Kumar A, Et Al. 2018. Determinants and Impacts of Contract Farming Evidence From Cultivation of Onion, Okra and Pomegranate in India
Kumar A, Et Al. 2018. Determinants and Impacts of Contract Farming Evidence From Cultivation of Onion, Okra and Pomegranate in India
December 2018
Anjani Kumar
Gaurav Tripathi
Devesh Roy
P. K. Joshi
Bhushana Karandikar
AUTHORS
Anjani Kumar ([email protected]) is a research fellow in the South Asia Regional Office of
the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), New Delhi, India.
Gaurav Tripathi ([email protected]) is a senior research analyst in the South Asia Regional Office
of IFPRI, New Delhi, India.
Devesh Roy ([email protected]) is a senior research fellow in the Agriculture for Nutrition and Health
(A4NH) Division of IFPRI, New Delhi, India.
P. K. Joshi ([email protected]) is director of the South Asia Regional Office of IFPRI, New Delhi,
India.
Notices
1
IFPRI Discussion Papers contain preliminary material and research results and are circulated in order to stimulate discussion
and critical comment. They have not been subject to a formal external review via IFPRI’s Publications Review Committee. Any
opinions stated herein are those of the author(s) and are not necessarily representative of or endorsed by IFPRI.
2
The boundaries and names shown and the designations used on the map(s) herein do not imply official endorsement or
acceptance by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) or its partners and contributors.
3
Copyright remains with the authors. The authors are free to proceed, without further IFPRI permission, to publish this paper,
or any revised version of it, in outlets such as journals, books, and other publications.
Contents
Abstract .................................................................................................................................. v
Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................... vi
Abbreviations .......................................................................................................................vii
1. Introduction ..................................................................................................................... 1
3. Methodology ................................................................................................................... 6
5. Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 25
REFERENCES .................................................................................................................... 33
iii
Tables
Table 4.2 Economics of onion, okra and pomegranate cultivation for contract and
independent farmers in India ..................................................................................................18
Table 4.3 Determinants for farmers’ participation in CF for onion, okra and pomegranate
cultivators ...............................................................................................................................20
Table 4.4 Impact of CF on profits for onion, okra and pomegranate cultivators in India......22
Table 4.5 Impact of CF on profits for onion, okra and pomegranate cultivators in India:
Outcomes of the nearest-neighbour matching and bootstrap standard errors (kernel-
based matching) ......................................................................................................................24
Table A.1 The economics of cultivation of onion by sample contract and independent
farmers in India (Rs per ha) ....................................................................................................26
Table A.3 Hausman test for endogeneity in the profit equation for onion, okra and
pomegranate ...........................................................................................................................29
Table A.4 Sargan test for over-identification of instrumental variables in the 2SLS
regression................................................................................................................................30
Table A.5 List of variables involved in satisfying the balancing property and common
support of the propensity score ..............................................................................................31
Table A.6 Household characteristics of surveyed farmers taking together the onion, okra
and pomegranate cultivators ...................................................................................................32
iv
ABSTRACT
This paper attempts to quantify the benefits of contract farming (CF) on farmers’ income and
investigates the determinants of participation in CF. This is based on a survey of 1,331 farmers from
Maharashtra State in India engaged in onion, okra and pomegranate cultivation. The study, using 2-
Stage Least Squares method and propensity score matching approach, reveals that CF ensures higher
returns for smallholders to the tune of Rs 14.5 per kilogram over independent farmers. Access to
institutional credit, extension services, farm size, personal ownership of transport and migration
significantly affected farmers’ participation in CF. The empirical evidence of the benefits of CF for
high-value export commodities should encourage government policies to promote and scale up the
use of CF in India.
v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
We are grateful to the United States Agency for International Development (USAID) and Indian
Council of Agricultural Research (ICAR) for extending financial support to conduct this study. Our
special thanks are due to Jain Farm Fresh Foods Limited, Kay Bee Exports, and Sangola Dalimb
Kharedi Vikri Sangh, for their heartfelt cooperation in interviewing farmers. Last but not the least,
we express our sincere thanks to all the farmers who provided the needed information for
accomplishment of this study.
This work was undertaken as part of the CGIAR Research Program on Policies, Institutions,
and Markets (PIM) led by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
vi
ABBREVIATIONS
vii
1. INTRODUCTION
Contract farming (CF) has played a key role in promoting the modernization and
facilitates direct firm-to-farm linkages. CF may help farmers overcome the high transaction
costs of marketing their produce. It provides farmers with opportunity for nonspot transactions,
which are useful when transaction costs are high or markets fail. Markets fail because of factors
marketing, asymmetric information about market prices and lack of capacity for smallholders
to absorb risk. Further, spot markets are less able to efficiently solve quality and food safety
issues, mainly owing to the asymmetric information in these markets. A number of studies have
shown that CF can increase agricultural productivity, profitability and farmers’ income, and
reduce food insecurity; see, for instance, Maertens and Swinnen (2009), Bellemare (2012),
Wang et al. (2014), Bellemare and Novak (2016) and Kumar et al. (2016). Even though CF has
significant potential benefits for both the contractors and the contracted, particularly for critical
quality and safety issues, its role and possible impacts in developing countries are still
controversial. One contentious issue is the threat that smallholders may be excluded from CF
arrangements, particularly if higher transaction costs (along with more stringent quality and
safety demands) prevent small and marginal farmers from participating in CF (Pingali 2006).
India has gone through significant rural transformations and institutional changes that
have shaped today’s agricultural sector and agricultural policies. According to Chand (2005),
CF’s benefits to smallholders, who represent about 80 per cent of the rural population, include
access to credit, inputs and extension services. Another benefit is the links that CF can create
1
between input markets and providers and the international markets by organizing the
production of high-value food crops. The evidence of CF’s impact in the Indian context has
been mixed. For instance, Dev and Rao (2005); Nagaraj et al. (2008); Kumar and Kumar
(2008); Ramaswami, Birthal and Joshi (2006); Tripathi, Singh and Singh (2005); Birthal, Joshi
and Gulati (2005); Kalamkar (2012); Kumar (2006); and Dileep, Grover and Rai (2002) all
found that contract producers earned profits almost three times higher than those of
independent producers, owing to the former’s higher yields and assured output prices.
