Charting The Rise of The West Manuscripts and Printed Books in Europe A Long Term Perspective From The Sixth Through Eighteenth Centuries 17 37
Charting The Rise of The West Manuscripts and Printed Books in Europe A Long Term Perspective From The Sixth Through Eighteenth Centuries 17 37
FIGURE 2
BOOK PRODUCTION PER CAPITA IN WESTERN EUROPE, 501–600 TO 1701–1800
33
See Blum and Dudley, “Standardized Latin,” who argued that these innovations—and in
their view in particular the standardization of Latin in 800—launched not only the book but a
new, uniform, and more efficient form of writing, helping to promote European economy in the
centuries after ca. 950.
34
Rouse and Rouse, Manuscripts and Their Makers. With the pecia system, university
stationers in high medieval Paris and Bologna hired out for a short period a loose quire
containing texts of books to those who wanted to copy a manuscript; this system greatly sped up
the process of copying, as more people could now be working on the same manuscript at one
time.
We may therefore hypothesize that during the early Middle Ages book
production was to a large extent driven by the number and size of
monasteries, which was in turn determined by the share of the
agricultural surplus that regions and countries directed to this part of the
economy.
To test this hypothesis, we derived estimates of the numbers of
monasteries in the different regions and centuries from several sources
(Table 5), which can be plotted against book production in the same
35
Gorman, “Manuscript Books at Monte Amiata,” p. 229.
Central Europea 0 0 0 0 16
Bohemia 0 0 0 0 17
British Islesb 236 460 463 437 437
France 586 988 1,240 1,636 2,091
Belgium 0 53 68 70 88
Netherlands 0 2 4 7 13
Germany 0 138 622 824 1,129
Switzerland 10 19 37 71 104
Austria 12 11 70 99 113
Italy 291 306 495 704 995
Iberiac 58 117 170 537 1,340
Western Europe 1,193 2,094 3,168 4,385 6,343
New foundations (1,193) 1,021 1,284 1,533 2,397
Increase in percent 86 58 44 48
time and place (see Figure 3).36 The correlation between the two
variables is fairly consistent, stressing the important role monasteries
played in this period.
36
Zero values for either the number of monasteries or book production have not been
included in Figure 3.
FIGURE 3
BOOK PRODUCTION AND THE NUMBER OF MONASTERIES SIXTH TO FIFTEENTH
CENTURIES
(log-scale)
to claim a greater share of the agricultural surplus. The tenth and eleventh
centuries witnessed the rise of the local lords who were increasingly able
to control the countryside around their castle and who used their power to
impose new taxes and duties or to reimpose old ones.38 Monasteries often
acted as local lords. The combination of these changes caused a dramatic
growth in the monastic movement from 900 to 1300, which greatly
increased the production of books. After about 1300 this rapid growth
came to a halt, and thereafter the number of monasteries in the Latin West
stabilized at some 21,000 until 1500.39
During the height of the Middle Ages other sources of demand—the
cities, universities, and more generally, the growth of literacy among the
lay population—were becoming increasingly important.40 To test the ideas
that book production before the eleventh to twelfth centuries was driven
by the monastic movement and that afterwards urban factors took over,
we have tried to perform a regression for book production on the
following explanatory variables: the number of monasteries (as shown in
Table 5), estimated urbanization ratios from Paul Bairoch, Jean Batou, and
Pierre Chèvre (Table 6) and the number of universities (Table 7).41 One of
the problems with these regressions is that some observations are zero,
making it difficult to use logs. On the other hand, the growth of book
production is so spectacular that it would normally be preferable to
specify the model in log terms so that observations about the later period
do not dominate the regressions. Two different sets of regressions were
carried out: panel data regressions using only the nonzero observations,
and a procedure that makes it possible to integrate the zeros, Tobit
regressions.42 Moreover, two different versions of the hypothesis were
38
Fossier, “Rural Economy,” pp. 50–53; see also the discussion on the feudal revolution in
this period: Bisson, “Feudal Revolution”; and Wickham, “Debate.”
39
Only the Netherlands was an exception to this trend, as its numbers continue to grow; the
rapid expansion of relatively small and mainly urban monasteries during the fifteenth century is
probably related to the Devotio Moderna of that period, which was concentrated in the northern
Netherlands.
40
Rouse and Rouse, Manuscripts and Their Makers.
41
Bairoch, Batou, and Chèvre, La population, estimates show many gaps, which were
intrapolated by us; when no estimates were available at all, we assumed that the city was below
the 10,000 inhabitant threshold; all estimates for the period before 1000 are extremely tentative.
