Why Do European Firms Go Public?: Franck Bancel
Why Do European Firms Go Public?: Franck Bancel
4, 2009, 844–884
doi: 10.1111/j.1468-036X.2009.00501.x
Usha R. Mittoo
University of Manitoba, Canada
E-mail: [email protected]
Abstract
We survey chief financial officers (CFOs) from 12 European countries regarding
the determinants of going public and exchange listing decisions. Most CFOs
identify enhanced visibility and financing for growth as the most important
benefits of an IPO, but other motivations for IPOs differ significantly across firms,
countries, and legal systems. We find strong support for the IPO theories that
emphasise financial and strategic considerations, such as enhanced reputation
and credibility, and financial flexibility as a major advantage of an IPO. At
the same time, we find moderate support for theories that focus on exit strategy,
balance of power with creditors, external monitoring, and merger and acquisition
motivations. European CFOs’ views on the major benefits of an IPO are generally
similar to those of US managers as reported in Brau and Fawcett (2006), but
differ significantly on outside monitoring; outside monitoring is considered a
major benefit by European CFOs but a major cost by US CFOs. Our evidence
suggests that the decision to go public is a complex one, and cannot be explained
by one single theory because firms seek multiple benefits in going public. These
motivations are influenced by the firm’s ownership structure, size and age as well
as by the home country’s institutional and regulatory environment.
Keywords: going public, European firms, IPO, survey, financing, exit, ownership
JEL classification: F30, G32, G34, G30
We are grateful to all Chief Financial Officers who have participated in this study, and to
the corporate finance team of BNP Paribas and Euronext for their valuable comments and
suggestions. We would like to thank John Doukas (editor) and two anonymous referees for
valuable comments and suggestions. We also thank Douglas Cummings, Susanne Espenlaub,
Anjo Koenter-Kant and participants at the 2008 EFM Special IPO Symposium, 2008
Financial Management European, and 2007 Northern Finance Association meetings for
helpful comments, and Zhou Zhang, Weimin and Huihui for excellent research assistance.
Mittoo acknowledges funding from the Bank of Montreal Professorship and from the Social
Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. Correspondence: Franck Bancel.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 845
1. Introduction
The decision to go public has important consequences for the firm. A public listing
subjects the firm to the enhanced disclosure and regulatory requirements of stock
exchanges, and to intense scrutiny of analysts and media. Yet little is understood about
why firms choose to go public. While several theories have been proposed for why
firms go public, there is little empirical evidence to support them. Pagano et al. (1998)
is the only study that directly tests different initial public offering (IPO) theories, using
a sample of 69 Italian firms that went public between 1982 and 1992. The authors
conclude that Italian firms choose to go public primarily to rebalance their leverage,
and experience a reduction in cost of credit after the IPO. The authors use a proprietary
database to compare both ex ante and ex post characteristics of their sample firms to
discriminate between different theories. Such data are not easily available or comparable
across countries and, as a result, the extent to which their findings can be generalised
to other countries has not been investigated.
In this study, we survey chief financial officers (CFOs) of firms from 12 European
countries that went public between 1994 and 2004 about the costs and benefits of the
decision. The survey approach has several advantages that complement traditional em-
pirical studies. We can directly ask questions on both the implications and assumptions
of different theories. We can also collect data on several variables that may not be
publicly available, such as ownership control both before and after the IPO. A major
drawback is that surveys measure beliefs – and not necessarily actions – of managers.
To minimise this bias, we ask both structured and open-ended questions on the same
topic. To check the robustness of our findings, we also interview CFOs of three firms
who were closely involved with their firms’ IPO decisions, and we interview the head
of Global Equity Capital Markets in a large European bank.
Our study extends the IPO literature in three ways. First, most IPO theories focus
on only one major motivation for going public, such as raising funds for growth, or
facilitating an exit strategy for owners. However, firms may seek multiple benefits
in going public, and those perceived benefits might differ across firms. Further, two
IPO theories might propose the same benefits but different costs of going public. For
example, Maksimovic and Pichler (2001) and Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) both
model the IPO decision as a strategic move to raise equity financing for growth but
the former specifies it as a trade-off between enhanced credibility and disclosure of
sensitive information whereas the latter models it as a trade-off between the dispersion
of ownership and the information production costs. The main contribution of our study
is that we attempt to untangle these multiple motivations and trade-offs by asking CFOs
questions on both assumptions and implications of major IPO theories. We also collect
data on the ex ante and ex post firm characteristics, and use cross-correlations among
CFO responses and firm characteristics to discriminate between IPO theories. We find
support for most IPO theories, but in different subsamples of firms.
Second, motivations for going public are also likely to differ across countries due
to differences in legal and institutional environments. However, most prior studies
examine the determinants of IPO decisions in a single country. Our study fills this
gap by comparing European CFOs’ views on going public across the English and civil
system countries in our sample to those of US managers in Brau and Fawcett (2006) and
Brau et al. (2006). We find significant differences in some dimensions. For example,
European firms consider external monitoring to be a major benefit whereas the US
firms view it as a major cost.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
846 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
Finally, while the choice of a listing exchange is an integral part of the decision to
go public, few studies have examined these decisions together. We ask firms separate
questions about the exchange listing (home or foreign) and decisions to go public in
order to gain insight into the major determinants of these interrelated decisions. We find
that enhanced visibility and the ability to raise capital are most important criteria for
the choice of a listing exchange.
Our main finding is that the motivations for an IPO differ significantly across firms,
countries, and legal systems. Large firms consider the enhanced external monitoring to
be the most important benefit; small firms value the ability to raise capital for growth,
and family-controlled firms view the IPO as a vehicle to strengthen their bargaining
power with creditors without relinquishing control. The English system firms value
the ability of the pre-IPO investors to exit and enhanced stock liquidity as the most
important benefits of an IPO whereas the Italian firms identify the reduction in the cost
of financing as most valuable. The European and US CFOs have similar views on most
benefits of an IPO but disagree strongly on the costs (both direct and indirect) of an
IPO.
Our evidence suggests that the decision to go public is a complex one that cannot be
explained by one single theory because firms seek multiple benefits in going public.
We find strong support for the IPO theories that focus on financial and strategic
considerations, such as increased credibility and reputation, and financial flexibility for
growth, moderate support for theories that emphasise exit strategy, balance of power,
monitoring, or mergers and acquisitions as a major benefit, and less support for the
asymmetric information and cost of capital theories.
The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 describes our survey design and sample.
Section 3 presents and analyses the survey results. Section 4 presents cross-country
comparisons and Section 5 provides conclusions.
