0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

l16 New

Uploaded by

Daniel Balcha
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

l16 New

Uploaded by

Daniel Balcha
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 17

Lecture 16: Capital Budgeting,

Beta, and Cash Flows

■ Reading:
– Brealey and Myers, Chapter 9
– Lecture Reader, Chapter 15
■ Topics:
– Final topics on basic CAPM
– Debt, Equity, and Asset Betas
– Leveraged Betas
– Operating Leverage

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 1 U.C. Berkeley


Calculating the beta of a portfolio

■ Consider a portfolio of n securities, with weights


w1, ..., wn.
■ The beta of the portfolio, βp, is given by
βp = w1β1 + w2β2 + ... + wnβn.
■ The expected return on the portfolio is
rp = w1r1 + w2r2 + ... + wnrn
= rf + βp(rm-rf).

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 2 U.C. Berkeley


Example
($100 Total Value Portfolio)
$
Asset β w
1 0 -.25 -$25

2 .5 1.5 $150

3 1 -.75 -$75

4 1.5 .5 $50

The portfolio β is:


βp = -.25(0) + 1.5(.5) - .75(1) + .5(1.5) = .75

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 3 U.C. Berkeley


Beta and the Market Portfolio

■ The market portfolio’s beta equals exactly 1 since:


Cov( ~rm , ~rm ) Var ( ~rm )
βm = ~ = ~ =1
Var ( rm ) Var ( rm )

■ Therefore the weighted sum of all the betas in the


economy equals one.

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 4 U.C. Berkeley


The CAPM in practice
(BM 199-211)
■ Graham and Harvey (1999) sent a survey to CFOs
of all Fortune 500 companies, plus the 4,440
members of the Financial Executives Institute.
■ Main findings:
– 74.9% of respondents (almost) always use NPV!!
» Compares with 9.8% found by Gitman/Forrester (1977).
– 73.5% set discount rate using CAPM!!
– 58.8% would use a single company-wide discount rate
for all projects, regardless of type..
■ See BM pp. 199-211 for more discussion
© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 5 U.C. Berkeley
Betas and Cash Flows
■ Any cash flow can be an asset with its own β.
■ For example, a company with many divisions may
have a different β for each division’s revenues.
– a division with β = 1.5 will require a higher discount
rate than a division with β = .75.
■ Even individual machine cash flows may have β:
– Further, the machine’s expense cash flows and its
revenue cash flows may have different β.
■ Now, what effect does Debt have on β?

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 6 U.C. Berkeley


Debt, Equity and Asset Betas

■ The profits generated by a firm's assets are


distributed to its debt and equity holders.
■ Therefore, one can think of a firm's assets as
equivalent to a portfolio of debt and equity.
– A = dollar value of the firm's assets.
– D = dollar value of the firm's debt.
– E = dollar value of the firm's equity.
■ By accounting definition: A = D + E.

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 7 U.C. Berkeley


The Asset Beta

■ Since A = D+E, we can write the asset beta as a


function of the debt and equity betas:
D E
βA = β D + βE = (d )(β D ) + (e)(β E ),
D+E D+E
D E
where d = ;e= .
D+E D+E
■ We can also write βE = (βA - dβd)/(e)
■ If firm’s debt is risk free, equity beta has form:
βE = βA/e = βAA/E = βAA/(A-D).

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 8 U.C. Berkeley


The Effect of Risk-Free Debt on Beta

■ A firm’s asset beta depends on the assets alone;


it does not change as the amount of debt changes.
■ But a firm’s equity beta does depend on its risk-
free debt: βE = βA/e = βAA/E = βAA/(A-D).
– The linkage between the firm's equity beta and its debt-
equity mix is often overlooked.
– In fact, we see that βE rises in tandem with debt D.
– What does this tell you about the effect of more debt on
the firm’s riskiness?

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 9 U.C. Berkeley


Is Debt Less Costly then Equity?
(No!)

