0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

Lecture 7

The document discusses the role of government in social insurance programs and the economics of insurance markets. It covers topics like actuarially fair insurance, risk aversion, risk pooling, and asymmetric information problems like adverse selection. Potential solutions to adverse selection through risk rating or creating multiple insurance products are also examined.

Uploaded by

cycwssy
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
17 views

Lecture 7

The document discusses the role of government in social insurance programs and the economics of insurance markets. It covers topics like actuarially fair insurance, risk aversion, risk pooling, and asymmetric information problems like adverse selection. Potential solutions to adverse selection through risk rating or creating multiple insurance products are also examined.

Uploaded by

cycwssy
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 22

PUBLIC ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

INTRODUCTION TO SOCIAL INSURANCE

1
ROLE OF GOVERNMENT IN INSURANCE

• New topic: Insurance

• Two kinds of insurance: social vs. self


• Self insurance: various private means of insurance against adverse events
• Social insurance: government intervention in the provision of insurance

• In the US, social insurance programs include:


• Unemployment insurance
• Disability insurance
• Workers’ compensation
• Social Security
• Medicaid/Medicare 2
INSURANCE MODEL

• Two “states of the world”: good and bad

• Payoffs: different payoffs (e.g., income) in different states: πGood and πBad
• πGood > πBad

• Probabilities: don't know which state of the world you will be in, but you do
know the probabilities
• Probability of bad state: p
• Probability of good state: 1-p
3
ROLE OF GOVERNMENT IN INSURANCE

• What is my expected payoff?


• Answer: (1-p)*πGood + p*πBad
• i.e., (prob good state)x(payout in good state)+(prob bad state)x(payout in bad state)

• Example: I earn $30,000 per year. There is a 1% chance I get hit by a car and
need to pay a medical bill of $30,000 and 99% chance I’m healthy.

• Expected payoff = .99*30,000 + .01*0 = $29,700

4
STRUCTURE OF INSURANCE

• Now suppose you have the opportunity to insure your payoffs


• i.e., the insurance company pays you a certain amount if you end up in the bad state of
the world

• In return, you pay an insurance premium


• Note: you pay the premium regardless of which state of the world you end up in

• How much should the premium be?

5
ACTUARIALLY FAIR INSURANCE

• An actuarially fair insurance premium is equal to the expected payout by


the insurance company:
• Premium = (probability of bad state)x(payout in bad state)
• Example: premium = .01*30,000 = $300 if insurance company pays full medical bill

• What is the expected payoff for a consumer who buys actuarially fair insurance?
• Example: expected payoff = .99*(30,000-300) + .01*(0+30,000-300)=29,700

• Result: same expected payoff if buy actuarially fair insurance or not!


6
ACTUARIALLY FAIR INSURANCE

• So why would anyone ever buy actuarially fair insurance?

• Both options (actuarially fair insurance vs. no insurance) give the same payoff in
expectation: $29,700. BUT...
• Without insurance: receive $29,700 on average
• With insurance: receive $29,700 with certainty

• Which would you prefer? Why?

7
EXPECTED PAYOFF VS. EXPECTED UTILITY

• Important difference between expected payoff and expected utility


• Expected payoff= p*πBad +(1-p)* πGood
• Expected utility= p*U(πBad)+(1-p)*U(πGood)

• If expected payoff=expected utility, then I get the same utility from my first dollar
of income as my 1000th dollar of income etc.

• Why might expected payoff ≠ expected utility?


• Answer: Diminishing marginal utility
• Diminishing marginal utility  risk aversion
• Constant marginal utility  risk neutral 8
EXPECTED PAYOFF VS. EXPECTED UTILITY

• Example: Suppose U(x)=√x

State of the Payoff Expected Expected


World Payoff Utility
No Insurance Accident (1%) 0 29,700 171.5
No Accident (99%) 30,000
Actuarially Accident (1%) 29,700 29,700 172.34
Fair Insurance
No Accident (99%) 29,700

9
INSURANCE AND RISK AVERSION

• Risk averse consumers: always fully insure when offered actuarially fair
insurance (i.e., a risk averse person would like to consumption smooth)

• Risk neutral consumers: indifferent between no insurance and actuarially fair


insurance

• Will consumers ever pay more for insurance than the actuarially fair premium?
• Risk neutral: no
• Risk averse: yes (willing to pay an additional risk premium)

10
RISK POOLING

• Typically, we think of insurance companies as being risk neutral. Why?