However, Singh (2002) and Opondo (2000) found negative impact of CF on the environment,
farmer welfare and the power structure between contractors and farmers.
This study is aimed at identifying the factors that motivate farmers’ participation in CF
economic welfare. In doing so, it contributes to the ongoing debate on CF in India. This is
especially important as the Government of India has developed a new model law to promote
CF domestically.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the production of onion, okra
and pomegranate in India and presents the details of the survey data. Section 3 deals with the
methodological approach. Section 4 presents and discusses the estimation results, and Section
2
2. THE COMMODITIES AND THEIR CONTEXTS
Owing to its diverse agro-climatic conditions that favour cultivation of a variety of crops, India
is a leading global producer of fruits and vegetables. It is the world’s largest okra producer (5.5
million tonnes) with a share of 62 per cent of global production (8.9 million tonnes) during
2016. India is also the second-largest producer of dry onion (19.4 million tonnes) with 21 per
cent of global production (93.2 million tonnes) (FAO 2017). Further, India is the world’s
largest producer of pomegranate (2.3 million tonnes) (GoI 2017a, GoI 2017b). Among India’s
states, Maharashtra is the leading state in the production of onion (6.5 million tonnes) and
pomegranate (1.5 million tonnes), as well as a major producer of okra (0.12 million tonnes) in
2016 (GoI 2017a). Maharashtra accounted for 31 per cent of onion, 64 per cent of pomegranate
The study is based on survey data from 1,131 farmers covering three commodities:
onion, okra and pomegranate. The survey was conducted in Maharashtra during March–April
2016. The list of contracting farmers for the year of the survey was obtained from one
contracting firm (hereafter, the sample firm) for each commodity. We collected data on various
farm and farmer characteristics, including cropping patterns, cultivation economics, marketing
The survey for onion was conducted in Nashik and Jalgaon districts, located in the
Khandesh and Northern Maharashtra regions of Maharashtra. Farmers in the Jalgaon district
had formal contracts to produce and supply white onions for Jain Farm Fresh Foods Limited.
Contract onion farmers were from the Shirsoli, Vadali, Pasardi, Dhanora, Panchak, Nashirabad
and Mhaswad villages in Jalgaon district. The independent farmers were selected from the
Nashik district, adjacent to the Jalgaon district. Nashik is the largest onion-producing district
in Maharashtra, contributing more than 25 per cent of state onion production. Jalgaon and
Nashik are located in the same agro-climatic zone (Western Maharashtra Scarcity Zone). We
3
surveyed 105 contract onion growers (a majority of the total contract farmers) and 478
blocks from the Nashik district: Nifad, Sinnur and Baglan. The sample size for Nifad, Sinnur
and Baglan was 139, 163 and 176, respectively. Then, we selected five villages from each
block. Finally, we chose sample households in proportion to the village population for detailed
investigation. Jain Farm Fresh Foods Limited is a subsidiary of the parent company Jain
Irrigation Systems Limited. The firm has been contracting onion growers for around 15 years
in Maharashtra. The contracts are formal and annually renewable. On an average, the surveyed
contract farmers have been in contract for last 6 years with the firm. The firm targets
international market and exports processed white onion powder to the US.
independent farmers. Kay Bee Exports, an exporting company of fresh fruits and vegetables,
had contracts with okra farmers in Baramati block of Pune district and Faltan block of Satara
district. The firm’s purchase price for okra was dynamic, based on changes in its export market
price on a weekly to fortnightly basis. The company supplies its own inputs such as pesticides,
insecticides and bio-fertilizers to the farmers, without any additional cost, to ensure minimum
residual levels in okra for its exports to Europe. We surveyed most of the contract okra farmers
from eight villages in sample districts. The independent farmers were surveyed randomly from
the Solapur, Pune and Satara districts in the Western Maharashtra region. As relatively fewer
independent farmers grow okra, we could survey only 57 farmers from the Solapur, Pune and
Satara districts, scattered over 21 villages in three districts. The contracting firm Kay Bee
Exports, established in 1989, has annually renewable formal contracts with farmers. The
surveyed farmers have been in contract with the firm for an average of around 4 years. The
firm’s purchase price for okra is dynamic and depending on changes in export market price.
4
The survey for pomegranate was conducted in Solapur, a leading pomegranate-
producing district. A sample of 407 pomegranate farmers were surveyed, comprising 130
contract and 277 independent growers, from 18 villages in the Pandharpur, Malshiras and
Sangola blocks of Solapur district. We surveyed contract farmers from the Pandharpur,
Malshiras and Sangola blocks, as most contract pomegranate farmers are located in these
blocks. Sangola Pomegranate Purchasing and Selling Union (Sangola Dalimb Kharedi Vikri
Sangh), a cooperative established in 1992, purchases the produce from its members and sells it
to various agencies, primarily traders in Pune and other markets in India. Independent farmers
were chosen randomly from the same blocks and villages from where contract farmers were
5
3. METHODOLOGY
We carried out a partial budget analysis to estimate the costs and returns for both contract and
independent farmers for each commodity. A farmer’s profit is calculated as the difference
between revenue generated and cost incurred in onion, okra and pomegranate cultivation. We
performed econometric analysis to identify the factors that motivate farmers’ participation in
CF and to assess the impacts of CF on farmers’ profitability, a proxy for farmers’ economic
welfare.
These two aspects of CF have been examined extensively in the empirical literature.
Various studies determine the probability of a farmer’s decision to contract as the first step in
a two-step econometric process to analyse the impact of CF on farmers’ welfare (for example,
Katchova and Miranda 2004; Simmons, Winters and Patrick 2005; Miyata, Minot and Hu 2009;
Wang, Zhang and Wu 2011; Bellemare 2012; Gupta and Roy 2012; Ito, Bao and Sun 2012).
Many other studies, by contrast, focus only on the decision to participate in CF (Birthal, Joshi,
and Gulati 2005; Guo, Jolly, and Zhu 2005; Masakure and Henson 2005; Zhu and Wang 2007;
examine the impact of factors associated with a farmer’s willingness to opt for CF (in the first
stage of regression) and to assess the impact of participation in CF on farmers’ profitability (in
the second stage of regression). The equation for the 2SLS regression is
where, 𝜋𝜋𝑖𝑖 is the net profit per kilogram (kg) for a farm household that cultivates onion, okra or
pomegranate, 𝑑𝑑𝑖𝑖 is a dummy variable that equals 1 if a farmer is under contract and 0 if not
under contract, 𝑋𝑋𝑖𝑖 is a vector of farmer characteristics and 𝜀𝜀𝑖𝑖 is the error-term.
