Cooperative Games in Two-Echelon Supply Chains
Cooperative Games in Two-Echelon Supply Chains
Keywords: Coalition formation game, Worth of coalition, Stackelberg game, Stability and blocking by a coalition.
Abstract: Competition and cooperation are inherent features of any multi-echelon supply chain. The interactions among
the agents across the same echelon and that across various echelons influence the percolation of market demand
arXiv:2401.04939v1 [econ.TH] 10 Jan 2024
across echelons. The agents may want to collaborate with others in pursuit of attracting higher demand and
thereby improving their own revenue. We consider one supplier (at a higher echelon) and two manufacturers (at
a lower echelon and facing the customers) and study the collaborations that are ‘stable’; the main differentiator
from the existing studies in supply chain literature is the consideration of the following crucial aspect – the
revenue of any collaborative unit also depends upon the way the opponents collaborate. Such competitive
scenarios can be modeled using what is known as partition form games.
Our study reveals that the grand coalition is not stable when the product is essential and the customers buy
it from any of the manufacturers without a preference. The supplier prefers to collaborate with only one
manufacturer, the one stronger in terms of market power; further, such collaboration is stable only when the
stronger manufacturer is significantly stronger. Interestingly, no stable collaborative arrangements exist when
the two manufacturers are nearly equal in market power.
plier and a manufacturer operate together, we have a • d¯M is the dedicated market size of Mi ,
i
coalition with vertical cooperation (VC), e.g., Vi = • αM pi is the fraction of demand lost by Mi due to
i
{Mi , S}. When any agent operates alone, we have its price pi , sensitized by parameter αM , i
a coalition with a single player, e.g., Mi = {Mi } or
S = {S}. When all the agents operate together as in a • The essentialness factor γ dictates the sensitivity
centralized SC, we have a grand coalition (GC), rep- of price pi on demand – for example, when γ ≈ 1,
resented by G = {S, M1 , M2 }. the product is highly essential, and the customers
are insensitive to price,
• εαM−i p−i is the fraction of customer base of M−i
First Echelon Supplier
that rejected M−i and shifted to Mi ,
q q
• The demand is positive as long as the term inside
(·)+ is positive; else, the demand is zero.
Second Echelon Manufacturers
The product is essential, either when γ ≈ 1 or
when ε ≈ 1 and then almost all the customers buy the p1 p2
product (for these parameters, observe DM + DM ≈
1 2
the per-unit manufacturing cost of the manufacturer spective actions are represented by aV and aG and the
Mi . As the best of the two capabilities are utilized, action sets by AV and AG (defined as before).
and as the customers are aware of it, we assume the
2.3.1 Utilities in ALC Partition
reputation of the coalition equals that of the best. In
all, we assume the demand function of coalition with We begin with describing the utilities of various
horizontal cooperation to be: agents when all of them operate alone, i.e., when the
DM = d¯M − αM p, with αM := min{αM , αM }, partition is PA (see Figure 1). Let a := (aS , aM ) rep-
1 2
resent the actions of all the agents (the supplier, and
d¯M = d¯M + d¯M . (2)
1 2
both the manufacturers), where aM := (aM , aM ). 1 2
There is obviously no cross-linking (shift of cus- Manufacturers’ Utility: The utility of manufacturer
tomers from one manufacturer to the other), or ba- Mi is zero either if it chooses not to operate or if the
sically, the customers have no choice. In some cases, supplier does not operate. Otherwise, utility is the
this can be fatal to the system, as the customers can total profit gained minus the operating cost, where the
get discouraged by the unavailability of options. The former is the product of the demand attracted DM (1) i
product may not appear essential anymore, and the and the profit gained per-unit:
customers may find solace in other related products. UM (a) = (DM (aM )(pi −CM − q)FS − OM ) FM ,
i i i i i
(3)
We observe this phenomenon has significant influence
on stability results of sections 5.1-5.2. where CM is the per-unit production cost incurred
i
2.3 Costs, Actions and the Utilities 1{aC ̸=no } represents the flag that coalition C operates,
and q denotes the wholesale price quoted by supplier.
