Xuemei Zhang Operation Strategy in An e Commerce
Xuemei Zhang Operation Strategy in An e Commerce
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 31 (2024) 1093–1121 RESEARCH
DOI: 10.1111/itor.13186
Received 7 December 2021; received in revised form 3 July 2022; accepted 13 July 2022
Abstract
E-commerce platforms provide sales channels for enterprises to exploit more markets. Meanwhile,
E-commerce platform supply chain members are increasingly using live streaming services to boost prof-
its. However, whether to introduce live streaming services to E-commerce platform supply chain and which
operation strategy to implement is unclear. In this study, we construct three models to examine the oper-
ation strategy in an E-commerce platform supply chain by considering live streaming services. The results
show that introducing live streaming services is always beneficial for both the E-commerce platform and live
streaming services supplier. When live streaming services is introduced and an appropriate revenue sharing
proportion and signing fees are set by the E-commerce platform supply chain members, the operation strat-
egy of live streaming services introduced and implemented by the manufacturer is the consistent choice for
E-commerce platform supply chain members, which is also beneficial for E-commerce platform supply chain
system and consumers.
Keywords: supply chain management; E-commerce platform; live streaming services; operation strategy
1. Introduction
The rise of Internet information and mobile technology over the past few years led to the rapid
development of E-commerce. Many E-commerce platforms, such as Amazon, eBay, and JD, have
entered to the E-commerce market (Wang et al., 2019; Yoo and Jang, 2019; Shi et al., 2022). These
platforms and their suppliers make up E-commerce platform supply chains (EPSCs) (Tsunoda
and Zennyo, 2021; Guan et al., 2022). In EPSCs, E-commerce platforms act as retailers (reselling
∗
Corresponding author.
1
Available at https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1724818485657722150&wfr=spider&for=pc (Accessed 1 July 2022).
2
Available at https://www.iimedia.cn/c400/83735.html (Accessed 1 July 2022).
3
Available at https://www.askci.com/news/chanye/20220318/1451401746320_2.shtml (Accessed 1 July 2022).
4
Available at https://www.cnbc.com/2021/05/03/retailers-from-bloomingdales-to-petco-test-livestreaming-to-win-
sales.html (Accessed 1 July 2022).
5
Available at http://www.southmoney.com/caijing/caijingyaowen/202111/19125546.html (Accessed 1 July 2022).
6
Available at https://www.300.cn/dspd/341064.html (Accessed 1 July 2022).
7
Available at https://zhuanlan.zhihu.com/p/262053824 (Accessed 1 July 2022).
8
Available at https://www.sohu.com/a/133710602_633472 (Accessed 1 July 2022).
2. Literature review
There are three main streams of literature closely related to this study: decision-making in EPSCs,
application of live streaming commerce, and operation strategy in supply chains.
The first stream of literature concerns the decision-making in EPSCs, which received considerable
attention (Shi et al., 2022; Zhang et al., 2022b). The majority of previous studies mainly focus on the
topics such as price strategy (Li et al., 2021b; Zhao et al., 2022), advertising investment (Du et al.,
2019), service level (Bian et al., 2021; Guo et al., 2021b), and spillover effects (Xia and Niu, 2019).
Specifically, Lu and Liu (2013) examined the impact of channel acceptance on the pricing strategy
and profits in an EPSC. Hao et al. (2017) analyzed the role of two unique features of advertising
in determining the optimal advertising revenue-sharing contract in an EPSC. Other studies related
9
Available at https://www.agoow.cn/xinwen/1217.html?ivk_sa=1024320u (Accessed 1 July 2022).
The second stream of related literature is about application of live streaming commerce (Park and
Lin, 2020; Lu et al., 2021; Zhang et al., 2022a). Live streaming is a type of user-generated content
(Lu and Chen, 2021), and it is also a new type of E-commerce shopping in which consumers can
interact with streamers in real time (Kang et al., 2021). The research mainly explored the factors
that influence consumer shopping behavior, including influencer effect (Hou et al., 2019), consumer
use intention (Chen and Lin, 2018) and consumer trust (Guo et al., 2021a). In particular, Zhuo
et al. (2019) evaluated the impact of social media influencers (SMIs) on the live streaming users.
Park and Lin (2020) explored the influences of various matches on the consumer attitudes with
the context of live streaming shopping with internet celebrities in China. The rise of live stream-
ing also boosted its fusion with platform (Kang et al., 2021; Li et al., 2021a). For example, Chen
and Lin (2018) studied the influence of platform-generated factors such as flow, social interac-
tion, and endorsement on customer behavior. Sun et al. (2019) found that live streaming shop-
ping platforms factors such as IT affordance play an important role in customer behavior. Li et al.
(2021c) developed a theoretical model to understand how LSSs affect user stickiness through users
attachment.
This area of research mainly empirically studies the application of live streaming commerce. Few
studies examine application issues of live streaming commerce from the perspective of operation
management. Accordingly, we examine whether and how to introduce LSSs in an EPSC, and how
the LSSs affect the decisions of pricing and service and operational performance of the EPSC
system. To the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to address these issues in EPSCs by
considering different operation strategies.
The third stream of literature relates to the operation strategy in supply chains, which aroused ex-
tensive attention (Qi et al., 2017; Dong et al., 2021). Many existing studies focused on channel
structure selection in supply chains (He et al., 2020). In particular, Tian et al. (2022) derived man-
agerial insights by considering horizontal differentiation across channels. Qiao and Su (2021) ad-
dressed the choice issues of a manufacturers licensing strategy and the independent remanufacturers
We consider an EPSC consisting of a manufacturer (M), an E-commerce platform (E), and a LSSs
supplier (L) when LSSs are introduced. In this EPSC, M sells products to consumers through plat-
form selling mode. By considering whether and how to introduce LSSs, three models are found:
benchmark model without LSSs (Model NL), operation model of LSSs introduced by M (Model
ML), and operation model of LSSs introduced by E (Model EL), which are illustrated in the fol-
lowing Fig. 1.