6
We chose various socio-demographic and economic characteristics that can influence
farmers’ decision to participate in CF. These characteristics included age, education, gender of
household head, social caste group, family size, farm size, farming experience, migration,
primary occupation and access to institutional credit. In the first stage of 2SLS regression, the
dependent variable was a binary variable (farmer’s participation in CF = 1, otherwise = 0), and
the independent variables were a mix of qualitative and quantitative factors, representing
various farmer characteristics. We prefer to use the Linear Probability Model in stage one of
the 2SLS process than other approaches like Probit model. We follow Angrist 2000 who
observes that 2SLS estimates using a linear probability model are consistent vis-à-vis other
approaches, thereby underscoring the use of a linear first-stage to be safe. The use of
instrumental variable in the 2SLS model takes care of unobserved factors and helps in getting
An estimation of equation (1) using ordinary least squares (OLS) regression may give
biased results, as a farmer’s decision to participate in CF is not random. Farmers either are
selected for a contract by the contractor or choose to participate in CF. Hence, different
observed and unobserved factors could guide farmers’ entry into CF. Thus, the variable
representing a farmer’s participation in CF (di) can be endogenous, and thus correlate with the
error-term εi. The use of an OLS regression for determining the contribution of CF to farmers’
We used the 2SLS model with instrumental variables to address the unobserved factors
and thereby minimise the bias in estimating the impact of CF on a farmer’s profit. An ideal
instrumental variable should not correlate with the dependent variable in equation (1). It
should, however, correlate with di, the variable representing CF participation. It should not be
7
Accordingly, we attempted to find suitable instrumental variables for the profit equation
variables: (1) ‘information about contracting facility received by farmer from an institutional
source’ (yes = 1, 0 otherwise), (2) ‘distance of bank from farmer’s home’, (3) ‘averse to
financial risk in investment’ (yes = 1, 0 otherwise), (4) ‘risk of limited marketing channels’
(yes = 1, 0 otherwise), and (5) ‘risk of poor roads’ (yes = 1, 0 otherwise). If a farmer receives
information about a contract facility from an institutional source, then the farmer’s decision to
join a farming contract will be influenced. The distance between the farmer’s home and
institutions like banks provides farmers with an opportunity to interact with farmers from
various locations, including the farmers engaged in contract farming. The networking effect is
likely to prompt such farmers for joining contract farming. Farmers residing near to the banks
are expected to visit banks more frequently. Further, proximity to banks may help in facilitating
production, sale, or delivery risks is more likely to participate in CF. For instance, farmers who
are concerned about the risks of limited marketing channels or poor roads are more likely to
join CF in order to reduce these risks. Although these instrumental variables are strongly related
with di, they are not systematically related with the dependent variable—profit—in
equation (1). We conducted the OLS and 2SLS regressions with product-fixed effect.
We conducted a Hausman test for endogeneity for the profit equation of onion, okra
and pomegranate (Table A.3). Because the Hausman test indicated endogeneity, the 2SLS
We then assessed the validity of instruments (when more than one instrumental variable
is used) using the Sargan test for over-identification (Table A.4). The two instruments are valid
8
if the Sargan test outcome is statistically insignificant, and invalid if the outcome is significant.
The Sargan test was statistically insignificant, and so the instrumental variables are valid.
We also used propensity score matching (PSM) method to gauge the impact of CF on
unit profit. The matching approach helps find a large group of control households that are
similar to the treatment households in all relevant pre-treatment characteristics X. Then, the
differences between the outcomes of the control group and of the treatment group can be
attributed to the treatment. Since conditioning on all relevant covariates is limited in the case
of a high-dimensional vector X, Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) suggest the use of balancing
scores b(X), that is, functions of the relevant observed covariants X such that the conditional
distribution of X given b(X) is independent of assignment into treatment, also known as the
conditional independence assumption (CIA). One possible balancing score is the propensity
score; that is, the probability of participating in a treatment given observed characteristics X.
The matching procedures based on this balancing score are known as PSM. PSM also will be
helpful in checking the robustness of the results based on OLS and independent variables.
have comparison observations “nearby” in the propensity score distribution. This common
support or overlap condition ensures that persons with the same X values have a positive
probability of being both control and treatment households (Heckman, LaLonde and Smith
1999). The common support thus represents the area where there are enough of both control
and treatment observations. The common support region allows effective comparisons of
Assuming that the CIA holds and that there is overlap between both groups, the average
treatment effect can then be estimated. Ideally, we wanted to estimate ∆ = 𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡1 − 𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡0 , which is
the difference of the outcome variable of interest at time t between two groups, denoted by the
superscripts 1 and 0. However, we were unable to estimate Δ in this way because a household
9
cannot be in the treatment and the control groups simultaneously. Therefore, we measured the
average treatment effect (ATE) given the observable data, and estimated the ATE on the treated
𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴𝐴 = 𝐸𝐸(∆|𝑋𝑋, 𝑇𝑇 = 1) = 𝐸𝐸(𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡1 − 𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡0 |𝑋𝑋, 𝑇𝑇 = 1) = 𝐸𝐸(𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡1 |𝑋𝑋, 𝑇𝑇 = 1) − 𝐸𝐸(𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡0 |𝑋𝑋, 𝑇𝑇 = 0) (2)
used to match households with similar observable characteristics. PSM entails forming
matched sets of treated and untreated subjects that share similar propensity score values
(Rosenbaum and Rubin, 1983, 1985). PSM allows one to estimate the ATT (Imbens 2004). We
used nearest-neighbour matching to select best control matches for each subject in treatment
group. We matched one, three and five control subjects to each treated subject using nearest-
neighbour matching, along with kernel-based matching with bootstrap standard errors.
