it, but addressing its causes efficiently.
11
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
This may be Trump’s nightmare vision of China. But Don Quixote too had
notions about windmills. It is a view as out of date as that of rebuilding smo-
ke-stack America. Unlike the US political leadership, China’s knows when a
development model is past its use-by-date. And knows to change it rapidly, or
the Party may not survive the economic damage inherent in persisting with it.
So, what is that economic model for the future? Disruptive technologies are
to be both the economic drivers and means of social control.
China is spending more on R&D than any other country in the world except
the US (Figure 2). Its academic papers on key areas of research and techno-
logy are now quantitatively ahead of the US, Europe and Japan (Figure 3,
page 13), even if they are still lacking qualitatively. This progress is being
bankrolled by massive state support that dwarfs government-funded research
in the US and elsewhere. The change has already transformed global research
and information flow (Figure 4, page 13).
The environment for these “new economy” sectors is relatively free with
few constraints in medical research (genome or stem-cell technology) and
little or no data protection laws. In contrast to personal data, the protection
of intellectual property enjoys increasingly effective legal cover. This is
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
China US Eurozone
0.5
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2017
12
Chapter 1
2,000,000
1,500,000
1,000,000
500,000
0
China US EZ Japan
significant. For example, you can get more uninhibited access to citizens’ big
data in China than anywhere else. You can then use it to create a new process
or application, which you can then legally protect effectively.
Focus, funding and brain power make it highly likely the Chinese will
succeed in becoming globally dominant in a wide range of ‘new economy’
sectors, as Xi targeted with in his “Made in China 2025” plan. This is
designed to push China up the value chain, giving it the lead in a number
of nascent technologies (e.g. AI, quantum computing, clean energy). The
edict also calls for a push into industrial automation while reducing Chinese
dependency on imported components, aiming for a domestic content of
70% in manufactured products.
What could cause all this felicity to flop is China’s over-leverage (Figure 5,
page 14) and malinvestment problem. But that is unlikely — partly because
Change in the evolution of cross-patent citations within and across regions, 1995-2014
1995 2014
13
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
200
144.9
150
100
50
0
Dec-07
Dec-08
Dec-09
Dec-10
Dec-11
Dec-12
Dec-13
Dec-14
Dec-15
Dec-16
Jun-08
Jun-09
Jun-10
Jun-11
Jun-12
Jun-13
Jun-14
Jun-15
Jun-16
Jun-17
Figure 5. Source: BIS, Independent Strategy
the money is owed to themselves as borrower and lender are all state control-
led. But there is another reason for thinking a crisis can be avoided, which
is wrapped up in the drive towards new technologies.
The “new economy” sectors need less capital to grow. Rising consumption
lowers the savings rate. The result is less and better-allocated savings. This
also means China’s net savings (saving minus investment) are likely to fall,
thus reducing the current account surplus.
There are four ways in which the new technology paradigm reinforces the
Chinese state.
14
Chapter 1
The state is also advanced in using this data and that from its own sophi-
sticated intelligence network, for social profiling with the aim of matching
an individual’s access to resources (like social pay-outs, housing, education
and travel permits) with how well the individual meets the Party’s criteria.
A rather amusing example is the Beijing sperm bank that carries notices on
its website that only donors with excellent conformity to Communist Party
ideals need apply.
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
1992
1993
1994
1995
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
15
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
Much of China’s current R&D boom is directly linked to weaponry and com-
munications. For example, drone deliveries are already a consumer reality
in China today. But they are also a key military technology (both offensive
and defensive).
Nearly a decade ago our book, Democrisis2, predicted bad things for democracy
based on these observations:
• Fragmentation of the political system after the fall of the Berlin wall, which
heralded the end of ideological politics, would deprive much of the political
structure of its purpose.
All of this happened and it was made worse by the rise of populism fuelled
by inequality, the collapse of social services and lack of education.
16
Chapter 1
Traditional elitist leadership and parties in many countries, but most markedly
in Germany, Italy and the Netherlands, now garner less than 50% of the vote.
Populists make up the difference.
To keep the populists at bay in many EU states, coalitions have been formed.
But it is not evident that these coalitions have a vision or are capable of the
decisiveness that are needed to address the root causes of the rise of populism.
Only rejuvenation of the popularity of the EU as a widely supported ideal,
will work. Economic expansion and more jobs will not work alone, although
it gives the politicians a window to achieve reform.
The hope is that the Macron-Merkel axis delivers EU reform. The list of
mooted changes includes the creation of an EMF (an EU version of the IMF)
to enhance and potentially replace the European Stability Mechanism (ESM);
completion of the banking union; establishment of a more democratically
accountable European Parliament; and the partial mutualisation of sovereign
debt. All of these would be positive steps. But at best it is a 50:50 bet that
they will enthuse the masses, even if they help deliver stability and growth.
If the EU’s traditional political parties fail in this, then populism will continue
to spread and strengthen, threatening the EU itself.
This process will take many years to evolve. During this time, the EU may
provide a counterweight to China and the US in terms of its liberal values,
but hardly as a political-economic entity that makes China’s look bad.
What the EU will do, along with its trading partners, is to continue to further
globalisation and open markets. The EU’s recent trade agreements with
Canada and Japan point the way here. Of itself, that is sufficient to ensure
that globalisation will continue with or without the US.
President Trump is doing a good job at .... Making China Great Again! And,
in the process, weakening the US, both geopolitically and economically.
17
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
The policy mix to recreate industrial America and put President Trump’s voters
back in jobs is fiscal spending and protectionism, together with some social
deregulation (mainly at the expense of the environment and social justice).
The absurdity of increasing the fiscal deficit, while seeking to reduce the trade
deficit through protectionism is contained in the simple economic equation
and accounting identity:
NS = S + GS = I + NX
This says that national savings (NS) is made up of private sector savings
(S) and public-sector savings (GS). If public sector savings fall due to fiscal
deficit spending, then either private sector savings have to compensate, or
investment (I) has to drop (meaning lower growth or recession), if the current
account deficit (NX) is to even stay the same. Put it another way;in a full
employment economy at the peak of its economic cycle, the US government
spending more money will suck in more imports, increasing both the fiscal
and current account deficits.
Rising twin deficits (Figure 7) can only be funded if China (and other current
account surplus countries) that are willing (in economic jargon ‘ex-ante’) to
invest more of their external surpluses in US Treasuries. That is an unlikely
if there is a US-China trade war.
-2.0
-2.4
-4.0 -3.6
-6.0
-8.0
-10.0
C/A Budget Balance
-12.0
Mar-04
Mar-07
Mar-10
Mar-13
Mar-16
Dec-04
Dec-07
Dec-10
Dec-13
Dec-16
Jun-03
Sep-05
Jun-06
Sep-08
Jun-09
Sep-11
Jun-12
Sep-14
Jun-15
Sep-17
18
Chapter 1
The deficits will be funded eventually because dollars leaked abroad by the US
current account deficit and held overseas have to be held and invested by some-
one. But not at today’s price. So the US will have to pay more, either in terms of
higher interest rates or in a weaker US dollar (falling to a level where investors
can count on exchange rate gains plus higher interest payments going forward).