We are aware that these estimates are not as definitive as they might be, especially for Spain.
We estimated two sets of urbanization: for the Christian part of Spain and for the country as a
whole. Our data set does not really cover manuscript production in the Muslim part of the
country, which was more urbanized and developed; for that reason, we also included a dummy
variable for Spain in the regressions, which also helps to neutralize possible biases in the
estimates of urbanization ratio.
42
The Tobit regressions also use logs (for monasteries and book production per capita), and
the logs of the zero-values are artificially set at zero, which may create a small bias (but the
number of zero observations is small). Because Tobit regressions with fixed effects are
tested: the first model estimated all coefficients for the period 500–1500
as a whole, the second tested for changes in the coefficients of
monasteries and the urbanization ratio before and after 1000 (Table 8).43
problematic, we present the results of the random effects only; cf. Wooldridge, Econometric
Analysis, chaps. 15 and 16; the OLS-estimates were without fixed effects; including century
effects would in both cases reduce the coefficient of universities, because this variable also
captures the time trend; including country fixed effects only marginally changes the estimated
coefficients.
43
Because there were no universities before 1000, the coefficient of that variable could not be
tested for the first period.
Central Europe 0 0 0 3 3 5
Bohemia 0 0 0 1 1 1
British Isles 0 1 2 2 3 5
France 0 1 4 10 13 15
Belgium 0 0 0 0 1 1
Netherlands 0 0 0 0 0 0
Germany 0 0 0 3 6 11
Switzerland 0 0 0 0 0 1
Austria 0 0 0 1 1 1
Italy 1a 4 10 17 17 17
Iberia 0 0 4 7 7 9
Latin West 1 6 20 44 52 66
Central Europe 6 6 8 9 10 11
Bohemia 1 2 2 2 2 2
British Isles 5 7 7 7 7 7
France 15 15 16 16 16 16
Belgium 1 1 1 1 1 1
Netherlands 0 3 5 5 5 5
Germany 14 17 20 22 24 24
Switzerland 1 1 1 1 1 1
Austria 1 2 3 4 4 4
Italy 17 17 17 17 17 17
Iberia 9 9 9 9 9 9
Latin West 70 80 89 93 96 97
a
The University in Italy prior to the twelfth century is Salerno (medicine), presumed date of
foundation in ninth century.
Source: Encyclopedia Britannica, vol. 23, p. 858.
Table 8 shows the results of these regressions, which explain the log
of per capita book production in country x in period y by the log of the
number of monasteries (per capita), the number of universities (again
per capita), the urbanization ratio, and a dummy for Spain. If we take
the Middle Ages as a whole, the three factors we have data for—
universities, monasteries, and urbanization—together explain almost 60
percent of the variation in per capita book production (first two
columns). All coefficients show the expected signs, independent of the
specification. Dividing the period in two shows the changes in the
determinants for book production: the link to monasteries is very
strong in the first half of the period but less so during the Late
44
Allen, “Progress and Poverty,” p. 415.
45
Baten and Van Zanden, “Book Production.”
46
Van Zanden, “Common Workmen”; and Clark, “Lifestyles.”
47
The elasticity of demand for books is from Ringstad, “Demand for Books,” which has a
discussion of the different estimates for the price elasticity of demand; the value of –1.4 was
suggested by a number of studies cited.
48
It is of course possible that the relationship between literacy and book consumption differs
between countries, because there is a higher propensity to buy books per literate individual in
for example the Protestant countries than in the Catholic countries; the fact that in 1800 the
estimates presented here for the Catholic countries are generally somewhat lower than those of
Allen (Italy being the exception here), suggests that this may have played a role and that the
actual level of literacy in those countries may have been somewhat higher than presented in
Table 9.
the exceptions being the Low Countries and England where the decline
was limited and per capita real incomes probably increased. Ignoring
this effect means that we perhaps overestimate the growth of literacy in
the North Sea area, or alternatively underestimate its increase in the rest
of Europe.
The long-term trends also identified by Allen—a rise of literacy
from about 10 percent in 1500 to one-third three centuries later—
is also evident from these estimates, but there are a differences between
the two sets of estimates. The comparison suggests that Allen may
have overestimated literacy in Spain and Poland at about 1500, and
probably underestimated it in the Low Countries and Italy in the same
period.49 Other long-term trends known from the literature, such as the
significant rise of literacy in Great Britain during the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries, followed by stagnation during the eighteenth
century, are also clearly found in the estimates in Table 9.50 Perhaps
most worrying is the estimated decline of literacy in Belgium in the
eighteenth century, which may be due to the underestimation of
consumption per capita; because of the growing importance of the
international trade in books, the consumption estimates for the small
countries are weaker than the estimates of production there. The overall
pattern shows a strong increase in the North Sea area (including
Sweden), stagnation on the southern periphery (Spain), and slow
49
In fact, the estimates published here are probably still too low for the Low Countries; see
Van Zanden, “Common Workmen.”