10
4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS
Table 4.1 presents the average values of key household characteristics for farmers of each of
the three commodities i.e. onion, okra and pomegranate. The average age of farmers ranged
from 44 years to 47 years. Ninety-seven per cent of the households surveyed were headed by
males. The caste 1 structure of households differed across commodities. Around 47 per cent of
onion growers belonged to the Other Backward Castes (OBCs), 38 per cent were from the
general class and the remaining 15 per cent were Scheduled Castes (SCs) and Scheduled Tribes
(STs). More than 75 per cent of okra growers were from the general class, while 18 per cent
were OBCs and 6 per cent were SCs or STs. Fifty-six per cent of pomegranate farmers were
from the general class, 33 per cent were OBCs and 12 per cent were SCs or STs. The farmers’
average years of education ranged from 8.4 years (pomegranate growers) to 9.9 years (okra
cultivators), while the average years of education of the highest-educated person in each
farming family was around 12 years. Around 99 per cent of onion, okra and pomegranate
farmers had farming as their main occupation. The average length of farming experience
ranged from 19 years for pomegranate farmers to 21 years for onion farmers. The average
family size for onion, okra and pomegranate farmers was around six persons. Average
dependency ratio ranged between 0.5 and 0.6 for cultivators across crop types. The average
farm size was 1.7 hectares (ha) for onion growers, 1.9 ha for okra growers and 2.2 ha for
pomegranate growers. About half of onion (52 per cent) and okra (49 per cent) farmers and
68 per cent of pomegranate farmers had access to institutional credit. One-third of the sample
1
In India, the socio-economically most unprivileged caste groups relate to schedule caste and
schedule tribe. Then, besides the schedule caste and schedule tribe, other caste groups that are
socio-economically less privileged have been identified by the Government of India as other
backward castes (OBC). The schedule caste, schedule tribe and OBCs receive reservation quota
in education and government employment. The open category is known as the general class
comprising of socio-economically privileged castes.
11
farmers were members of a cooperative. The percentage of farmers with their own means of
personal transport was 73 per cent of onion growers, 67 per cent of okra growers and 51 per
farmers. For example, contract and non-contract onion farmers differed in terms of social caste,
crop insurance purchase, number of annual visits by private extension officials and own means
of personal transport. The contract and independent okra growers differed in terms of family
size, access to institutional credit and own means of personal transport. The contract and
experience, operational holding size, access to institutional credit, number of annual visits by
private extension officials and own means of personal transport. Among contract onion
growers, 81 per cent belonged to OBCs and 17 per cent were from general castes, but only
2 per cent were from SCs or STs. By contrast, 40 per cent of independent onion farmers were
from OBCs, 43 per cent belonged to general castes and more than 17 per cent farmers
represented SCs and STs. The average years of education of contract onion farmers (11 years)
was higher than that of independent farmers (9 years). Contract onion farmers had higher
average highest education in family (12.6 years) than independent farmers (11.5 years).
Operational holding size was much higher among contract onion farmers (3.1 ha) than
noncontract onion farmers (1.3 ha). Access to institutional credit was significantly higher for
contract onion growers (72 per cent) than independent onion growers (47 per cent). More than
compared with about a quarter of the independent farmers. Twenty-four per cent of contract
onion growers had crop insurance, whereas only 1.5 per cent of independent onion growers
insured their crops. Contract onion farmers received an average of six yearly visits from private
12
extension officials; independent onion farmers received only one visit. Regarding personal
ownership of transport, 64 per cent of contract onion growers had their own means of transport
Other differences were observed in the different groups of okra and pomegranate
producers. In the case of okra, the contract farmers had a smaller average family size (5.6) than
independent growers (6.8). However, access to institutional credit was lower for contract okra
farmers (37 per cent) than independent farmers (67 per cent). In the case of pomegranate,
contract farmers had higher average highest education in family (12.1 years) than independent
farmers (11.3 years). Contract pomegranate farmers also had a longer average farming
experience (22 years) compared with independent farmers (18 years). The operational holding
size for contract pomegranate farmers (2.7 ha) was higher than that for noncontract
pomegranate farmers (2.0 ha). Access to institutional credit was significantly higher for
contract pomegranate growers (87 per cent) than for independent growers (59 per cent). Private
extension officials visited contract pomegranate farmers three times per year and independent
farmers twice per year. Regarding personal ownership of transport, 65 per cent of contract
pomegranate growers had their own means of transport compared with 44 per cent of
independent farmers. Table A.6 provides the average figure for household characteristics of
onion, okra and pomegranate taken together by appending observations of the three
commodities.
13
Table 4.1 Household characteristics of farmers
Household characteristics All Contract Independent Difference t-Test value
Onion
Age of household (HH) head (years) 47.1 46.4 47.2 −0.9 0.6886
Gender of HH head (%) (male=1,
99.8 100.0 99.8 0.2 0.4684
otherwise=0)
Social caste (%)
5.0 0.0 6.1 −6.1
Scheduled Caste
9.4 1.9 11.1 −9.2 ***
Scheduled Tribe
OBC 47.3 81.0 40.0 41.0 (Pr = 0.000)
14
Household characteristics All Contract Independent Difference t-Test value
Operational land (ha) 1.9 1.8 2.0 −0.3 0.7887
Access to institutional credit (%) 48.9 36.9 66.7 −29.8*** 3.6019
Membership of cooperative or other
27.0 29.8 22.8 7.0 0.9096
organisation (%)
No. of yearly visits by private extension
1.2 1.0 1.5 −0.5 1.1348
officials
Own means of personal transport (%) 67.4 78.6 50.9 27.7*** 3.5710
Pomegranate
Age of HH head (years) 43.9 45.0 43.5 1.5 1.1832
Gender of HH head (%) (Male=1,
98.8 100.0 98.2 1.8 1.5421
otherwise=0)
Social caste (%)
6.9 11.2 −4.3
Scheduled Caste 9.8
0.8 2.2 −1.4
Scheduled Tribe 1.7
Pr = 0.393
OBC 33.9 32.5 1.4
32.9
General 58.5 54.2 4.3
55.5
Education of HH head (years) 8.4 8.7 8.2 0.5 0.9837
Education of highest educated person in
11.5 12.1 11.3 0.9** 2.2239
HH (years)
% farmers with farming as main
98.8 98.5 98.9 −0.4 0.3880
occupation
Experience in farming (years) 19.3 21.6 18.3 3.4*** 2.9953
Household size 5.8 6.0 5.6 0.4 1.4244
Dependency ratio 0.52 0.53 0.52 0.01 0.0520
Operational land (ha) 2.2 2.7 2.0 0.8*** 2.8985
Access to institutional credit (%) 67.6 86.9 58.5 28.4*** 5.9438
Membership of cooperative or other
31.9 100.0 0.0 100.0 –
organisation (%)
No. of yearly visits by private extension
2.3 3.1 1.9 1.2*** 6.5214
officials
Own means of personal transport (%) 50.6 65.4 43.7 21.7*** 4.1591
Source: Field survey (2016).