Similar to He et al. (2022), in the benchmark model NL, M sells products to consumers di-
rectly through E-commerce platform channel, and M pays a certain proportion of the revenue
and slotting fee to E. When the LSSs are introduced, M sells products to consumers through
E-commerce platform and live streaming channel by sharing a certain proportion of the revenue
with E and L (Xie et al., 2021), respectively. In the model ML, M introduces and adopts the LSSs
by paying a signing fee to L. While in the model EL, E introduces and adopts the LSSs by pay-
ing a signing fee to L (Fan et al., 2019; Guo et al., 2021b; Liu et al., 2021). For example, the
E-commerce platform Taobao launched Taobao live streaming to sell products (Hu and Chaudhry,
2020).
In Fig. 1, we can also find that, in the model ML, M shares a certain proportion of the revenue
from the live streaming channel with L, such as in Twitch.tv.10 In the model EL, L obtain a certain
proportion of M’s revenue and pay a certain proportion to E, such as Pinduoduo and Kuaishou.11
Moreover, the LSSs introduced by M or E has a service spillover effect (Chai et al., 2020),
which represents the impact of the LSSs on the E-commerce platform channel (Abhishek et al.,
2016).
Based on the problem description, we employ the symbols and notations given in Table 1 through-
out this paper.
To make the analysis tractable, we introduce the following assumptions.
Consumer√demand. √ We assume that the positive effect of advertising/service investment on the
demand is ε ke /ε kl , ε > 0 (Du et al., 2019). Moreover, the market demand is a linear function
of the price and service level. Considering the advertising/service
√ factor and service spillover
√effect,
the demands of the two channels are De = α − βe pe + ε ke + ρs and Dl = α − βl pl + ε kl + s
(Ma, 2021; Qin et al., 2021), respectively, where α > 0, βl ≥ βe > 012 , and 0 ≤ ρ ≤ 1 (Xia and Liu,
2019; Chai et al., 2020).
Cost structure. Following Xue et al. (2020) and Zhang et al. (2021a), the service cost of live
streaming channel depends on the service level provided by L. Thus, the service investment cost
10
Available at https://www.sohu.com/a/127500647_483767 (Accessed 1 July 2022).
11
Available at https://zhuanlan.zhihu.com/p/262053824 (Accessed 1 July 2022).
12
http://www.ifastdata.com/data/upload/ueditor/20211009/616104925d62a.pdf (Accessed 13 April 2022).
Notations Definitions
Indexes
i EPSC member i, where i ∈ {E, L, M, T } and E, L, M, and T refer to the E-commerce
platform, LSSs supplier, manufacturer, and EPSC system, respectively
j Model j, where j ∈ {NL, ML, EL}
h Channel h, where h ∈ {e, l, t} and e, l, and t refer to the E-commerce platform channel, live
streaming channel, and two channels, respectively
Parameters
α Potential market size of the two channels
βe /βl Price elasticity coefficient of the E-commerce platform/live streaming channel
ε Consumers sensitivity coefficient toward advertising/service
ρ Degree of the service spillover effect
φ Revenue sharing proportion paid by M/L to E
λ Revenue sharing proportion paid by M to L
cm Unit production cost of products manufactured by M
ce /cl Unit operation cost of E-commerce platform/live streaming channel
Fe Slotting fee paid by M to E
Fl Signing fee paid by M/E to L
Decision variables
s Service level provided by L
ke /kl Investment of E’s advertising/L’s service
pe /pl Unit retail price of E-commerce platform/live streaming channel
Other notations
Dhj Demand of channel h in model j
πi j Profit of EPSC member i in model j
is assumed to be a convex function of the service level, that is, 12 s2 (Li et al., 2019b; Zhang et al.,
2021b). In addition, since E and L only display the products (Liu et al., 2021), while M produces
products and processes customer orders, we assume that the unit operation cost of E-commerce
platform or live streaming channel is zero, that is, ce = cl = 0 (Li et al., 2019b; Zhang et al., 2021a).
Power structure. Following Fan et al. (2019), Rahmani et al. (2020), and Quintero-Araujo et al.
(2019), both the cooperative and competitive relationships are assumed to exist simultaneously in
the EPSC. Meanwhile, we assume that the E and M have the highest and the lowest bargaining
powers, respectively (Xie et al., 2021; Shen et al., 2022). Thus, in the model NL, M and E play a
Stackelberg game, in which E is the leader and M is the follower. In the models ML and EL, M,
E, and L paly a sequential game, in which E is the leader, followed by L, and lastly by M (Zennyo,
2020; Zhang et al., 2021a).
If the price elasticity coefficient of the E-commerce platform channel βe is sufficiently large and
that of the live streaming channel βl is very small, that is, βe > 2α(1−φ)
cm
and βl < λ2 , and then the de-
mand of the E-commerce platform channel is negative, and thus, L will not provide service (Li et al.,
2019a, 2019b; Zhang et al., 2021a, 2021b). Therefore, to ensure that the optimal decision results are
meaningful and generate interesting managerial insights, we focus only on the case of βe ≤ 2α(1−φ) cm
and βl ≥ λ2 (which we elaborate on and demonstrate in the proofs of Theorems 1 and 2).
In this section, we derive the equilibrium results for the models NL, ML, and EL. Following Zhang
et al. (2021b), we denote γ1 = 2βl − λ, γ2 = 2βl − λ + λφ, γ3 = 2βl − λ + 2ρλ, and γ4 = 2βl − λ +
λφ + 2ρ(1 − λ). According to the above assumptions of 0 < φ < 1 and βl ≥ λ2 , we can easily find
that γ2 , γ3 , γ4 > γ1 > 0, and γ4 > γ2 > 0.
4.1. Model NL
In the model NL, the LSSs are not introduced, M sells products directly to consumers through
E-commerce platform channel by paying slotting fee Fe to E and sharing a certain proportion φ
of the revenue with E. M and E play a dynamic Stackelberg game. E firstly decides the advertising
investment ke , and then M sets the retail price pe . The optimization models of profit maximization
for E and M are formulated as
max πM
NL
= ((1 − φ)pNL
e − cm )De − Fe .
NL
(2)
pNL
e
By using the reverse induction, we have the optimal results for the model NL, which are described
in the following Theorem 1.
∗ α2
Theorem 1. In the model NL, the optimal advertising investment is kNL
e = ε2
, and the retail price of
NL∗ 2α(1−φ)+βe cm
the E-commerce platform channel is pe = 2βe (1−φ) .