The real driver of job losses in the US is technology, not trade. In nearly
every manufacturing sector, it takes less people to produce a given level of
output than ten years ago. That is called productivity and it drives econo-
mic growth and progress from low- to high value-added activities, ensuring
that workers earn more. It is by far the major reason why the US produces
approximately the same amount of steel products today as ten years ago, but
with 40% less people. Protectionism is an attack on technological progress.
That won’t stop technology advancing. It just means the cost will be paid in
terms of productivity, growth and living standards in the US.
US attempts to impede the flow of ideas and technology will only succeed
in isolating the US. It would mean that the US is effectively cutting itself
off from the global flow of ideas that underpins research and development
of new technologies. And it ignores history: evolving states always benefit
from the innovations of others, which they enhance. The US took the ideas of
the industrial revolution from Europe and then surpassed Europe. Moreover,
China does not need US technology anymore. Those days are long gone.
AN UNSAFE WORLD
The world will have to look for new alliances and balances of power as US
influence declines and is increasingly mistrusted. That is highly destabilising
as there really is no replacement for the US on the global stage. But a sta-
bilising factor will be a continued commitment to globalisation outside the
US, as one means of achieving stable relations between states.
19
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
As the US retreats into isolationism, China steps up: economically and geopo-
litically. Economically, China is increasingly self-sustaining. Technologically,
China is way beyond the point of depending on the US.
In the Middle East, President Trump’s aim to withdraw from Syria opens
the door for Iran to increase its influence and open a supply route to its
Hezbollah allies in Lebanon. To contain Iran, Israel and Saudi Arabia would
be empowered to act as US surrogates, with arms to match!
20
CHAPTER 2
Globalisation: the cracking sound?
Meanwhile, new trade agreements are being forged. Trump might have
dumped the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), but the treaty should be imple-
mented by the remainder of the group. Europe is also signing major deals.
China meanwhile is leveraging its economic might to launch the One Belt
One Road (OBOR) project that will ultimately reach right to the doorstep of
Europe. Globalisation will persist because of the benefits it brings, both in the
form of lower inflation and ultimately through higher levels of productivity
and growth. It also serves geopolitical aims like furthering European and
Japanese ‘soft power’ as bulwarks against populist isolationism and China’s
aim of filling the US’s shoes on the global stage. The only thing the populists
pursuing more inward-looking ideologies will discover is that they’ve been
left further behind economically, technologically and geopolitically.
Wherever you look, it seems that someone has trouble with trade. While globa-
lisation hefted global living standards by boosting incomes, raising productivity
and slashing the price of goods, the perception that ‘someone has benefited more
than you’ reinterpreted the issue (certainly in many developed markets) from
one of gain to one of pain. Populists have sought to exploit this fundamental
misunderstanding, blaming globalisation for job losses and income stagnation.
And voters have responded, ushering in Brexit and Donald Trump.
The boom in global trade pre-crisis was driven by two distinct events. The
first was the end of the cold war, which brought shackled consumers stuck
behind the ‘iron curtain’ into the global market place. The second wave was
driven by China’s accession to the WTO, the culmination of the economic
reforms started by Deng Xiaoping which then gained traction under Jiang
Zemin (Figure 1, page 22). This surge pushed global trade as a share of GDP
up from around 35% to a peak of 60% before the financial crisis hit.
21
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
0.60
0.55
0.35
*= (Imports + Exports) / GDP
0.30
Mar-92
Oct-01
Mar-15
Aug-82
Dec-97
Aug-05
Jan-96
Nov-99
Sep-80
Jun-86
Feb-94
Sep-03
Jun-09
Feb-17
Jul-84
May-88
Jul-07
May-11
Apr-90
Apr-13
2400 31.0
29.0
2200
27.0
2000
25.0
1800
23.0
1600
21.0
1400
19.0
1200 17.0
US$ bn as % of GDP - rhs
1000 15.0
Mar-09
Oct-09
Mar-16
Oct-16
Aug-08
Dec-10
Aug-15
Jan-08
Nov-13
Jan-15
Feb-12
Sep-12
Jun-14
May-10
Jul-11
May-17
Apr-13
22
Chapter 2
But growth in trade volumes has also slowed. There is something a little
‘chicken and egg’ about this as the shock of the crises mechanically dampened
trade. This was most acute during the global financial crisis itself, but the
slowdown in global growth thereafter was also a significant factor in trade’s
sluggish expansion. That period captures the Eurozone debt crisis and the
emerging market recession which hit commodity producers in 2015 as well
as the slowdown in China during 2015-16.
A study from the Peterson Institute shows how barriers crept up. Between 2008
and 2013 Peterson clocked the imposition of 117 local content requirement
measures, estimating this affected $928bn of trade in goods and services. WTO
data corroborates the scale of the problem. Between 2008 and the middle of
2016, the G20 economies had introduced 1,196 restrictive measures.
Multilateral efforts also faltered. The WTO’s Doha round of trade talks —
which started in 2001 and collapsed in 2008 — is still unresolved. Other trade
agreements have also run into obstacles post-crisis. The American withdra-
wal from the TPP is the most high-profile case of a multilateral agreement
stumbling. Trump is also posturing to recalibrate the US’s trading relationship
with China, which is pitched as “deeply unfair”. And the administration is
meddling counter-productively with the NAFTA agreement. While some sort
of re-negotiated pact might not materially impact existing North American
supply chains, uncertainty creates execution risk for future investment projects
and the efficiencies these would generate, acting as a break on trade-deepening
and the associated gains in productivity.
23
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
61.0
59.0
57.0
55.0 55.1
53.0
51.0
49.0
48.5
47.0
EU as % of Total Exports EU as % of Total Imports
45.0
Oct-02
Oct-05
Oct-08
Oct-11
Oct-14
Jan-05
Jan-08
Jan-11
Jan-14
Jan-17
Jul-03
Jul-06
Jul-09
Jul-12
Jul-15
Apr-04
Apr-07
Apr-10
Apr-13
Apr-16
Figure 3. Source: ONS, Independent Strategy
appealing one for certain British romantics. The Bank of England is more
realistic, acknowledging that this is likely to lead to lower productivity, lower
growth and higher prices, which has clear implications for monetary policy.
While the US remains the world’s largest economy in nominal dollar terms,
its importance in global trade has been diminishing since the start of the mil-
lennium. Indeed, US exports at the turn of the century were around 12% of
24
Chapter 2
the world total compared to 9% today whereas China has grown from about
3.5% to over 13% (Figure 4). This mirrors the general pattern seen between
advanced and emerging economy trade activity.