Notes: ***, ** and * represent 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent significance, respectively.
15
Table 4.2 presents data on yield, production cost, output prices and profits of both contract and
independent onion, okra and pomegranate farming households. The average onion yield was
higher for contract growers (239.3 quintals per hectare [q/ha]) than for noncontract producers
(187.4 q/ha), and differed significantly at the 1 per cent level. Additionally, the average price
realised by onion contract farmers (Rs 753/q) was significantly higher than that received by
noncontract farmers (Rs 598/q). Moreover, the cost of onion cultivation was significantly lower
for contract farmers (Rs 515/q) than for noncontract farmers (Rs 762/q). The higher yields,
better prices and lower production costs achieved by contract farmers made onion cultivation
more profitable. Further, the open-market prices for onions had crashed in 2016 owing to
increased production, and so the independent onion growers incurred a loss of Rs 164/q. The
contract farmers were protected from these price fluctuations because of their contract-fixed
prices and earned a profit of Rs 238/q. In case of okra, contract farmers produced a significantly
higher yield than that of independent farmers. However, okra prices and production costs for
contract farmers were lower than that of independent farmers. The independent farmers
received higher open-market prices for okra, compared with the fixed prices received by
contract farmers. Nevertheless, contract okra farmers received subsidies for their input costs,
particularly for plant protection material and bio-fertilizers, which contributed to their lower
production costs (Rs 1,469/q). The contract okra farmers therefore earned significantly higher
profits (Rs 1,231/q) because of their lower production costs and higher yields. In case of
pomegranate, the contract and independent farmers did not differ significantly in yield, price,
cost or profit. Table A.1 depicts various components of the cost of cultivation. Table A.2 gives
percentage distribution of the components in total cost of cultivation. Several studies have
reported substantial positive impact on gross margins, crop income or total household income
of contract farmers in developing countries; these include studies on Kenya (Wainaina, Okello
and Nzuma 2012), India (Singh 2002; Birthal, Joshi and Gulati 2005; Tripathi, Singh and Singh
16
2005; Ramaswami, Birthal and Joshi 2006; Kalamkar 2012), Senegal (Warning and Key 2002),
Laos (Leung, Sethboonsarng and Stefan 2008), Madagascar (Bellemare 2012), Nicaragua
(Michelson 2013), China (Zhu 2007; Miyata, Minot and Hu 2009; Xu and Wang 2009) and
17
Table 4.2 Economics of onion, okra and pomegranate cultivation for contract and independent
farmers in India
Onion
Yield (q/ha) 196.7 239.3 187.4 51.9***
(76.7) (74.8) (73.9)
18
Determinants for farmers’ participation in CF
Table 4.3 presents the results of the first stage of 2SLS regression (equation 1) that exhibits the
determinants of farmers’ participation in CF for onion, okra and pomegranate. The variables
farm size, access to institutional credit, number of visits by government extension officials,
number of visits by private extension officials, and own personal transport, had significant
negative impact on CF participation, because migration may hamper activities related to the
contractual arrangements. In addition, okra and pomegranate farmers were more likely than
19
Table 4.3 Determinants for farmers’ participation in CF for onion, okra and pomegranate
cultivators
Dependent variable: Participation in contract farming (yes=1/no=0)
Variable Coefficient S.E.
Socio-demographic variables
ln(Age of HH head) (years) −0.142 (0.919)
Square of ln(Age of HH head) 0.0233 (0.126)
Gender of HH head (Male=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0810 (0.0890)
Caste
OBC (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0203 (0.0337)
General (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0291 (0.0258)
ln(Years of education of HH head) −0.0394 (0.0663)
Square of ln(Years of education of the HH head) 0.0163 (0.0208)
ln(Number of economically active family members) 0.00652 (0.0175)
Migration (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) −0.109*** (0.0401)
Ln(Operational land) (Ha) 0.0364** (0.0168)
Own personal transport (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0847** (0.0428)
Economic variables
Main occupation (Farming=1, Other=0) −0.00184 (0.125)
Access to institutional credit (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0742*** (0.0219)
ln(Number of visits by government extension officials) 0.0650** (0.0304)
ln(Number of visits by private extension officials) 0.0338** (0.0160)
ln(Number of visits by farmer for extension officials) −0.00332 (0.0168)
Product Fixed Effect (Okra) 0.903*** (0.0421)
Product Fixed Effect (Pomegranate) 1.180*** (0.0741)
Instrumental variables
Information about contract facility received from an institutional
0.0499 (0.0325)
source (Yes=1, 0 otherwise)
Distance to bank from home (kilometre) −0.00355* (0.00190)
Averse to financial risk in investment (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0588*** (0.0175)
Risk of limited marketing channels (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0910** (0.0437)
Risk of poor roads (Yes=1, 0 otherwise) 0.0709* (0.0418)
Constant −0.0340 (1.579)
No. of observations 1,131
R-squared 0.628
Root MSE 0.2777
District Fixed Effect Yes
Source: Authors’ analysis based on field survey (2016).
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses; ***, ** and * represent 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent
significance, respectively. Standard errors are clustered at the district level.
20
Impact of contract farming on farmers’ profit
Table 4.4 exhibits the results of the impact of CF on profits made by onion, okra and
pomegranate cultivators. It gives the outcomes of the second stage of 2SLS regression along
with OLS regression. Unlike OLS regression, the 2SLS regression takes care of the unobserved
factors in regression and gives the true impact of CF on farmers’ profit. The instrumental
variables used in the 2SLS model were (1) ‘information about contracting facility received by
farmer from an institutional source’ (yes=1, 0 otherwise), (2) ‘distance of bank from farmer’s
home’, (3) ‘averse to financial risk in investment’ (yes=1, 0 otherwise), (4) ‘risk of limited
marketing channels’ (yes=1, 0 otherwise), and (5) ‘risk of poor roads’ (yes=1, 0 otherwise).