And thus, the optimal demand of the E-commerce platform channel, profits of M, E, and
∗
NL∗ (2α(1−φ)−βe cm )2 NL∗ (4α 2 (1−φ)2 −βe2 c2m )φ
EPSC system are: DNL
e = 2α(1−φ)−β
2(1−φ)
e cm
, π M = 4βe (1−φ)
− Fe , π E = 4βe (1−φ)2
+ Fe ,
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ 2α(1−φ)
and πTNL = πM NL
+ πENL . To ensure that DNL
e ≥ 0, we assume that βe ≤ cm
, and this assump-
tion holds throughout the paper (Ren et al., 2021b).
4.2. Model ML
In the model ML, the LSSs are introduced by M, and M sells products to consumers through
the E-commerce platform and live streaming channels by paying slotting fee Fe and signing fee Fl
to E and L, respectively. In addition, M shares a certain proportion φ or λ of revenue with E or
L, respectively. M, E, and L play a three-stage sequential game (Fan et al., 2019). E first decides
the advertising investment ke , and then L determines the service investment kl and service level s.
Finally, M sets the retail price pe and pl . The optimization models of profit maximization for E, L,
and M are formulated as
max πM
ML
= ((1 − φ)pML
e − cm )DML
e − Fe + ((1 − λ)pML
l − cm )DML
l − Fl . (5)
e ,pl
pML ML
By using the reverse induction, we have the optimal results for the model ML, which are described
in the following Theorem 2.
∗ α 2 γ32
Theorem 2. In the model ML, the optimal advertising and service investments are kML
e = ε 2 γ12
,
∗ α2 ∗
kML
l = ε2
, respectively; the service level is sML = 2λα
γ1
; and the retail prices of the two channels are
∗ α 2 γ32 +αγ3 ∗
pML
e = 2βe γ1
+ 2(1−φ)
cm
and pML
l = 2α
γ1
+ cm
2(1−λ)
.
∗
To ensure that sML ≥ 0, we assume that βl ≥ λ2 (Ren et al., 2021b), which holds throughout the
paper. Theorem 2 shows that, with the increase of the potential market demand of products, the
advertising and service investments, service level, and retail prices of the two channels all increase.
When the production cost increases, M will raise the retail prices of two channels.
And thus, the demands of E-commerce platform and live streaming channels, profits of M, E, L,
and EPSC system are
4.3. Model EL
In the model EL, the LSSs are introduced by E, and M sells products to consumers through the
live streaming and E-commerce platform channels. M and E pay slotting fee Fe and signing fee
Fl to E and L, respectively. M and L all share a certain proportion φ of the revenue with E. In
addition, M also shares a certain proportion λ of the revenue with L. M, E, and L play a three-
stage sequential game (Fan et al., 2019). E first decides the advertising investment ke , and then
1
max πLEL = λ(1 − φ)pEL EL
l Dl + Fl − (sEL )2 , (7)
kl ,s
EL EL 2
max πM
EL
= ((1 − φ)pEL
e − cm )De − Fe + ((1 − λ)pl
EL EL
− cm )DEL
l , (8)
e ,pl
pEL EL
By using the reverse induction, we have the optimal results for the model EL, which are described
in the following Theorem 3.
∗ α 2 γ42
Theorem 3. In the model EL, the optimal advertising and service investments are kEL
e = ε 2 γ22
and
∗ α2 ∗ 2λ(1−φ)α
kEL
l = ε2
, respectively; the service level is sEL = γ2
; and the retail prices of the two channels
∗ α 2 γ42 +αγ4 ∗
are pEL
e = 2βe γ2
+ cm
2(1−φ)
and pEL
l = 2α
γ2
+ cm
2(1−λ)
.
Theorem 3 shows that, with the increase of the potential market demand of the products, the
advertising, and service investments, service level and retail prices in the two channels all increase.
When the production cost increases, M will raise the retail prices of the two channels.
And thus, the optimal demands of the E-commerce platform and live streaming channels, profits
of M, E, L, and EPSC system are
In this section, we explore the decisions of M, E, and L, and investigate the impact of market,
production, and revenue sharing parameters on the EPSC members decisions and profits. First, we
characterize the equilibrium results in Subsection 5.1. In Subsection 5.2, we compare the optimal
solutions of the three models. Finally, we derive the optimal operation strategy in Subsection 5.3.
By analyzing the impacts of unit production cost cm , service spillover ρ, and revenue sharing pro-
portion λ on the retail prices, we have the following Proposition 1.
Proposition 1. The change trends of the retail prices of the two channels with parameters cm , ρ, and λ
are:
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(1) ∂ pNL
e /∂cm = ∂ pMLe /∂cm = ∂ pEL
e /∂cm > 0, ∂ pl
ML
/∂cm = ∂ pEL
l /∂cm > 0;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(2) ∂ pe /∂ρ > ∂ pe /∂ρ > ∂ pl /∂ρ = ∂ pl /∂ρ = 0;
ML EL ML EL
∗ ∗
(3) ∂ pML
l /∂λ > ∂ pEL
l /∂λ > 0.
Proposition 1 (1) shows that a higher unit production cost will increase the retail prices of the
E-commerce platform and live streaming channels. That is to say, M will increase the retail prices
of two channels with the increase of production cost in the three models NL, ML, and EL. Ad-
ditionally, the change trends of the retail prices in three models are the same. Hence, production
cost has the same effect on pricing strategy in the three models. Proposition 1 (2) indicates that
when the LSSs are introduced, a higher service spillover effect coefficient will increase the retail
price of the E-commerce platform channel, which will not affect the retail price of the live stream-
ing channel. And the increase range of the retail price in the model ML is greater than that in the
model EL. Because the service spillover effect can expand market share. Therefore, M should in-
troduce and adopt the LSSs to heighten the service spillover effect to expand market share, and
then take advantage of this effect to obtain more benefits. Proposition 1 (3) shows that, when
the LSSs are introduced, with the increase of the revenue sharing proportion paid by M to L,
M will increase the retail prices of the live streaming channel, and the increase range of the retail
price in the model ML is greater than that in the model EL. Because when M shares its revenue
with L, M’s revenue decreases, and then M will heighten the retail prices of the live streaming
channel.