Meanwhile, China is pursuing its own strategy to expand trade ties, most
notably with its OBOR project. That is designed geographically around
the old Silk Road but has been repurposed to serve the needs of Chinese
development3 Critics point out that this is merely a way to redirect Chinese
excess capacity while expanding its geopolitical influence across tra-
ditionally more neglected parts of Asia. And that many of the planned
investments are likely to be decided by political considerations rather
than economic. All of which is probably correct. But that doesn’t detract
from the growth such a programme will still generate (both in terms of
reshaping value chains and creating the foundations for future demand
growth) and underlines the lesson China learnt from its own development
14.0
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
US Germany Japan China
0.0
Oct-98
Oct-05
Oct-12
Dec-99
Dec-06
Dec-13
Aug-97
Aug-04
Aug-11
Jun-96
Feb-01
Jun-03
Feb-08
Jun-10
Feb-15
Jun-17
Apr-95
Apr-02
Apr-09
Apr-16
25
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
The TPP also looks set to live on despite the US’s withdrawal, having been
revamped into the CPTPP (Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for
Trans-Pacific Partnership) with ratification likely in early 2018 between the
remaining members (Inset 1) after which it would head to national parliaments
to approve. Even China has expressed an interest in signing up, somewhat
ironically given that the TPP was initially created to try and counter the threat
of Chinese dominance in the region.
The data also suggest the trade revanchists remain on the wrong side. Indeed,
trade volumes are on the up again. Growth rates are now only around 1%
pt below pre-crisis levels (Figure 5, page 27). The structure is also positive,
being driven by the factory economies of Eastern Europe and Asia rather
than the commodity producing states in the Middle East and Latin America.
This reflects the upswing we’ve seen in global economic growth, emanating
specifically from the broadening eurozone recovery and rebound in Asia
ex-China.
26
Chapter 2
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
-5.0
-10.0
World Trade
Sep-03
Sep-05
Sep-07
Sep-09
Sep-11
Sep-13
Sep-15
Jan-01
Jan-03
Jan-05
Jan-07
Jan-09
Jan-11
Jan-13
Jan-15
Jan-17
May-02
May-04
May-06
May-08
May-10
May-12
May-14
May-16
Figure 5. Source: CBP, Independent Strategy
the US fares given it is ‘late cycle’, having soaked up the vast majority of
its domestic spare capacity. But that is unlikely to dent world demand near
term and could in fact provide an additional catalyst once the Republican tax
reform package goes through. A large chunk of the estimated ~$1trn increase
in the US deficit will end up being financed from the recycling of flows from
an even larger US trade deficit.
27
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
or amend details for the shipment without the corroboration of the network.
That could dramatically improve efficiency and productivity, greasing the
wheels of global trade.
Trade suffered an almighty hangover after the financial crisis, the collapse
in global demand hit volumes and the recovery was stretched out by ensuing
crises in Europe and emerging markets. While protectionism was vilified by
policy makers there was still an increase in less direct barriers to trade. The
sum of these parts was an effective stagnation in global trade growth and
investment for much of the past decade. This narrative has been compoun-
ded more recently by a populist political wave that has ridden the post-crisis
stagnation in living standards.
Populists seek to apportion blame and the trade boom driven by globalisation
has been top of the list. Trump’s America has been conditioned to believe
trade is bad and the country now looks inward. Brexit was a further expression
180.0
160.0
140.0
120.0
100.0
Jan-05
Jan-07
Jan-09
Jan-11
Jan-13
Jan-15
Jan-17
Sep-05
Sep-07
Sep-09
Sep-11
Sep-13
Sep-15
Sep-17
May-06
May-08
May-10
May-12
May-14
May-16
28
Chapter 2
But globalisation is not yet dead and certainly not at a point of unwinding
even if the US (directly) and the UK (via its own twisted logic) are pushing
against this trend. Some trade deals might have faltered, but others are moving
ahead and grand plans, such as China’s OBOR project should drive a further
round of trade growth in Asia over the next decade or so. Although many
western leaning states in the region view China warily, intra and extra-Asia
trade is now growing strongly.
The Eurozone recovery is also supporting the recovery in global trade volu-
mes. And with global growth likely to pick up further in 2018, trade will
continue to quicken. That is positive for the investment outlook and for
productivity and living standards, most notably for the middle-income coun-
tries of Asia and the higher-income German feeder economies of Eastern
Europe. It also fits with the lower-for-longer inflation narrative and further
complicates the job of central bankers still trying to reconcile the world in
traditional monetary terms.
If we are wrong and globalisation is dying, the post mortem will be a long,
drawn-out process. It will be logistically complex and, beyond that, require
a shift in mind-set to facilitate it. Such adjustments only ever happen gradu-
ally. The quantifiable impact is well beyond any normal investment horizon.
29
CHAPTER 3
A big deal
Demography is perhaps the single most important investment theme over the
next half century. Many of its implications will begin to bite much sooner.
Three trends are happening simultaneously:
Once in a while, there are developments so important that they define the
investment era. That moment was in the 1950s when the cult of the equity
took hold; Japan’s economic miracle and Germany’s Wirtschaftswunder of
the 1960s; the collapse of the gold exchange standard in the early 1970s;
31
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
Most of these epoch-defining events are obvious only with the benefit of
hindsight. Occasionally, however, we get to see one well in advance. And
no matter how slow-burn it might be, its force is irresistible. Demography is
one such theme. It’s so gradual that many investors struggle to get excited
about it. But that doesn’t mean it isn’t of central importance to future asset
returns. Here we try to bring out the kernel developments and consider their
implications.
The challenges can be summed up, in the first instance, by a single chart
(Figure 1). We are entering a new paradigm in which the combined working
age populations of the richest nations, coupled with that of the world’s
most populous, are about to start shrinking. Instead of adding 15-25 mil-
lion new workers every year, as they had reliably done for half century
or more, we’re going to have to adjust to an era in which the number of
workers from the countries that dominate global demand and supply chains
is actually declining.
32
Chapter 3
30% 26%
20% 22%
10% 13%
0%
1965
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
2015
2020
2030
2040
2050
2060
2065
Figure 2. Source: UN, Independent Strategy
(Figure 2). Within 30 years, most regions are going to have an age-profile
like Japan’s today. And Japan will be off the charts, with three workers
responsible for funding the dotage of two senior citizens — as well as their
own living expenses!
Of course, this isn’t the whole story. The advanced economies and China
together only account for 40% of today’s global working population. By 2065,
the UN Population Division’s base case scenario predicts that their combined
share will have dropped to less than a quarter (Figure 3).
60%
60%
50%
47%
40%
30% 32%
21%
20%
21% 19% 14%
10%
11%
0%
1965
1970
1980
1990
2000
2010
2015
2020
2030
2040
2050
2060
2065
33
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
TOO HOT
Overall, however, the world’s population will still be growing rapidly.
According to the UN, within 50 years, there are likely to be three billion
more inhabitants on the planet. Adjusting their assumptions for different fer-
tility and mortality scenarios, gives a wider range of “extreme” outcomes for
population increase — from a low-ball estimate of +1.3bn, to an eye-popping
+5.9bn. But under any scenario the numbers are vast.
Of course, this is not a new phenomenon. The global population has more
than doubled from 3.3bn in 1965, to 7.3bn now. That represents an average
annual growth rate of 1.6% p.a., with the fastest expansion being in devel-
oping economies (Figure 4).
“So what’s the big deal?” one might ask. We coped with 4bn new mouths to
feed in the last half century, so surely we can cope with another 3bn over the
next 50 years? Well maybe, maybe not. Hidden beneath these headline numbers
are some dramatic shifts with consequences of potentially biblical proportions.