The instrumental variables were tested for their validity using the Sargan test (Table A.4) and
found to be valid. The Hausman test for endogeneity shows endogeneity in the profit equation
(Table A.3). This means that estimates of 2SLS regression should be preferred over that of
OLS regression. The results in table 4 show that CF had a significant positive impact on the
profits of onion, okra and pomegranate growers. Participation in CF enhanced farmers’ profit
by Rs 14.5/kg. Migration had a negative impact on the profits. However, the product fixed
effect did not indicate significant difference in the unit profits of okra and pomegranate with
respect to onion.
21
Table 4.4 Impact of CF on profits for onion, okra and pomegranate cultivators in India
Dependent variable: Unit profit in production of onion, okra and pomegranate (Rs/kg)
Variable OLS 2SLS 2nd stage
Coefficient
Coefficient S.E. S.E.
22
Robustness for profitability
We use the PSM method to evaluate the impact of CF on unit profit for onion, okra and
pomegranate cultivators in India (Table 4.5). Table A.5 gives the variables involved in
satisfying the balancing property and common support of the propensity score. Table 5 gives
the outcomes of the nearest-neighbour matching estimation with analytical standard errors, as
in Abadie and Imbens (2006), and kernel-based matching with bootstrap standard errors. For
both okra and onion farmers, the unit profit for contract farmers was significantly higher than
that for independent farmers. However, CF did not appear to have had a profit impact on
pomegranate growers. The profit for onion contract farmers was more than that for independent
Rs 4.4/kg (nearest-neighbour matching with number of matches = 1). In the case of okra
growers, the contract farmers earned higher profit than the independent farmers, ranging from
matches = 5). Further, when observations pertaining to onion, okra and pomegranate are taken
together, contract farmers received higher returns with regard to independent farmers in the
number of matches = 1). Thus, the results validate the outcomes of the 2SLS regression that
contract farmers earn significantly higher profit than independent farmers do.
23
Table 4.5 Impact of CF on profits for onion, okra and pomegranate cultivators in India:
Outcomes of the nearest-neighbour matching and bootstrap standard errors (kernel-based
matching)
Number of matches (m) Variable Unit profit in production (Rs/kg)
24
5. CONCLUSION
This study is based on 2016 survey data of farm households cultivating onion, okra and
pomegranate in India. It assesses the drivers for participation in CF and estimates the impact
of CF on profits for growers of these commodities. Our results show that access to institutional
credit, extension facility official visits, personal ownership of transport and farm size have a
positive effect on farmers’ participation in CF, whereas migration has a negative impact.
Conditional on participation, the contract farmers were able to earn significantly higher profits
in their onion, okra and pomegranate cultivation. CF also played an important role in
heterogeneity in the impact of CF. The higher CF profits for onion and okra stemmed mainly
from higher yields and lower production costs, whereas CF did not realize higher yield or profit
for pomegranate growers. In the case of pomegranate farmers, the motivation for CF may come
from a desire to share the risks of cultivation. These findings have several important policy
implications. The benefits of CF are product- and contract-specific, and therefore policymakers
25
APPENDIX: SUPPLEMENTARY TABLES
Table A.1 The economics of cultivation of onion by sample contract and independent farmers in India (Rs per ha)
Onion Okra Pomegranate
Particulars of cost of cultivation
Contract Independent Difference Contract Independent Difference Contract Independent Difference
Labour 25,076 20,970 4,106*** 99,707 116,404 −16,697 53,543 58,961 −5,417
(15,607) (12,225) (59,339) (80,800) (34,861) (56,581)
Inputs:
Seed 12,552 22,580 −10,028*** 24,926 22,167 2,579* 25,024 28,801 −3,776**
(3,966) (12,452) (8,563) (8,865) (8,452) (17,832)
Fertilizers 15,058 13,166 1,892* 28,818 56,123 −27,304*** 48,213 55,572 −7,358**
(10,504) (9,990) (25,623) (28,815) (34,302) (35,301)
Irrigation 31,676 29,094 2,581 63,844 73,220 −9,376 101,872 130,370 −28,498*
(25,038) (21,549) (44,699) 65,579 (100,507) (173,275)
Farm Yard Manure (FYM) 6,268 11,263 −4,994*** 17,372 18,143 −1,941 19,862 21,485 −1,623
(7,986) (12,046) (17,852) (12,706) (18,455) (14,703)
Pesticides 9,648 13,714 −4,065*** 1,486 51,744 −50,258*** 39,693 42,345 −2,651
(11,568) (11,104) (7,825) (52,581) (33,545) (37,085)
26
Onion Okra Pomegranate
Particulars of cost of cultivation
Contract Independent Difference Contract Independent Difference Contract Independent Difference
Rent for bullock pair / machinery 8,570 12,126 −3,555*** 17,919 19,825 −1,906 19,289 11,843 7,446***
(7,281) (11,097) (11,829) (20,557) (15,927) (10,066)
Marketing costs 9,053 9,543 −490 1,691 27,181 −25,489*** 19,448 20,872 −1,423
(5,252) (7,771) (9,674) (26,511) (12,422) (12,924)
Total cost of cultivation 117,901 132,472 −14,571** 261,959 389,220 −127,262*** 333,066 375,020 −41,954*
(49,808) (61,689) (116,246) (171,796) (164,060) (236,247)
Source: Field survey (2016).
Notes: ***, ** and * represent 1 per cent, 5 per cent and 10 per cent significance, respectively. Figures in brackets represent standard deviation.
27
Table A.2 Composition of cost of cultivation of onion in India (%)
% share in total cost of cultivation
Labour costs
Input costs
Marketing costs
28
Table A.3 Hausman test for endogeneity in the profit equation for onion, okra and pomegranate
Dependent variable: Unit profit in production of onion, okra and pomegranate (Rs/kg)
Independent Variables: (1) Information on
contract facility received from institutional
source; (2) Distance of bank from home;
(3) Averse to financial risk in investment;
Variable (4) Risk of limited marketing channels;
(5) Risk of poor roads
Coefficient S.E.
