Theory of Second Best - Microeconomics by Perloff
Theory of Second Best - Microeconomics by Perloff
12
Letting the poor decide how to spend their income is efficient by our definition, even if they spend
it on “sin goods” such as cigarettes, liquor, or illicit drugs. A similar argument was made regarding
food stamps in Chapter 5.
10.5 Efficiency and Equity 379
may either increase or decrease welfare. For example, if a small country has a ban
on trade and a subsidy on one good, permitting free trade may not raise efficiency.
Suppose that a wheat-producing country is a price taker on the world wheat
market, where the world price is pw. As we saw in Chapter 9, the country’s total
welfare is greater if it permits rather than bans free trade. Panel a of Figure 10.9
shows the gain to trade in the usual case. The domestic supply curve, S, is upward
sloping, but the home country can import as much as it wants at the world price,
pw. In the free-trade equilibrium, e1, the equilibrium quantity is Q1 and the equi-
librium price is the world price, pw. With a ban on imports, the equilibrium is e2,
quantity falls to Q2, and price rises to p2. Consequently, the deadweight loss from
the ban is area D.
Now suppose that the home government subsidizes its agricultural sector with
a payment of s per unit of output. The subsidy creates a distortion: excess produc-
tion (Chapter 9). The per-unit subsidy s causes the supply curve to shift down from
S to S* in panel b of Figure 10.9. If there is a ban on trade, the equilibrium is at e3,
with a larger quantity, Q3, than in the original free-trade equilibrium and a lower
consumer price, p3. Because the true marginal cost (the height of the S curve at Q3)
is above the consumer price, there is deadweight loss.
If free trade is permitted, the Theory of the Second Best tells us that welfare
does not necessarily rise, because the country still has the subsidy distortion. The
free-trade equilibrium is e4. Firms sell all their quantity, Q4, at the world price,
with Q1 going to domestic consumers and Q4 - Q1 to consumers elsewhere.
S
Domestic
supply, S
s S*
e2
P2 C
e1 e1
D Pw World
Pw World
A B e
price P3 e3 4 price
Demand Demand
Q2 Q1 Q1 Q3 Q4
Q, Bushels per year Q, Bushels per year
380 CHAPTER 10 General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare
The private gain to trade—ignoring the government’s cost of providing the sub-
sidy—is area A + B (see the discussion of Figure 9.9). However, the expansion
of domestic output increases the government’s cost of the subsidy by area B + C
(the height of this area is the distance between the two supply curves, which is the
subsidy, s, and the length is the extra output sold). Thus, if area C is greater than
area A, there is a net welfare loss from permitting trade. As the diagram is drawn,
C is greater than A, so allowing trade lowers welfare, given that the subsidy is
provided.
Does it follow from this argument that the country should prohibit free trade?
No: To maximize efficiency, the country should allow free trade and eliminate the
subsidy. However, unless winners compensate losers, not everyone will benefit.
C HAL LE NG E We can use a multimarket model to analyze the Challenge questions about the
S O LUT I O N effects of a binding price ceiling that applies to some states but not to others. The
figure shows what happens if a binding price ceiling is imposed in the covered
Anti-Price sector—those states that have anti-price gouging laws—and not in the uncovered
Gouging Laws sector—the other states.
S S
p
Q
p p
{
p*
Dc Du D
d
Q Qc Qc Qud Qus Qu Q, Units per year
{
Shortage
We first consider what happens if the anti-price gouging laws are not in effect.
The demand curve for the entire market, D in panel c, is the horizontal sum of
the demand curve in the covered sector, Dc in panel a, and the demand curve in
the uncovered sector, Du in panel b. The national supply curve S intersects the
national demand curve at p in panel c.
Now suppose that the anti-price gouging law states impose a price ceiling at
p that is less than p. Suppliers might consider selling only in the uncovered sec-
tion. As panel b shows, the national supply curve, S, hits the uncovered sector’s
demand curve, Du, at a price p*. If p were less than p*, then the entire supply will
be sold only in the uncovered sector.