While people are living longer in almost all countries due to giant medical
advances4, fertility rates are dropping faster (Figure 5, page 35). Indeed, by
the end of this century, all regions are expected to fall below the “replace-
ment rate” of 2.1-3.4 children per woman (depending on regional infant
mortality rates). So the phenomenon of a growing global population is
actually finite.
0.0
-0.2
-0.5
-0.5
-1.0
Oceania
Asia (xJap)
World
Japan
Europe
Lat Am
North Am
Africa
34
Chapter 3
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
1950-60
1960-70
1970-80
1980-90
1990-00
2000-10
2010-15
2015-20
2020-30
2030-40
2040-50
2050-60
2060-70
2070-80
Africa Oceania North Am Lat Am Asia (xJap) Europe Japan
From today’s 7.3bn starting point, under the UN’s base case, global popula-
tion growth is expected to slow sharply, declining from an historical 1.6%
p.a. since 1965 to just 0.7% annually through 2065. All regions are affected,
with particularly eye-catching slowdowns in northern Asia, Latin America
and Europe. Indeed, Europe and Japan will see their populations shrink stea-
dily, by almost 60m and 30m respectively over the next half century, while
China’s will fall by an astonishing 140m.
At the other end of the spectrum, while Africa’s population growth will also
slow, it will remain at least 1% point p.a. faster than any other region. This
will have significant implications for the distribution of global population,
with Africa’s share almost doubling from 16% now to 30% in 2065 (Figure
6, page 36).
The last half century was undoubtedly about the rise of Asia, which accounted
for 62% of the global population increase. Over the next 50 years, almost
two-thirds of it will be in Africa, where the population is expected to grow
at 1.9% p.a. This will drive the continent’s headcount up from 1.2bn today
to 3.1bn in 2065. At least ten African countries will see their populations
expand by more than 50m each.
35
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
Together they’ll account for 2.7bn, or almost 90%, of the 3.0bn global popu-
lation increase anticipated by the UN through 2065 (Figure 7). And over
half of this is due to just six countries — India, Pakistan, Nigeria, Tanzania,
Ethiopia and DR of Congo. The AIME bloc goes from representing 41%
of the global population today, to 55% in 2065. Were population growth to
slow more rapidly than in the UN’s base case, all net population growth in
the world would, in effect, be African.
50% 2.9
20% Africa
10% 21.5
0%
1965-2015 2015-2065
36
Chapter 3
Demand for food and housing will be the main challenge. The countries in
question need to buck historical trends and develop themselves rapidly with
sensible governments implementing structural reforms. If they can, growth
could make these the investment hotspots of the future. But there are serious
dangers to stability if they can’t, such that people aren’t adequately fed or
housed.
According to the UNHCR, there are already 65m displaced persons today,
representing almost 1% of the world’s population5. Given the concentration
of population growth outlined above, it seems highly likely that the flow of
displaced persons is going to increase. 2.7bn more people in the AIME region
implies half a million new refugees every year if just 1% find themselves
displaced. On that basis, the idea that Europe has solved its refugee crisis
is delusional.
TOO COLD
If population expansion in the AIME bloc of countries is too hot, that in much
of Europe, Japan and China is too cold (Figures 8 and 9, page 38). Declining
fertility rates and lengthening lifespans mean that by 2050, a third of the
population will be over 65. The inevitable consequence? There will be too
many old people and not enough workers to generate the tax revenue to pay
for seniors’ pension and healthcare needs.
Even the richest countries are ill-prepared. A 2015 study by the National
Institute on Retirement Security showed that 45% of all US households — 40
Italy
Nigeria
DR Congo
Japan
China
Tanzania
India
Germany
E Europe
Pakistan
Thailand
37
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
DR Congo
Nigeria
China
Japan
India
Europe
Pakistan
The burden will inevitably fall on the state. How heavy might this burden be?
The social contract for the elderly principally covers two kinds of entitlement:
pensions and healthcare. The cost to the public purse of these two items, across
a range of advanced economies, is currently in the order of 14-23% of GDP.
By 2050, however, due to demographic shifts, this will increase by a further
5-10% pts of GDP. This incremental burden will account for a much larger slice
of government revenue — in the case of the US, almost 30% of it! (Figure 10
& 11, page 39).
Squaring this circle can only be done by increasing tax rates, raising the reti-
rement age and reducing entitlements. But higher taxes will dampen growth
38
Chapter 3
Pak
Kor
Brz
Arg
Ita
SAfr
Rus
Chn
Mex
Indo
Fra
US
UK
Jap
Tur
Ind
Figure 10. Source: PEW, Independent Strategy
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
0.0
-10.0
Spa
Ger
Kor
Brz
Arg
Pak
Ita
SAfr
Rus
Chn
Indo
Mex
Jap
Fra
US
UK
Tur
Ind
while curtailed entitlements will lead to rising inequality and civil unrest.
There is no easy way around it.
A POST-GROWTH WORLD?
There are two other consequences of aging populations. First, they repre-
sent a drag on productivity (Figure 12, page 40), with the increased costs
of caring for society drawing workers away from more productive sectors.
There is ample evidence from countries like the US, Japan and Australia
39
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
-0.5
Can Fra Ger Jap US UK Ita
-1.0
1996
2001
2006
2011
2016
Figure 12. Source: AMECO, Independent Strategy
20.0
32.7
27.8
22.0
18.6
10.0
16.8
12.8
10.0
5.6
0.6
8.4
2.2
6.8
2.2
4.6
3.3
0.0
-13.9
-6.4
-0.1
-3.6
-10.0
-20.0
Other Services
Prof & Bus
Resources
Wholesale, Retail
Manufacturing
Hospitality
Education
Activities
Construction
Information
& Health
Financial
Services
Leisue &
Natural
& Transport
that job creation is being dominated by the care sectors (Figure 13).
40
Chapter 3
In reality, it is only investment spending that can create the foundations for
the strong growth needed to fund these growing liabilities. But that would
require a rebalancing of the spending pie, which given electoral participation
is unlikely to happen voluntarily. In fact, the political appeal of maintaining
entitlements has long undermined investment (Figure 14), which might go
some way to explaining the current productivity dilemma.
Countries with deficient public investment, in terms of both fixed capital and
education, alongside large unfunded liabilities, will find it difficult to raise
productivity and growth rates. Fiscal accounts will see continual pressure.
Historical investment returns will not be repeated. Increases in real per capita
incomes will fall.
One possible solution would be to means-test all benefits, apply constant taxa-
tion into retirement on income (i.e. pensioners continue to pay social security
contributions into retirement, like most commercial insurance policies require)
and introduce wealth taxes. This would allow for increased investment in
infrastructure, education and state backing for new technologies that are not
5.00
4.75
4.50
4.25
4.00
3.75
3.50
G4 (Weighted) Trend
3.25
Mar-94
Mar-95
Mar-96
Mar-97
Mar-98
Mar-99
Mar-00
Mar-01
Mar-02
Mar-03
Mar-04
Mar-05
Mar-06
Mar-07
Mar-08
Mar-09
Mar-10
Mar-11
Mar-12
Mar-13
Mar-14
Mar-15
Mar-16
Mar-17
41
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
yet commercially viable. It is the latter that historically have proved critical to
driving the technological breakthroughs needed to cope with such challenges.
