Brian Ropi Elasticity of Demand Notes Lower Six 2022
Brian Ropi Elasticity of Demand Notes Lower Six 2022
ELASTICITY 0F DEMAND
Meaning of Elasticity of demand
Demand for a commodity is affected by many factors such as its price, price of
related goods, income of its buyer, tastes and preferences etc. Elasticity means
degree of response. Elasticity of demand means degree of responsiveness of
demand. Demand for a commodity responds to change in price, price of related
goods, income etc.
There are three types of elasticity of demand which measure how the quantity demanded
responds to changes in the key influences on demand that is price, price of related
products and income and therefore we have:
With elasticity of demand we will be concerned not only with the direction of change in
demand but also the size of the change (that is. the magnitude of the change).
PED measures the responsiveness of demand for a product following a change in its own price.
The formula for calculating the co-efficient of elasticity of demand is:
Example: If the price of an ice cream cone increases from $2.00 to $2.20 and the amount
you buy falls from 10 to 8 cones then your elasticity of demand would be calculated as:
Since changes in price and quantity nearly always move in opposite directions, economists
usually do not bother to put in the minus sign. We are concerned with the co-efficient of
elasticity of demand.
Why should we ignore the 'minus sign' in the price elasticity of demand formula?
We know from the downward sloping demand curve that price and quantity demanded are
inversely related (demand law). This means that the price elasticity coefficient of demand will
always yield a negative number. For example, if price declines, then quantity demanded will
increase. This means that the numerator in our formula positive and denominator negative,
yielding a negative coefficient. Conversely, for an increase in price, the coefficient will also
be negative.
This negative sign is usually ignored and it is simply presented the absolute value of the
elasticity coefficient to avoid an ambiguity which might otherwise arise. It can be confusing
to say that an elasticity coefficient of '- 4' is greater than one of '- 2', this possible confusion is
avoided when we say a coefficient of 4 indicates greater elasticity than one of 2. Hence, we
ignore the minus sign in the coefficient of price elasticity of demand and merely show the
absolute value.
Example; If the price of a product decreases from $10 to $8, leading to an increase in quantity
demanded from 40 to 60 units, then the price elasticity of demand can be calculated as:
$4
If PED is between 0 and 1 the percentage change in demand is smaller than the percentage
change in price), then demand is inelastic. Producers know that the change in demand will be
proportionately smaller than the percentage change in price. The demand for necessary goods
like medicines and food items etc. is less than unit elastic. The amount consumed does not
vary very much with price, this can be illustrated as follows:
Inelastic Demand
Price D
P3
P3
Q2 Q1 Q3 Quantity Demanded
Inelastic demand
If PED = 1 (The percentage change in demand is exactly the same as the percentage change
in price), then demand is said to unit elastic. Using a midpoint formula a 25% rise in price
would lead to a 25% contraction in demand leaving total spending by the same at each price
level. A change in price will lead to the same change in the amount demanded.
$4
If PED > 1, then demand responds more than proportionately to a change in price i.e.
demand is elastic. For example using midpoint formula a 22% increase in the price of a good
might lead to a 67% drop in demand. The price elasticity of demand for this price change is –
3. Even small changes in prices lead to big changes in demand.
Elastic Demand
Price
$4
Price
At exactly $4 consumers
$4 D will buy any quantity
Quantity Demanded
Nature of commodity
All necessities like salt, cooking oil, mealie meal that have no substitutes/or less
substitutes will have an inelastic demand. People have to purchase such commodities
for their sustenance. Therefore, there will be some demand despite the changes in price.
Demand for luxury goods, on the other hand, will be elastic. If prices of such
commodities rise even a little, consumers refrain to buy. At the same time a little
lowering of price of such commodities attract a large number of consumers.
Goods which can be used more than once are called durable goods. They are likely to
have more elastic demand. Non-durable goods are likely to have inelastic demand.
time such as computers, printers and scanners. People may wait till they become
cheaper. Therefore, their demand is elastic. But the demand for food or electricity
cannot be postponed. As such their demand is inelastic.
At the price intercept, demand is perfectly elastic. At the mid-point of the demand curve,
demand is unit elastic. At the quantity intercept, demand is perfectly inelastic. Between the
price intercept and mid-point of the demand curve, demand is elastic while between the mid-
point and the quantity intercept, demand is inelastic.
The effects of a change in good price on the total revenue of a firm depends on whether the
demand for the good is elastic or inelastic. When demand is elastic an increase in the price of
a good will cause a decrease in total revenue as illustrated below and a decrease in price will
cause an increase in total revenue. When demand is inelastic for example necessities an
increase in the price of a good will increase total revenue as illustrated below and a decrease
in price will decrease total revenue.
Revenue Revenue
$200 D $100 D
50
Quantity 20 Quantity
Demanded Demanded
$3
Revenue
$1 $240
Revenue
$100 D D
100 Quantity 80 Quantity
Demanded Demanded
When a good has elasticity of demand which is unity, a decrease or increase in price of
good leaves TR unchanged. As the price of a good/service changes up or down, how
TR will change depends on the PED of the good/service. This can be summarized in the
table below:
The diagram below illustrates the relationship between price elasticity of demand and total
revenue.
On the diagram above, As the firm lowers its price, it leaves the elastic region of the demand
curve and enters the unitary elastic region. At this point, any further decreases in price will
lead to an inelastic result and revenue will fall. Firms must realize that when they are in the
elastic range of the demand curve, they must lower prices; when they are in the inelastic
range of the demand curve, they can raise prices.
The demand curve has a downward slope where the three regions of elasticity are illustrated.
The total revenue curve has a point called the maximum point. This is the area where firms’
revenues decline if surpassed.
(ii) Elasticity is more than unit elastic (ed >1): When the demand for a commodity is more
than unit elastic, a fall in price leads to rise in total expenditure and a rise in price leads to a fall
in total expenditure on the commodity. (Price of the commodity and total expenditure move in
opposite direction).See table below
(iii) Elasticity is equal to one (ed = 1): When the demand for a commodity is unit elastic, total
expenditure incurred on the commodity does not change with the change in its price. See table
below
All the three cases discussed above are shown on the diagram below
Illustration 1:
Due to 2% fall in price of good X total expenditure on good X rises by 3%. A 10 % rise in price
of good Y leads to 20 % rise in total expenditure on good Y. Using total expenditure method,
compare price elasticity of demand of good X and good Y.
Solution:
Demand for good X is more than unit elastic because price of the commodity and total
expenditure on the commodity move in opposite direction.
Demand for good Y is less than unit elastic because price of the commodity and total
expenditure on the commodity move in same direction.
1. In the case of necessities that is goods which are required no matter what the price
is (consumption of such goods cannot be dispensed with). For example when the
price of maize rises, the quantity demanded will decrease slightly because maize
is essential to the Zimbabwean diet. This is true for all staple foods.
2. Most raw materials, except rubber have no close substitutes. So, despite changes
in price the demand for such goods will be inelastic. This is also generally true
for food.
3. When a taste or preference becomes a force of habit, it becomes very difficult to
change the habit. For instance, a person who consume rice daily will find it
difficult to switch to other types of grain. Such forces of habit will bring about
inelastic demand.
4. Most primary products are relatively cheap and consumers are not overly
bothered by changes in prices. Most vegetables, for example, do not cost more
than US$5 per kilogram. Moreover, these goods constitute only a minor portion
of one’s total expenditure, such as salt and sugar.
5. The intake of food is limited. Hence, even though the prices of primary products
may be cheap or prices may have dropped considerably, consumers will not buy
large quantities of such goods (e.g. rice) because human intake of food is limited.
6. Most primary products are produced in bulk and although the price may be cheap,
consumers would not buy in large quantities because they do not have the
facilities to store such goods.
7. Associated with the problem of storage is the problem of perishability. Most
primary products, especially agricultural goods such as eggs and fresh fish, cannot
be kept for long as they rot easily.