Any agent, supplier, manufacturer, or coalition Suppliers’ Utility: The demand for the supplier’s
has a fixed cost of operation. Therefore, if the raw materials (at higher echelon) percolates from the
agent/coalition does not generate sufficient profit, it lower echelon (manufacturers), based on the choices
incurs negative revenue and can choose not to oper- of the manufacturers. This dictates the utility of the
ate. Let no represent the choice of not operating. The supplier, which is non-zero only if the supplier and
utility of any agent/coalition is 0 when it chooses no . at least one of the manufacturers operate. In all, the
The supplier can decide not to operate, or can utility of the supplier S when it operates alone equals:
quote a price q ∈ [0, ∞). Thus, the action set of sup- ! !
plier when operating alone is AS := {no } ∪ [0, ∞), 2
US (a) = ∑D (aM )FM (q −CS ) − OS FS , (4)
and its action aS ∈ AS . Similarly, when manufacturer i=1
Mi i
tion. In this case, N = {S, M} and the only possible If there is no cross-linking (i.e., if ε = 0), the demand
partitions are PG = {N} and PA = {{S}, {M}}. functions get decoupled, and each of them resemble
Clearly, the worth of grand coalition wPG G = UG∗ to that of the single manufacturer SC (see (5)).
given in (11), and that of manufacturer and sup- One needs to derive the worths {wPC } for all possi-
plier, while operating alone, are respectively given by ble coalitions C and partitions P to study the stability
wPMA = UM∗ and wPS A = US∗ of Theorem 1. These com- aspects. The worth wPC can be defined as the ‘best’
plete the definition of the partition form game. Also utility (the maximum sum utility) that the members
observe that any pay-off vector x = (xM , xS ) is consis- of C can derive, while facing the competition from
tent with GC partition if and only if xM + xS = UG∗ = agents outside the coalition arranged as in partition P.
wPG G . On the other hand, the only payoff vector con- The competition between various coalitions is
sistent with the ALC partition is x = (wPMA , wPS A ). The captured via a Stackelberg game (as in Subsec-
Theorems 1-2 immediately imply the following sta- tion 3.1), when at least one manufacturer is not collab-
bility result: orating with the supplier – the partitions of this type
are, ALC partition PA = {S, M1 , M2 }, HC partition
Lemma 1. In the single manufacturer SC: i) ALC PH = {S, M} and the VC partition PV i = {Vi , M−i }.
partition PA is blocked by grand coalition; and ii) In all these cases, the leader is the coalition CL with
The GC-core, the set of consistent pay-off vectors that the supplier. The coalitions with only manufactures
form stable configurations with PG ( see (8), is: form the followers - the followers respond optimally
{x : xS > 2φ − OS , xM > φ − OM and xS + xM = 4φ − OG } . for any given action aL (the quoted prices or no ) of
the leader. The solution of the followers is either an
Proof. From (16), the pessimal anticipated utilities optimizer (when all manufacturers form a coalition)
with |N| = 2, clearly equal wCpa = wPC G for any C. Thus or an NE. Let a∗M (aL ) represent this solution in either
by Theorems 1-2, wGpa = wPG G > wPMA + wPS A and hence case. The leader coalition is aware of this optimal
part (i); part (ii) follows by direct verification. choice, i.e., a∗M (aL ) for every aL is a common knowl-
edge. Thus, the optimal choice of the leader is,
Remarks: From (3)- (4), if the supplier and the man- a∗L ∈ arg max ∑ U j (aL , a∗M (aL ))) ,
ufacturer participate in a strategic form game (i.e., aL
j∈CL
when they make choices simultaneously), the resul- ∗ ∗ ∗
and then (aL , aM (aL )) represents the SBE. We then de-
tant Nash Equilibrium (NE) is (no , no ) – the best re- fine the worth of the leader coalition by:
sponse of the manufacturer is no for any aS = q > CM
or when aS = no , while that of the supplier is no when wPCL = ∑ U j (a∗L , a∗M (a∗L )) .