By analyzing the effects of potential market demand α and the service spillover effect coefficient
ρ on the advertising investment, we have the following Proposition 2.
Proposition 2. The change trends of the advertising investment with parameters α and ρ are:
∗ ∗ ∗
e ∗ /∂α > ∂ke ∗ /∂α > ∂ke
(1) ∂kML EL NL
/∂α > 0;
(2) ∂ke /∂ρ > ∂ke /∂ρ > 0.
ML EL
From the perspective of advertising investment, Proposition 2 indicates that higher potential mar-
ket demand and service spillover effect will increase the advertising investment. This implies that
Proposition 3 (1) indicates that a higher potential market demand will increase the service invest-
ment, but a higher service investment sensitivity will decrease the service investment. In addition,
the effects of potential market demand and service investment sensitivity on the service investment
in the models ML and EL are the same. This implies that EPSC members should introduce and
adopt the LSSs to attract more potential consumers, and then motivate L to increase the service
investment. Proposition 3 (2) shows that a higher potential market demand and revenue sharing
proportion will increase the service level, and the effects of potential market demand or revenue
sharing proportion on the service level in the model ML are larger than that in the model EL.
From the perspective of increasing L’s service level, it can be suggested that EPSC members should
invest advertising to expand market share and set an appropriate revenue sharing proportion.
In this part, by comparing the equilibrium results in the three models NL, ML, and EL, we can
derive the following conclusions.
First, by comparing the optimal retail prices in the three models, we have the following Proposi-
tion 4.
Proposition 4. The optimal retail prices of the two channels in the different three models satisfy
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(1) if α > 1, then pML
e > pNLe , otherwise pMLe ≤ pNL
e ;
EL∗ NL∗ EL∗ NL∗
if α > 2 , then p e > p e ∗, otherwise p e ∗ ≤ p e ∗;
EL∗
if α > 3 , then pe > pML
e , otherwise pEL
e ≤ pML
e ;
∗ ∗
(2) pML
l > pEL
l .
Proposition 5 (1) indicates that when the potential market demand is high enough, the retail
prices of the E-commerce platform channel in the models ML and EL are all higher than that in
the model NL, while the retail price of the E-commerce platform channel in the model EL is higher
than that in the model ML. However, only the thresholds of potential market demand are different
in each model (see Fig. 2). In other words, under some conditions, M will set a higher retail price
when the LSSs are introduced, and the retail price is the highest in the model EL. This implies
that M will set an appropriate retail price of the E-commerce platform channel according to the
parameters of the market, revenue sharing proportion, and service spillover effect.
Different from the retail price of the E-commerce platform channel, when the LSSs are intro-
duced, Proposition 4 (2) shows that the retail price of the live streaming channel in the model ML
is higher than that in the model EL. That is to say, M sets higher retail price of the live streaming
channel in the model ML than that in the model EL. The reason is that, M can control the live
streaming channel in the model ML, and then set a higher retail price of the live streaming channel.
To describe the impacts of potential market demand on the retail prices of E-commerce platform
channel in the three models, the parameters are setting as βe = 0.1, βl = 0.12, ρ = 0.1, ε = 0.1,
φ = 0.2, λ = 0.1, cm = 5, Fe = 500, and Fl = 1000. And then, the thresholds of 1 , 2 , and 3
are calculated as 1 = 4.6875, 2 = 4.6488, and 3 = 3.9894. To clearly describe the relationship
between the optimal retail prices in the E-commerce platform channel, α varied within the range of
[3.8,4.8]. Figure 2 illustrates the optimal retail prices in three models.
Figure 2(a) indicates that a higher potential market demand will increase the retail price of the E-
commerce platform channel. Besides, when the potential market demand is enough high, M will set
the highest retail price of the E-commerce platform channel in the model EL. On the contrary, when
the potential market demand is low, M will set the highest retail price of the E-commerce platform
channel when the LSSs are not introduced. This implies that EPSC members should introduce and
adopt the LSSs to explore more potential consumers. Manufacturers determine the retail prices
according to the parameters of the market, cost, and revenue sharing proportion. Figure 2(b) shows
that, a higher potential market demand will increase the retail price of the live streaming channel.
M always sets a higher retail price of the live streaming channel in the model ML than that in the
model EL, which verifies the conclusions in the Proposition 4.
We set α = 10, βl ∈ [0.1, 0.15], and ρ ∈ [0.1, 0.3], and illustrate the effect of the price elasticity
coefficient of live streaming channel βl and service spillover effect ρ on the retail price in the three
models, which are described in the following Fig. 3.
Fig. 3. Impact of retail price elasticity and service spillover effect on the retail price.
From Fig. 3(a), we can find that a higher service spillover effect will increase the retail price of
the E-commerce platform channel. When the effects of the price elasticity and service spillover on
the retail price of E-commerce platform channel are very low, M will set higher retail price of the
E-commerce platform channel when the LSSs are introduced. When the service spillover effect is
high, the retail price of the E-commerce platform channel in the model ML is higher than that in
the model EL. This implies that the LSSs and service spillover effect can raise the retail price of
the E-commerce platform channel. Therefore, manufacturers would more likely to introduce and
adopt the LSSs from LSSs supplier. Figure 3(b) indicates that M will decrease the retail price of
the live streaming channel with the increase in the price elasticity coefficient of the live streaming
channel. The service spillover effect will not affect the M’s price decisions. These findings verify the
conclusions in the Propositions 1 and 4.
Next, we analyze the optimal decisions of E and L in the three models. By comparing the op-
timal advertising investments, service investments, and service levels in the three models, we have
Proposition 5.
Proposition 5. The optimal advertising investment, service investment, and service level in the three
models satisfy
∗ ∗ ∗
e ∗ > ke ∗ > ke
(1) kML EL NL
;
ML
(2) kl = kl ;
EL
∗ ∗
(3) sML > sEL .
Proposition 5 (1) indicates that when the LSSs are introduced, M will increase its advertising in-
vestment. Additionally, E will provide the highest advertising investment in the model ML. There-
fore, M and E should agree to introduce the LSSs to increase the adverting investment and attract
more potential consumers. Proposition 5 (2) shows that when the LSSs are introduced, the LSSs
supplier will provide the same service investments in the models ML and EL. Proposition 5 (3)
shows that the L will provide a higher service level in the model ML than that in the model EL.
Consequently, EPSC members should introduce the LSSs, and the operation strategy of the LSSs
introduced by M will increase the advertising investment and service level, which can expand mar-
ket share.
By denoting Dti = Die + Dil , i ∈ {NL, ML, EL}, and comparing the equilibrium demands of the
E-commerce platform channel, live streaming channel, and two channels in the three models, we
have the following Proposition 6.
Proposition 6. The demands of the two channels in the three models satisfy:
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
e ∗ > De ∗ , otherwise De ∗ ≤ De ∗ ;
(1) if α < 4 , then DML NL ML NL
∗ ∗
if α < 5 , then De > De , otherwise De ≤ De ; DML
EL NL EL NL
e > DEL
e ;
∗ ∗
(2) DMLl > DEL
l ;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(3) if 6 < α < 7 , then DtML > DtNL , otherwise DtML ≤ DtNL ;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
if 8 < α < 9 , then DtEL > DtNL , otherwise DtEL ≤ DtNL ; DtML > DtEL .
Proposition 6 (1) indicates that when the potential market demand is low, comparing with the
case without LSSs, the LSSs will increase the demand of the E-commerce platform channel in
the models ML and EL. However, only the thresholds of potential market demand in the three
models are different (see Fig. 4). Specifically, the demand of the E-commerce platform channel in
the model ML is larger than that in the model EL. Proposition 6 (2) shows that the demand of the
live streaming channel in the model ML is larger than that in the model EL. Hence, the LSSs should
be introduced by M, which can increase the market demand. Proposition 6 (3) shows that when the
potential market demand satisfies some conditions, the total demands in the models ML and EL
are all higher than that in the model NL. When the potential market demand is either very low or
high, the total demand in the model NL is higher than that in the model ML or EL. In other words,
the LSSs do not always increase the total demand of the EPSC. When the LSSs are introduced, the
total demand in the model ML is higher than that in the model EL. Therefore, manufacturers
should introduce and adopt the LSSs to expand the market demands of each channel and the total
demand of EPSC.
Under the above parameter settings, the thresholds of 4 − 9 are calculated as 4 = 7.8125,
5 = 6.7149, 6 = 0.1380, 7 = 26.4245, 8 = 0.1561, and 9 = 22.0546. To clearly describe the
relationships of the optimal demands of the E-commerce platform channel and total demand in
the three models, α varied within the range of [6,8] and [0,30], respectively. Figure 4 describes the
optimal demands in the three models.
Figure 4 indicates that with the increase of the potential market demand, the demand of the E-
commerce platform channel and the total demand of EPSC in the model NL all increase, but the
demand of the E-commerce platform channel and the total demand of EPSC in the models ML
and EL first increase and then decrease. In addition, when the potential market demand is low, the
demand of the E-commerce platform channel and the total demand of EPSC in the model ML are
the highest. When the potential market demand is high, the demand of the E-commerce platform
channel and the total demand of EPSC in the model NL are the highest. And thus, EPSC members
should introduce and adopt the LSSs, invest advertising, etc., to explore the potential demand of
the market to derive greater profits. Moreover, when the market demand is close to saturation, there
is no need to introduce the LSSs. When the LSSs are introduced, comparing with the case in the
model EL, it is more conducive to expanding the market demands of the E-commerce platform and
live streaming channels and the total demand of EPSC in the model ML. That is to say, to increase
the market demand, the LSSs should be introduced by manufacturers. These verify the conclusions
in the Proposition 6.
To ensure that the demand is positive, we set α = 10, βl ∈ [0.1, 0.15], and ρ ∈ [0.1, 0.3]. By an-
alyzing the effects of price elasticity coefficient βl and service spillover effect ρ on the demand of
the E-commerce platform channel and the total demand of EPSC in the three models, we have the
following Fig. 5.
Figure 5 indicates that when the price elasticity is low, the demand of the E-commerce platform
channel in the model ML is the highest. When the price elasticity is sufficiently high, the demand
Comparing the optimal profits of the EPSC members, we derive the optimal operation strategy for
the EPSC in the following Propositions.
Proposition 7. The optimal profits of M in the three models satisfy:
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(1) if Fl < F1 , then πM
ML
> πM
NL
, otherwise πM
ML
≤ πM
NL
;
∗ ∗
EL∗ NL∗
(2) if 0 < cm < C1 or cm > C2 , then πM > πM , otherwise πM
EL NL
≤ πM ;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(3) if Fl > F2 , then πM
EL
> πM
ML
, otherwise πM
EL
≤ πM
ML
.
Proposition 7 shows that when the signing fee is below a certain value, M will obtain more profit
in the model ML than that in the model NL. When the production cost is in a certain range, M’s
profit in the model EL is higher than that in the model NL. That is to say, when the signing and
production cost satisfy some conditions, M will prefer to introduce the LSSs. In addition, when the
signing fee is small, the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by M is the best choice for M.
Otherwise, M will prefer E to introduce the LSSs. Therefore, manufacturers should control their
production costs, and then introduce and adopt the LSSs to expand market share when the signing
fee is small.
Proposition 7 gives the condition under which M can benefit from introducing the LSSs. Under
the above parameter settings, the thresholds of F1 , F2 , C1 , and C2 are calculated as F1 = 2262.9003,
F2 = 626.3608, C1 = 161.7161, and C2 = 318.2839. We employ Fig. 6 to illustrate the operation
strategy for M and the corresponding insights.
Figure 6(a) indicates that a higher signing fee will decrease M’s profit in the model ML. Since
cm = 5 < C1 = 161.7161, M’s profit in the model EL is always higher than that in the model NL. In
addition, when the signing fee is very small, M gains the highest profit in the model ML. While when
the signing fee is high, M’s profit in the model EL is the highest. That is to say, when the production
cost is in a certain range, the LSSs should be introduced and implemented in the EPSC. And when
the signing fee is small, the LSSs should be introduced by M. In other words, the operation strategy
of the LSSs introduced by M is the best choice for M. Otherwise, the operation strategy of the LSSs
introduced by E is beneficial for M. And thus, manufactures should control their production costs
and then introduce and adopt the LSSs. These verify the conclusions in Proposition 7.
