Microeconomics I - Chapter One
Microeconomics I - Chapter One
• Budget Constraint
• Preference
• Utility
• Optimal Choice
• Demand
2
I. Budget Constraint
• Economists assume that consumers choose the best bundle of
goods they can afford.
3
Assumptions
1. The consumer buys only two goods 𝑥1 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑥2
𝑝1 𝑥1 + 𝑝2 𝑥2 ≤ 𝑀
• The sum of amount of money spent on two goods can not be more than
the consumer’s income.
4
Budget Set and Budget Line
• Budget set: the set of affordable bundles at a given price (𝑝1
and 𝑝2 ) and income M.
5
Budget Set and Budget Line
• Intercept: how much of 𝑥1 (𝑥2 ) can the consumer buy, if s/he spent all
of her/his income on 𝑥1 (𝑥2 =0) or 𝑥2 (𝑥1 = 0)?
• If 𝑥2 = 0, 𝑥1 = 𝑀Τ𝑝1
• If 𝑥1 = 0, 𝑥2 = 𝑀Τ𝑝2
• These two extremes or vertical and horizontal intercepts produce a
downward sloping line known as the budget line.
𝑥2 = 𝑀Τ𝑝2 − 𝑝1 Τ𝑝2 𝑥1
6
Budget Set and Budget Line
Budget Set
7
The slope of the budget line
• The slope of the budget line has an interesting economic interpretation.
• The slope indicates the rate at which the market is willing to substitute
good 1 for good 2.
8
The slope of the budget line
• By subtracting equation 2 from 1 we get
• p1 ∆x1+p2 ∆x2=0
• p1 ∆x1=-p2 ∆x2
• p2 ∆x2= -p1 ∆x1
• ∆x2/ ∆x1=-p1/p2..................3
9
The Budget Line
• Numerical Examples: Draw the budget line in each
case.
b) let M=100,p1=10,p2=5
10
Factors that Shift the Budget Line
• The budget line shifts if one of the following
things change;
11
Change in Income
Change in income (∆𝑴)
12
Change in Income
• Numerical Examples: Graphically show how the
budget line changes in each case.
13
Change in Price
Change in price of good 1 (∆𝒑𝟏 )
14
Change in Price
• Numerical Examples: Initially, p1=2, p2=4 and M=200.
Graphically show how the budget line changes in each
case.
a) p1increased to p1’ = 5.
b) p1 decreased to p1″ = 1.
c) p2 increased to p2’= 5.
d) p2 decreased to p2″=2.
15
Change in Price
• What happens to the budget line if the price of good 1 and 2
change at the same time?
16
Exercise
1. Suppose the original budget line equation is p1x1+p2x2=M.
Write down an equation for the new budget line such that
p1 doubles, p2 becomes 8 times more while income
becomes 4 times as large.
17
Taxes, Subsidies and Rationing
• Three ways in which the government can affect the
consumers budget line.
(i) Taxes
18
(i) Tax
b. Value /Ad valorem tax
19
(i) Tax
C. Lump-sum tax
20
(i) Tax
• Numerical Examples: Initially, M=100, p1=10,p2=5.
Show how the budget line shifts for the following
cases.
21
(ii) Subsidies
a. Quantity subsidy
22
(ii) Subsidies
b. An ad valorem subsidy
Example: a maximum
amount of sugar that can
bought (𝑥ҧ1 ) = 5kg
25
Exercise
1. Suppose the price of good 1 is p1 and price of good 2 is p2 and
income is m. X1 is rationed/fixed at 𝑥ҧ1 and if the consumer
wants to buy more than 𝑥ҧ1 , she has to pay a quantity tax of t.
Draw the new budget line.
26
II. Preference
• In this section, we will focus on the concept of how the
consumer determine what is best, i.e., the best bundle.
• Given any two consumption bundles, {x1, x2} and {y1, y2}, the
consumer can rank/order them according to his/her
preference.
27
Preference Ranking
• There are three ways of ranking:
• (x1, x2) > (y1, y2) ………………. Strictly Preferred (i.e. the
consumer strictly preferred bundle x than y).