j∈CL
The worth of the rest of the coalitions of P can be partitions are significantly complex and hence we be-
defined similarly using the SBE (a∗L , a∗M (a∗L )). gin with a specific yet an important asymptotic case
We are just left with the GC partition PG = {G}, study in this conference paper – while the complete
which can be analysed exactly as in Subsection 3.2 generality would be considered in future. We con-
and is considered in the immediate next – we once sider an asymptotic regime near (ε, γ) ≈ (1, 1); as
again assume ‘operating-conditions’ assumption A.2 mentioned previously, here the customers are willing
(with terms like CG etc., accordingly changed); with- to switch the loyalties towards their manufacturers
out loss of generality, we consider d¯M ≥ d¯M .1 2
and hence we call such a regime as Essential and
Substitutable-Manufacturer (ESM) regime. We also
5.1 GC Partition consider manufacturers of equal reputation, i.e., with
In GC partition PG , the two manufacturers and the α̃M = α̃M . Towards obtaining the asymptotic study
1 2
During blocking by mergers, i.e., say when block- a∗Vi ∈ arg max UVi (aV , a∗M (aV )), −i
ing coalition C = C1 ∪ C2 , then recall by consistency aV ∈AVi
(27)
i i
ers Mi and competes with the other. The Stackel- aM = arg max UM (aM , aM ; a∗S ) for all i.
∗
i i i −i
aMi
berg game is between the coalition Vi as leader and
the manufacturer M−i as follower. The manufacturer The worth of supplier S is, wPS A = US (a∗S ), and the
M−i (when it operates) obtains raw material from Vi , worth of manufacturer Mi is, wPMA = UM (a∗M ). As al- i i
quotes p−i and the demand DM attracted by M−i also −i ready mentioned, it is complicated to analyze this
contributes towards the revenue of Vi ; the VC coali- game theoretically, we instead obtain the ESM lim-
tion Vi also derives utility due to its own demand its in the following:
DM (recall here a direct price pi is quoted to the cus-
i
Lemma 3. Assume αM = αM = α. The worth- 1 2
tomers). Thus the utilities of the two coalitions are:
limits ( fSPA , fMPA , fMPA ) and the derivative limits ( fS(1),PA ,
i −i
UVi = DM (aM )(pi −CM −CS ) + FM DM (aM )(q −CS ) (1),P (1),P
i i −i −i fM A fM A ) for ESM regime are respectively in Ta-
i −i
6 Stability Results – ESM regime that a coalition blocks it. Then the said configuration
remains stable (or is blocked by the said coalition) for
We have derived the worths {wPC } and the worth-
all (γ, ε) around (1, 1) and in a set as in (23) of sub-
limits { fCP } in the previous section and now aim to
section 5.3. We begin with ALC partition.
identify the partitions and configurations that are sta-
ble in ESM regime. We have worth-limits only for ALC partition is not stable: Note that there is
VC and ALC partitions, and thus for the compari- only one scaled configuration at limit involving ALC
son purposes (see (16), (20) and (21)), compute the (PA , y) with yS = fSPA , yM = fMPA and yM = fMPA , be-
1 1 2 2
same for GC and HC partitions. By Corollaries 1-2, cause of consistency. The coalitions that can possibly
fGPG = fMPH = fSPH = 0; these are also tabulated in Ta- block ALC partition are the merger coalitions such as
ble 1. G, M, Vi . Consider a merger Vi which gets the same
From Table 1, the immediate result is that, the GC utility as yS + yM of ALC at limit. Thus we compare
i
and HC partitions (irrespective of the pay-off vectors) using the derivative limits of Table 1b ,
are both blocked by coalition Vi . Thus none among 2
these two partitions are stable. As discussed at the (1),PA (1),PA d¯M2 5d¯M + d¯M
i −i
fS + fM i
=− +
end of Subsection 2.2, the customers may no longer 8α̃ 144α̃
feel the product is essential in the absence of choices, d¯M2 − 2d¯M d¯M − d¯M2
i −i (1),P −i
< i
= fVi V , (31)
and this may be the reason for non-stability of the GC 16α̃
and HC partitions.1 and hence the merger Vi blocks PA (see (22) and ob-
We now identify the stable configurations. To- serve (ε − 1) is negative) and this is true with a strict
wards this, the pessimal anticipatory worth-limits (see inequality at limit. Therefore, PA is not a stable parti-
equation 16), using Table 1, are: tion in the ESM regime.
fSpa = min{ fSPH , fSPA } = 0 Continuing in this manner we obtain the following
result (the remaining proof is in the Appendix):
fMpa = fMPH = 0 (28)
Theorem 3. [ESM regime] Consider any
pa PV −i pa
α̃, d¯M , d¯M , {CC } and {OC } with d¯M ≥ d¯M . There ex-
PA
fMi
= min{ fM i
, fM } = 0, fG = 0, and
i 1 2 1 2
pa PV i d¯2 ists a ε̄ < 1 such that for every ε ∈ (ε̄, 1), there exists
fVi = fVi = M. (29) a γ̄ε < 1 and for any system with above parameters
8α̃
and with (ε, γ) ∈ {ε ≥ ε̄, γ ≥ γ̄ε }, the following are
In the following we prove that: i) the partitions PA and true:
PV 2 are not stable, while PV 1 is stable when √
√ i) When d¯M ≤ d¯M < ( 2 + 1)d¯M , none of the par-
2 1 2
and hence, (d¯−α p∗ )+ = d¯−α p∗ , w∗ −Oc > 0. Thus, and the above interval is non-empty.