29
Table A.4 Sargan test for over-identification of instrumental variables in the 2SLS regression
Instrumental variables: (1) Information on contract facility received from institutional source; (2) Distance
of bank from home; (3) Averse to financial risk in investment; (4) Risk of limited marketing channels;
30
Table A.5 List of variables involved in satisfying the balancing property and common support of the
propensity score
Contract Farming
Socio-demographic variables
ln(Age of the HH head) (Years)
Square Ln(Age of the HH head)
Gender of HH head (Male=1, 0 otherwise)
Social caste
ln(Years of education of the HH head)
Square Ln(Years of education of the HH head)
ln(Number of economically active family members)
Migration
ln(Operational land)
Own personal transport
Economic variables
Main occupation
Access to institutional credit
ln(Number of visits by government extension officials)
ln(Number of visits by private extension officials)
ln(Number of visits by farmer for extension official)
31
Table A.6 Household characteristics of surveyed farmers taking together the onion, okra and
pomegranate cultivators
t-Test
Household characteristics All Contract Independent Difference
value
Age of household (HH) head (years) 45.6 45.2 45.7 -0.5 0.6422
Gender of HH head (%) (male=1,
99.2 99.4 99.2 0.2 0.4001
otherwise=0)
Social caste (%)
6.8 3.4 8.1 -4.7
Scheduled Caste
***
5.5 0.9 7.3 -6.3
Scheduled Tribe
(Pr =
OBC 38.5 45.5 35.8 9.6
0.000)
General 49.2 50.2 48.8 1.4
32
REFERENCES
Abadie, A., and Imbens, G. W. 2006. “Large Sample Properties of Matching Estimators for
Average Treatment Effects.” Econometrica 74(1): 235–267. doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-
0262.2006.00655.x
Angrist, J. (2000), Estimation of limited dependent variable models and zero-one endogenous
regressors: simple strategies for empirical practice. NBER Technical Working Paper 248,
Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bellemare, M. F., and Novak, L. 2016. “Contract Farming and Food Security.” American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 99(2): 357–378. doi:10.1093/ajae/aaw053.
Bellemare, M. F. 2012. “As You Sow, So Shall You Reap: The Welfare Impacts of Contract
Farming.” World Development 40(7): 1418–1434. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.12.008.
Birol, E., Ndirangu, L., Roy, D., and Yakhshilikov, Y. 2011. “Assessing the Livelihood
Impacts of a Livestock Disease Outbreak: An Alternative Approach.” Markets, Trade and
Institutions (MTID) Discussion Paper No. 01081. Washington, DC: International Food
Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
Birthal, P. S., Joshi, P. K., and Gulati, A. 2005. “Vertical Coordination in High Value Food
Commodities: Implication for Small Holders.” MTID Discussion Paper No 85.
Washington, DC: IFPRI.
Chand, R. 2005. India’s Agricultural Challenges: Reflections on Policy, Technology and Other
Issues. New Delhi: Centre for Trade & Development.
http://www.centad.org/images/download/agricultural_book.pdf.
Dev, S. M., and Rao, N. C. 2005. “Food Processing and Contract Farming in Andhra Pradesh:
A Small Farmer Perspective.” Economic and Political Weekly 40(26): 2705–2713.
Dileep, B. K., Grover, R. K., and Rai, K. N. 2002. “Contract Farming in Tomato: An Economic
Analysis.” Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics 57(2): 197–210.
Fischer, E., and Qaim, M. 2012. “Linking Smallholders to Markets: Determinants and Impacts
of Farmer Collective Action in Kenya.” World Development 40(6): 1255–1268.
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2011.11.018.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations). 2017. FAOSTAT database.
Accessed December 15, 2017. http://faostat.fao.org/
33
GoI (Government of India). 2017a. Horticultural Statistics at a Glance 2017. New Delhi:
Department of Agriculture, Cooperation and Farmers Welfare, Ministry of Agriculture &
Farmers Welfare.
http://nhb.gov.in/statistics/Publication/Horticulture%20At%20a%20Glance%202017%20
for%20net%20uplod%20(2).pdf.
GoI. 2017b. Annual Report 2016–17. New Delhi: Department of Agriculture, Cooperation and
Farmers Welfare, Ministry of Agriculture & Farmers Welfare.
http://agricoop.nic.in/sites/default/files/Annual_rpt_201617_E.pdf.
Guo, H., Jolly, R. W., and Zhu, J. 2005. “Contract Farming in China: Supply Chain or Ball and
Chain.” Proceeding of the Minnesota International Economic Development Conference,
University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, April 29−30.
Gupta, K., and Devesh, R. 2012. “Gains from Coordination in Milkfed Dairy in Punjab.”
Journal of Agribusiness in Developing and Emerging Economies 2(2): 92–114.
doi:10.1108/20440831211272571.
Heckman, J., LaLonde, R., and Smith, J. 1999. “The Economics and Econometrics of Active
Labor Market Programs.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3, edited by O.
Ashenfelter and D. Card, 1865–2097. Amsterdam: Elsevier. doi: 10.1016/S1573-
4463(99)03012-6.
Imbens, G.W. 2004. “Nonparametric Estimation of Average Treatment Effects under
Exogeneity: A Review.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86(1): 4–29.
doi:10.1162/003465304323023651.
Ito, J., Bao, Z., and Sun, Q. 2012. “Distributional Effects of Agricultural Cooperatives in China:
Exclusion of Smallholders and Potential Gains in Participation.” Food Policy 37(6): 700–
709. doi:10.1016/j.foodpol.2012.07.009.
Kalamkar, S. S. 2012. “Inputs and Services Delivery System under Contract Farming: A Case
of Broiler Farming.” Agricultural Economics Research Review 25(Conf): 515–521.
http://www.aeraindia.in/publication/Contents_Vol%2025_conf..pdf.
Katchova, A. L., and Miranda, M. J. 2004. “Two-step Econometric Estimation of Farm
Characteristics Affecting Marketing Contract Decisions.” American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 86(1): 88–102. doi:10.1111/j.0092-5853.2004.00564.x.
Kumar, A., Roy, D., Tripathi, G., Joshi, P K., and Adhikari, R. P. 2016. “Can Contract Farming
Increase Farmers’ Income and Enhance Adoption of Food Safety Practices? Evidence from
Remote Areas of Nepal.” IFPRI Discussion Paper No. 01524. Washington, DC: IFPRI.