28
Assumptions (axioms) of Consumer Preferences
o Transitivity: if (x1, x2) ≥ (y1, y2) and (y1, y2) ≥ (z1, z2), then
we assume that (x1, x2) ≥ (z1, z2).
29
Indifference Curve
• Indifference curve is graphical representation of consumer
preference.
31
Indifference Map
Indifference map is a set
of indifference curves.
32
Characteristics of Indifference Curve
1) Downward sloping: this is because since they represent
combination of good 1 and good 2 which gives the
consumer the same level of utility; to consume more of
one good s/he has to consume less of the other good so
as to remain on the same level of utility.
33
Characteristics of Indifference Curve
34
Types of preferences
• Perfect Substitutes
• Perfect Complements
• Economic Bad
• Neutral
35
Perfect Substitutes
• Two goods are called perfect substitutes if the consumer is willing to
substitute on good for the other at a constant rate.
• Suppose, the consumer does not care about the color of the pens, all he
wants is to consume twenty pens.
• This means, any bundle (x1, x2) such that x1 + x2 = 20 will be on this
consumer’s indifference curve.
• Since the consumer is willing to substitute red pen for blue pen on one-
to-one basis, the slope the indifference curve of perfect substitutes will
be constant (i.e. IC’s will be straight line with a slope -1).
36
Perfect Substitutes
If the consumption of x1
increased by one unit, the
consumption of x2 has to
decrease by one unit to leave
the consumer on the same IC.
Thus, the slope of the IC is -1.
37
Perfect Complements
• These are goods that are always consumed together in
fixed proportions.
38
Perfect Complements
The vertex of the IC
occurs when individuals
consume equal number
of left and right shoes.
39
Economic Bad
• A bad is a commodity that the consumer does not
like to consume.
40
Economic Bad
Salt
Here salt is the “bad” and
egg is the “good” for this
consumer.
Egg
41
Neutrals
A neutral is a good about
which the consumer does
Salt not care.
42
Concave Preferences
• What if the consumer likes x1 and x2 but does not want to consume
them together?
• Utility will increase when he/she consumes less and less of both
goods.
• I3 > I2 > I1
X2
I1
I2
I3
X1
43
Satiation
• It is the maximum level satisfaction/bliss point.
45
Properties of well-behaved preferences
Monotonicity (more is
better)
46
Properties of well-behaved preferences
47
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
• MRS measures the rate at which the consumer is willing to substitute on
good for the other in such a way that s/he gets the same level of
satisfaction.
• This because it measures the amount of good 2 that the one is willing to
give for a marginal amount of extra consumption of good 1.
• Note: The MRS for perfect substitutes is constant while the MRS for
perfect complements and neutrals is either infinity or zero.
48
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
49
III. Utility
• Utility is a way to describe preferences.
• (x1, x2) > (y1, y2) if and only if U (x1, x2) > U (y1, y2)
50
The Cardinal Approach
• This approach states that Unit Total Marginal
utility can be measured in the
form of 1, 2, 3 etc. consumed Utility Utility
0 0 -
• Marginal Utility (MU): the
change in total utility when 1 10 10
consumption of x1 increases
by one unit. 2 18 8
∆𝑇𝑈 𝑑𝑇𝑈
MU = = 3 24 6
∆𝑥1 𝑑𝑥1
4 28 4
• Diminishing Marginal Utility:
as the consumer consumes 5 30 2
more and more of the same
product (x1) the extra 6 30 0
satisfaction (MU) s/he gets
declines. 7 28 -2
51
The Ordinal Utility Approach
• This approach states utility • Example 1
cannot be measurable in the
form of 1, 2, 3 rather it can be Bundles U1 U2 U3
ranked or ordered in the form of
1st, 2nd, 3rd, etc. A 40 4 2
B 30 3 1.5
• Monotonic transformation: is a
way of transforming one set of C 20 2 1
numbers into another set of • Example 2
numbers in such a way that the
original order is preserved.
Bundles U f = 2U f = U3 f = U +10
X 2 4 8 12
• Given U1 > U2, f (U) is considered
to be a monotonic Y 3 6 27 13
transformation if and only if f (u1)
> f (u2). Z 5 10 125 15
52
The Ordinal Utility Approach
• A monotonic transformation of a utility function is a
function that represents the same preference as the original
utility function.
o Therefore, f (U (x1, x2)) > f (U (y1, y2)) if and only if (x1, x2) >
(y1, y2) and f (U) represents the same preference U.