• Suppose there is a 1 in 10 chance of any individual getting sick. If individual buys


insurance, this risk is transferred to the insurance company
• Only one customer: a lot of uncertainty about insurance company's costs
• If 10 customers: more certainty about costs
• If 1000 customers: even more certainty about costs

• Insurance companies risk pool across individuals, lowering their total risk

11
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
• We established the benefits of insurance
• But why get the government involved? Why can't individuals insure themselves?

• Suppose there are two types of customers: careful and careless


• Each has different probability of bad state  different actuarially fair premiums

• Ideally, insurance companies could charge each customer a different premium


• But if there is asymmetric information (e.g., customers know their “type”, but
insurers don't), then the problem gets more complicated...

12
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: WHAT CAN
INSURANCE COMPANIES DO?

• Example: Insurance company has 200 customers with different likelihood of


getting into an accident
1
• 100 careful customers (p= %)
2

• 100 careless customers (p=5%)

• Insurer can’t observe who is careful and who is careless

• What can insurance companies do?


13
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: WHAT CAN
INSURANCE COMPANIES DO?

• Solution 1: Charge two different actuarially fair premiums and ask customers if
they are careful or careless
• Careful premium = .005*30,000=$150
• Careless premium = .05*30,000=$1,500

• Result: careless people will have an incentive to lie about being careless
• All customers say they are careful and pay the low premium  insurance company
loses money and goes out of business

14
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: WHAT CAN
INSURANCE COMPANIES DO?

• Solution 2: Set premium = average expected payout across all customers


100∗.005∗30,000+100∗.05∗30,000
• Premium = = $825
200

• Will careless people want to buy this insurance?


• YES. Expected costs = $1,500 > premium

• Will careful people want to buy this insurance?


• NO (unless really risk averse). Expected costs = $150 < premium

• Result: careful people won't want to pay, insurance company loses money since only
careless join and insurance company charges them less than actuarially fair premiums
• Adverse Selection
15
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: WHAT CAN
INSURANCE COMPANIES DO?

• Solution 3: Set premium = expected payout of careless customers only


• Premium = .05*30,000 = $1,500

• Will careless people want to buy this insurance?


• YES. Expected costs = premium

• Will careful people want to buy this insurance?


• NO (unless really, REALLY risk averse). Expected costs = $150 < $1,500

• Result: Careful won't buy insurance, insurance company doesn't lose money
• However, only careless get insured
16
INSURANCE AND MARKET FAILURES

• Adverse selection causes insurance companies to not insure all customers


• “Death spiral”

• But any customer who is even a little risk averse will want to fully insure and
insurance companies would want to provide it for them
• Under-provision  Market failure!

• Will there always be adverse selection?


• NO: if careful customers are very risk averse, they might be willing to pay the
actuarially fair premium of the careless
17
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: WHAT CAN
INSURANCE COMPANIES DO?

• Solution 4: Create two different insurance products with two different prices
• High coverage: pays more for an accident, but higher premium
• Low coverage: only pays some of the expenses, but charge lower premium
• e.g., the healthcare market has a low-cost, minimal coverage catastrophic insurance
plan and a high-cost traditional insurance plan

• Suppose the high coverage plan is set to the actuarially fair price of the careless
• Will careless people want to buy this insurance? Yes
• Will careful people want to buy this insurance? Maybe

18
POOLING VS. SEPARATING EQUILIBRIUM

• If both buy the high coverage…


• Called a pooling equilibrium

• If careless buy the high coverage and careful buy the low coverage…
• Called a separating equilibrium

• How do we know which type of equilibrium we end up in?


• Answer: depends on customers' utility function (i.e., level of risk aversion)
• If careful customers are really risk averse, they'll pay the high premium for the high
coverage
• Numerical example in this week’s recitation
19
INSURANCE AND MARKET FAILURES

• We showed before that any risk averse customer will want to fully insure

• Efficiency = everyone fully insures (i.e., no market failure)

• So when do we have a market failure in the private insurance market?


• Adverse selection?
• Pooling equilibrium with full insurance?
• Separating equilibrium?

20
INSURANCE AND GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION

• Reasons for government intervention


• Adverse selection
• Experience rating
• Redistribution
• Externalities
• Job lock
• Individuals underweight probability of bad events (paternalism)

21
NEXT CLASS

• Examples of social insurance programs


• Health insurance (next class)
• Income insurance: Social Security & Unemployment insurance (following class)

22

You might also like