From Fig. 6(b), we can find that, when the signing fee is very low, M prefers to introduce and
adopt the LSSs. When the signing fee is sufficiently high (i.e., Fl > F2 ) and the production cost is
low (i.e., cm < C1 ), the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by E is beneficial for M. When
the signing fee and the product cost are high (i.e., Fl > F1 and cm > C1 ), M will not introduce
the LSSs. Consequently, when the signing fee and production cost are sufficiently low or high,
M has different operation strategy preferences. Under different conditions, all the three operation
strategies may be selected by manufacturers. Therefore, manufacturers can control their production
costs, and the EPSC members can set an appropriate signing fee Fl to choose the optimal operation
strategy.
Proposition 8. The optimal profits of E in the three models satisfy:
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(1) if cm > C3 , then πEML > πENL , otherwise πEML ≤ πENL ;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(2) if Fl < F3 , then πEEL > πENL , otherwise πEEL ≤ πENL ;
∗ ∗ ∗ ∗
(3) if Fl < F4 , then πEEL > πEML , otherwise πEEL ≤ πEML .
Proposition 8 indicates that when the production cost is above a certain value, E can obtain more
profit in the model ML than that in the model NL. In addition, when the signing fee is small, E’s
profit in the model EL is higher than that in the model NL or ML. That is to say, when the signing
fee is in a certain range, E would like to introduce and adopt the LSSs to obtain more profits. When
the production cost and signing fee satisfy some conditions, the operation strategy of the LSSs
introduced by E is beneficial for E.
Proposition 8 gives the condition under which the retailer can benefit from introducing the LSSs.
Under the above parameter settings, the thresholds of F3 , F4 , and C3 are calculated as F3 = 39.3117,
F4 = 5.8831, and C3 = −267.3684. We employ Fig. 7 to illustrate the operation strategy for E and
the corresponding insights.
In Fig. 7(a), we can find that, a higher signing fee will decrease E’s profit in the model EL.
Since cm = 5 > C3 = −267.3684, E can always obtain more profit in the model ML than that in
the model NL. In addition, when the signing fee is very small, the operation strategy of the LSSs
introduced by E is always beneficial for E. Otherwise, the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced
by M is beneficial for E. That is to say, the LSSs are beneficial for E in most cases. The reason is
that the LSSs can exploit more potential consumers. Therefore, E should introduce and adopt the
LSSs when the signing fee is sufficiently small. And thus, the EPSC members should negotiate to
determine the signing fee to choose the appropriate operation strategy.
Figure 7(b) indicates that when the signing fee is relatively low (i.e., Fl < F4 ), E prefers to intro-
duce and adopt the LSSs. Otherwise, the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by M is the best
choice for E. In most cases, the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by M is beneficial for
E. Therefore, the EPSC members should set an appropriate signing fee Fl to ensure that all EPSC
members choose the same operation strategy.
∗ ∗
Proposition 9. The optimal profits of L in the three models satisfy: if cm > C4 , then πLEL > πLML ,
∗ ∗
otherwise πLEL ≤ πLML .
Proposition 9 indicates that, when the production cost is high, L’s profit in the model EL is higher
than that in the model ML. This result implies that the LSSs supplier prefers E to introduce the
LSSs when the production cost is high. Otherwise, the LSSs supplier will prefer M to introduce
the LSSs. Therefore, manufacturers should control their production costs to introduce and adopt
the LSSs.
Proposition 9 gives the condition for L to select the operation strategy. Under the above param-
eter settings, the threshold of C4 is calculated as C4 = 240.5351. We employ Fig. 8 to illustrate the
operation strategy for L and the corresponding insights.
Figure 8(a) shows that a higher production cost will decrease the L’s profit. When the produc-
tion cost is low, L prefers M to introduce the LSSs. Otherwise, the operation strategy of the LSSs
introduced by E is beneficial for L. These results confirm that manufacturers should control their
production costs, and then the LSSs suppliers will prefer M to introduce the LSSs. Figure 8(b) in-
dicates that the signing fee will not affect L’s operation strategy choice. When the production cost is
low (i.e., cm < C4 ), the LSSs supplier prefers M to introduce the LSSs. Otherwise, the LSSs supplier
will prefer E to introduce the LSSs. Consequently, manufacturers should control their production
costs to introduce the LSSs.
Under the above parameter settings, to ensure that the profit of the EPSC system is positive, cm
varied within the range [0,100]. In addition, we set cm to be 5, βl and ρ varied within the ranges of
[0.1,0.15] and [0.1,0.3], respectively. The optimal profits of the EPSC in three models are described
in the following Fig. 9.
Figure 9 indicates that the EPSC’s profit in the model ML is the highest, while it is the lowest in
the model NL. This implies that introducing the LSSs are always beneficial for the EPSC system
because the LSSs can exploit more potential consumers, which can bring more benefits for EPSC
members. To be more specific, the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by M is more effective
for EPSC system than that of the LSSs introduced by E. From the perspective of the EPSC system,
the operation strategy of the LSSs introduced by M is the best choice. Therefore, the EPSC members
should agree to let manufacturers introduce the LSSs by setting appropriate parameters.
To determine the conditions under which the EPSC members choose a consistent operation strat-
egy, we employ the above parameter settings and use Fig. 10 to illustrate the corresponding insights.
In Fig. 10, we can find that, when the signing fee and production cost parameters satisfy some
conditions (i.e., if cm < C1 , F4 < Fl < F2 and cm > C1 , F4 < Fl < F1 ), the operation strategy of
the LSSs introduced by M is the best choice for the EPSC members and system. In addition, with
the increase of the production cost, the value space of the consistent operation strategy becomes
smaller. Consequently, we can conclude that when the EPSC members set an appropriate signing
fee and manufacturers control their production costs, all EPSC members will choose the same
operational strategy of the LSSs introduced by M. In practice, many manufacturers would not only
sell products through E-commerce platform channel, but also choose to introduce LSSs to attract
more consumers. Manufacturers such as Gree and Shell prefer to directly introduce LSSs from the
live streaming platforms Kuaishou and TikTok to further expand the consumer demand.13,14
6. Conclusions
This study explores whether and how to introduce LSSs and puts forward an operation strategy in
an EPSC. We construct three models to analyze the decisions of EPSC members and investigate
the impacts of the LSSs on decisions and operation strategy. The results show that: (1) When the
production cost is very high, the manufacturer will not introduce the LSSs, while introducing the
LSSs is always beneficial for the E-commerce platform. However, the LSSs may not always increase
13
Available at https://www.sohu.com/a/407968919_120013420 (Accessed 1 July 2022).