p∗ is also the maximizer of (33) with U ∗ = w∗ − Oc . There exists an ε̄ < 1 such that the last two in-
If ∆ < 0 then no is the optimizer, as U ∗ = U(no ) = 0 > equalities of (39) are satisfied (see Table 1 and Ap-
w∗ − Oc . The last sentence now follows trivially. pendices 9 and 10 for the proof of the values in the
Proof continued, Theorem 3: Without loss of gen- table, which follows in similar lines as (31)).
erality, consider stability of PV 1 . To ensure (PV 1 , x) is Thus from (36), all three strict inequalities of (39)
stable, it should not be blocked by HC coalition M, as are definitely satisfied (if required for a larger ε̄),
well as VC coalition V2 . In other words, we require, when (30) is satisfied.
Instability: On the other hand, say (30) is negated
wMpa − wPMV 1 ≤ xM ≤ wPV1V 1 − wPV2V 2 + wPMV 1 ,
2 1 2
(35) with strict inequality. Then from (36) there exists an
ε̄ < 1 such that for all ε ≥ ε̄ the following is satisfied:
and this is because for any pay-off vector consistent
with PV 1 , we have xM = wPMV 1 and xM + xS = wPV1V 1
2 2 1
w̃PV1V 1 − w̃VP2V 2 + w̃PMV 1 < (w̃Mpa − w̃PMV 1 )
2 2
and wVpa2 = wVP2V 2 . Towards this, consider the limit2 As before there exists γ̄ε for each ε ≥ ε̄, and then for
any γ ≥ γ̄ε and ε we have:
P P P pa P
w̃V1V 1 − w̃V2V 2 + w̃MV2 1 − (w̃M − w̃MV2 1 )
wPV1V 1 − wPV2V 2 + wPMV 1 < (wMpa − wPMV 1 ).
1−ε 2 2
d¯2 − d¯M2 2 d¯M2 2 d¯2 Then (30) can never be satisfied when roles of M2 and
= M1 + − M + o((1 − ε)) M1 interchanged and thus the partition PV 2 is never
8α̃ 8α̃ 16α̃
d¯M2 1 − d¯M2 2 − 2d¯M1 d¯M2 stable in ESM regime. However, as proved above,
= + o((1 − ε)) (36) PV 1 is stable with payoff vectors additionally satisfy-
16α̃
ing (40) when (30) is satisfied and unstable when (30)
2 It
is easy to observe that the derivative limit in case of is negated with strict inequality.
HC from Corollary 2 is equal to fM1,PH = −d¯M2 /16α̃ . Thus we have proved the theorem. □
8 Appendix – Generic Game
In this appendix, we solve the game between the manufacturers, where the supplier announces a price q and
the manufacturers respond via the game ⟨{M1 , M2 }, (W1 ,W2 ), (AM , AM )⟩. The result of this game will be used
1 2
After obtaining these relevant quantities, and checking the operating condition for M2 and the coalition V1 , we
find the worth limits and derivative limits of coalition V1 and the agent M2 for the ESM regime. Now, we begin
with the detailed proof.
The utility of the vertical coalition V1 , as defined in (24), is modified as follows, by substituting the demand
DM (aM ) from (1),
i
UV1 (aV1 ; aM ) = DM (aM )(p1 −CM −CS ) + DM (aM )FM (q −CS ) − OS − OM FV1 ,
2 1 1 2 2
(46)1
= (d¯M − αM p1 + εαM p2 )(p1 −CM −CS ) + (d¯M − αM p2 + εαM p1 )FM (q −CS ) − OS − OM FV1 .
1 1 2 1 2 2 1 2 1
(47)
Using (25), the utility of the manufacturer M2 for a given aV is,
UM (aM ; aV ) = DM (aM )(p2 −CM − q)FV1 − OM FM .