■ People often think debt is less costly than equity, since


bond interest rates < expected stock returns.
– This misses point that more debt makes equity riskier.
■ In fact, a firm’s cost of capital is independent of how it
finances a project. Proof follows.
■ Assume firm can issue all the risk free debt it wishes.
■ We know the following:
– rD = rf (since the debt is risk free.)
– βE = βA/e (again, the debt is risk free)
– rE = rf + βE(rm - rf)

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 10 U.C. Berkeley


Cost of Capital is Independent of
Financing: Proof Continued
■ Define the total financing cost rT:
rT = (e)(rE ) + (d)(rD )
■ Now substitute out rE, rD and use βE=βA/e to get
é βA ù
rT = (e )êrf + ( rm − rf ) + (d )(rf ) .
ë e
■ Finally, with just a bit of algebra:
rT = rf + βA(rm - rf)
■ Total cost of capital is independent of financing!

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 11 U.C. Berkeley


Example 1:
But Leverage does Raise rEE

■ Suppose: βA = 2, A = 100, rf = .05, rm - rf = .1


■ Let’s see how rE rises as amount of debt, D, rises:
D βE rE
0 2 .25
10 2.22 .272
50 4 .45
90 20 2.05 (Yes, it really is 2.05!)

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 12 U.C. Berkeley


Sample Problem with
Leveraged Betas

■ You can buy the well diversified mutual fund Get Rich
Yesterday (GRY) containing only stocks.
– The mutual fund beta (βG) = .8. Market portfolio SD = 20%.
– Your portfolio goal is a standard deviation of 12%.
– In what proportions should you mix GRY and the risk free asset?
■ (Step 1) SD(GRY)=.8(20)=16. (All diversified portfolios
with β = .8, must be 80% as risky as the market portfolio.)
■ (Step 2) If you combine GRY with the risk free asset:

SD ( w G ~rG + (1 − w G ) rf ) = w G σ G = w G (16 ) = 12 .
So , w G = 3 / 4 = . 75 .

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 13 U.C. Berkeley


Sample Problem with
Leveraged Betas, Continued

■ Now let every firm held by GRY change from 60% equity
financing to 40% equity financing.
– All the debt is risk free
– What change is required for wG?
■ Recall that βE=βA/e, so βA= eβE.
– With initial 60% equity financed, firms’ βA = (.6)(.8) =.48.
– With final 40% equity financed,.48 = .4βE, so βE = 1.2.
– If the new βE=1.2, then the S.D. of GRY must be 1.2(20)=24.
– This implies wG(24) = 12, or WG=.5.
– So you reduce your holdings in GRY to 50% of your portfolio

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 14 U.C. Berkeley


Operating Leverage
■ An asset creates a portfolio of 3 cash flows:
– Revenues from the asset (R)
– Fixed cost to purchase and use the asset (F)
– Variable cost of using the asset (V)
■ Asset cash flow (A) is written as: A = R – F – V
– Rearrange to get: R = A + F + V.
– Treat revenues as a portfolio of asset, fixed cost and
variable cost.
– Then use portfolio formula to get revenues beta:
A F V
βR = βA + βF + βV .
R R R
© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 15 U.C. Berkeley
Operating Leverage, Continued
A F V
■ Now start with: β R = β A + βF + βV .
R R R
– The beta of the fixed costs equals 0.
– Also assume revenue beta equals the variable cost beta.
– So set βF=0 and βV=βR, and we get
A V
βR = βA + βR .
R R
– Now solve for βA, using R-V = A+F from above:
R−V é Fù
βA = βR . βA = β R ê1 + .
A ë A

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 16 U.C. Berkeley


Operating Leverage, Conclusion

é Fù
βA = β R ê1 + .
ë A
■ Holding the asset value constant, an increase in the
fixed costs increases the asset beta.
■ Thus, projects with large fixed costs have their
cash flows discounted at a higher rate than
projects with low fixed costs.

© M. Spiegel and R. Stanton, 2000 17 U.C. Berkeley

You might also like