14
Available at https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1669168968083401575&wfr=spider&for=pc (Accessed 1 July 2022).
Acknowledgment
This research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No.
71771055 and No. 71801003).
References
Abhishek, V., Jerath, K., Zhang, Z.J., 2016. Agency selling or reselling? Channel structures in electronic retailing. Man-
agement Science 62, 8, 2259–2280.
15
Available at https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1704769940414445343&wfr=spider&for=pc (Accessed 1 July 2022).
16
Available at https://www.jiemian.com/article/4216218.html (Accessed 1 July 2022).
Appendix
∂ 2 πM
NL
Proof of Theorem 1. In the model NL, since 2 = 2βe (φ − 1) < 0, πM
NL
is concave on pNL
e . It
∂ (pNL
√e NL)
∂πMNL α+ε ke
can be obtained from ∂ pNL
= 0 that pNL
e = 2βe
+ cm
2(1−φ)
. Substituting pNL
e into πENL , we have
e
plML∗
= 2βl −λ + 2(1−λ) .
2α cm
Proof of Proposition 1. From the assumptions βl ≥ λ2 , 0 < φ < 1, and 0 < λ < 1, by examining the
optimal retail prices of E-commerce platform and live streaming channels in the three models NL,
ML, and EL, it is easily verified that
Proof of Proposition 2. From the assumptions βl ≥ λ2 , 0 < φ < 1, and 0 < λ < 1, by examining the
optimal advertising investments in the three models NL, ML, and EL, it is easily verified that
2βl −λ
− 2βl −λ+λφ+2ρ(1−φ)
2βl −λ+λφ
= 2ρλ (2βλφ+φ(2β l −λ)
l −λ)(2βl −λ+λφ)
> 0, thus, ∂α e
− ∂α e
> 0;
Proof of Proposition 3. From the assumptions βl ≥ λ2 , 0 < φ < 1, and 0 < λ < 1, by examining the
optimal service investments and service levels in the two models ML and EL, it is easily verified
that
∂kML∗ ∂kEL∗ ∂kML∗ ∂kEL∗ 2
(1) l
∂α
= ∂α l
= 2α
ε2
> 0, ∂ε l
= ∂εl = − 2α ε3
< 0;
∂sML∗
∂sEL∗ ∂sML∗ ∂sEL∗
(2) ∂α
= 2βl −λ >
2λ
∂α
= 2βl −λ+λφ > 0, ∂λ = (2β4αβ
2λ(1−φ) l
2 > ∂λ
= 4αβl (1−φ)
(2βl −λ+λφ)2
> 0.
l −λ)
Proof of Proposition 5. From the assumptions βl ≥ λ2 , 0 < φ < 1, and 0 < λ < 1, comparing the
optimal advertising investments, service investments and service levels in the three models NL, ML,
and EL, we have
4α 2 ρλ(2βl −λ+ρλ)
= 4(1−φ)α ρλ(2β l −λ+λφ+ρλ−ρφλ)
2
(1) kML∗
e − kNL∗
e = ε 2 (2βl −λ)2
> 0, kEL∗ e − kNL∗
e ε 2 (2βl −λ+λφ)2
> 0, kEL∗
e −
2 2
= −2ρλφ(2β l −λ)−2ρλ φ
2
= αε2 [(1 + 2β
2 2ρλ(1−φ) 2ρλ(1−φ)
kML∗
e l −λ+λφ
) − (1 + 2β2ρλ
l −λ
) ], since 2β l −λ+λφ
− 2β2ρλ
l −λ (2βl −λ+λφ)(2βl −λ)
< 0, and
thus kEL∗
e − kML∗
e < 0. Therefore, we have kML∗ e > kEL∗e > kNL∗
e ;
(2) ML∗
kl − kl = 0;
EL∗
4αβl λφ
(3) sEL∗ − sML∗ = − (2βl −λ)(2β l −λ+λφ)
< 0.
2βl −λ+6ρλ 2βl −λ+λφ+6ρλ(1−φ)
Proof of Proposition 6. Denoting 4 =
(2βl −λ+2ρλ)2
, 5 = (2β −λ+λφ+2ρλ(1−φ))2 , 6 =
√ √ l √
(6βl −λ+6ρλ)(1−λ)− (6βl −λ+6ρλ)(1−λ)+ (6βl −λ+λφ+6ρλ(1−φ))(1−λ)−
, 7 = , 8 = , 9 =
1 1 2
2(2βl −λ+2ρλ)2 (1−λ) √ 2(2βl −λ+2ρλ)2 (1−λ) 2(2βl −λ+λφ+2ρλ(1−φ))2 (1−λ)
(6βl −λ+λφ+6ρλ(1−φ))(1−λ)+
2(2βl −λ+λφ+2ρλ(1−φ))2 (1−λ)
2
, 1 = (6βl − λ + 6ρλ)2 (1 − λ)2 − 4βl cm (2βl − λ + 2ρλ)2 (1 − λ)(2βl −
2 2 2
λ) and 2 = (6βl − λ + λφ + 6ρλ(1 − φ)) (1 − λ) − 4βl cm (2βl − λ + λφ + 2ρλ(1 − φ)) (1 −
λ)(2βl − λ + λφ). From the assumptions βl ≥ λ2 , 0 < φ < 1, and 0 < λ < 1, comparing the opti-
mal demands of E-commerce platform and live streaming channels and total demands of EPSC in
the three models NL, ML, and EL, we have
7, then DtML∗
− Dt NL∗
> 0, otherwise, Dt ML∗
− Dt NL∗
≤ 0; Dt − DtNL∗ =
EL∗
2
−(2βl −λ+λφ+2ρλ(1−φ)) (1−λ)α +(6βl −λ+λφ+6ρλ(1−φ))(1−λ)α−βl cm (2βl −λ+λφ)
2
2(2βl −λ+λφ)(1−λ)
, if 8 <α <
9, then Dt − Dt
EL∗ NL∗
> 0, otherwise, Dt − Dt
EL∗ NL∗
≤ 0; Dt − DtML∗ =
EL∗
2ρ(2β−λ)+2ρλ+α(1+2ρ )(2(2β−λ+2ρλ(1−φ))+λφ(1+2ρ ))+4β
−αλφ 2(2β−λ)(2β−λ+λφ)
< 0.