2 2 2 2 2 2
(48)
Since M2 is follower, for any given (q, p1 ) the optimizer of UM using Lemma 4 is, 2
¯
∗ ∗ dM + εαM p1 CM + q
2 1 2
aM (p1 , q) = p2 (p1 , q) = 1{q≤θ2 (p1 )} + + no 1{q>θ2 (p1 )} , (49)
2
2αM 2 2
where √
d¯M + εαM p1 − αM CM − 2 αM OM
2 1 2 2 2 2
θ2 (p1 ) = . (50)
αM 2
For all the following calculations in this section, we assume αM = αM = α. Define 1 2
d¯M 2
CM 2
e1 := + ,
2α 2
¯
ε2
¯ dM CM CS εα
e2 := α 1 − (CM +CS ) + dM + εα 1
+ − , 1
2 2
2 2α 2 2
d¯M CM εα α
e3 := −α
2
− (CM +CS )
2
+CS .
2 2 2 2
If q < θ2 (p1 ) then from Lemma 4, we have p∗2 (p1 , q) = q/2 + p1 ε/2 + e1 . Since coalition V1 is the leader, and
M2 is the follower, as in proof of Theorem 1, substituting aM = p∗2 (p1 , q) into (46) (by neglecting the operating
2
conditions), consider
ε2
¯ εαq
UV1 (p1 , q) := UV1 (p1 , q; p2 (p1 , q)) = dM − α p1 1 − + εαe1 +
1
(p1 −CM −CS ) 1
2 2
α p1 ε − αq
+ d¯M − αe1 + (q −CS ) − OS − OM .
2 1
2
The first step of this analysis is to derive the optimizers of the function UV . Later we show that the operating
conditions are satisfied at these optimizers (as in proof of Theorem 1). Now, differentiating UV1 with respect to
p1 and q, we get
ε2 ε2
dUV1 ¯ εαq (q −CS )εα
= −α 1 − (p1 −CM −CS ) + dM − α p1 1 −
1
+ εαe1 + 1
+ ,
d p1 2 2 2 2
= −α(2 − ε 2 )p1 + αεq + e2 ,
dUV1 (p1 −CM −CS )εα α p1 ε − αq (q −CS )α
= 1
+ d¯M − αe1 + − 2
= αε p1 − αq + e3 .
dq 2 2 2
Observe that the Hessian matrix H(p1 , q) of second order partial derivatives of UV1 is always positive for any
(p1 , q), and the diagonal entries of the Hessian matrix are always negative for any (p1 , q). Solving the simultane-
ous equations dUV1/d p1 = 0 and dUV1/dq = 0, we get the unique extreme p∗1 and q∗ , where
e2 + e3 ε e3 + αε p∗1
p∗1 = and q ∗
= . (51)
α(2 − 2ε 2 ) α
Since these optimizers are unique, using the second derivative test, we conclude that p∗1 and q∗ are the global
optimizers.
Now consider the ESM regime, where (ε, γ) → (1, 1). Now consider the following limits, which will be used
in the further calculations,
d¯M d¯M d¯M
lim lim αe1 = 2
, lim lim e2 = + d¯M , and lim lim e3 = 2
(52)
1
2
q∗ d¯M
ε
= lim lim d¯M − αe1 + α p∗1 − α
2
= . 2
(54)
ε→1 γ→1 2 2 4
To ensure that at limit q∗ ≤ θ2 (p∗1 ), using (50), (51), and (52),
d¯M
lim lim θ2 (p∗1 ) − q∗ = d¯M + εα lim lim p∗1 − α lim lim q∗ = d¯M − e3 =
2 2
> 0.2
Again, by substituting the values of p∗1 , q∗ , p∗2 (p∗1 , q∗ ) from (51), (49) into the utility of a coalition V1 (see (46))
and manufacturer M2 (see (48)) at γ → 1, we get,
¯
ε d¯M
¯
dM + d¯M ε
¯ ¯
dM + ε d¯M
PV 1 dM dM
lim (1 − γ)wV1 = + + 1 2
(55) 1 2 2 2 1
16α̃
(1),P d¯2
fM V 1 = − M . 2
2
16α̃
Along the similar lines, we can derive the expressions of worth-limits and the derivative-limits for the other
partition PV 2 which completes the proof.