53
The Ordinal Utility Approach - Utility Functions
54
The Ordinal Utility Approach- Marginal Utility
∆𝑈 𝜕𝑈 ∆𝑈 𝜕𝑈
𝑀𝑈𝑥1 = = 𝑀𝑈𝑥2 = =
∆𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1 ∆𝑥2 𝜕𝑥2
55
The Relationship between Marginal Utility and MRS
∆𝑈 𝜕𝑈 ∆𝑈 𝜕𝑈
• 𝑀𝑈𝑥1 = = 𝑀𝑈𝑥2 = =
∆𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1 ∆𝑥2 𝜕𝑥2
• Suppose both x1 and x2 changes but the consumer is on the same IC.
𝑀𝑈𝑥1 Δ𝑥2
• =−
𝑀𝑈𝑥2 Δ𝑥1
56
The Relationship between Marginal Utility and MRS
𝑴𝑼𝒙𝟏
• MRS𝒙 ,𝒙 =-
𝟏 𝟐 𝑴𝑼𝒙𝟐
1/2 1/2
• Example: U = 𝑥1 𝑥2 and U = 𝑥1 𝑥2
57
Exercise
• Identify the preferences, draw the IC’s and find the
MUX1, MUX2 and MRS.
58
IV. Optimal Choice
• Given the objective market information contained in the budget
line and the subjective preferences of the consumer embodied in
the indifference curves, we can now determine the consumers
optimum or utility maximizing position.
59
Optimal Choice
• In the left panel, point A gives
The consumer maximizes us the optimum of the
utility at a point consumer.
∆𝒙𝟐 −𝑷𝟏 −𝑴𝑼𝒙𝟏
= = = MRS
∆𝒙𝟏 𝑷𝟐 𝑴𝑼𝑿𝟐
• At point B, the IC is crossing the
budget line from below (i.e. the
budget line is steeper than the
C IC) and hence to reach optimal
point, the consumer should
reduce the consumption of X1
and increase the consumption
A D of X2 .
I3
• At point C, the budget line is
flatter than the indifference
I2 curve and hence to reach
B optimal point, the consumer has
to increase consumption of x1
I1 and reduce consumption of X2.
60
Optimal Choice
• The tangency condition is a
necessary condition but not
sufficient for the bundles to
be optimal.
61
Mathematical derivation of the optimal choice and
consumer demand
• The Lagrange Multiplier Method: is a method of finding the maximum
or minimum of a constrained function.
62
Mathematical derivation of the optimal choice and
consumer demand
𝜕𝐿 𝜕 𝑈 (𝑥1 ,𝑥2 )
• = - λ𝑃1 = 0 …………………………. (1)
𝜕𝑥1 𝜕𝑥1
𝜕𝐿 𝜕 𝑈 (𝑥1 ,𝑥2 )
• = - λ𝑃2 = 0 …………………………. (2)
𝜕𝑥2 𝜕𝑥2
𝜕𝐿
• = M - P1x1 - P2x2 …………………………….. (3)
𝜕𝜆
63
Mathematical derivation of the optimal choice and
consumer demand
64
Mathematical derivation of the optimal choice and
consumer demand
𝑎𝑥1𝑎−1 𝑥2𝑏 𝑃1 𝑎𝑥2 𝑃1
• Since λ = λ; we will have 𝑏−1 = → =
𝑏𝑥1𝑎 𝑥2 𝑃2 𝑏𝑥1 𝑃2
𝑏𝑃1 𝑥1
• 𝑥2 = ………………………. (4)
𝑎𝑃2
• From equation (3) P1x1 + P2x2 =M substituting (4) into this: P1x1 +
𝑏𝑃1𝑥1
P2 =M
𝑎𝑃2
𝑴 𝒂 𝑎
• 𝒙𝟏 = ………………… Consumer demand for x1; where is share
𝑷𝟏 𝒂+𝒃 𝑎+𝑏
of income spent on x1
• The demand for x1 = f (P1, M), is positively related with income and
negatively related to its own price.