Sample characteristics
Panel A lists the survey response rate by country and legal system. Panel B presents summary statistics on 1) For year 2005: Market capitalisation (million euro),
Employees, Total assets (million euro), Year incorporated, and IPO year; 2) At the IPO time: Market capitalisation (million euro standardised to 2005 real euro
value), PE ratio, Price per share, First day IPO return, New shares in IPO as % of shares outstanding, Number (%) of firms that raised capital in IPO. Panel C
presents information on the firms’ ownership structure and largest shareholder in 2005. Panel D presents the summary statistics on the control (%) of the major
shareholder(s) before and after the IPO. Panel E summarises the responses to the questions, ‘Did the IPO change a) the percentage of control of major shareholders,
% of Respondent
Country of Origin # of Sample Firms % of Sample Firms Reponding Firms % of Respondent Firms Firms by Country
French Law Countries 619 34.2 38 48.7 6.1
Belgium 41 2.3 3 3.9 7.3
France 245 13.6 17 21.8 6.9
Greece 144 8.0 5 6.4 3.5
Italy 74 4.1 5 6.4 6.8
Netherlands 58 3.2 1 1.3 1.7
Portugal 19 1.1 4 5.1 21.1
Spain 38 2.1 3 3.9 7.9
Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
IPO new shares as of shares outstanding 50 31.4% 25.0% 19.9% 1.8% 100.0%
Raising capital during IPO (Yes) 77 74.0%
849
850
Table 1
Continued.
Panel D: Did the IPO change the percentage of control of major shareholders? If YES, please, specify
Panel E: Did the IPO change the following? If YES, please, specify
N Yes % No %
% of control of major shareholders 63 81.0 19.0
Your firm’s shareholding 54 88.9 11.1
Your firm’s leverage 63 44.4 55.6
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 851
greater than 500 million euros. 1 The mean (median) market capitalisation is 3315 (400)
million euros. The mean (median) market capitalisation at the IPO time standardised
to 2005 real euro value is similar to that in 2005 (2394 (340) million euros)) (Table 1,
Panel B). Our sample represents firms with varying size ranging from a minimum of 4
million euros to a maximum of 50 billion euros based on the 2005 market capitalisation.
The pattern is similar when we measure firm size based on total assets, or number of
employees (Table 1, Panel B).
The next two variables, ‘Age’ and ‘Initial Return’ are measured at the time of the
IPO. The IPO year ranges from 1994 to 2005. The mean (median) IPO year is 2000
(2001). We define a firm as old if it has a founding year of 1987 or earlier (the median
is 1988). The mean (median) age of sample firms at the time of the IPO is 24 (12) years.
The oldest firm is over 190 years old and the youngest is only one year old (Table 1,
Panel B). ‘Initial Return’ is the stock return on the first day of the IPO listing reported
by the respondents. Following Brau and Fawcett (2006), we define an IPO as hot if the
first day IPO return is greater than 10% and cold otherwise. The mean (median) first
day IPO return is 36.7% (5%) but varies from a low of −8% to a high of 1000%. The
extreme 1000% return is for a high-tech IPO conducted at the height of dotcom bubble
in 1999. The average (median) IPO price is 18.2 (12.83) euros and the average (median)
Price to Earnings ratio is 20 (15).
‘Hi-Tech’ is an indicator variable that equals one if the firm is a high-technology firm
and zero otherwise. High technology firms comprise 22% of our sample. Other industries
with large representation include financial (13%), manufacturing (12%), services (12%),
and pharmaceutical (7%). The percentage of foreign revenue varies across firms; about
36% of firms concentrate their sales in the country. Eighteen firms (21%) are listed on
foreign exchanges, eleven on the European, six on US exchanges (NYSE or NASDAQ)
and one in other countries (not tabulated).
The next conditioning variable, ‘Ownership’, is an indicator variable that equals one
if the firm is controlled by a family and zero otherwise. Panel C in Table 1 shows
that 52% of firms are widely held and 35% are family controlled. An individual or a
family is the largest shareholder in about half of the firms (47%), followed by a public
company (17%) and banks or mutual funds (10%). The state, private equity, fund or a
foundation is the major shareholder in the remaining 22% of the firms. The controlling
shareholder(s) retains a majority stake in most firms even after going public, although the
mean (median) shareholding of the largest shareholders declines from 72.2% (77.5%) in
the pre-IPO period to 46.3% (50.1%) after the IPO (Table 1, Panel D). After the IPO, the
managers’ holdings decline by about half and founders’ by 33%. In contrast, the stakes
of the institutional and retail investors increase; the number of firms with institutional
investors almost doubles and those with retail investors jumps three-fold (not tabulated
for brevity).
The last two conditioning variables, ‘Raising Capital’ and ‘Change Leverage’, are
indicator variables. ‘Raising Capital’ equals one if firm issued new shares in the IPO
and zero otherwise. Panel B shows that 74% of firms issued new shares in the IPO. The
proportion of new shares as a percentage of shares outstanding varies from a minimum
of 1.8% to a maximum of 100%. The mean (median) shares issued is 31% (25%) of
the shares outstanding. ‘Change Leverage’ equals one if the firm answered yes to the
question ‘Did the IPO change your firm’s leverage (total debt/equity – in book value)?’
1
June 2005 exchange rates were used to convert non-euro currencies to euro: EUR/USD:
1.21, EUR/GBP: 0.66, EUR/CHF: 1.54, EUR/ SEK: 9.38 and EUR/NOK: 7.93.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
852 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
About 45% of the firms reported a change in leverage (total debt/equity in book value)
after the IPO (Table 1, Panel E). Of the 35 (55%) firms that reported no change in
leverage, 17 firms did not raise new capital in the IPO. The remaining 18 capital raising
firms that reported no change in capital may have increased their short-term or long-
term debt at the time of the IPO. The firms specified leverage change before and after
the IPO in four broad categories: D/E <20%, between 20 and 50%, 50 and 100%, and
over 100% (not tabulated). All firms that reported no change in leverage either did not
answer this question or reported no change in category which is consistent with their
answer.
3. Survey Evidence
Tables 2–4 present CFOs’ responses to different questions. Column 1 reports the
percentage of respondents who agree or strongly agree with the statement, and Column 2
the overall mean rating based on a five-point Likert scale (−2 = not important; +2 =
very important). 2 The remaining columns present univariate analyses on each survey
question using conditioning variables based on several firm characteristics such as firm
size, firm age and ownership structure. The responses to the open-ended question are
summarised in Table 6. For brevity, we do not tabulate the responses on foreign listing
decision because they are largely similar to the home listing decision, but we discuss
these in the paper when they differ significantly.
The small sample size and the high correlations among several of the conditioning
variables limit our ability to perform multivariate analysis. Instead, we examine cor-
relations among responses to each question on the IPO and exchange listing decision
to test implications of major IPO theories. The correlations are presented in Table 5.
Below, we summarise our survey evidence on these theories, which are grouped under
nine major benefits proposed in the IPO literature that are neither mutually exclusive
nor exhaustive.
3.1. Benefits
3.1(a) Investor recognition, reputation and credibility. Merton (1987) predicts that an
increase in investor recognition and shareholder base lowers the firm’s cost of equity
and increases its value. Bancel and Mittoo (2001) report that European CFOs consider
enhanced visibility and investor recognition as the most important benefit of listing on
foreign exchanges.
We find strong support for Merton’s model. Most CFOs indicate that ‘to enhance
the company’s prestige and visibility’ and ‘to broaden the shareholder base’ are major
criteria for the listing decision (Table 2). Over 80% of CFOs agree or strongly agree that
the IPO acts as an advertisement for the company and increases its reputation/image
2
We also measure the relative importance of each factor by controlling for the average
response of each respondent. We compute the mean and standard deviation of their responses
across all categories, and then measure how many standard deviations from the mean each
response is. We average these deviations across respondents and compute the standard errors
of the average responses to test each factor’s perceived impact relative to the average. The
relative importance of most factors using this score is similar to those for the raw average
presented in the tables.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Table 2
Survey response to the question: home exchange listing criteria
Respondents are asked to rate factors on a scale of −2 (not important) to +2 (very important). We report the sample means and the percentage of respondents
who answered +1 (important) and +2 (very important). The subsample means are based on the following conditioning variables: Size (a large firm has market
capitalisation greater than 500 million euros), Hi-Tech (a high-technology firm), Age (an old firm has a founding year of 1987 or earlier), Initial Return (a hot
n) To appeal to institutional 60.56 0.75 0.72 0.72 0.75 0.65 1.00 0.48∗ 0.68 1.00 0.91 0.52 1.11 0.61∗ 1.03 0.58
investors
g) To be recognized by the 59.72 0.56 0.44 0.69 0.53 0.71 0.44 0.68 0.46 0.93 0.50 0.64 0.60 0.53 0.47 0.58
relevant financial community
as a major player
i) To facilitate mergers and 55.56 0.50 0.62 0.46 0.47 0.71 0.42 0.58 0.46 0.67 0.52 0.56 0.10 0.67∗ 0.32 0.42
acquisitions
853
854
Table 2
Continued.
Ownership:
Important Initial family Raising Change
or very Size Hi-Tech Age return control capital leverage
important
(%) Mean Small Large No Yes Young Old Cold Hot No Yes No Yes No Yes
h) To minimise the cost of the 21.43 −0.44 −0.50 −0.39 −0.47 −0.41 −0.42 −0.69 −0.44 −0.47 −0.33 −0.63 −0.63 −0.34 −0.56 −0.43
IPO
f) To follow competitors/peers 20.83 −0.57 −0.53 −0.57 −0.57 −0.71 −0.22 −1.00∗∗ −0.61 −0.40 −0.59 −0.52 −0.90 −0.41 −0.82 −0.42
that are listed on this
exchange
o) To create ‘good relations’ 13.04 −0.62 −0.66 −0.59 −0.63 −0.75 −0.68 −0.70 −0.73 0.21 −0.67 −0.58 −0.47 −0.65 −0.71 −0.50
with government or local
authorities
Table 3
Survey response to the question: in your opinion, the IPO has allowed your company
Respondents are asked to rate factors on a scale of −2 (not important) to +2 (very important). We report the sample means and the percentage of respondents
who answered +1 (important) and +2 (very important). The subsample means are based on the following conditioning variables: Size (a large firm has market
capitalization greater than 500 million euros), Hi-Tech (a high-technology firm), Age (an old firm has a founding year of 1987 or earlier), Initial Return (a hot
firm has initial return greater than 10%), Ownership/Family Control (whether the firm is controlled by a family), Raising Capital (whether the firm issued new
shares in the IPO), Change Leverage (whether the IPO changed the firm’s leverage (total debt/equity – in book value)). ∗∗∗ ,∗∗ ,∗ denote significant differences at
the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Ownership:
creditors
Table 3.
Continued.
856
Ownership:
Important Initial family Raising Change
or very Size Hi-Tech Age return control capital leverage
important
(%) Mean Small Large No Yes Young Old Cold Hot No Yes No Yes No Yes
r) To pay for future acquisitions 53.33 0.36 0.58 0.15 0.26 0.68 0.46 0.19 0.47 0.00 0.35 0.46 −0.30 0.59∗∗∗ 0.14 0.63
with the firm’s shares
h) To allow founding 47.37 0.26 −0.11 0.60∗∗ 0.33 0.16 0.41 0.03 0.30 0.13 0.60 −0.32∗∗∗ 0.89 0.02∗∗ 0.47 −0.14∗
Table 4.
Continued.
Spearman correlations between selected survey responses on IPO and listing decisions
Spearman correlations among responses to the following survey questions are reported: 1) Managers’ views on IPO costs and benefits (Q4); 2) Managers’ views
on IPO decisions? (Q5); and (3) Home exchange listing criteria (Q3). ∗∗∗ , ∗∗ , ∗ denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Managers’ views on Home exchg
Managers’ views on IPO benefits (Q4) IPO decision (Q5) listing decision (Q3)
Q4a Q4b Q4c Q4d Q4e Q4f Q4g Q4h Q4i Q4j Q4k Q4l Q4m Q4n Q4r Q4s Q5a Q5b Q5c Q5e Q5g Q5j Q3a Q3d Q3f Q3i
valuation)
Table 5
Continued.
Managers’ views on Home exchg
Managers’ views on IPO benefits (Q4) IPO decision (Q5) listing decision (Q3)
860
Q4a Q4b Q4c Q4d Q4e Q4f Q4g Q4h Q4i Q4j Q4k Q4l Q4m Q4n Q4r Q4s Q5a Q5b Q5c Q5e Q5g Q5j Q3a Q3d Q3f Q3i
Q4r To pay for future 0.40∗ ∗ 0.22 0.35∗ ∗ 0.49∗ ∗ 0.29∗ 0.23∗ −0.19 −0.01 0.15 0.28∗ 0.44∗ 0.26∗ 0.33∗ ∗ 0.33∗ ∗
acquisitions with the
firm’s shares
Q4s To increase firm value 0.01 0.03 0.09 0.11 0.07 0.23∗ 0.22 0.18 0.34∗ ∗ 0.14 0.49∗ ∗ 0.33∗ ∗ 0.68∗ ∗ 0.59∗ ∗ 0.37∗ ∗
by attracting diversified
investors who value shares
more than undiversified
investors
(mean = 0.90, Table 4). Consistent with the Merton model, the CFOs who value
enhanced visibility are also more likely to agree that the IPO has lowered the cost
of financing (Q4c/Q5b, corr. = 0.24, p = 0.040, Table 5). In the open-ended question,
the CFOs cite: ‘reputation among businesses, awareness of the company by stakeholders,
good reputation as an employer, and international visibility’ as major benefits.
Maksimovic and Pichler (2001) model the going public decision as the firm’s strategic
choice to gain the first-mover advantage in the product market. The public trading of
stock enhances the firm’s visibility, reputation, and credibility, enabling the firm to raise
capital for growth but also forcing the firm to disclose sensitive information that may
be valuable to its competitors, especially in high-tech industries. Their model implies
that the IPO firms will highly value the capital raising benefits of going public, and will
lead rather than follow their industry peers in going public.
We find support for three implications of the Maksimovic–Pichler model. Consistent
with the Maksimovic–Pichler model, most CFOs agree that funding for growth is a
major benefit of an IPO whereas few (21%) agree that they follow their industry peers
on the home exchanges. The high-tech firms assign significantly higher ranking to
the benefits of enhanced visibility and prestige than their peers (mean = 1.35 versus
0.89, p = 0.082, Table 2), and firms that tend to agree that an IPO enhances the
firm’s reputation also tend to place a higher value on external monitoring (Q4i/Q5b,
corr. = 0.26, p = 0.023, Table 5). However, only 22% of firms agree with the model’s
main assumption that going public forces the firm to disclose information that is crucial
for its competitive advantage (mean = −0.38, Table 4). Firms that raise capital in the
IPO disagree more strongly with this assumption (mean = −0.5 versus 0.0, p = 0.083,
Table 4).
3.1(b) Funding for growth opportunities. Ritter and Welch (2002) argue that most
firms go public primarily to raise new capital for growth. Kim and Weisbach (2008)
examine IPOs from 38 countries and find that almost all firms raise a substantial amount
of new capital in the IPO, but new funds raised in the IPO are used for several purposes in
addition to financing growth, such as rebalancing leverage and increasing cash balances.
We find strong support that funding for growth is a major motivation for going
public. Over 70% of the CFOs agree that financing investment opportunities is the
most important benefit of the IPO and listing (Tables 2 and 3). Three-fourth of our
sample firms raise new capital in the IPO. The capital-raising firms exhibit higher
annual average growth rates than do non-capital raising firms in assets (53% versus 3%,
p = 0.017,) in market capitalisation (33% versus 15%) and in the number of employees
(18% versus 12%). 3
In line with Kim and Weisbach (2005), we find that the cash raised in the IPO is used
for several purposes. The firms that report a reduction in leverage after the IPO assign
a higher mean rating to the benefit of raising capital for growth (mean = 1.48 versus
0.57, p = 0.001, Table 3), suggesting that a portion of the funds might be used for
rebalancing their leverage. The CFOs’ views on the benefits of raising capital (columns
1–3 of Table 5) are strongly positively correlated with their responses to the questions
regarding the reduction of leverage (Q4a/Q4b, corr. = 0.42, p = 0.000), the enhanced
3
These comparisons are based on survey data reported by CFOs from the year of the IPO
to 2005. These differences are modest when we restrict our analysis to firms with growth
rates between −50% and +100%, suggesting that the difference in growth rates is driven by
a few high performing capital-raising firms.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
862 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
financial flexibility (Q4a/Q4d, corr. = 0.41, p = 0.000) and the reduction in cost of
financing (Q4a/Q4c, corr. = 0.48, p = 0.000). The CFOs also mention different uses
of funds in the open-ended question: ‘Raise cash; reduction of debt; money to finance
new investments’.
Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) model the going public decision in an asymmetric
information framework as a trade-off between the option to raise equity financing in
public markets compared to the private sale of equity to a small group of large investors.
Their model predicts that firms tend to go public only when a sufficient amount of
information about them is accumulated in the public domain because it lowers their
information production costs. It also implies that firms go public when they are older,
well established and have a track record. The exception to this pattern is high technology
firms, which have a greater need for public financing.
Consistent with the Chemmanur–Fulghieri model, a typical firm in our sample goes
public at an average (median) age of 24 (12) years, but the high-tech firms go public
at a younger age and value the financing benefit more than their peers (mean = 1.37
versus 0.91, p = 0.036, Table 3). The CFOs who value the benefit of raising external
financing also tend to value the enhanced balance of power with creditors (Q4a/Q4e,
corr. = 0.25, p = 0.033, Table 5), consistent with the model. However, only 37% of the
CFOs agree that asymmetry of information was a major problem before going public.
Moreover, this support arises mainly from the firms that went public in cold markets
(mean = 0.35 versus −0.03, Table 4), suggesting that it is related to market timing. We
also find little support for the Chemmanur–Fulghieri model’s implication that access
to better financing stems from broadening the shareholder base since the correlation
between the two benefits is low (Q4a/Q3d, corr. = −0.05, Table 5).
3.1(c) Mergers and acquisitions. Lyandres et al. (2008) argue that firms go public
primarily to pursue an efficient merger and acquisition (M&A) strategy. They assume
that a private firm is uncertain about the precise value of its capital. An IPO removes this
valuation uncertainty and allows the firm to exercise its restructuring options optimally
with cash or stock financing for acquisitions. Consistent with this theory, Celikyurt
et al. (2007) find that there is a high incidence of M&A activity among newly public
US firms, and that the amount of post-IPO acquisitions is positively related to the degree
of valuation uncertainty and market conditions. Brau et al. (2003) argue that an IPO
allows firms to create publicly traded shares that can be used as a currency for growth
through mergers or acquisitions.
Although we do not ask direct questions regarding the uncertainty valuation theory,
we find support for the three main implications of the theory in the answers to several
related questions in our survey. First, 56% of the CFOs agree that facilitating mergers
and acquisitions is important in their listing decision (mean = 0.50, Table 2). Second,
over half of the CFOs agree that the IPO has allowed them to estimate the market value
of the company (mean = 0.46, Table 3) and to use stock currency for future acquisitions
(mean = 0.36, Table 3). The responses on both these questions are positively correlated
(Q4r/4l, corr. = 0.26, p = 0.026, Table 5). Further, firms that consider these two factors as
major benefits of an IPO are also more likely to agree that favourable market conditions
were a factor in their IPO timing (Q4l/Q4n – Q4r/Q4n, corr. = 0.36 – corr. = 0.33,
p = 0.002– p = 0.004, Table 5). In addition, the capital-raising firms assign a higher
ranking to the use of stock currency for future M&As compared to non-capital raising
firms for both the IPO (mean = 0.59 versus −0.30, p = 0.008, Table 3) and the listing
(mean = 0.67 versus 0.10, p = 0.086, Table 2) decisions.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 863
Finally, the CFOs’ comments in the open-ended question and in the interviews also
underscore the link between IPOs and M&As, and indicate that both cash and stock are
used for financing M&As: ‘the growth of the company thanks to acquisition and joint
ventures; ability to issue shares for acquisitions; currency for acquisitions; potential
capital raise for M&A’. Two of the three CFOs we interviewed told us that growth
through M&A was a primary objective in the firm’s IPO decision. Both firms completed
a major acquisition within three years of their IPO – one financed with stock, the other
with only cash – consistent with the predictions of Lyandres et al. (2008). The CFO of
the third firm also mentioned that the listing provided a clear idea of the firm’s value
and enhanced its financial flexibility, which was in turn useful in future M&As. All
three CFOS also told us that their firms did not set up any takeover defenses at the time
of the IPO.
3.1(d) Financial flexibility and greater bargaining power with banks. Rajan (1992)
argues that going public increases the firm’s financial flexibility, enhances its bargaining
power with bankers and financial creditors, and consequently reduces the firm’s cost
of credit. Huyghebaert and Hulle (2005) argue that an IPO allows the firm to enhance
its financial flexibility by generating additional sources of capital to finance its growth
and expansion. Pagano et al. (1998) document that Italian firms executing an IPO
experienced a reduction of about 0.30 percentage points in cost of credit after going
public.
We find strong support for Rajan’s theory but primarily in the family-controlled firms.
Over half of the CFOs agree that the IPO has reinforced the firm’s balance of power with
bankers and creditors but this support is primarily seen within family-controlled firms
(mean = 0.96 versus 0.31, p = 0.009, Table 3). Further, the firms that value an enhanced
balance of power are also more likely to agree that an IPO increases financial flexibility
(Q4e/Q4d, corr. = 0.56, p = 0.000, Table 5), reduces cost of capital (Q4e/Q4c, corr. =
0.41, p = 0.000, Table 5) and are more likely to reduce their leverage after going public
(Q4e/Q4b, corr. = 0.39, p = 0.001, Table 5), consistent with the theory. We also find
support for the Huyghebaert–Hulle theory since firms that value financing for growth
more also tend to value financial flexibility more (Q4a/Q4d, corr. = 0.41, p = 0.000,
Table 5). Moreover, while most CFOs agree that financial flexibility is a major benefit
of going public, this support is higher among firms that raise capital in the IPO (mean =
1.04 versus 0.50, p = 0.067, Table 3) and that reduce leverage after the IPO (mean =
1.18 versus. 0.63, p = 0.019, Table 3).
3.1(e) Exit strategy. Zingales (1995) argues that an IPO is a first step in the owner’s
exit strategy. The owner maximises the total proceeds from the firm’s eventual sale by
selling part of the cash flow rights in the IPO, and the ownership control rights at a
later stage. His theory implies that pre-IPO owners would be less interested in the firm’s
growth through mergers and acquisitions. Mello and Parsons (1998) argue that an IPO is
a vehicle to enhance stock liquidity and firm value, which enables owners to sell shares
in several stages. Black and Gilson (1998) model the IPO decision as an opportunity
for the venture capitalists to cash out their investments.
We find moderate support for exit strategy theories. Over half of the CFOS identify
the sale of the company as a major motivation, but the support is stronger among firms
that do not reduce leverage after the IPO (mean = 0.89 versus 0.15, p = 0.033, Table 3).
The firms that cite the sale of the company as the primary reason for an IPO are also less
likely to agree that an IPO creates a currency for mergers and acquisitions (Q4g/Q3i,
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
864 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
corr = −0.25, p = 0.037, Table 5), consistent with Zingales. These firms are also more
likely to value stock liquidity in their listing decision (Q4g/Q4k, corr. = 0.13, Table 5),
consistent with Mello and Parsons (1998). They are less likely to use the cash raised in
the IPO for reducing leverage (mean = 0.89 versus 0.15, p = 0.033, Table 3), consistent
with Black and Gilson (1998).
3.1(f) Lower cost of capital. We find less support for cost of capital theories. The
trade-off theory implies that firms go public to achieve an optimal capital structure and
to lower their cost of capital (see, for example, Scott (1976) and Modigliani and Miller
(1963)). Only 45% of the CFOs agree that cost of capital is important in their listing
decision (mean = 0.04, Table 2). Although about 58% of the CFOs agree that going
public has reduced their firms’ cost of financing (mean = 0.33, Table 3), this support
arises mainly from the firms that reduce their leverage after the IPO (mean = 0.86
versus −0.17, p = 0.000, Table 3) and appears to be related to the enhanced balance of
power with creditors. We also find weak support for the pecking order theory by Myers
and Majluf (1984) because few CFOs agree that asymmetric information was a problem
at the time of the IPO, and capital-raising firms agree even less with this statement. We
find some support for Holmstrom and Tirole (1993), who argue that firms can reduce
their cost of capital by obtaining cheap financing directly from the capital markets since
capital-raising firms in our survey agree that the IPO reduces the cost of capital whereas
non-capital raising firms do not (mean = 0.55 versus −0.20, p = 0.012, Table 3).
Several CFOs also comment on the value of monitoring in the open-ended question:
‘Pressure on management to perform; better governance; greater management discipline;
transparency of value; better monitoring and improved performance; having the market
as a reference for managers, external scrutiny and accountability focuses; management’s
attention on value-creating’. All CFOs we interviewed told us that they had completely
redesigned their accounting and managerial reporting systems after the IPO, and that
these changes had enhanced managerial accountability and efficiency.
3.1(i) Stock liquidity. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) suggest that a stock exchange
listing enhances stock liquidity, which in turn increases firm value. Maug (1998) argues
that stock liquidity is valuable for managerial incentive schemes, and predicts a positive
correlation between liquidity and external monitoring.
Although 75% of the CFOs agree that stock liquidity enhances firm value, few
mention it as a major benefit in the open-ended question. The importance of stock
liquidity for listing also varies across firms. The non-family-controlled firms view stock
liquidity as more important than family-controlled firms (mean = 0.82 versus 0.24, p =
0.093, Table 2), and old firms value it more than young firms (mean = 0.23 versus 0.83,
p = 0.071, Table 2). We find that CFOs’ views are more consistent with Maug (1998).
Consistent with his predictions, Table 5 shows that the CFOs who value stock liquidity
are also more likely to value external monitoring (Q4k/Q4i, corr. = 0.64, p = 0.000,
Table 5), compensation plans for employees (Q4k/Q4j, corr. = 0.43, p = 0.000, Table 5)
and relations with stakeholders (Q4k/Q4f, corr. = 0.38, p = 0.001, Table 5).
3.2. Costs
The IPO literature mentions both direct costs, such as underwriting costs, and indirect
costs of going public, such as increased disclosure requirements and public scrutiny.
The European CFOs are less concerned with the costs of going public. About 42% of
the CFOs agree that the direct costs are not a real issue (mean = 0.08, Table 4) and
only 37% CFOs agree that indirect costs related to asymmetric information or public
scrutiny matter. In the open-ended question, the CFOs mention professional fees of
bankers, lawyers and accountants as the major IPO costs (Table 6). One CFO estimated
the professional fees to be about 9% of the funds raised. About 30% of CFOs also
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
866 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
Table 6
Major costs and benefits of IPO
Panels A and B summarise the major costs and benefits identified by the CFOs in open-ended questions.
Panel C presents the views of CFOs on the net benefits of the IPO.
Panel A: What have been the major costs of the IPO? – open-ended question
Panel B: What have been the major benefits of the IPO? – open-ended question
% of reponding firms
Significantly positive 77
Marginally positive 21
Equal 1
Significantly negative 1
mention costs, such as public relations costs, management time, frequency of reporting,
need to change accounting systems, and short-term focus of the market.
4. Cross-Country Comparisons
The CFOs’ views are compared across European countries. We exclude three countries (the Netherlands, Switzerland, and Greece) that have a small number of
observations and distinct firm characteristics, such as mostly high-tech or very large firms. Countries are grouped by legal system and/or the firm’s ownership
structure as follows: 1) English (UK and Ireland) versus Civil (French and German system) countries; 2) French (France and Belgium) versus German (Germany
and Austria) system countries with similar proportions of family-controlled firms; 3) French system countries with a high (74%) percentage of family-controlled
firms (Italy, Portugal, and Spain) versus low percentage (40%) of such firms (France and Belgium); and 4) Italy versus other Civil system countries. Panel A
presents mean ratings for only those responses that differ significantly across at least two country groups. Panel B compares firm and offering characteristics, and
Panel C compares ownership structures before and after the IPO. T-test is used to test equality of means for English versus Civil system countries; Bonferroni
l Q4c To reduce the cost of 0.15 0.40 0.20 0.40 0.45 0.20 1.20 0.32∗∗∗
financing (debt and equity)
Q4g To sell the company to 1.15 0.2∗∗∗ −0.11 0.20 0.73 −0.11 0.00 0.22
external shareholders
Q4e To reinforce the firm’s 0.20 0.59 0.89 0.00∗∗ 0.27 0.89∗ 0.60 0.59
balance of power with bankers
and other financial creditors
Q4r To pay for future acquisitions 0.55 0.30 0.37 0.73 −0.55 0.37∗ 0.00 0.33
with the firm’s shares
867
Table 7
Continued.
Panel A: Managers’ views on IPO
868
English VS. Civil French VS. German Across French System Italy VS. Other
UK & Civil Fr & Gr & It & Pr & Sp Fr & Bel Other
Ire Countries Bel Aus (Hi Family) (Lo Family) Italy Civil
Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean
(Median) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median)
Q5c We analyse the IPO as a −0.10 0.11 0.11 −0.07 0.36 0.11 1.25 0.02∗∗
trade off between
diversification gains and
private benefits of control
Q3a To enhance the company’s 0.83 1.06 0.90 1.21 1.09 0.90 1.75 1.00
prestige, image and visibility
Q3g To be recognized by the 0.00 0.75∗∗ 0.74 0.71 0.64 0.74 0.25 0.80
relevant financial community
as a major player
Q3i To facilitate mergers and 0.50 0.53 0.58 0.64 −0.18 0.58 −0.25 0.59
acquisitions
Panel B: IPO firm and offering characteristics
Market capital at IPO time (million euro) 178 3223∗∗∗ 4,602 4,154 1,830 4,602 724 3,432
Age IPO 8 31∗∗∗ 26 35 27 26 18 32
mean ratings only for those questions that differ significantly across at least two country
groups. Panel A of Table 7 compares the mean ratings of the CFOs’ responses on
different questions; Panel B compares the firm and IPO characteristics, and Panel C
examines the firm’s ownership structures before and after the IPO. These data are self-
reported and collected through the survey.
4.1(a) English versus civil system countries. This comparison shows several striking
differences across the two groups. The English system (the UK and Ireland) CFOs
strongly disagree with their civil system peers on the major motivations for going public
(Table 7, columns 1 and 2). The English system CFOs go public primarily to sell the
company (mean rank = 1.15 versus 0.2, p = 0.001, Table 7), and to enhance stock
liquidity (mean rank = 1.40 versus 0.84, p = 0.047, Table 7). They are significantly
less concerned with IPO costs and recognition than their European peers.
Panel B shows that the English system firms are significantly smaller and younger
than their civil system peers when they go public. At the time of the IPO, the market value
of a typical English system firm is about 178 million euros, less than one-eighteenth that
of a Continental European firm (3.223 million euros), and its age is 8 years compared
to 31 years for its civil system peer; both differences are significant at the 1% level.
The English system IPOs also include a much larger proportion of primary shares in
the IPO (39% versus 28%), and are more likely to reduce their leverage after the IPO
compared to their Continental European peers.
The ownership and control structure also differs between the two groups. Panel C of
Table 7 shows that family-controlled firms comprise about 42% of the civil system firms
but only 5% of the English system firms. Prior to the IPO, the English system firms are
typically controlled by five or more large shareholders who own 85% of the firm’s shares
on average (not tabulated). In contrast, the largest shareholder in a pre-IPO civil system
firm owns an average of 80% (median = 90.5%) of shares compared to 50% (median =
36%) in an English system firm. After the IPO, the largest shareholder/founder continues
to hold a majority stake (over 50%) in a typical civil system firm but owns less than
30% of shares in a typical English system firm.
Taken together, these pieces of evidence suggest that ownership differences might
explain why English system firms value the ability to sell shares much more than
their civil system peers do. Several large pre-IPO investors in the English system firms
may wish to harvest their investment and relinquish control whereas the typical large
controlling shareholder in a Continental European firm continues to maintain control
of the firm.
A major concern in our study is whether our small sample of English system firms is
representative of the population. To address this concern, we compare how our findings
stack up against other European IPO studies. Burton et al. (2006) survey managers
and interview financial intermediaries who were associated with the IPOs conducted
in the UK between 1999 and 2001. Their focus was to identify the determinants of the
decisions regarding the IPO timing, the amount to raise and the choice of an exchange.
We examine these issues as well as both motivations and consequences of going public
decision for IPOs conducted in the UK between 1994 and 2004. The majority of their
sample IPOs were conducted in 2000 whereas most of our UK sample IPOs are from
the post-2000 period.
Burton et al. (2006) find that the need to obtain funds for growth, the need to increase
the company’s profile, and industry trends were the most important influences on the
timing of an IPO. We find that enhancing stock liquidity, obtaining funds for growth, and
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 871
facilitating sale of the company are the primary motivations for the UK firms in going
public. Burton et al. also note that the views of the firm’s major investors, who generally
wanted to realise some of their investment (especially in the smaller companies) and
strengthen the management team, were very important in the IPO decision. One of
their interviewees argued that facilitating an exit route for major shareholders, whether
individuals, companies or venture capitalists, was vital. This finding is consistent with
our conclusions.
Our findings are also in line with those of several other empirical studies and
managerial surveys. Brennan and Franks (1997) document that the pre-IPO owners
in the UK tend to relinquish control after the IPO. Goergen and Renneboog (2007) find
that new large shareholders in the UK tend to accumulate stronger control in smaller,
riskier and faster growing firms, whereas new large shareholders in Germany tend to
acquire control in older, profitable firms. They argue that economic and legal factors
drive these observed differences between the UK and German IPOs.
4
We exclude three countries (the Netherlands, Switzerland and Greece) that either have
a small number of observations or distinct firms characteristics, such as mostly high-tech
firms or very large firms. Our results remain essentially the same when we include these
countries.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
872 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
a higher value on visibility compared to their civil system peers (mean = 1.75 versus
1.00, Table 7). The pre-IPO owners in Italian firms also do not disengage from the
business (mean = −0.75 versus 0.41, p = 0.007, Table 7) and agree more strongly than
their peers that an IPO is a trade-off between diversification gains and private benefits
of control (mean = 1.25 versus 0.2, p = 0.015, Table 7).
In sum, our cross-country comparisons indicate that ownership control has a major
influence on the motivations for going public, even across countries with similar legal
systems.
We compare the European CFOs’ mean ratings in our survey with those of the US CFOs’ ratings reported in Brau and Fawcett (BF, 2006) and Brau, Ryan and
DeGraw (BRD, 2006). Although, our survey questionnaire and the scale used for responses are different from the two US surveys, several questions are similar.
We compare the US CFOs’ mean ratings on the comparable questions with European CFOs’ ratings. We rescale the US responses using our survey scale, from
−2 (not important) to +2 (very important). The last two columns present the UK CFOs’ mean ratings from our survey.
Europe USA (BF, (2006)) USA (BRD, (2006)) UK
874
b) The IPO acts as advertising for 83.12 0.90 49.11 0.27 82.35 0.65
the company and increases its
reputation/image
j) Making the IPO, we believed it 72.73 0.96 59.2 0.44 82.35 1.12
was the best time to do it
h) The IPO has obliged us to 22.37 −0.38 63.5 0.73 11.76 −0.82
disclose information that was
crucial for our competitive
advantage
f) The high cost of the IPO 14.10 −0.62 59.6 0.57 29.41 −0.41
(underwriting fees, etc.) was a
major problem for our
company
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 875
Why do European and US CFOs’ have such divergent views on IPO costs? One
plausible explanation could be that the direct costs of going public are significantly
higher in the USA compared to those in Europe. For example, the gross underwriting
spread that makes up the largest explicit cost of conducting an IPO clusters around 7%
in the US but varies between 3–4% in Europe (e.g., Chen and Ritter, 2000, and Torstila,
2001)) Moreover, the IPO costs may also be less burdensome for European firms because
they are larger and older when they go public compared to their US peers. We find some
support for this argument since large firms in our survey are significantly less concerned
with direct costs than small firms (mean = −1.08 versus −0.21, p = 0.000, Table 4).
More puzzling is the finding that the European IPO firms consider public scrutiny
to be a benefit whereas their US peers consider it as an onerous cost. One plausible
explanation could be that the disclosure and market scrutiny levels are generally much
higher and more burdensome in the US compared to that in Europe. However, this
argument is not supported in our survey because the firms that went public on the
US exchanges also consider external monitoring as a benefit, similar to their peers
listed on home exchanges. Our discussions with some European managers suggest that
the increased transparency and disclosures required by stock exchanges motivate the
firms to initiate better internal control systems for setting future goals and measuring
managerial performance. All CFOs interviewed stated that a public listing forced them
to design accounting and reporting systems that improved firm performance.
Finally, we also note that the UK firms value the IPO as a vehicle to facilitate pre-IPO
owners’ exit whereas the pre-IPO owners in the US continue to retain control after going
public. These differences suggest that the local institutional and regulatory environment
might play a major role in why firms go public, even across countries with similar legal
systems.
We survey CFOs from 12 European countries about the costs and benefits of going public
and exchange listing. Our evidence suggests that the decision to go public cannot be
explained by one single theory because firms seek multiple benefits in going public. We
find support for most IPO theories but mainly among firms with specific characteristics.
Following Brau and Fawcett’s (2006) Appendix C, Appendix 2 summarises the main
IPO theories and our survey findings. In the first column, we present the theory and its
implications. In the second column, we summarise our survey evidence and conclusions
for each theory with a rating of strong support, moderate support, and low support,
and the evidence across countries within Europe and the USA. Our major findings are
summarised below.
• The CFOs identify enhanced visibility and prestige, funding for growth and financial
flexibility as the most important benefits of going public. These benefits are common
across all firms and countries.
• Motivations for an IPO differ significantly across firms based on ownership structure,
size, and age. Large firms consider external monitoring to be the most important
benefit, whereas small firms value the ability to raise capital for growth and care less
about monitoring. Family-controlled firms view the IPO as a vehicle to strengthen
their bargaining power with creditors without relinquishing control. They also care
less about growth through mergers and acquisitions, and stock liquidity compared to
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
876 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
their peers. Old firms and non-family controlled firms value stock liquidity more than
their peers.
• The CFOs’ views are largely similar across legal systems and countries but differ
strongly on exit strategy and external monitoring. The English system firms value the
ability of the pre-IPO investors to exit and experience significant changes in ownership
structure after the IPO whereas their civil system peers continue to maintain control
of the firm after the IPO. The European and US CFOs disagree strongly on external
monitoring. The European CFOs consider it a major benefit whereas their US peers
view it as an onerous cost.
• Most CFOs agree that going public is a stage in the firm’s life-cycle, express less
concern about costs, and perceive benefits to be significantly higher than the costs of
going public.
• We find strong support for the theories that focus on financial and strategic considera-
tions, such as increased credibility and reputation, and financial flexibility for growth.
We find moderate support for theories that emphasise exit strategy, balance of power,
monitoring, or mergers and acquisitions as a major benefit but less support for the
asymmetric information and cost of capital theories.
Our findings are also confirmed through one-on-one interviews with three CFOs who
were closely involved with his or her firm’s IPO decision. All three firms went public
to achieve multiple but varying strategic objectives. One firm went public to allow the
venture capitalists and financial investors to cash out, and to fund for growth but not for
visibility or cost of capital considerations. The second firm made an IPO primarily for
financial flexibility to grow through M&As, to adapt to the new competitive industry
environment and to meet the expectations of its diverse stakeholders. Investor recognition
or pure financial considerations, such as firm value, cost of capital or windows-of-
opportunity were not an issue. In contrast, the third firm (a high-tech firm) used its IPO
mainly as a vehicle to enhance its reputation and credibility, and its ability to recruit key
personnel through managerial incentive schemes such as stock options; raising funds for
growth and cost of capital were not important motivations. The head of the Global Equity
Capital Market division of a large European bank who is familiar with the European
IPO market also validated most of our survey results, and remarked that the importance
of a specific criterion is mainly a function of the firm’s shareholdings, its industry, and
its size, a view consistent with our findings.
In conclusion, our analysis indicates that the IPO decision is a strategic decision that
is motivated by different factors across firms, and countries. Our study identifies key
factors underlying this decision and suggests that future IPO studies should incorporate
these factors in theoretical and empirical considerations of the going public decision.
References
Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H., ‘Asset pricing and the bid–ask spread’, Journal of Financial
Economics, Vol. 17, 1986, pp. 223–49.
Bancel, F. and Mittoo, U. R., ‘European managerial perceptions of the net benefits of foreign stock
listings’, European Financial Management, Vol. 7 (2), 2001, pp. 213–36.
Black, B. S. and Gilson, R. J., ‘Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: banks versus stock
markets’, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 47, 1998, pp. 243–77.
Brau, J., Francis, B. and Kohers, N., ‘The choice of IPO versus takeover: empirical evidence’, Journal
of Business, Vol. 76 (4), 2003, pp. 583–612.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 877
Brau, J. and Fawcett, S. E., ‘Initial public offerings: an analysis of theory and practice’, Journal of
Finance, 2006, pp. 399–436.
Brau, J., Ryan, P. and Degraw, I., ‘Initial public offerings: CFO perceptions’, Financial Review,
Vol. 41, 2006, pp. 483–511.
Brav, A., Graham, J., Harvey, C. and Michaely, R., ‘Payout policy in the 21st century’, Journal of
Financial Economics, Vol. 77, 2005, pp. 483–527.
Brennan, M. and Franks, J., ‘Underpricing, ownership and control in initial public offerings of equity
securities in the UK’, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 45, 1997, pp. 391–413.
Brounen, D., De Jong, A. and Koedijk, K., ‘Corporate finance in Europe: confronting theory with
practice’, Financial Management, Vol. 33, (4) 2004, pp. 71–101.
Burton, B., Helliar, C. and Power, D., ‘Practitioners’ perspectives on the IPO process and the perils of
flotation’, The European Journal of Finance, Vol. 12(8), 2006, 671–92.
Celikyurt, U., Sevilir, M. and Shivdasani, A. L., ‘Going public to acquire? The acquisition motive in
IPOs’, Working Paper (North Carolina University, 2007).
Chemmanur, T. J. and Fulghieri, P., ‘A theory of the going public decision’, Review of Financial
Studies, Vol. 12, 1999, pp. 249–79.
Chen, H. C. and Ritter, J. R., ‘The seven percent solution’, Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, 2000,
pp. 1105–31.
Goergen M. and Renneboog, L., ‘Does ownership matter? A study of German and UK IPOs’,
Managerial Finance, Vol. 33(6), 2007, pp. 368–87.
Holmstrom, B. and Tirole, J., ‘Market liquidity and performance monitoring’, Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 101, 1993, pp. 678–709.
Huyghebaert, N. and Hulle, C. V., ‘Structuring the IPO: empirical evidence on the portions of primary
and secondary shares’, Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 12(2), 2005, pp. 296–320.
Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H., ‘Theory of the firm: managerial behaviour, agency costs and
ownership structure’, Journal of Financial Economics, 3/4, pp. 305–60.
Kim, W. and Weisbach, M. S., ‘Motivations for public equity offers: an international perspective’,
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 87(2), 2008, pp. 281–307.
Lyandres, E., Zhdanov, A. and Hsieh, J., ‘A theory of merger-driven IPOs’, EFA 2008 Athens Meetings
Paper.
Maksimovic, V. and Pichler, P., ‘Technological innovation and initial public offerings’, Review of
Financial Studies, Vol. 14, 2001, pp. 459–94.
Marchisio, G. and Ravasi, D., ‘Going public and the enrichment of a supportive network: some evidence
from Italian initial public offerings’, Small Business Economic, Vol. 21, 2003, pp. 381–95.
Mello, A. S. and Parsons, J. E., ‘Going public and the ownership structure of the firm’, Journal of
Financial Economics, Vol. 49, 1998, pp. 79–109.
Merton, R., ‘A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information’, Journal of
Finance, Vol. 42, 1987, pp. 483–510.
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M., ‘Taxes and the cost of capital: a correction’, American Economic Review,
Vol. 53, 1963, pp. 433–43.
Maug, E., ‘Large shareholders as monitors: is there a tradeoff between liquidity and control?’ Journal
of Finance, Vol. 53(1), 1998, pp. 65–98.
Myers, S. and Majluf, N., ‘Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information
that investors do not have’, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 13, 1984, pp. 187–221.
Pagano, M. and Röell, A., ‘The choice of stock ownership structure: agency costs, monitoring, and
the decision to go public’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 113, 1998, pp. 187–225.
Pagano, M., Panetta, F. and Zingales, L., ‘Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis’,
Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, 1998, pp. 27–64.
Rajan, R. G., ‘Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and arm’s-length debt’, Journal of
Finance, Vol. 47, 1992, pp. 1367–1400.
Ritter, J. R., ‘Differences between European and American IPO markets’, European Financial
Management, Vol. 9(4), 2003, pp. 421–34.
Ritter, J. R. and Welch, I., ‘A review of IPO activity, pricing, and allocations’, Journal of Finance,
Vol. 57(4), 2002, pp. 1795–1828.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
878 Franck Bancel and Usha R. Mittoo
Scott, J., ‘A theory of optimal capital structure’, Journal of Economics, Vol. 7, 1976, pp. 33–54.
Torstila, S., ‘What determines IPO gross spreads in Europe?’ European Financial Management,
Vol. 7, 2001, pp. 523–41.
Zingales, L., ‘Insider ownership and the decision to go public’, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 62,
1995, pp. 425–48.
Appendix 1
Survey Questionnaire
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Why Do European Firms Go Public? 879
Appendix 1
Continued.
C 2009 Blackwell Publishing Ltd
Appendix 2
880
Survey evidence
Theory or concept (Strong Support – SS; Moderate Support – MS; Low Support – LS)
b. Funding for Growth Primarly Reason for IPO SS: about 75% CFOs agree and raise capital in the IPO;
Theory and Evidence Across Europe: no difference; USA SS: 66% agree (BRD, (2006))1
Ritter and Welch (2002) SS: about 75% CFOs agree and raise capital in the IPO
– Firms go public primarily to raise new capital for growth
Kim and Weisbach (2008) SS – Corr: benefits
– Most firms raise new funds in the IPO, and these funds are – finance investments and reduce leverage (0.42)∗
used for serveral purposes, including funding growth, and – finance investments and reduction in cost of capital (0.48)∗∗
reducing leverage – finance investments and financial flexibility (0.41)∗∗
Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) MS – support for implications, not for the assumptions
– Firms go public when older and well-established SS – average (median) IPO age 24 (12) years; high-tech at younger age
– Enhances power of balance with private investors MS – Corr: finance investments and enhance power balance (0.25)∗
– Broadening investor base to raise capital LS – Corr: finance investments and broaden shareholder base (−0.053)
– Asymmetric information LS – only 37% CFOs agree that asymmetric information was a problem
c. Mergers and Acquisitions (M&A) MS: 50% CFOs agree that facilitaing M&A is important listing criteria;
Rajan (1992) SS but mainly in family-controlled firms (mean = 0.96 vs. 0.31)
– Enhances flexibility and bargaining power with creditors SS – Corr: benefits : power balance and flexibility (0.56)∗∗
– Reduces cost of credit – power balance and reduce cost of capital (0.41)∗∗
Huyghebaert and Hulle (2005) SS – Corr: financing for growth and flexibility (0.41)∗∗
– Enhances flexibility for financing growth – capital raising firms value flexibility more (mean = 1.04 vs. 0.50)
– firms reducing leverage value flexibility more (mean = 1.18 vs. 0.63)
881
Appendix 2
882
Continued.
Survey evidence
Theory or concept (Strong Support – SS; Moderate Support – MS; Low Support – LS)
e. Exit Strategy SS mainly among English system firms;
Theory and Evidence Across Europe: LS among Civil system firms; USA: LS (BRD, (2006))1
Scott (1976), Modigliani and Miller (1963) MS to LS: 58% (45%) agree cost of capital is important for IPO (listing)
– Trade-off between benefits and cost of debt decision
– IPO firms optimize capital structure and minimize cost of LS – support mainly among firms that reduce their leverage (mean = 0.86
capital vs. −0.17), and is also related to the enhanced balance of power with
creditors.
Myers and Majluf (1984) Pecking order theory
– Asymmetric information between investors and managers; LS – only 37% agree asymmetric information was a problem
firms first raise internal funds, then debt, and equity
Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) MS – capital raising firms agree more about the reduction in cost of capital
– Cheap financing from capital markets reduces cost of capital (mean = 0.55 vs. − 0.20); Corr: finance investments and reduce cost
(0.48)∗∗
– Clustering of IPOs during strong industry and market – high-tech IPOs agree more that trading at better P/E is important for
conditions foreign listing (mean = 1.33 vs. 0.0)
– firms listing on foreign exchanges agree more that they follow industry
peers compared to listing on home exchanges(mean = 0.55 vs. −0.57).
883
884
Appendix 2
Continued.
Survey evidence
Theory or concept (Strong Support – SS; Moderate Support – MS; Low Support – LS)
i. Stock Liquidity MS: 75% agree but few mention in open-ended question;
a. Direct Costs – underwriting costs, and other professional fees SS – 62% cited direct cost is important in the open-ended question
Ritter (2003)
b. Indirect Costs – asymmetric info., loss of confidentiality, etc. LS – few agree, asymmetric information and disclosure are a major costs
Chemmanur and Fulgheri (1999), Maksimovic and Pichler (2001)
C. Net benefit SS: 77% agree significantly positive;
Across Europe: no difference; USA: N/A
1. BF – Brau and Fawcett (2006); BRD – Brau et al. (2006)