Globally, both savings and investment rates, as well as potential output growth,
are likely to fall as these demographic tailwinds become headwinds. The
Bank of International Settlements (BIS) contends, however, that ex ante
savings will fall faster than ex ante investment. The net impact will be a
higher “market-clearing” real interest rate (ex post, of course, savings and
investment must balance).
That might be right. But bear in mind also that the real cost of capital is partly
a function of the real return that can be generated on it; and this is likely to
fall as growth slows. Furthermore, inflationary pressures are likely to rise.
The cheap expanding labour from productive areas of the world (i.e. the esta-
blished global supply-chain) may be replaced at the margin by unproductive
and forcibly-subsidised labour from other areas of the world (principally
the AIME bloc, currently outside the supply-chain).This can only be highly
inflationary. So even if real interest rates rise only gradually, nominal inte-
rest rates would be pushed up more significantly. Most governments in the
western world have reached a debt limit that is only made sustainable due to
historically low interest rates (Figure 15).
Zombie corporations, loaded with debt, survive for the same reason.
Productivity growth is declining because too much cheap capital is being
allocated to those who use it inefficiently or to speculate on high-yielding,
high-risk assets. Central banks (CBs) co-opted as economic agents of last
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
-1.0
US Jap Ger UK
-2.0
Nov-03
Nov-04
Nov-05
Nov-06
Nov-07
Nov-08
Nov-09
Nov-10
Nov-11
Nov-12
Nov-13
Nov-14
Nov-15
Nov-16
Nov-17
42
Chapter 3
(and first!) resort, have been painted into a corner, unable to raise interest
rates much even if they wanted to. This is a vicious cycle. Shrinking and
ageing populations in the rich world, coupled with weak labour productivity
growth, effectively limit the capacity of economies to “grow” their ways out
of these debt burdens.
The implications for financial asset markets are profound. Lower savings
and less growth reduce the capacity to pay down debt burdens or work
them out. It’s hard to see the discount rate dropping much from current
levels. Similarly bond yields further along the curve are unlikely to go
lower either in real or nominal terms. As growth slows, richly-valued
equities would seem to be particularly vulnerable, not least given how
complacent investors have become about risk (Inset 1). A more dramatic
shift into a post-growth world could even bring to an end the golden age
of investing.
Near term, of course, the question of CBs’ reaction function comes into play.
Falling stock prices, probably driven by contracting multiples, would under-
mine private sector balance sheets and investment confidence. Certainly, if
there were to be a precipitous drop in equity markets, it seems likely that
CB monetary policy would remain highly accommodative to offset the dete-
rioration in “secondary market” liquidity conditions (under the mantra of
maintaining financial stability).
Bubble trouble
• A painting sold for $450 million
• Bitcoin soared over 1600% from $952 to ~$17,000
• The BoJ and the ECB bought $2 trillion of assets
• Global debt rose to $225 trillion, or more than 324% of world
GDP
• US corporations sold a record $1.75 trillion in bonds
• European high-yield bonds traded under a 2% yield
• Argentina, a serial defaulter, sold 100-year bonds in an
oversubscribed offer
• Illinois, hopelessly insolvent, sold 3.75% bonds to bondholders
fighting for allocations
• Global stock market capitalization skyrocketed by $15 trillion to
over $85 trillion and a record 113% of global GDP
• The market cap of the FANGs increased by more than $1 trillion.
• S&P 500 volatility dropped to 50-year lows and Treasury
volatility to 30-year lows
• Money-losing Tesla Inc. sold 5% bonds with no covenants as it
burned $4+ billion in cash and produced very few cars
43
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
This is the sort of Orwellian world where governments and CB’s distribute
cash as universal basic income to individual accounts (held at CBs?) using
blockchain ledger technology and force spending through time limits on
these transfers. It would make the achievement of financial stability, the
key challenge CBs face in the next decades, illusory. Where this all comes
unstuck is if inflation rises and CBs are backed into a corner from which
they can’t escape.
• Governments in most DMs and many EMs will have to spend an ever-greater
proportion of their tax revenue on pensions and healthcare. This diminishes
the resources available for other discretionary expenditure items. Or else
taxes will have to go up.
• Citizens in ageing societies will have to work for longer before gaining a
pension. Those with assets (including their own home) will increasingly
be relied upon to fund at least part of their own dotage.
• Pensions are likely to be lower as a share of final salary than in the past.
44
Chapter 3
• Boosting productivity will come into focus. Competition for skilled labour
will rise and wages will reflect this, incentivising the substitution of capital
for labour.
45
CHAPTER 4
Price and prejudice
The reflation trade took on renewed urgency in the first half of 2018, as the
late-cycle fiscal stimulus delivered by the White House brought those already
fretting over resurgent price risks to a fresh pique. The short-term cyclical
drivers are certainly all pointing to a quickening of inflation. Indeed, head-
line US price levels have picked up and even core PCE is not too far from
the Fed’s 2% target. The gradual increase in nominal wage growth has also
continued (Figure 1).
The persistence of low inflation has not simply been an overhang from the
financial crisis. Disinflation was present well in advance of the downturn. It
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
Dec-07
Dec-08
Dec-09
Dec-10
Dec-11
Dec-12
Dec-13
Dec-14
Dec-15
Dec-16
Dec-17
Jun-07
Jun-08
Jun-09
Jun-10
Jun-11
Jun-12
Jun-13
Jun-14
Jun-15
Jun-16
Jun-17
Avg Hourly Earnings All Employee Hourly Atlanta Fed ECI (Wages) Avg
47
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
just took this shock to create some clear water between the hangover from
the 1970s and 1980s to the structurally low inflation environment that has
dominated since the mid-1990s. While most academic economists (and the-
ories) are wedded to the lessons learnt from the 1970s shock, the fact is this
period is the historical outlier (Figure 3).
Even the very long-term averages don’t look different. If you take US infla-
tion all the way back to 1872 the annual change averages 2.2%. Ex-out the
inflationary 1970/80s decade and it falls to just 1.8%. For a ten-year period
0.0
-1.0
-2.0
Aug-13
Aug-14
Aug-15
Aug-16
Aug-17
Nov-13
Nov-14
Nov-15
Nov-16
Nov-17
Feb-14
Feb-15
Feb-16
Feb-17
Feb-18
May-13
May-14
May-15
May-16
May-17
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
PCE Avg 1960-2017 Avg 1960-2017 (Ex 1973-1982)
-2.0
1960
1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
2008
2011
2014
2017
48
Chapter 4
within a near 150-year sample to have such an effect underlines how unique
a time the stagflationary 1970s was. It also shows central banks have been
undershooting their mandates for over a century!
