Input and Output Analysis-4
Input and Output Analysis-4
JIWAJI UNIVERSITY
PRODUCTIVITY:
INPUT AND OUTPUT ANALYSIS
UNIT-V BE 8sem
(EL-8103) Electronics
Submitted By
Swati Dixit
Electronics Dept.
Input-Output Analysis
An Example
Here's an example of how I-O analysis works: A local government
wants to build a new bridge and needs to justify the cost of the
investment. To do so, it hires an economist to conduct an I-O
study. The economist talks to engineers and construction
companies to estimate how much the bridge will cost, the supplies
needed, and how many workers will be hired by the construction
company. The economist converts this information into dollar
figures and runs numbers through an I-O model, which produces
the three levels of impacts. The direct impact is simply the original
numbers put into the model, for example, the value of the raw
inputs (cement, steel, etc.). The indirect impact is the jobs created
by the supplying companies, so cement and steel companies. The
induced impact is the amount of money that the new workers
spend on goods and services.
Input-Output Analysis in
Economics
The first row total shows that the agricultural output totals 250
units (million of tons) per year. Of this total, 50 units go directly to
final consumption, i.e., to households and government, as shown
in the third column of row 1. What happens to the remaining 200
units of agricultural output?
The ‘total outputs’ column gives the overall input of labour and
output of each commodity. The first column describes the input or
cost structure of the agricultural industry : the 250-unit agricultural
output was produced with the use of 25 units of agricultural
goods, 40 units of manufacturing goods, and 10 units of labour.
These items in Table 1 show that the sales of the two industries to
themselves and to each other might be described as “non-
GNP” items. The ‘final demand’ column represents the output
side of GNP, and the labour row represents the factor-cost side.
The economy can be thought of as a machine that uses up labour
(and has 50 units of labour per year at its disposal) and produces
final consumption. With its 50 units of labour the economy is
capable of producing an annual flow of 50 units of agricultural
goods and 60 units of manufactures.
Leontief assumes:
Then
The available output certainly cannot be less than the sum of its
alternative uses, but it could, physically, be greater.
Thus we get:
Giving up one unit of C1 sets free (directly and indirectly) A0i units
of labour. To get 1 more unit of C2 requires A02 units of labour. By
giving up 1 unit of C1 society can, therefore, procure for itself
A01/A02 units of C2. The straight line constant cost nature of the
transformation curve reflects not only the linearity of the
technology, but also the presence of only one primary factor and
the absence of joint production.
The constant MRS was shown to be A01/ A02. This must determine
the relative price of the two commodities: