KBT 203 Agricultural Production Economics Lecture Notes
KBT 203 Agricultural Production Economics Lecture Notes
COURSE GOALS/OBJECTIVES
1. Develop a better understanding of applied microeconomic theory of the firm
2. Improve understanding and use of simple algebra and graphical analytical skills to applied economic
theory in agricultural production
3. To understand the various agricultural production interrelationships
4. Enhance the importance of agricultural production in the economy
RECOMMENDED REFERENCES
1) Heady, Earl O, 1964, Economics of Agricultural Production and Resource Use:, Prentice Hall of India,
Private Limited, New Delhi
2) Debertin, D.L. 2002. Agricultural Production Economics Second Edition.
3) Samuelson, Paul A. Foundations of Economic Analysis. New York: Atheneum, 1970 (Originally
published in 1947).
4) Smith, Adam. 1937. The Wealth of Nations, Edwin Cannan ed. New York: The Modern Library, 1937
(Originally written in 1776).
5) Jhingan, M.L (2006). Microeconomic Theory. Vrinda Publications Ltd. Delhi.
6) Colman, D and Trevor, Y. 1989. Principles of Agricultural Economics: Markets and Prices in Less
developed Countries. Cambridge University Press.
EXAMINATIONS
All students will be required to attend scheduled lectures and sit all CATs as well as Final Examination
The University examination regulations will apply.
All Students will be expected to take written examinations in this unit.
The Final examination will constitute 70% of the total marks while the course work assessment tests
(CATS) will constitute 30%.
2
LECTURE 1: NATURE AND CHARACTERISTICS OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION
AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION
Agriculture is a basic industry supplying the primary needs of man, hence is of special significant and no
nation can afford to neglect it, if required agriculture needs even to be protected.
Agricultural production is characterized by a high degree of uncertainty, being a biological activity it is
subject to the vagaries of nature. A large number of physical factors like soil, temperature, precipitation,
evaporation, latitude, altitude and accessibility serve as limiting factors in man‟s effort to improve agriculture.
In addition to these are the risks of innumerable crop pests and diseases. However, technological progress has
placed more and more power in the hands of man to overcome some of these limitations.
The limited area of land poses a restriction on efforts to expand agricultural production, unlike
manufacturing industries. In the majority of manufacturing and industrial undertakings fresh injection of capital
leads to increased returns. In agriculture however, the application of the law of diminishing returns is more
pronounced than in any industry.
Other industries can adjust their production at short notice in response to the changing pattern of demand.
This is not possible in agriculture once a crop is planted; the plant is in no position to alter the course of
production. A favourable prevailing price may attract the farmer to devote more resources to particular
enterprises but when prices deteriorate, the farmer cannot alter the course of production until the following
season. Due to agriculture‟s inability to make quick adjustments n supplies as a response to changes in market
demand, agriculture faces greater price risks.
Agriculture is a seasonal activity with production being realized at specific periods during the year. The
turnover is therefore low. This also creates problems of transport, marketing and credit, etc during peak periods.
3
In addition, farm products are bulky and perishable. This creates a need for storage, processing and
refrigeration. To overcome the perishability of some of these products, processing is necessary. The bulkiness
of some agricultural products, like fruit and vegetables, which contain high moisture content, causes these
products to have a low value per unit weight.
Due to the seasonal nature of production, production resources are at certain times stretched to the limit
while at other times the resources are unemployed.
Farmers produce largely identical products which compete against one another in the market.
The demand for agricultural produce like cereals and milk is more common or less inelastic.
There are however, other produces like fruits, vegetables, sugar, and, meat which may have a high elasticity
of demand in ill fed and underdeveloped areas. But as compared with industrial products, the demand for most
products is less elastic.
Agricultural products are generally joint products. Straw and wheat, sawdust with timber, beef and hides.
Efforts are being made to put these by-products to economic use. Organizing producers, even on regional basis
is difficult because production is in small and scattered units measured in terms of capital and income.
Economies of large scale production and division of labour are not practicable in agriculture to the same extent
as in industries.
Definition: Agricultural Production Economics is an applied field of science wherein the principles of choice
are applied to the use of capital, labour, land and management resources in the farming industry.
4
Objectives of Agricultural Production Economics
The main objectives of Agricultural production economics are:
1) To determine and define the conditions which provide for optimum use of resources.
2) To determine the extent to which the existing use of resources deviates from the optimum use.
3) To analyze the factors or forces which are responsible for the existing production pattern and resource
use and
4) To explain means and methods for changing existing use of resources to the optimum level.
Some major concerns in agricultural production economics include the following.
b) The firm can sell as much as it wants at the going market price, and no single firm is large enough to
influence the price for the commodity being produced
For many agricultural commodities, the farmer can sell as much as he or she wants at the market price.
Farmers are price takers, not price setters, in the production of commodities such as wheat, maize, beef, and
pork. However, for certain commodities, the sparcity of farms means that the producers might exert a degree of
control over the price obtained.
d) There is free entry and exit, and thus free mobility of resources (inputs or factors of production) exists
both in and out of farming
6
The free-mobility assumption is currently seldom met in agriculture. At one time it may have been possible
for a farmer to begin with very little money and a lot of ambition. Nowadays, a normal farm may very well be a
business with a million shillings investment. It is difficult to see how free entry and exit can exist in an industry
that may require an individual firm to have a million shillings in startup capital. Inflation over the past decade
has drastically increased the startup capital requirements for farming, with resultant impacts on the mobility of
resources.
Free mobility of resources in linked to an absence of artificial restraints, such as government involvement.
There exist a number of artificial restraints in farming. The government has been and continues to be involved
in influencing production decisions with respect to nearly every major agricultural commodity and numerous
minor commodities as well. Agricultural cooperatives have had a significant impact on production levels for
commodities such as milk and coffee.
Grain production in the Kenya is often heavily influenced by the presence of government programs. The
maize and wheat programs are major examples. Though liberalized the prices for the maize subsector are
occasionally regulated by the government. In milk production, the government has largely determined the prices
to be received by dairy farmers before liberalization.
e) All variables of concern to the producer and the consumer are known with certainty
Some economists distinguish between pure competition and perfect competition. These economists argue
that pure competition can exist even if all variables are not known with certainty to the producer and consumer.
However, perfect competition will exist only if the producer knows not only the prices for which outputs will be
sold, but also the prices for inputs. Moreover, with perfect competition, the consumer has complete knowledge
with respect to prices.
Most important, with perfect competition the producer is assumed to have complete knowledge of the
production process or function that transforms inputs or resources into outputs or commodities. Nature is
assumed not to vary from year to year. Of course, this assumption is violated in agriculture. The vagaries of
nature enter into nearly everything a farmer does, and influence not only output levels, but the quantity of inputs
used as well.
7
mechanism which operates with the help of the forces of demand and supply. These forces help to determine the
equilibrium price at the household and at the individual firm levels.
Macroeconomics on the other hand, basically concerned with issues such as at the national income, output and
employment which are determined by aggregate demand and supply in the economy.
8
LECTURE 2: PRODUCTION THEORY
INTRODUCTION
Production is important because of the fact that all economic activities depend on it. For consumption to
take place, goods and services must be produced. Without production goods and services will not be produced
Production is the process involved in transforming a number of inputs into a product. In terms of
satisfaction derived, production can be termed creation of utility.
Inputs are also called resources or factors of production. However, the use of these terms is not permanent
because what is a product to one person may be an input to another person. For example, a farmer may produce
maize using land, labour, capital (hoes and cutlasses) and his managerial skills as factors of production. On the
other hand, a poultry farmer sees the maize as one of the inputs in producing eggs or chicken as outputs.
A positive relationship exists among these inputs and the output such that the greater availability of any
of these factors will lead to a greater potential for producing output. In addition, all factors are assumed to be
essential for production to take place. The functional relationship f (.) represents a certain level of technology
and know-how that presently exists, for conversion these input such that any technological improvements can
also lead to the production of greater levels of output. Egg production process requires at least two inputs, feeds
and pullets in addition to other fixed input like water, housing etc .in every case, production can only take place
with at least two inputs.
FACTORS OF PRODUCTION
A factor of production can be defined as that good and service which is required for production. A factor
is indispensable for production because without it no production will be possible. The factors can be grouped
broadly into four categories though the line of demarcation between some of them is not very clear.
Natural resources - This includes land, water, climate and soil conditions. These are necessary for agricultural
production and without them agriculture is impossible. Land is obviously the most important natural resources
for agricultural purposes and is often defined economically to include all materials and forces that supplied by
nature for use in the production of goods and services. In other words, land include all the other natural
resources e.g. water, forest, soil, climate, etc.
Labour - Labour can defined as all human efforts made in the process of transforming inputs to output. Labour
is always used in combination with other factors to produce outputs. The labour may be skilled or unskilled,
family, hired or exchange. Labour is measured agriculturally per day, i.e., Man-day. For accounting purposes,
children labour is rated 0.5 unit of adult while woman and old men (over 60 years) are rated 0.75 units of adult.
But this practice may not be totally acceptable in today‟s situation.
Capital - Capital can be called means of production or intermediate Production. It represents resources
produced by past human efforts. Capitals include long-term investment seen as buildings, machinery as well as
equipment, implements such as tractors and their implements.
Seeds, fertilizers, as well as cash (at hand) are all capital. Capital may also include tree crops, breeding stock (of
animals), dairy cattle, and bullocks (used in land preparation) as well as bullock plough. Some capital items
normally loose value with years, the annual loss in momentary term is called depreciation or capital term called
appreciation or capital gain or accumulation.
Management or Entrepreneurship - This is a qualitative input as against others, which are quantitative. It is
the effective harnessing of the other factors of production for maximum profit. Thus it involves planning,
decision making, supervision, evaluation and general co-ordination of all activities on the farm.
In order for this function to be useful to decision makers, information, the types of inputs used must be known,
and the particular quantities of it used to produce particular quantities of products. The producer needs to know
the quantitative relation between inputs and outputs.
The production function is the basis for production function analysis, in seeking to answer the following
questions:
What is efficient production?
How is the most profitable amount of input determined?
How will farm production respond to a change in price of output?
What enterprise combinations will maximize profits?
Tabular form: Production function can be expressed in the form of a table, where one column represents input,
while another indicates the corresponding total output of the product. The two columns constitute production
function.
Graphical Form: The production function can also be illustrated in the form of a graph; where horizontal axis
(X axis) represents input and the vertical axis (Y axis) represents the output.
Algebraic Form: Algebraically production function can be expressed as Y= f(X). Where, Y represents
dependent variable, output (yield of crop, livestock enterprise) and X represents independent variable, input
(seeds, fertilizers, manure etc), f = denotes function of.
When more number of inputs is involved in the production of a product, the equation is represented as
Y=f(X1, X2, X3, X4 ……… Xn)
11
In case of single variable production function, only one variable is allowed to vary, keeping others constant, can
be expressed as
Y=f(X1 | X2, X3 ………. Xn)
The vertical bar is used for separating the variable input from the fixed input. The equation denotes that the
output Y depends upon the variable input X1, with all other inputs held constant.
If more than one variable input is varied and few others are held constant, the relationship can be expressed as
Y=f(X1, X2 | X3, X4 …….. Xn)
Assumptions under the Short Run and the Long Run Functions
Production in the Short run
There are some assumptions about the production function. In order to better understand the technological
nature of production, we distinguish between short run production relationships where only one factor input
may vary (typically labour) in quantity holding the other factors of production constant (i.e., capital and/or
materials) and the long run where all factors of production may vary. The short run allow for the development
of a simple two variable model to understand the behavior between a single variable input and the
corresponding level of output. Thus we can write:
Y = f (L | K, M, R) or Y =f (L)
For example we could develop a short run model for agricultural production where the output is measures as
kilograms of grain and labour is the variable input. The fixed factor production includes the following: 1
plough, 1 tractor, (capital), 1 truck, 1 acre of land, 10 kilograms of seed grain. We might hypothesize the
production relationship to be as follows:
In this example we find that each time we add more units of labour, output increases by 100kg. The third
column MPL defines this relationship. This column measures the marginal productivity of labour, that is, a
measure of the contribution of each additional unit of labour input to the level of output. In this case, we have a
situation of constant marginal productivity which is unrealistic with production in the short run.
Constant marginal productivity implies that as labour input increases, output always increases without bound.
This situation is difficult to imagine with limited capital and one acre of land.
12
A more realistic situation would be that of diminishing marginal productivity where increasing quantities of a
single input lead to less and less additional output. This property is just an acknowledgement that it is
impossible to produce an infinite level of output when some factors of production (machines or land) fixed in
quantity. Numerically, we can model diminishing marginal productivity as follows:
In this case, additional labour input results in additional output. However, the contribution of each additional
unit of labour is less than previous units such that the sixth unit of labour contributes nothing to output. With 5
or 6 workers, the available amount of land cannot support additional output.
A short run production relationship can be modeled as shown. In this example, labour is the variable factor
input and land, capital, and entrepreneurship are fixed in quantity. There is a positive relationship between
labour input and output levels. However, as additional labour is used, less and less additional output is
produced. The shape of this production function is consistent with the law of diminishing marginal productivity.
Production in the Long run
Production in the long run is distinguished from short run production in that all factor inputs may be used in
varying amounts. Though the long run is more of planning concept, it is important for economic analysis. Given
the production function:
X = f (L, K, M, R)
We find that one factor may be substituted to some degree, for another factor of production. For instance;
Increasing the amount of capital or machinery „K‟, can replace some labour „L‟, but not all of the labour
in a production process.
Increasing amounts of labour (greater care being taken in production to avoid waste) can reduce the need
for some material inputs „M‟.
In addition, where all factors or production are allowed to vary in quantity, proportional increases in all factors
of production may lead to unbounded increases in output.
As we begin to model production in the long run, we will simplify the production function somewhat as:
X = f (L, K),
Where, we assume that the extraction of raw materials or the development of land is accomplished with
combinations of labour and capital input. Entrepreneurship is embedded in the production technology used. This
allows for a two-dimensional representation of combinations of factor inputs required to produce chosen levels
of output.
It is possible to produce 100 units of output (Y = 100) with the following combinations of labour and capital.
L K
50 200 Capital Intensive Production
100 100 Equal Amounts
200 50 Labour Intensive Production
13
LECTURE 3: PRINCIPLES AND CONCEPTS IN PRODUCTION ANALYSIS
14
PHYSICAL PRODUCT
Total Physical Product (TPP) - This is the amount of product which results from different quantities of
variable input. Total product indicates the technical efficiency of fixed resources.
Average Physical Product (APP) - It is the ratio of total product to the quantity of input used in producing that
quantity of product.
APP= Y/X where Y is total product and X is total input.
Average product indicates the technical efficiency of variable input.
Marginal Physical Product (MPP) - The marginal physical product (MPP) refers to the change in output
associated with an incremental change in the use of an input. The incremental increase in input use is usually
taken to be 1 unit. Thus MPP is the change in output associated with a 1 unit increase in the input.
MPP = ΔY/ΔX
The MPP of input xi might be referred to as MPPxi. Notice that MPP, representing the incremental change in
TPP, can be either positive or negative.
15
VALUE PRODUCT
Total Value Product (TVP) - Expression of TPP in terms of monetary value, it is called Total Value Product.
TVP = TPP*Py or Y*Py
Average Value Product (AVP) - The expression of average physical product (APP) in monetary value.
AVP = APP*Py
Marginal Value Product (MVP) - When MPP is expressed in terms of monetary value, it is called Marginal
Value Product.
MVP = MPP*Py or (ΔY/Δ X)* PyΔ Y. Py /Δ X
FACTOR COST
Total Factor Cost (TFC) - This is the total money cost of the factors used in a production process. It is
obtained as;
TFC = ΣX1 .Px
Average Factor Cost (AFC) - This is the average cost of the factors or cost per unit of the factors in a
production process. It is given as
AFC = TFC/ X1
Marginal Factor Cost (MFC) - This is addition to total costs by using an extra unit of the variable input. It is
given as MFC= ΔTFC/ ΔX1 = Δ (Σ{X1 .Px})/ ΔX1
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
The concept of comparative advantage simply is specialization of countries or regions in production of
goods in which it has comparative advantage and imports those in which it has comparative disadvantage. In
agriculture, the concept is very important because weather and soil conditions vary from place to place. If for
instance, it costs country A Kshs.30 to produce a kilogram crop X and KShs. 40 to produce crop Y while it
costs country B Kshs.50 to produce a kilogram crop X and Kshs.30 to produce crop Y country A has advantage
in producing crop X while country B has advantage in producing crop Y.
The principle encourages country A to concentrate in the production of X while country B concentrates on
Y and they in turn imports the other crop for which they are at disadvantage.
16
A farm firm should produce or engage in enterprises in which it has comparative advantage e.g. in producing
cattle, savannah, and region has comparative advantage over the other areas of country because: There is vast
grassland; Cattle move freely over a long distance without obstruction; There is adequate water supply; There is
less tsetse fly infestation, and the climate is favourable.
It is mostly used in cases where the fixed cost is negligible as in peasant farming.
17
LECTURE 4: ANALYSIS OF PRODUCTION FUNCTION
INTRODUCTION
An agricultural production function is presented using graphical and tabular approaches. Algebraic examples of
simple production functions with one input and one output are developed. Key features of the neoclassical
production function are outlined. The relationship between factors of production or inputs and outputs
(production function) can be studied under three main analytical headings; factor-product, factor-factor and
product-product relationships.
FACTOR-PRODUCT RELATIONSHIP
This is a case of producing a product by using one variable factor. For example, a farmer may produce maize
using fertilizer as the variable factor. Although this type of relationship is very easy to analyse, it rarely occurs
in real life situation. That means the use of fertilizer varies with the quantity of maize produced. The
relationship can be represented technically as:
Q = f (X1|X2, X3, …, Xn) or Q = f(X1)
Where Q = quantity of output
X1 = quantity of variable input
X2, X3, …., Xn = fixed inputs.
Graphically, the relationship can be represented as;
18
First Stage or I Region or Zone 1:
The first stages of production starts from the origin i.e., zero input level.
In this zone, Marginal Physical Product is more than Average Physical Product and hence Average
Physical Product increases throughout this zone.
Marginal Physical Product (MPP) is increasing up to the point of inflection and then declines.
Since the marginal Physical Product increases up to the point of inflection, the Total Physical Product
(TPP) increases at increasing rate.
After the point of inflection, the Total Physical Product increases at decreasing rate.
Elasticity of production is greater than unity up to maximum Average Physical Product (APP).
Elasticity of production is one at the end of the zone (MPP = APP).
In this zone fixed resources are in abundant quantity relative to variable resources.
The technical efficiency of variable resource is increasing throughout this zone as indicated by Average
Physical Product.
The technical efficiency of fixed resource is also increasing as reflected by the increasing Total Physical
Product.
Marginal Value Product is more than Marginal Factor Cost (MVP >MFC).
Marginal revenue is more than marginal cost (MR > MC).
This is irrational or sub- optimal zone of production.
This zone ends at the point where MPP=APP or where APP is Maximum.
19
Second Stage or II Region or Zone II:
The second zone starts from where the technical efficiency of variable resource is maximum i.e., APP is
Maximum (MPP=APP).
In this zone Marginal Physical Product is less than Average Physical Product. Therefore, the APP
decreases throughout this zone.
Marginal Physical Product is decreasing throughout this zone.
As the MPP declines, the Total Physical Product increases but at decreasing rate.
Elasticity of production is less than one between maximum APP and maximum TPP.
Elasticity of production is zero at the end of this zone.
In this zone variable resource is more relative to fixed factors.
The technical efficiency of variable resource is declining as indicated by declining APP.
The technical efficiency of fixed resource is increasing as reflected by increasing TPP.
Marginal Value Product is equal to Marginal Factor Cost (MVP=MFC).
Marginal Revenue is equal to Marginal Cost (MR= MC).
This is rational zone of production in which the producer should operate to attain his objective of profit
maximization.
This zone ends at the point where Total Physical Product is maximum or Marginal Physical Product is
zero.
20
FACTOR-FACTOR RELATIONSHIP
1. This relationship deals with the resource combination and resource substitution
2. It deals with the production efficiency of resources.
3. The rate at which the factors are transformed in to products is the study of this relationship.
4. Optimization of production and Cost minimization are the goals of this relationship.
5. This relationship is known as input-output relationship by farm management specialists and fertilizer
responsive curve by agronomists.
6. Factor-Product relationship guides the producer in making the decision „how much to produce?
7. This relationship helps the producer in the determination of optimum input to use and optimum output to
produce.
8. Price ratio is the choice indicator.
9. This relationship is explained by the law of diminishing returns.
10. Algebraically, this relationship can be expressed as
Y = f (X1 / X2, X3………………Xn)
In the production, inputs are substitutable. Capital can be substituted for labour and vice versa, grain can be
substituted for fodder and vice versa. The producer has to choose that input or inputs, practice or practices
which produce a given output with minimum cost. The producer aims at cost minimization i.e., choice of inputs
and their combinations.
Isoquants
The relationship between two factors and output cannot be presented with a two dimensional graph. This
involves three variables and can be presented in a three dimensional diagram giving a production surface.
An isoquant is a convenient method for compressing three dimensional picture of production into two
dimensions.
Definition:
An isoquant represents all possible combinations of two resources (X 1 and X2) physically capable of producing
the same quantity of output.
Isoquants are also known as isoproduct curves or equal product curves or product indifference curves.
22
2. Constant rate of Substitution - For each one unit gain in one factor, a constant quantity of another
factor must be sacrificed. When factors substitute at constant rate, isoquants are linear, negatively
sloped.
The above table shows that the six combinations of resources X 1 and X2 can be used in producing a given level
of output. As X1 input is increased from 0 to 5 units, 10 units of X2 are replaced. Similarly addition of another 5
units of X1 replaces another 10 units. The MRS of X1 for X2 is 2. That means if we want to obtain one unit of
X1, we have to forego 2 units of X2.
Example: family labour and hired labour. When inputs substitute at constant rate, it is economical to use only
one resource, and which one to use depends up on relative prices.
23
X1 X2 ΔX1 ΔX2 MRTS X1X2 =ΔX2/Δ X1
1 18 - - -
2 13 1 5 5/1=5
3 9 1 4 4/1=4
4 6 1 3 3/1=3
5 4 1 2 2/1=2
The MRS of X1 for X2 becomes smaller and smaller as X1 replaces X2. Isoquants are convex to the origin when
inputs substitute at decreasing rate.
24
X1 = TVC/ PX1 - PX2 / PX1X2
The two important aspects of the isocost line are its distance from the origin and its slope.
When prices do not change, each possible total variable cost has a different isocost line.
As total variable cost increases, the ration TVC / PX1 increases and the isocost line moves to a higher points on
the cost surface, located further from the origin.
Changes in the input price change the slope of the isocost line.
Characteristics of Isocost line:
1. As the total outlay increases, the isocost line moves farther away from the origin.
2. Isocost line is a straight line because input prices do not change with the quantity purchased.
3. The slope of isocost line indicates the ratio of factor prices.
Minimum cost combination of inputs for an output of 105 (P X1 =KShs. 180. PX2 = KShs. 270)
Units of X2 Units of X1 Cost of X2 Cost of X1 Total Variable Cost
2 9.0 KShs. 540 KShs 1,620 KShs. 2,160
3 6.0 810 1,080 1,890
4 5.0 1,080 900 1,980
5 4.4 1,350 792 2,142
6 4.1 1,620 738 2,358
7 4.0 1,890 720 2,610
8 4.1 2,160 738 2,898
2) Algebraic method:
a. Compute marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS)
MRS = Number of units of replaced resource / Number of units of added resource
MRSX1X2 =ΔX2/ΔX1
MRSX2X1 =ΔX1/ΔX2
b. Compute Price Ratio (PR)
PR=Price per unit of added resource/Price per unit of replaced resource
PR=PX1/PX2 if MRSX1X2
Or
PR= PX2/PX1 if MRSX2X1
c. Workout least cost combination by equating MRS and PR
ΔX2/ΔX1= PX1/PX2 MRSX1X2
ΔX1/ΔX2= PX2/PX1 MRSX2X1
The same can be expressed as
ΔX2. PX2= Δ X1. PX1
Or
ΔX1. PX1= ΔX2. PX2
25
The least cost combination is obtained when Marginal Rate of substitution is equal to Price Ratio.
3) Graphical Method: - Since the slope of isoquant indicates MRTS and the slope of isocost line indicates
factor price ratio, minimum cost for given output will be indicated by the tangency of these isoclines.
For this purpose, isocost line and isoquant are drawn on the same graph for different levels of
production. The least cost combination will be at the point where isocost line is tangent to the isoquant
i.e., slope of isoquant=slope of isocost line i.e., MRS=PR
The isoquant has an infinite number of points – only one will represent the cost minimizing combination. At
this point the following criterion called the least cost criterion will hold:
MRS of X2 for X1 = - PX2 / PX1
Because of definition of MRS, the criterion can be written
ΔX1 / ΔX2 = - PX2 / PX1
Thus the least cost combination of inputs occurs at the point where the isocost line is tangent to the isoquant,
given that the isoquant is convex to the origin.
Isoclines are lines or curves that pass though points of equal marginal rates of substitution on an isoquant map.
That is, particular isocline will pass through all isoquants at points where the isoquants have a specific slope.
There can be a number of possible output levels as shown in the figure and the least cost combination can be
found out for these various output levels.
A line or curve connecting the least cost combination of inputs for all output levels is called isocline
Isocost Map
The isocline passes through all the isoquants at points where they have the same slope.
Isoclines can be drawn at different sets of price ratio. All isoclines of course converge at the point of maximum
output. Though all the points on isocline represent least cost combination, only one point represents the
maximum profit output.
26
The expansion path too is an isocline. The expansion path traces out the least cost combination of inputs for
every possible output level. While all the points on an expansion path represent the least cost combinations,
only one point represents the maximum profit output.
The choice indicator of expansion path is the input price ration. On the expansion path the marginal rate of
substitution must be equal the input price ratio.
If resources are technical substitutes and the marginal rate of substitution is decreasing, any change in the
relative prices of the inputs also changes the expansion path. The changes in input prices shift the expansion
path to a new isocline that assumes the role of expansion path.
The economic implications of expansion path are:
1. If the expansion path is a straight line emanating from the origin, then the inputs will be used in the
same proportions at all output levels.
2. When the expansion path is curved, the proportion of the inputs that must be used to achieve the least
cost combination will vary among yield level.
Ridge lines or Border or Boundary lines
Ridge lines represent the points of maximum output from each input, given a fixed amount of another input.
Also they represent limits of substitution. Ridge lines reflect the limits of economic relevance, the boundaries
beyond which isoquant map ceases to have economic meaning. The portions of isoquants which lie between the
lines are suited for economic production (Where MPP of both inputs are positive but decreasing and isoquants
are negatively sloped). Portions of isoquants outside the ridge lines are not suitable for production in economic
terms (outside the ridge lines, MPP of both factors are negative and methods of production are inefficient).
Ridge lines represent special types of isocline which represent the limit of economic relevance, the boundaries
beyond which the isocline and isoquant maps cease to have economic meaning.
On the ridge line of X1, MPPX1 is zero; the tangent to the isoquant is vertical and has no definite slope. Ridge
lines represent the points of maximum output from each input, given a fixed amount of the other inputs.
The expansion path traces out the least cost combination of inputs for every possible output level. The question
of which output level is the most profitable is answered by proceeding on the expansion path, that is, increasing
output until the value of the product added by increasing the two inputs along the expansion path is equal to the
combined cost of the added amounts of the two inputs.
PRODUCT-PRODUCT RELATIONSHP
Product-Product relationship deals with resource allocation among competing enterprises.
The goal of Product-Product relationship is profit maximization. Under Product-Product relationship, inputs are
kept constant while products (outputs) are varied. This relationship guides the producer in deciding „What to
produce‟. This relationship is explained by the principle of product substitution and law of equimarginal returns.
This relationship is concerned with the determination of optimum combination of products (enterprises).The
choice indicators are substitution ratio and price ratio. Algebraically it is expressed as Y1=f
(Y2 Y3, ……. Yn) Or (Q1, Q2) = f (X1|X2, X3, …..,Xn) or X1 =f(Q1,Q2)
SUMMARY
There are three stages in the production process. The stage of rational production is the stage
II. However, the point of production which maximizes the producer‟s objective is determined through the
imposition of price variable into the model. The producer could thus produce to either maximise revenue, profit
or minimize costs. This is achieved at the point of tangency between the isoquant and the isocost line. For the
revenue maximization, the iso-revenue line must be tangent to the production possibility curve.
29
LECTURE 5: RELATIONSHIPS AMONG INPUTS AND PRODUCTS
31
LECTURE 6: THEORY OF COSTS
COST FUNCTION
The cost functions are derived functions. They are derived from the production function, which describes the
available efficient methods of production at any one time. Economic theory always distinguishes between long
run and short run costs. Thus the cost function is the technical relationship between the quantity of output and
the cost of producing the output, e.g.
Q =f(X1) production function
C =f (X1PX1) cost function
The above means the quantity of output is a function of the cost of the variable inputs provided all other factors
are fixed. The two functions above can be represented graphically thus:
COST THEORY
Cost refers to the value of inputs used in production. The traditional theory distinguishes two types of costs in
terms of the short run and the long run periods. The short run is the period during which some factor(s) is fixed;
usually capital equipment and management are considered as fixed in the short run. The long run is the period
over which all factors become variable. Thus the firm‟s total costs are split into two groups: total fixed costs and
the total variable costs.
Costs are classified into two major categories.
a. Variable costs - These are costs that increase or decrease as output change e.g. labour hired, machine
use, seed, fertilizer, pesticides, and herbicide.
b. Fixed costs - These are incurred for the resources that do not change as output is changed. These costs
cannot be allocated to a particular enterprise on the farm e.g. depreciation on buildings and equipment,
land rent, interest charges, family labour, management, taxes, telephone and stationary charges.
32
Total fixed costs are costs that remain the same for a given farm, no matter how much output varies
within the capacity of the operation.
Fixed and variable costs are further classified into total, average and marginal costs.
Total Fixed Costs (TFC) - It is total costs on all fixed factors. These include interest payments on
borrowed capital, rental expenditures on leased plant and equipment, property taxes, cost of managerial
and administrative staff, etc.
Total Variable costs (TVC) - On the other hand, are total obligations of the firm for all the variable
inputs that the firm uses. These include payments for raw materials, most labor costs, etc.
Total Costs (TC) - Equal total fixed costs (TFC) plus total variable costs (TVC). That is,
TC = TFC + TVC
TYPES OF COST
Average Cost
From the total fixed, total variable and total cost functions, we can derive the corresponding per-unit (average
fixed, average variable, average total, and marginal) cost functions of the firm.
The total fixed cost can be identified by considering the value of the total cost at the level of output
equal zero. Note that variable cost will always be equal to zero if no output is produced.
Therefore, TFC = KShs. 60 at all levels of output.
By deducting the value of TFC from the TC we are able to derive the value of TVC at each level of
output. For example, at X = 3, TVC = TC – TFC (i.e. 105 – 60 = 45).
These schedules are plotted below.
33
Short run cost curves
Cost (KShs)
TC
TVC
60 TFC
0 Output (X)
The TFC is graphically denoted by a straight line parallel to the output axis since it does not vary with
the variation in the output between zero and a certain level of output.
The TVC varies with the variation of output. When output is zero, TVC = 0. It starts from the origin and
has an inverse-S shape.
The total cost curve (TC) has the same shape as the TVC curve, but it does not start from the origin.
Where it intersects the vertical axis depends on the value of the fixed cost.
The TVC has an inverse-S shape. It shows that the TVC first increases at a decreasing rate and then at
an increasing rate with the increase in the total output. The pattern of change in the TVC stems directly
from the law of increasing and diminishing returns to the variable inputs.
According to this law, at the initial stages of production with a given fixed input, additional variable
factor is productive so that output increases at an increasing rate.
Taking total variable cost and dividing it by output would mean that average variable cost declines.
At optimal combination of the fixed and variable factor, marginal productivity of additional variable
factor reaches its maximum, implying that average variable cost reaches its minimum.
Beyond an optimal combination of the fixed and variable factor(s), increased employment of the
variable factor causes productivity of the variable factor(s) to decline and thus average variable costs to
rise. TVC increases at an increasing rate.
35 AVC
AFC
15
0 3 4 Output (X)
34
The AFC, which is given by the vertical distance between the ATC and the AVC, declines continuously
as output expands as the given total fixed costs are spread over more and more units of output.
AFC
0 Output (X)
Average Fixed Cost (AFC) Curve
Graphically, AVC is the slope of a ray from the origin to the TVC curve. The ATC is equal to the slope
of a ray from the origin to the TC curve, while the MC is the slope of the TC or TVC curves.
In the top panel, the ray from the origin and tangent to the TC and TVC at points A and B, respectively,
have the lowest slopes compared to all other lines from the origin. At point A, the ATC is at its
minimum. Similarly, the AVC is at its minimum at point B.
Note that since the ray from the origin is tangent to the TC and the AVC, it implies that MC cuts both
AVC and ATC at their minimum.
This brings us to the three important relationships between the average curves and the marginal cost
curves.
1) So long as the MC lies below the ATC curve, ATC must be declining.
2) When MC is above ATC, the ATC will be rising.
3) The MC cuts the ATC when ATC is at its minimum.
The same relationship can be observed between MC and AVC.
Also observe that the ATC and AVC curves do not reach their minimum at the same level of output.
ATC reaches its minimum after the AVC. In other words, the minimum point of the ATC occurs to the
right of the minimum point of the AVC. This is due to the fact that ATC includes AFC, and the latter
falls continuously with increases in output.
After AVC has reached its lowest point and starts rising, its rise is over a certain range offset by the fall
in the AFC, so that ATC continues to fall. However, the rise in AVC eventually becomes greater than
the fall in the AFC so that the ATC starts increasing.
Thus,
AVC = TVC = wL = w = w
X X X/L APL
35
From the theory of production, it was observed that the average product of labor (AP L) usually rises first,
reaches a maximum, and then falls. This implies, therefore, that the AVC curve first falls, reaches a minimum,
and then rises. Since the AVC curve is U-shaped, the ATC curve is also U-shaped.
Similarly, we can explain the U shape of the MC curve as follows:
Recall from the theory of production that the marginal product of labor (MP L) first rises, reaches a maximum,
and then falls. This means that MC curve first falls, reaches a minimum, and then rises. Thus, the rising portion
of the MC curve reflects the operation of the law of diminishing returns.
C1
0 X0 X1 X2 X3 Output (X)
In the long-run, planning period is long enough for a firm to be able to vary all factors of production it
uses. As a result, all costs become variable in the long run.
To derive the long-run cost curves it is helpful to imagine that a long-run is composed of a series of
short-run production decisions. Each short-run alternative situation comprises a combination of a certain
quantity of a fixed input (e.g. capital) with various units of variable inputs.
SAC (K1) is a short run average cost curve associated with K1 units of capital input.
SAC (K0) is a short run average cost curve associated with a lower amount of capital.
By joining the minimum points of the SAC curves we obtain the long-run average cost (LAC) curve.
The LAC curve is also known as „Envelope Curve‟ or planning Curve‟ because it covers various short-
run average cost curves.
It shows the least possible cost per unit of producing various output using different sizes of plants
(capital). For instance, for the firm to produce X 2 units of output, it would be appropriate to employ K2
units of capital because it minimizes cost (SAC (K2) is at its minimum). The firm would pay a higher
cost if it tried to produce X2 with K1 units of capital.
BREAK-EVEN ANALYSIS
It has been implicitly assumed in the earlier analysis that minimization of cost or optimization of output is the
primary objective of the firm. However, in traditional theory of firm the objective of the firm is to maximize
profit, which does not necessarily coincide with the minimum cost.
The break-even analysis is an important analytical technique used to study the relationship between the total
costs, total revenue and the total profits and losses over the whole range of stipulated output. Firms can plan
their production better if they know the profitable and non-profitable ranges of production.
36
The break-even analysis under both linear and nonlinear revenue and cost conditions is described next.
TC, TR
TR
Profit TC
Break even
A
-100
D
TR
B
G TFC
0 X1 X2 OUTPUT (X)
∏
C’
D’
0 X1 X2 OUTPUT (X)
G’
∏
Points B and D are the lower and the upper break-even points, respectively. A firm producing more than 0X1
and less than 0X2 units will make profits.
38
Input (X) Output (Y) APP AVP(APP.Px) MPP VMP(MPP.Py) MFC
0 0 0 0
10 75 7.5 7.50 7.5 7.50 5
20 245 12.3 12.30 17 17.00 5
30 435 14.5 14.50 19 19.00 5
40 560 14 14.00 12.5 12.50 5
50 648 13 13.00 8.8 8.80 5
60 710 12.8 12.80 6.2 6.20 5
70 753 10.8 10.80 4.3 4.30 5
80 782 9.8 9.80 2.9 2.90 5
90 800 8.9 8.90 1.8 1.80 5
100 810 8.1 8.10 1 1.00 5
110 808 7.4 7.40 -0.2 -0.20 5
To confirm this in another way, we work out the TR values and TVC values for all input and output levels.
TR = Y.Py
TVC = X.Px
Then subtract TVC from TR to get net revenue. Find the level of output and input at which net value is at a
maximum.
Input TR (Y.Py) TVC (X.PX) NR
50 648 250 398
60 710 300 410
20 753 350 403
AVP (Average Value of Product) is the average value of output per unit of input at each level of use of input.
AVP = APP x Py
VMP (Value Marginal Product) is the value of additional output produced by each additional unit of input used
VMP = MPP x Py
Profit maximization
Profit = TVP – TC = TVP – TFC - TVC
Profit = PyY – Px,X – TFC
When an algebraic expression is available for the profit function, Y = f(x), then profit is expressed as a function
of the input X, as follows.
Profit = Py. f(x) – Px.X – TFC
To maximize this function with respect to the variable input, the 1st derivative would be to set to zero.
39
LECTURE 7: THEORY OF REVENUE
REVENUE
This is the value of output obtained in a production process. It is given as;
R = f (Q, Pq)
Where Q = quantity of output
Pq = price of output
TYPES OF REVENUE
Total revenue - This is the total value of the output produced by the production process given by;
TR= Q.Pq
Average Revenue - This is the total revenue per unit of the output and it is given as;
AR = TR/Q = Q.Pq/Q=Pq
Marginal Revenue - Marginal revenue (MR) is defined as the change in the total revenue per unit change in
output.
MR= ∆TR/∆Q
PROFIT ANALYSIS
Profit is the total revenue less total cost. The function is represented as;
Π = TR-TC
PROFIT MAXIMIZATION
Whatever the structure within which the firm operates, the underlying assumption is that it wishes to maximize
profits. Profits (Π) are defined as the difference between total revenue (TR) and total cost (TC):
Π = TR-TC
Both total revenue and total cost depend upon the firm‟s output. If a firm is to maximize its profits it must
increase output for as long as each additional unit adds more to total revenue than it does to total cost, or for as
long as marginal revenue (MR) exceeds marginal cost (MC). By the same token a profit maximizing firm
should refrain from increasing output when the MC exceeds the MR. This implies, therefore, that firm
maximizes profit at the point at which MC equals MR.
The essential of this rule is presented mathematically by differentiating the equation with respect to output (Q).
dΠ = d(TR) - d(TC)
dQ dQ dQ
Note however that this condition could also identify a profit maximizing position and so there is need to
consider the second order condition which for a maximum is given as;
dΠ2 = d(MR) - d(MC) < 0
dQ2 dQ dQ
40
LECTURE 8: RISK AND UNCERTAINTY IN AGRICULTURE
DEFINITIONS
Risk is a situation where all possible outcomes are known for a given management decision and the probability
associated with each possible outcome is also known. Risk refers to variability or outcomes which are
measurable in an empirical or quantitative manner. Risk is insurable.
Uncertainty exists when one or both of two situations exist for a management decision. Either, all possible
outcomes are unknown, the probability of the outcomes is unknown or neither the outcomes nor the
probabilities are known. Uncertainty refers to future events where the parameters of probability distribution
(mean yield or price, the variance, range or dispersion and the skew and kurtosis) cannot be determined
empirically. Uncertainty is not insurable.
43