Of course, pre-WW2, the volatility of both prices and growth was far more
extreme. Jumps in inflation were followed by periods of equally acute defla-
tion (Figure 4) while the economy naturally snapped back from recessions
with bursts of rapid growth (Figure 5, page 49). That meant there were not
ruinous periods of runaway prices where wealth was destroyed (outside of
20.0
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
-5.0
-10.0
-15.0
CPI Avg 1873-1949
-20.0
1873
1877
1881
1885
1889
1893
1897
1901
1905
1909
1913
1917
1921
1925
1929
1933
1937
1941
1945
1949
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
-5.0
-10.0
-15.0
% chg y/y 10yr Rolling Avg
-20.0
1871
1877
1883
1889
1895
1901
1907
1913
1919
1925
1931
1937
1943
1949
1955
1961
1967
1973
1979
1985
1991
1997
2003
2009
2015
49
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
the Great Depression). Losses one year were often recouped the next, while
the underlying direction of travel remained positive.
The economy that delivered the inflationary rush of the 1970s is also fun-
damentally different to the one we live and work in today. Many of these
structural shifts should influence price-setting behaviour. There were also
other unique factors at play, most notably the adjustment which followed the
demise of the post-war monetary regime — the gold standard.
12.0
10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
Health & Entitlements Discretionary
2.0
1970
1973
1975
1978
1981
1983
1986
1989
1991
1994
1997
1999
2002
2005
2007
2010
2013
2015
2018
2021
2023
2026
50
Chapter 4
First, population ageing. This is the combination of the baby boomer hump
reaching its twilight years and the more general increased longevity. This
is rapidly feeding in to entitlement and healthcare costs, creating signifi-
cant fiscal stress. One only has to look at the shift in federal spending in
the US to see the damage this has inflicted on value-added “discretionary
expenditure”. Unreformed entitlement programmes soak up an ever-grow-
ing (and increasingly disproportionate) share of revenues and the political
class, representing this demographic bulge, has paid for this at the expense
of future generations and more productive endeavours today (Figure 6,
page 50).
The drag from demographics not only impacts the fiscal and investment story
but also structural demand economy-wide. Older groups spend less, a function
of the move to lower retirement incomes as well as the lifestyle changes that
happen as we age. Taken together, these demographic shifts risk creating a
demand and investment vortex.
0.5 3.5
0.0 3.0
Dec-55
Aug-62
Dec-65
Aug-72
Dec-75
Aug-82
Dec-85
Aug-92
Dec-95
Aug-02
Dec-05
Aug-12
Dec-15
Apr-59
Apr-69
Apr-79
Apr-89
Apr-99
Apr-09
51
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0
IP Structures Equipment Total Investment
-1.0
1950
1953
1956
1959
1962
1965
1968
1971
1974
1977
1980
1983
1986
1989
1992
1995
1998
2001
2004
2007
2010
2013
2016
Figure 8. Source: BEA, Independent Strategy
52
Chapter 4
boomer bracket. The post-war baby-boom created a hump which drove labour
market growth sharply higher until the late 1970s. But they didn’t “recipro-
cate”. Birth rates have since fallen, constricting labour market supply. This
was a function of improvements in infant mortality, the advent of cheap
effective contraception and the surge of women into the workforce — most
noticeably between 1950 and 1990 (Figure 10).
More lately, declining fertility has been a contributor. These trends are difficult
to reverse once culturally engrained. The US actually has a higher fertility rate
than most DMs (the Eurozone’s fertility rate is a lowly 1.5 while in Japan it’s
just 1.4), but with a birth rate of 1.8 children per mother it’s still well below
the 2.1 line needed to keep the general population stable.
The rate of change of the labour market has numerous impacts on inflation.
The worker cohort has the highest propensity to consume and thus is the
primary determinant of demand growth. This is the group that needs to buy
a home and furnish it. Then raise children — an even more expensive hobby,
which no doubt is another contributor to the decline in birth rates. It’s hardly
surprising that the period which saw the fastest growth in the labour force
was the period where inflation was at its least controlled (Figure 11). This
was the natural peak of the post-war demand boom. And it’s a pattern that
will not be repeated.
The 1970s were also a time when markets were beholden to labour, negating
the supply-side response that the economy could be expected to generate today.
Indeed, this was the golden age of unionisation with a quarter of US workers
120.0 80.0
100.0
70.0
80.0
60.0 60.0
40.0
50.0
20.0
0.0 40.0
1951
1954
1957
1960
1963
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
2005
2008
2011
2014
2017
53
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
US labour force (% chg yoy 5yr avg) & CPI (% chg yoy)
3.0 16.0
Civilian Labour force CPI - rhs
14.0
2.5
12.0
2.0 10.0
8.0
1.5
6.0
1.0 4.0
2.0
0.5
0.0
0.0 -2.0
Mar-64
Oct-78
Mar-99
Oct-13
Dec-72
Aug-84
Dec-07
Jan-70
Nov-75
Jan-05
Nov-10
Jun-55
Feb-67
Sep-81
Jun-90
Feb-02
Sep-16
May-58
Jul-87
May-93
Apr-61
Apr-96
120.0
110.0
100.0
90.0
80.0
70.0
60.0
Manu Output Manu Employment
50.0
Oct-94
Oct-01
Oct-08
Oct-15
Feb-97
Feb-04
Feb-11
Feb-18
Aug-93
Aug-00
Aug-07
Aug-14
Apr-91
Jun-92
Dec-95
Apr-98
Jun-99
Dec-02
Apr-05
Jun-06
Dec-09
Apr-12
Jun-13
Dec-16
But just a decade later and the rot had set in. De-unionisation and the growth
of part-time and temporary employment, in response to the inflation surge,
created a far more flexible labour force. And the globalisation that followed
in the 1990s, with the formation of the WTO, opened up domestic labour
54
Chapter 4
It’s not the entire story of course. Non-wage income has grown over this
period, which adds a few percentage points to the tally. And there are argu-
ments that the deflators used don’t accurately capture the actual rise in living
120.0
115.0
110.0
105.0
100.0
95.0
90.0
85.0
80.0
1981
1982
1984
1985
1987
1989
1990
1992
1993
1995
1996
1998
2000
2001
2003
2004
2006
2008
2009
2011
2012
2014
2015
2017
58.0
51.0
57.0
49.0
56.0
55.0 47.0
54.0
45.0
53.0 53.0
43.0
52.0 43.0
Personal Compensation Wages - rhs
51.0 41.0
Oct-64
Oct-69
Oct-74
Oct-79
Oct-84
Oct-89
Oct-94
Oct-99
Oct-04
Oct-09
Oct-14
Apr-62
Apr-67
Apr-72
Apr-77
Apr-82
Apr-87
Apr-92
Apr-97
Apr-02
Apr-07
Apr-12
Apr-17
55
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
standards over this period. It’s doubtful any worker today would swap their
life and its comforts for a trip back to 1975. But it’s difficult to find a single
metric that suggests workers have shared in the growth of the overall eco-
nomy. Indeed, wage share has fallen from around 50% of GDP to just 43%
(Figure 14, page 55). That acts as a further drag on demand, which in turn
filters through to price levels.
In addition to changes in the size, there have been interesting shifts within the
labour force that have similar effects. The decline in prime-age participation
rates is the most visible variation. The bulk of the decline in the participa-
tion rate can be explained by boomers exiting the workforce. But there is
a substantial residual that suggests there is still a large amount of “hidden”
slack that low headline unemployment rates obscure. Indeed, the number of
working-age people not in the labour force is some 15 million higher than it
was pre-millennium (Figure 15). It’s quite possible this reflects labour market
flexibility, which makes dropping in and out of the labour force far easier.