Proof of Propositions 7-9. We calculate the differences of the EPSC members’ profits among three
scenarios, respectively. Then, we obtain the following equations and conditions.
(α 2 γ 2 +αγ )(1−φ) 3αγ −α 2 γ 2 βe cm βl cm
Denoting F1 = ( 3 2βe γ31 − c2m )( 32γ1 3 − 2(1−φ) ) + ( 2α(1−λ)
γ1
− c2m )( 2αβ
γ1
l
− 2(1−λ) )−
(2α(1−φ)−βe cm )2 (α 2 γ 2 +αγ )(1−φ) 3αγ −α 2 γ 2 βe cm βl cm
4βe (1−φ)
, F2 = ( 3 2βe γ31 − c2m )( 32γ1 3 − 2(1−φ) ) + ( 2α(1−λ)
γ1
− c2m )( 2αβ
γ1
l
− 2(1−λ) )−
(α 2 γ42 +αγ4 )(1−φ) 3αγ −α γ
2 2
βe cm βl cm α γ
2 2
+αγ
( 2βe γ2
− c2m )( 42γ2 4 − 2(1−φ) ) − ( 2α(1−λ)
γ2
− c2m )( 2αβ
γ2
l
− 2(1−λ) ), F3 = φ( 2β4 e γ2 4 +
3αγ −α 2 γ 2 βe cm βl cm
2
(4α 2 (1−φ) −βe2 c2m )φ α 2 γ 2 +αγ
cm
2(1−φ)
)( 42γ2 4 − 2(1−φ) ) + λφ( 2α γ2
+ 2(1−λ)
cm
)( 2αβ
γ2
l
− 2(1−λ) )− 4βe (1−φ)2
, F4 = φ( 2β4 e γ2 4 +
3αγ −α 2 γ 2 βe cm βl cm α 2 γ 2 +αγ 3αγ −α 2 γ 2
cm
)( 42γ2 4 − 2(1−φ) ) + λφ( 2α γ2
+ 2(1−λ)
cm
)( 2αβ
γ
l
− 2(1−λ) ) − φ( 2β3 e γ1 3 + 2(1−φ) cm
)( 32γ1 3 −
2(1−φ) 2
βe cm α(1−λ) 16β ρλ(1−λ)(2βl +ρλ(1−φ))−βl γ42 (αγ4 +1)(3−αγ4 )+4βl γ22
), C1 = γ2 β l
[4(β l + ρλ(1 − φ)) − (1 − φ) e ],
2(1−φ) (1−λ)βe
16β ρλ(1−λ)(2βl +ρλ(1−φ))−βl γ4 (αγ4 +1)(3−αγ4 )+4βl γ2
2 2
C2 = α(1−λ) γ2 β l
[4(βl + ρλ(1 − φ)) + (1 − φ) e (1−λ)βe
], C3 =
(4αβe γ12 −αγ32 (αγ3 +1)(3−αγ3 ))(1−φ)
βe γ1 γ3 ((3−αγ3 )−βe (αγ3 +1))
and C4 = √ 4α(1−λ)
.
(2βl −λ)(2βl −λ+λφ)
(1) By comparing M’s optimal profits among the three scenarios, we can obtain: πM
ML∗
− πM
NL∗
=
(α 2 γ 2 +αγ )(1−φ) 3αγ3 −α 2 γ32 βe cm βl cm 2
( 3 2βe γ31 − c2m )( 2γ1
− 2(1−φ) ) + ( 2α(1−λ)
γ1
− c2m )( 2αβ
γ1
l
− 2(1−λ) ) − (2α(1−φ)−β
4βe (1−φ)
e cm )
− Fl ,
when Fl < F1 , then πM − πM > 0, otherwise πM − πM ≤ 0; πM − πM
ML∗ NL∗ ML∗ NL∗ EL∗ NL∗
=
2 (αγ4 +γ4 )(1−φ)(3γ4 −αγ4 )+16βe βl (1−λ)−4(1−φ)γ2
2 2 2
βl βl +ρλ(1−φ)
c − 2α
4(1−λ) m
2
γ2
cm + α 4βe γ22
, when 0 < cm < C1
and cm > C2 , then πM EL∗
− πM NL∗
> 0, otherwise πM EL∗
− πM NL∗
≤ 0; πEML∗ − πENL∗ =
(3γ3 −αγ32 )−(αγ32 +γ3 )βe αγ32 (αγ3 +1)(3−αγ3 )−4αβe γ12
αφ( 4βe (1−φ)γ1
cm + 4βe2 γ12
), when cm > C3 , then πEML∗ − πENL∗ > 0,
otherwise πEML∗ − πENL∗ ≤ 0;
(2) By comparing E’s optimal profits among the three scenarios, we can obtain: πEML∗ − πENL∗ =
(3γ −αγ 2 )−(αγ 2 +γ )β αγ 2 (αγ +1)(3−αγ )−4αβe γ12
αφ( 3 4β3e (1−φ)γ3 1 3 e cm + 3 3 4β 2 γ 2 3 ), when cm > C3 , then πEML∗ − πENL∗ > 0, oth-
e 1
α γ +αγ
2 2
3αγ −α 2 γ 2 βe cm
erwise πEML∗ − πENL∗ ≤ 0; πEEL∗ − πENL∗ = φ( 2β4 e γ2 4 + 2(1−φ) cm
)( 42γ2 4 − 2(1−φ) ) + λφ( 2α γ2
+
2
2αβl βl cm (4α (1−φ) −βe cm )φ
2 2 2
cm
2(1−λ)
)( γ2 − 2(1−λ) ) − 4βe (1−φ)2
− Fl , when Fl < F3 , then πEEL∗ − πENL∗ > 0, other-