50
Stephens, “Literacy in England.”
51
Applying the same procedure to the period before 1450, using the estimates of book prices
that can be derived from Bozzolo and Ornato, Pour une histoire du livre, and assuming that
before 1200 real book prices remained constant, yields the following estimates of the level of
literacy in Europe (per century): eleventh: 1.3 percent, twelfth: 3.4 percent, thirteenth: 5.7
percent, fourteenth: 6.8 percent, and first half of the fifteenth: 8.6 percent.
52
Allen, “Great Divergence,” to distinguish these changes within Europe from the “Great
Divergence” that occurred after 1800, Epstein suggested to use the term “Little Divergence” for
the former.
53
Cf. Derville, “L’alphabétisation du people.”
For Japan, the best estimates are that book production in “the three
cities of Edo, Osaka, and Kyoto” was about 400 new titles between
1727–1731 and almost 600 between 1750–1754.64 Again, these
estimates are low by European standards. France, which had a slightly
smaller population, produced more than 1,500 books annually between
1727 and 1731 and 2,350 per year between 1750 and 1754. These cities
produced the bulk of the Japanese books in the seventeenth and
eighteenth centuries.65 The Japanese level of book production was
considerably below that of France and of most other European
countries, but it exceeded the level in China or anywhere else in the
world.
CONCLUSION
66
Cf. Van Bavel and Van Zanden, “Jump-Start.”
67
Cf. Herlihy, “Church Property.”
than anywhere else in the world, including the two other main centers of
printing, China and Japan. One possible implication is that levels of
human capital formation were higher in Western Europe than in East
Asia (or in the rest of the world economy), which may conceivably help
to explain the “Great Divergence.”68
One final question is: Why did book consumption increase so
spectacularly despite the fact that at its height the standard of living of
the majority of the population did not increase at all?69 During most
of this period, books were luxury products consumed by the elite—
the religious elite at first, but after 1100 increasingly the urban and
academic elites. They were, apparently, able to mobilize a growing
portion of total income to spend on such items of luxury consumption.
Urbanization probably led to a significant increase in income inequality,
favoring the class of merchants and professionals who became the main
consumers of the product.70 Increased income inequality may therefore
be part of the explanation. Moreover, books are another example of a
luxury of which the prices declined much more than the consumer price
index, favoring the development of the real purchasing power of the
rich.71 At the same time, in the early modern period books came within
the reach of the lower middle classes. This development began with the
rise of “mass” literacy in the late fourteenth and fifteenth centuries,
when new religious movements (such as the Devotio Moderna) began to
encourage all believers to read the Bible. European citizens in 1800 may
not have been better fed than in 600, but their access to books and their
capabilities for reading them had changed fundamentally.
69
Baten and Van Zanden, “Book Production,” where we explain divergent patterns of
economic growth within Europe (between 1500 and 1800) and in the world economy (during
the nineteenth century) from levels of book consumption.
70
Koepke and Baten, “Biological Standard of Living.”
71
Van Zanden, “Tracing the Beginning.”
72
Hoffman et al., “Real Inequality.”
REFERENCES
Allen, Robert C. “The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices.” Explorations
in Economic History 38, no. 4 (2001): 411–47.
______. “Progress and Poverty in Early Modern Europe.” Economic History Review
56, no. 3 (2003): 403–43.
Bairoch, Paul, Jean Batou, and Pierre Chèvre. La population des villes Européennes
de 800 á 1850. Genève: Librairie Droz, 1988.
DeLong, J. Bradford, and Andrei Shleifer. “Princes and Merchants: City Growth
Before the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of Law and Economics 36, no. 2
(October 1993): 671–702.
Derville, Alain. “L’alphabétisation du peuple á la fin du Moyen Age.” Revue du Nord
26 (1984): 759–72.
De Vries, Jan. European Urbanization, 1500–1800. London: Methuen, 1984.
Ebersperger, Birgit. “Bernhard Bischoff’s Catalogue of Ninth-Century Continental
Manuscripts.” Gazette du Livre Médiéval 34 (1999): 44–48.