But there seems to be some fundamental social shift embedded here as well.
This is evident in the decline in prime working male participation rates, the
US being the only major country to exhibit this trend.
The loss of jobs in the US rustbelt and growth of new industries elsewhere
is a factor, creating a misallocation of both skills and labour that in hind-
sight was beyond the free markets ability to respond to. We’d note that this
period also ties with the massive increase in US incarceration rates. The
prison population has grown by nearly 2mn since 1980 and, if you include
those on parole, the net currently captures nearly 6mn Americans, or about
50.0
35.0
33.9
33.0
45.0
31.0
40.0
29.0
35.0 27.0
Mar-84
Oct-93
Mar-07
Oct-16
Dec-89
Aug-97
Dec-12
Jan-88
Nov-91
Jan-11
Nov-14
Jun-78
Feb-86
Sep-95
Jun-01
Feb-09
May-80
Jul-99
May-03
Apr-82
Apr-05
56
Chapter 4
half the increase seen in the prime-age non-working population during this
time. That’s a group that, assuming it is allowed to participate in the labour
market, has far more limited bargaining power.
So there are several factors that form our structural nutshell. Demographics
is the most far-reaching as it weighs both on supply and demand, via ageing
and falling birth rates. These have proved self-reinforcing, sucking money
from the solutions (investment and productivity). The decline in the growth
of the working-age population is a further drag on demand. And falling birth
rates act as yet another anchor.
This doesn’t mean inflation can’t ever rise again. But what it does suggest is
that there will be more viscosity to short-term cyclical upswings in prices.
Changes in underlying price levels should remain modest and the chance of
any sustained period of runaway inflation is minimal, even after a lengthy
period of low interest rates and an economy that is running closer to capacity.
57
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
58
CHAPTER 5
Of rabbits, bankers and what matters
While the central bank money-wheel keeps spinning, asset markets will
continue to rise. But central banks need to embrace the structural forces that
are affecting economies if they are to avoid the cycle ending in more than
just an echo of recent disasters.
If central bankers were rabbits they would have three ears. This is not to say
they are monsters. They are, in the main, diligent, dutiful and moderately
paid. But they are inbred. They are selected out of a pool of academics (and
the odd senior official) and return to academia when they are done — that is
if they don’t opt to cash-in at an investment bank instead. Their central bank
conferences are peopled by their peers and academics, who present esoteric
papers inaccessible to mankind, usually about yesterday’s policy options.
The result is an unrealism of thought that is critical now. “Now”, because of
the need to return to a normalised monetary policy almost everywhere that
matters. As we’ll explain, a lack of realism makes this more unlikely to be
a smooth transition.
Dead too is the day of the ‘generalist’ like Francis Bacon, 17th century English
philosopher, author, statesman, scientist, jurist and orator who died as a result
of pneumonia caught burying a chicken in snow to test refrigeration. The
result is narrow vision.
59
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
10.0
9.0
8.0
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
R² = 0.2889
3.0
2.0
0.75
1.00
1.25
1.50
1.75
2.00
2.25
2.50
2.75
Core PCE, % chg y/y
Today’s major central banks all have the same target — 2% inflation — and
similar tools for achieving it. But the target itself may not be relevant and
the tools used to set the policies to achieve it are based on theoretical models
which may lack reality.
But what if other forces drive the inflation rate — globalisation, technological
change and demography, for example? And what if wages do not rise with
employment because of the sorts of jobs now being created and the wages
they are worth? And what if these forces are global and not domestic? The
answer is that the models and policies are then dealing with a fantasy and
central bankers are a cavalry host of Don Quixotes tilting at windmills. That is
our view. If correct, it would mean that the traditional role of central bankers
60
Chapter 5
40.0
30.0
20.0
10.0
0.0
Mar-08
Mar-09
Mar-10
Mar-11
Mar-12
Mar-13
Mar-14
Mar-15
Mar-16
Mar-17
Sep-07
Sep-08
Sep-09
Sep-10
Sep-11
Sep-12
Sep-13
Sep-14
Sep-15
Sep-16
Figure 2. Source: BIS, Independent Strategy
as guardians of inflation is much diminished. But that does not mean they
have no purpose. They do.
The other day we laid out on the kitchen table all the current central bank
reports and minutes from the ECB, Fed, BoJ and also the BIS — the central
bank of central banks and in many ways their collective conscience. Only
the BIS dealt convincingly with what we see as the elephant in the room7 or
the major issue central banks should be addressing.
Yet there is no discussion in any of the world’s major central banks about this.
Only the BIS’s Claudio Borio8 is sounding the alarm. The rest are either in
denial or aware of the danger and doing the three monkey thing. Is the obses-
sion with the unmeasurable and the model down to denial or a smokescreen?
In any case, this defines the future primary task of central banks: financial
stability. This is all very neat but what does it mean for us as investors? Some
things are already apparent.
61
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
The inflation targets pursued by the major central banks are determined
globally more than domestically and won’t be achieved. This means bond
yields won’t rise as much as we once thought. Central banks are only likely
to raise rates very gradually because inflation targets will continue to be
elusive (or because there is a subliminal awareness of the elephant in the
room). But they will have to raise them nonetheless because they need a
buffer for future crises.
The increase in policy rates will not result in a meaningful rise in real long-
term rates. Central banks will9 endeavour to hold down term-premia and long
rates. The BoJ already does this as a part of its monetary policy targets. So
the build-up in debt relative to GDP will continue.
The result is that a future debt crisis is in the making. Timing is difficult.
But the new tools of central banks, such as high levels of excess commer-
cial bank reserves, will only be partially successful in assuaging the effects.
Until that happens, the markets will go on dancing to the music. The drivers
of currencies are likely to change. Relative monetary policies will wane in
influence. Relative growth and return on assets as well as geopolitical events
will be more relevant.
62
CHAPTER 6
The second machine age, the fourth industrial revolution, however you want
to term it, it’s undeniable that we’re living in an epoch of technological
transformation. And one that is unprecedented in history. While the indu-
strial revolution was disruptive, its reach was limited. But with the creation
of thinking machines, we face technologies that could end up competing
directly with what it means to be human. While the final outcome has yet to
be determined, this changes the rules of the game. And the policy responses
to cope will have to be equally innovative.
The sheer breadth of disruption in the information age makes analysing these
all the more problematic. Furthermore, there is a number of structural shifts
that are happening in lockstep, most of which are rooted in demography.
Disentangling these interwoven threads will be difficult. Explaining the
impact of these changes to an electorate whose lives are being disrupted will
be a task of even greater magnitude.