34
Kumar, A., Shinoj, P., and Shivjee. 2013. “Do Dairy Co-operatives Enhance Milk Production,
Productivity and Quality? Evidences from the Indo-Gangetic Plain of India.” Indian
Journal of Agricultural Economics 68(3): 457–468.
Kumar, J., and Kumar, P. K. 2008. “Contract Farming: Problems, Prospects and Its Effects on
Income and Employment.” Agricultural Economics Research Review 21: 243–250.
http://www.aeraindia.in/publication/Contents-%20Vol%2021%20No.%202.pdf.
Kumar, P. 2006. “Contract Farming through Agribusiness Firms and State Corporation: A Case
Study in Punjab.” Economic and Political Weekly 41(52):5367–5375.
Leung, P., Sethboonsarng, S., and Stefan, A. 2008. “Rice Contract Farming in Lao PDR:
Moving from Subsistence to Commercial Agriculture.” ADB Institute Discussion Paper
No. 90. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.
Maertens, M., and Swinnen, J. F. M. 2009. “Trade, Standards, and Poverty: Evidence from
Senegal.” World Development 37(1): 161–178. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.04.006.
Masakure, O., and Henson, S. 2005. “Why Do Small-scale Producers Choose to Produce under
Contract? Lessons from Nontraditional Vegetable Exports from Zimbabwe.” World
Development 33(10): 1721–1733. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.04.016.
Michelson, H. C. 2013. “Small Farmers, NGOs, and a Walmart World: Welfare Effects of
Supermarkets Operating in Nicaragua.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics
95(3): 628–649. doi:10.1093/ajae/aas139.
Miyata, S., Minot, N., and Hu, D. 2009. “Impact of Contract Farming on Income: Linking
Small Farmers, Packers, and Supermarkets in China.” World Development 37(11): 1728–
1741. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.08.025.
Nagaraj, N., Chandrakanth, M. G., Chengappa, P. G., Roopa, H. S., and Chandakavate, P. M.
2008. “Contract Farming and Its Implications for Input-Supply, Linkages between Markets
and Farmers in Karnataka.” Agricultural Economics Research Review 21(Conf): 307–316.
http://www.aeraindia.in/publication/Contents-%20Vol%2021%20Conf..pdf.
Opondo, M. M. 2000. “The Socio-Economic and Ecological Impacts of the Agro-Industrial
Food Chain on the Rural Economy in Kenya.” Ambio 29(1): 35–41.
Pingali, P. 2006. “Agricultural Growth and Economic Development: A View through the
Globalization Lens.” Presidential Address to the 26th International Conference of
Agricultural Economists, Gold Coast, Australia, August 12–18.
Ramaswami, B., Birthal, P. S., and Joshi, P. K. 2006. “Efficiency and Distribution in Contract
Farming: The Case of Indian Poultry Growers.” MTID Discussion Paper No. 91.
Washington, DC: IFPRI.
35
Rosenbaum, P. R., and Rubin, D. B. 1983. “The Central Role of the Propensity Score in
Observational Studies for Causal Effects.” Biometrika 70(1): 41–55.
doi:10.1093/biomet/70.1.41.
Rosenbaum, P. R., and Rubin, D. B. 1985. “Constructing a Control Group using Multivariate
Matched Sampling Methods that Incorporate the Propensity Score.” The American
Statistician 39(1): 33–38. doi:10.2307/2683903.
Simmons, P., Winters, P., and Patrick, I. 2005. “An Analysis of Contract Farming in East Java,
Bali, and Lombok, Indonesia.” Agricultural Economics 33(s3): 513–525.
doi:10.1111/j.1574-0864.2005.00096.x.
Singh, S. 2002. “Contracting Out Solutions: Political Economy of Contract Farming in the
Indian Punjab.” World Development 30(9): 1621–1638. doi:10.1016/S0305-
750X(02)00059-1.
Tripathi R. S., Singh, R., and Singh, S. 2005. “Contract Farming in Potato Production: An
Alternative for Managing Risk and Uncertainty.” Agricultural Economics Research
Review 18(Dec): 47–60.
Wainaina, P. W., Okello, J. J., and Nzuma, J. 2012. “Impact of Contract Farming on
Smallholder Poultry Farmers’ Income in Kenya.” Paper presented at the 2012 Triennial
Conference of International Association of Agricultural Economists, Foz do Iguaçu,
Brazil, August 18–24.
Wang H. H., Zhang, Y., and Wu, L. 2011. “Is Contract Farming a Risk Management Instrument
for Chinese Farmers? Evidence from a Survey of Vegetable Farmers in Shandong.” China
Agricultural Economic Review 3(4): 489–505. doi: 10.1108/17561371111192347.
Wang, H. H., Wang, Y., and Delgado, M. S. 2014. “The Transition to Modern Agriculture:
Contract Farming in Developing Economies.” American Journal of Agricultural
Economics 96(5): 1257–1271. doi:10.1093/ajae/aau036.
Warning, M., and Key, N. 2002. “The Social Performance and Distributional Consequences of
Contract Farming: An Equilibrium Analysis of the Arachide de Bouche Program in
Senegal.” World Development 30(2): 255–263. doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00104-8.
Wong, G. Y., Darachanthara, S., and Soukkhamthat, T. 2014. “Economic Valuation of Land
Uses in Oudomxay Province, Lao PDR: Can REDD+ Be Effective in Maintaining
Forests?” Land 3: 1059–1074. doi:10.3390/land3031059.
Xu, J., and Wang, X. 2009. “An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Contract Farming and Its
Organization Models on Farmers’ Income” [in Chinese]. Chinese Rural Economy 2009(4):
39–47.
36
Zhu, H. 2007. “An Assessment of the Effects of Adopting Contract Farming Structure in the
Tomato Industry in Xinjiang” [in Chinese]. Journal of Agrotechnical Economics 3: 89–
95.
Zhu, H., and Wang, X. 2007. “An Analysis on the Influencing Factors of Tomato Growers’
Participation in Contract Farming in Xinjiang Autonomous Region” [in Chinese]. Chinese
Rural Economy 7: 67–75.
37
ALL IFPRI DISCUSSION PAPERS
IFPRI HEADQUARTERS
1201 Eye Street, NW
Washington, DC 20005 USA
Tel.: +1-202-862-5600
Fax: +1-202-862-5606
Email: [email protected]