d¯M CM + q
pbi (q) := + ,i i
(59)
2αM 2 i
q > σib . Thus by Lemma 6, one can derive the NE of the inner-game (p∗1 (q), p∗2 (q)) for any supplier action
aS = q (which is not equal to no ) when both the manufacturers operate and (pbi (q), no ) when only manufacturer i
operates; after substituting this NE into (26), we get the utility of supplier as below (assume w.l.o.g that σ1b ≥ σ2b ):
0 if aS = no
−O if aS ̸= no and q > max{σ1a , σ2b }
¯ S
US (aS ) = dM −αM (CM +q) (62)
2 (q −CS ) − OS
1 1 1
if aS ̸= no and σ2b < q ≤ σ1a
(d¯M +d¯M +(ε−1)(αM CM +αM CM )−(1−ε)(αM +αM )q (q −CS ) − OS if aS ̸= no and q ≤ σ b .
1 2 1 1 2 2 2 1
(2−ε) 2
Observe here that the case when only the first manufacturer operates is given by third row of (62) and the case
when both manufacturers operate is given by the fourth row of (62).
Initially, we need to find the optimizer q∗ of the utility function US , and then the optimal utilities of the supplier
and the manufacturers to compare with other cases. Specifically, we find these quantities in the ESM regime, as
(γ, ε) → (1, 1). As before, we assume that αM = αM = α and also recall α = α̃(1 − γ). Towards optimizing (62),
1 2
we first need to analyse {σib , σia }; by (57) and (58), the corresponding limits in the ESM regime are:
lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε)σia = 0, , (63)
(ε,γ)→(1,1)
2d¯M + d¯M
lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε)σib = i
. −i
(64)
(ε,γ)→(1,1) 3α̃
Observe that in the ESM regime, at limit, when d¯M ≥ d¯M , we have at the limit, 0 = σ1a < σ2b < σ1b . Now, using
1 2
this strict inequality and continuity of functions σ1a , σ1b , and σ2b with respect to (ε, γ), the same strict inequality
is satisfied for all (ε, γ) in a neighbourhood of (1, 1). For all such (ε, γ), after substituting the inner-game NE
(p∗1 (q), p∗2 (q)) from (60), the utility of supplier as given in (62) modifies as follows:
0
if aS = no
−O
US (aS ) = S if aS ̸= no and q > σ2b (65)
d¯M +d¯M +(ε−1)α(CM +CM )−(1−ε)2αq (q −C ) − O if a ̸= n and q ≤ σ b .
1 2 1 2
(2−ε) S S S o 2
For any such (γ, ε), using Lemma 4, we get the optimizer of US as given below:
( )
d¯M + d¯M + (ε − 1)α(CM +CM )
∗ CS b
1 2 1 2
q = min + , σ2
4α(1 − ε) 2
Using simple algebra, and (64), observe that
!
d¯M + d¯M + (ε − 1)α(CM +CM ) d¯M + d¯M
1 2 CS 1 2
lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε) + = , and 1 2
(ε,γ)→(1,1) 3α̃
Thus as (d¯M +d¯M )/4α̃ < (2d¯M +d¯M )/3α̃ , we have that in the neighbhourhood of (ε, γ) → (1, 1), the optimizer of
1 2 2 1
Thus we have,
lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε)UM (a∗M , a∗S ) = 0
i
∀i. (69)
(ε,γ)→(1,1)
Thus from (67)and (69), the ESM limit of worths of coalition ALC are,
d¯M2
fSPA = lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε)wPS A =
(ε,γ)→(1,1) 8α̃
PA
fM =
i
lim (1 − γ)(1 − ε)wPMA = 0 ∀i.
i
(ε,γ)→(1,1)
Observe that after substituting q∗ from m (66) in (60), and then substituting q∗ and the obtained p∗i (q∗ ) in (65)
and (68) we get
d¯M2 ((6 − ε)d¯M + (3ε − 2)d¯M )2
lim (1 − γ)wPS A = , and lim (1 − γ)wPMA = i −i
for all i . (70)
γ→1 8α̃(1 − ε)(2 − ε) γ→1 i
16(4 − ε 2 )2 α̃
Thus after scaling the worths in equation (70) by (1 − ε) and differentiating the scaled worths with respect to ε
and then taking the limit ε → 1, we get,
(1),PA d¯M2
fS = .
8α̃
(1),PA −(5d¯M + d¯M )2 −i
fM i
= i
.
144α̃
This completes the proof.
‘