63
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
While the information and technology revolution that developed over the
course of this period created millions of new jobs, these were largely white
collar posts that required higher levels of skills and education, or at least
skills that were not directly transferrable from a Michigan car plant. And
even in some of the more disruptive sectors, the surge in productivity
meant that jobs created were often lost elsewhere in the industry, or even
within individual firms. Information, for example, saw near zero net job
creation over the entire pre- and post-crisis period, whereas professional
15.0
10.0
5.0
0.0
-5.0
-10.0
Wholesale
Retail
Utilities
Durable Goods
Mining
Other Serv
Prof & Biz
Financial Serv
Leisure
Construction
Information
Non-Durables
Retail
Utilities
Durable Goods
Mining
Other Serv
Prof & Biz
Financial Serv
Construction
Leisure
Information
Non-Durables
64
Chapter 6
and businesses services saw the strongest growth of any area (Figure 2, p.
64). The result has been a widening of inequality and decrease in social
mobility, as the gaps between the rungs of the ladder were pulled apart.
Indeed, in the US, the GINI coefficient rose from 34.6 in 1979 to 41.5 as
of 2016, which puts America alongside Mexico and Argentina in the ine-
quality stakes.
Disruption accelerating
We take this as the starting point for analysing just how technology will
impact the economy and society over the next decade or two. We are optimi-
stic that in the long-run the current information revolution will raise living
standards across the board. There is not one sector of the economy that can’t
be improved (Inset 1, p. 66). But as these innovations wash through it’s vital
that governments take steps to prevent “winner takes all” outcomes.
Unfortunately, the network effects of the internet mean nearly all online sectors
have a monopolistic predisposition. We’ve seen this in internet search, social
media and retail for example. And new challengers are more often than not
bought up by the dominant firms, further stifling competition. That’s not to
say that there is no social good to come from the network effects these behe-
moths create. There are clearly significant productivity gains to be unleashed
from this growth and the growth of other “intangibles”, both in terms of cost-
and time-saving as well as the ability to replicate digital goods or services
instantly, infinitely and for almost zero marginal cost.
65
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
Total disruption
As artificial intelligence matures as a more generalised technology
we should see breakthroughs in nearly every sector of the econo-
my. The ability of AI to sift through and analyse vast troves of data
will vastly improve the efficiency of most businesses. Medicine is
the most interesting example; already this technology is revolu-
tionising medical diagnosis, allowing diseases to be caught earlier
and treated more effectively. These advances should be comple-
mented by genetics, another field where AI is helping accelerate
development, often in lockstep with diagnostic programmes. Ad-
vanced robotics meanwhile will improve everything from surgery
to health and social care. In an aging society with a shrinking
working age population all of these advances are essential.
This research is driving forward some of the most critical new areas. This
includes breakthroughs in machine learning, which have accelerated develop-
ment of a number of dependent technologies such as big data, the internet of
things, robotics, self-driving cars, medical diagnostics and genetics. Innovation
is also driving down the costs of clean energy and battery storage, showing
that the exponential improvements that Moore’s law demonstrated for the
silicon chip is in fact applicable to many other innovations. But these changes
are not exclusive to new technologies. Machine learning can already process
legal documents and compose newspaper articles and it won’t be long before
it displaces call centres; one of the “new” soon-to-be “old” industries that
soaked up displaced workers from prior old industry.
The common denominator of all these innovations is that they will destroy
existing systems and replace them with new ones. They will impact the pro-
duction of things, but their real value-added is derived from their intangible
nature. They will, over time, increase living standards, lowering costs and
improving quality. Even at stable income levels, living standards will rise. It
will also make economic growth less dependent upon capital and raw material
66
Chapter 6
140.0
130.0
120.0
110.0
100.0
90.0
80.0
70.0
Mar-06
Mar-08
Mar-10
Mar-12
Mar-14
Mar-16
Mar-18
Nov-06
Nov-08
Nov-10
Nov-12
Nov-14
Nov-16
Jul-07
Jul-09
Jul-11
Jul-13
Jul-15
Jul-17
Figure 3. Source: BEA, Independent Strategy
inputs. Weak gross fixed capital formation alongside booming R&D spending
in the US highlights this ongoing shift (Figure 3).
Disruptive technologies and the growth of intangibles also improve the qua-
lity of life. Intangibles use less material inputs (the major desecrators of the
planet) and use them more efficiently. For example, using big data and the
internet of things to improve food distribution could slash the one-third of
production that is currently left to waste. That would decrease the cost of
food, reduce the environmental damage from its production and distribution
while delivering a social benefit by allowing land to be returned to the wil-
derness for our children.
Like all games everything has a finite lifespan and once the level of disruption
reaches a tipping point it’s difficult to recalibrate. That is the juncture many
67
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
4.5
4.0
3.5 3.35
3.0
Nov-76
Nov-07
Oct-58
Oct-89
Mar-56
Mar-87
Mar-18
Feb-69
Sep-71
Feb-00
Sep-02
Jul-66
Jan-82
Aug-84
Jul-97
Jan-13
Aug-15
May-61
Dec-63
Apr-74
Jun-79
May-92
Dec-94
Apr-05
Jun-10
Figure 4. Source: BEA, Independent Strategy
But the ability to push political narratives quickly, to millions, at almost zero
cost, was seized upon by the less altruistic as a way of protecting their inte-
rests (or simply agitate). These ranged from state actors to private sponsors
with specific agendas in mind. The most high-profile affront was executed
by Cambridge Analytica which rather cleverly found a way of exploiting
data on Facebook that allowed it to profile individual voters. The aim was to
predict and influence decision-making and do so without voters ever being
aware that they were being manipulated. Less sophisticated strategies have
been used in countless elections across the world, from the US Presidential
vote to Brexit.
Social media’s problem is far broader than just electoral manipulation. It’s
the selling of unqualified untruths alongside traditional reporting that has
68
Chapter 6
Ultimate benefits
It’s natural to feel slightly uncomfortable with these threats, but it really
only serves to highlight how quickly things are changing. There is no putting
this genie back in the bottle but being aware of the vulnerabilities allows
one to take steps to protect against them. The need to create more trusted
69
DEATH OF DEMOCRACY
11
6
Peter sends
Paul receives the
Bitcoin from
Bitcoin to Paul 2
Peter A new Block is
created online. This
represents the
transaction
5
The validated Block is
added to the Chain,
creating a permanent, non- 33
repudiable, transparent
This Block is
record
4 broadcast to
These nodes every node
approve the
transaction and
validate it
70
Chapter 6
That doesn’t address the bigger questions of what will become of the human
pecking order once intelligent machines are the norm. If it’s only those at
the top that will be able to capture the fruits of innovation more generalised
artificial intelligence will bring, then the systems that confer legitimacy on
these divergences will be increasingly called into question. That could lead
to a real break away from democracy. But it does at least provide a platform
from which to start to tackle the challenges presented by this process of
technological disruption.
• Social media and other forums that thrive on user-generated content will
increase in their power to exploit social grievances for political ends — mainly
in support of populism. This process erodes trust and accountability (fake
news), threatening the entire democratic model.
For techno-autocracies:
• Technology will facilitate the control of citizens through big data, blockchain
technologies and increasingly advanced forms of (AI-driven) surveillance;
• But technological advances will lift living standards as they are quickly
applied to both demand and production while the social and equality issues
are carefully controlled by the “all-seeing” state. This confers some degree
of legitimacy on regimes, even if personal freedoms are curtailed. That’s the
techno-autocratic quid pro quo!
71
Endnotes
73