65
Mathematical derivation of the optimal choice and
consumer demand
𝑏𝑃1𝑥1 𝑏𝑃1 𝑀 𝑎
• From (4) 𝑥2 = =
𝑎𝑃2 𝑎𝑃2 𝑃1 𝑎+𝑏
𝑴 𝒃
• 𝒙𝟐 = ………………… Consumer demand for x2
𝑷𝟐 𝒂+𝒃
𝑏
• Where is share of income spent on x2.
𝑎+𝑏
66
Exercise
1. Max U = 𝑥13 𝑥2 subjected to 6x1 + 3x2 =600
2. Max U = 𝑥12 𝑥23 subjected to 2x1 + 4x2 =600
3. Max U = 𝑥1 𝑥2 subjected to 2x1 + 4x2 =300
67
Exceptions to Tangency
• Utility maximization may not always be characterized
by tangency.
• Perfect Complements
• Bad/Neutrals
• Perfect Substitutes
• Convex Preferences
68
Exceptions to Tangency - Perfect complements
69
Exceptions to Tangency - Bad/Neutrals
Neutrals
Bad
U1 U1 U2 U3
U2
U3
Good
Good
• The above panels represent boundary optimum (until now we were dealing with
interior optimum).
• In this case the consumer spends all of his/her money on the good he/she likes
and does not purchase the neutral/bad at optimum.
70
Exceptions to Tangency - Perfect Substitutes
• In this case, the consumer
will buy the cheapest
commodity.
71
Exceptions to Tangency – Concave Preferences
72
V. Demand
• From the previous section recall that the consumers demand function
gives the optimal amount of each of the goods as a function of price and
income faced by the consumer.
• In this section, we will examine how the demand for goods changes as
prices and income change.
73
Normal and Inferior Goods
• 1. Normal Goods: the demand for such goods
increases as income increases and decreases as
∆𝑥
income decreases, i.e. >0
∆𝑀
74
Income offer curve and Engle Curve
• In section I, we have seen that an increase in income corresponds
to shifting the budget line outward in a parallel manner.
• The income offer curve (IOC) shows the bundles of goods that
are demanded at different levels of income. If both goods are
normal, IOC will have a positive slope.
75
Income offer curve and Engle Curve
• Panel A show income offer curve for normal goods (x1 and x2).
76
Income offer curve and Engle Curve
X2 Income
𝑀 ′′
𝑃1
𝑀′ ′
𝑒′
𝑃2
𝑀 𝑒′ 𝑀′′
𝑃2
e 𝑀′
M
𝑀′ 𝑀 ′′
X1 X1
𝑀
𝑥1′′ 𝑥1′ 𝑥1
𝑃1 𝑃1 𝑃1
(a) (b)
• Panel (b) shows Engle curve for good 1 and it is negatively sloped.
77
Perfect Substitutes
• Here we can consider three cases:
• (1) P1 < P2, X2 = 0 then the horizontal axis will be the IOC
while the Engle curve for X1 will be positive with a slope P1,
• (2) P2 < P1, X1 = 0 then the vertical axis will be the IOC while
the Engle curve for X2 will be positive with a slope P2 and
78
Perfect Substitutes
79
Perfect Complements
• In the case of perfect complements, since the consumer will always
consume the same amount of each goods, demand is given by X1 =
X2 = M/ (P1 +P2).
• Thus, the income offer curve is diagonal line through the origin and
also the Engle curve is a straight line with a slope of P1 + P2.
M Engle Curve
X2
IOC
Slope = P1+ P2
X1
X1
80
Cobb – Douglas Preferences
• For the case of Cobb-Douglas preferences, if U = 𝑥1𝑎 𝑥21−𝑎 the demand for
good 1 has the form 𝑎𝑀Τ𝑃1 and the demand for good 2 is
(1 − 𝑎)𝑀Τ𝑃2 .
• Based on the fact that the demand function for both goods are linear
functions, the income offer curve will be straight lines through the origin
and Engle curve for both good 1 and good 2 will be a straight line as well
with a slope 𝑃1 Τ𝑎 and 𝑃2 Τ1 − 𝑎 respectively.
M Engle Curve
X2
IOC Slope = 𝑃1 Τ𝑎
X1
X1
81
Ordinary and Giffen Goods
• 1. Ordinary Goods: the demand for such goods
increases as price decreases and decreases as price
∆𝑥
increases, i.e. < 0
∆𝑃
82
Price Offer Curve and Demand Curve
• Let us now consider the effect of price changes on the
consumer’s demand keeping everything else constant.
83
Price Offer Curve and Demand Curve
• Panel A contains a price offer curve for a normal good, which depicts the
optimal choices as the price of good 1 changes.
• Panel B contains the associated demand curve, which depicts a plot of the
optimal choice of good 1 as a function of its price.
84
Perfect Substitutes
We can consider three cases:
• If P1 < P2, demand for x2 will be zero and only x1 will be demanded
• If P1 > P2, demand for x1 will be zero and only x2 will be demanded
• If P1 = P2, any combination of x1 and x2 which on the budget line will be
demanded
P1 > P2
P1 < P2
85
Perfect Complements
• The price offer curve in the case of perfect complements is diagonal
line through the origin and the demand curve is downward sloping.
86
Decomposition of Income and Substitution Effects
• Change in price have two effects: (1) the rate at which you can exchange
one good for another changes, and (2) the total purchasing power of
your income is altered.
• For example, if good 1 become cheaper, it means that you have to give
up less of good 2 to purchase good 1, i.e., the rate at which the market
allows you to “substitute” good 2 for good 1 changes.
• At the same time, if good 1 becomes cheaper it means that your money
income will buy more of good 1, i.e., the purchasing power of your
money has gone up.
• The income effect – change demand due to having more purchasing power
88
Slutsky's Decomposition
• Suppose the price of good 1 declined. This means that the budget line
shift along the horizontal axis and becomes flatter.
• First pivot the budget line around the original demand bundle (i.e. draw
a new budget line that indicates the same relative price as the final
budget line but has a different income).
• Then, shift the pivoted line out to the new demand bundle.
• The first step – the pivot – is a movement where the slope of the budget
line changes while its purchasing power stays constant, while the
second step is a movement where the slope stays constant and the
purchasing power changes.
89
Slutsky's Decomposition
• Point ‘Y’ is optimal
purchase on the pivoted
budget line.
• Movement from X to Y is
the substitution effect and
it indicates how the
consumer “substitutes”
one good for the other
when price changes but
purchasing power remains
constant.
• Movement from Y to Z is
the income effect which
indicates how demand
changes when income
changes while relative
prices remain constant.
90
Slutsky's Decomposition
• Substitution effect is negative, since the change in demand due to the
substitution effect is opposite to the change in price, i.e., if price
increases, the demand for the good due to the substitution effect
decreases and vice versa.
• If the good is normal income effect will be positive while for an inferior
good it is negative.
• The total change in demand is the change in demand due to the change
in price, holding income constant.
91
Slutsky's Decomposition
• We can use what we know about the signs of the income and
substitution effect to determine the sign of the total effect.
92
Slutsky's Decomposition
• If we have inferior good, it might happen that the income effect
outweighs the substitution effect, so that the total change in
demand associated with a price increase is actually positive.
• This is the perverse Giffen good case where the increase in price
has reduced the consumer’s purchasing power so much that she
has increased her consumption of the inferior good.
93
The Law of Demand
• If the demand for a good increases when income
increases, then the demand for that good must
decrease when its price increases.
94
Hicksian Decomposition
• For the Hicks substitution effect, instead of pivoting the
budget line around the indifference curve through the
original consumption bundle, we now roll the budget line
around the indifference curve through the original
consumption bundle.
95
Hicksian Decomposition
• The Slutsky substitution
effect gives the consumer
just enough money to get
back to his old level of
consumption, while the
Hicks substitution effect
gives the consumer just
enough money to get
back to his old
indifference curve.
96
Market Demand
• Market Demand is derived by horizontally adding the quantity
demanded for the product by all buyers at each price.
• The figure below shows individual and market demand curve at price
equal to 3
Required Revision from Econ (1011)
• Elasticity of Demand
o Price elasticity
o Income elasticity
o Cross-price elasticity
98