Encyclopaedia Britannica, 25 vols. Edinburgh: Black, 9th edition, reprint 1898.
Eng lish Sho rt Title Ca ta logu e, ac c es s ib l e v i a B r i t ish L ib r ar y a t
http://estc.bl.uk/F/?func=file&file_name=login-bl-list.
Epstein, S. R. “Cities, Regions, and the Late Medieval Crisis: Sicily and Tuscany
Compared.” Past & Present 130 (1991): 3–50.
Febvre, Lucien, and Henri Jean Martin. The Coming of the Book. London: Verso,
1976.
Fossier, R. “Rural Economy and Country Life.” In The New Cambridge Medieval
History, III, c.900–c.1024, edited by T. Reuter, 27–63. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2000.
Gilmont, Jean Francois, ed. The Reformation and the Book. Aldershot: Ashgate, 1998.
Glick, Thomas F. Islamic and Christian Spain in the Early Middle Ages. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press, 1979.
Gneuss, Helmut. Handlist of Anglo-Saxon manuscripts, a list of manuscripts and
manuscript fragments written or owned in England up to 1100. Tempe: Arizona
Centre for Medieval and Renaissance Studies, 2001.
Gorman, Michael. “Manuscript Books at Monte Amiata in the Eleventh Century.”
Scriptorium 56, no. 2 (2002): 225–93.
Hand Press Book File, Consortium of European Research Libraries, available at
http://www.cerl.org/web/en/resources/hpb/main.
Harris, Michael H. History of Libraries in the Western World. Metuchen, NJ:
Scareow, 1984.
Hatcher, J., and M. Bailey. Modeling the Middle Ages: The History and Theory of
England’s Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Hayami, A., and H. Kitô. “Demography and Living Standards.” In The Economic
History of Japan: 1600–1990. Volume I: Emergence of Economic Society in
Japan 1600–1859, edited by A. Hayami, O. Saito, and R. P. Toby, 213–47.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999.
Herlihy, David. “Church Property on the European Continent, 701–1200.” Speculum
36, no. 1 (1961): 81–105.
Hoffman, Philip T., David S. Jacks, Patricia A. Levin, and Peter H. Lindert. “Real
Inequality in Europe Since 1500.” This JOURNAL 62, no. 2 (2002): 322–55.
Huff, Toby E. The Rise of Early Modern Science: Islam, China, and the West.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993.
Incunabula Short Title Catalogue, accessible via the British Library at
http://www.bl.uk/catalogues/istc/.
Ker, Neil R. Medieval Libraries of Great Britain: A List of Surviving Books. 2nd
edition. London: Offices of the Royal Historical Society, 1964.
Koepke, Nikola, and Joerg Baten. “The Biological Standard of Living During the Last
Two Millennia.” Review of European Economic History 9, no. 1 (2005): 61–97.
Kornicki, Peter. The Book in Japan: A Cultural History from the Beginnings to the
Nineteenth Century. Honolulu: University of Hawai’i Press, 2001.
Tsien, Tsuen-Hsiun. “Paper and Printing.” In Science and Civilization in China, vol.
5/1, edited by Joseph Needham. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
Van Zanden, Jan Luiten. “Tracing the Beginning of the Kuznets Curve: Western
Europe During the Early Modern Period.” Economic History Review 48, no. 3
(1995): 643–64.
______. “Early Modern Economic Growth: A Survey of the European Economy,
1500–1800.” In Early Modern Capitalism, edited by M. Prak, 69–87. London:
Routledge, 2001.
______. “Common Workmen, Philosophers, and the Birth of the European Knowledge
Economy: About the Price and the Production of Useful Knowledge in Europe
1350–1800.” Paper for the GEHN conference on Useful Knowledge, Leiden,
September 2004; revised 12 October 2004.
______. “Una estimación del crecimiento económico en la Edad Moderna.”
Investigaciones de Historia Económica 2, no. 1 (2005): 9–38.
______. “Economic Growth in a Period of Political Fragmentation, 950–1300.”
Seminar paper, Utrecht University, 2006.
Vaquero, Quintín Aldea, Tomas Marín Martinez, and José Vives Gatell, eds.
Diccionario de historia eclesiastica de España. 4 vols. and suppl. 1. Madrid:
CSIC Instituto Enrique Florez, 1972–1975.
Verhulst, A. “The Origins of Towns in the Low Countries and the Pirenne Thesis.”
Past & Present 122 (1989): 3–36.
______. The Carolingian Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.
Wickham, Chris. “Debate: The ‘Feudal Revolution.’” Past & Present 155 (1997):
196–208.
Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001.