03 - Competitor Analysis and Interfirm Rivalry
03 - Competitor Analysis and Interfirm Rivalry
Integration
Ming-Jer Chen
The Academy of Management Review, Volume 21, Issue 1 (Jan., 1996), 100-134.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0363-7425%28199601%2921%3A1%3C100%3 ACAAIRT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-F
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR’s Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR’s Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you
have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and
'you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or
printed page of such transmission.
The Academy of Management Review is published by Academy of Management. Please contact the publisher for
further permissions regarding the use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www jstor.org/journals/aom.html.
JSTOR and the JSTOR logo are trademarks of JSTOR, and are Registered in the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office.
For more information on JSTOR contact [email protected].
©2003 JSTOR
http://www jstor.org/
Thu Aug 14 15:35:01 2003
© Academy of Management Review
199, Vol. 21, No. 1. 100-134.
The study of competitor analysis (Hamel & Prahalad, 1990; Porac &
Thomas, 1990; Porter, 1980, 1985; Zajac & Bazerman, 1991) and of interfirm
rivalry (Bettis & Weeks, 1987; D'Aveni, 1994; MacMillan, McCaffery, & Van
Wijk, 1985; Smith, Grimm, & Gannon, 1992) occupies a central position in
strategy. Therefore, a basic understanding of each subject, as well as an
integrated comprehension of both, is of paramount importance.
A primary objective of competitor analysis is to understand and pre-
dict the rivalry, or interactive market behavior, between firms in their
to the idea of competitive asymmetry, the notion that a given pair of firms
may not pose an equal threat to each other. I first offer a number of
propositions that use market commonality and resource similarity to pre-
dict competitive attack and response. I also propose measures to assess
market commonality and resource similarity along with a demonstration
of how such measures could be implemented. The article ends with a
number of implications for research and practice.
THEORETICAL BACKGROUND
2 Many economic studies have also been devoted to this topic (e.g., Bernheim and
Winston, 1990; Scott, 1982), and Gimeno (1994) has provided a comprehensive review of this
research stream. In this article, I focus mainly on strategy studies on the subject.
104 Academy of Maragement Review January
construct, and different definitions are needed for different strategic pur-
poses. To allow generalizability, market is broadly defined here to in-
clude both product- and customer-based concepts such as geographical
market, market segment, or brand (Day 1981). Of course, within any in-
dustry, there is generally a commonly agreed-upon notion of market
(Abrahamson & Fombrun, 1994).
Resource similarity. The resource-based view of the firm seems par-
ticularly useful in differentiating competitors from a strategic point of
view (Amit & Schoemaker, 1993; Barney, 1991; Mahoney & Pandian, 1992;
Teece, Rumelt, Dosi, & Winter, 1994). The firm is the focal level of analysis
in this reemerging strategy theory; the underlying orientation considers a
firm as a unique bundle of tangible and intangible resources and capa-
bilities (Penrose, 1959; Wernerfelt, 1984). A basic assumption of the re-
source-based work is that resource bundles and capabilities are hetero-
geneously distributed across firms and that each firm is idiosyncratic
because of the different resources and assets it has acquired over time
and because of the various routines it has developed to manage them
(Barney, 1991; Peteraf, 1993a; Teece, Pisano, & Shuen, 1991). A firm's com-
petitive position and advantage in the industry are defined by its unique
resource bundle (Conner, 1994; Rumelt, 1984). More important, resource
endowments are "sticky” and likely to constrain a firm's strategic choices
(Teece et al., 1991). Collis (1991: 51) made this point explicit: “Strategy is
constrained by, and dependent on, the current level of resources . . . the
firm's asset investments, which in aggregate are the fundamental deter-
minants of its strategic position.”
Resource similarity is defined as the extent to which a given compet-
itor possesses strategic endowments comparable, in terms of both type
and amount, to those of the focal firm. The understanding of resource
similarity is important for competitive advantage because firms with sim-
ilar resource bundles are likely to have similar strategic capabilities as
well as competitive vulnerability in the marketplace. Similarly, firms
with divergent resource bundles are likely to have diverse competitive
repertoires to draw on because of the unique profiles of their strategic
resources.
In summary, the conceptualization of both market commonality and
resource similarity as firm-specific constructs developed from an individ-
ual firm's perspective is fundamentally rooted in the resource-based the-
ory of the firm. However, in this article I adopt a different perspective
arguing that each firm, although unique, differs from others in degrees
along a continuum of market commonality and resource similarity. Com-
parison is not only possible, but it is also necessary for purposes of em-
pirical research. A framework of competitor analysis, based on these two
dimensions, is proposed in Figure 1.
Juxtaposing these dimensions yields four quadrants into which
a given competitive relationship may fall. Quadrant I illustrates the
relationship of a focal firm with a competitor with high resource similarity
108 Academy of Maragement Review January
FIGURE 1
A Framework of Competitor Analysis
4 N
High
Market mjt
Commonality m| v
Low
& _/
Low Resource High
Similarity
Wijk, 1985; Smith et al., 1392). First, the research recognizes a distinction
between the concept of interfirm rivalry, which emphasizes the conduct of
individual firms, and the general conceptualization of competition, which
focuses on properties of the industry or market structure (Baum & Korn,
1994; Caves, 1984; Hannan & Freeman, 1989; Jacobson, 1992). Second, us-
ing the individual competitive move as the unit of analysis, rivalry can be
analyzed by studying the exchange of moves and countermoves (Caves,
1984; Porter, 1980; Smith et al., 1992), or the action/response dyad.
The action/response dyad is consequential because it is at this level
where competitive engagement occurs (Chen et al., 1992) and where the
dynamic nature of strategy and competition and the "mutual interdepen-
dence” of firms in an industry are best captured (Porter, 1980: 17). An
action (or attack) is defined here as a specific competitive move initiated
by a firm, such as introducing a new product or entering a new market,
that may lead to the firm's acquiring its rivals’ market shares or reducing
their anticipated returns (Chen & Hambrick, 1995; Chen & MacMillan,
1992). Similarly, a response (or retaliation) is a specific countermove,
prompted by a rival’s attack, that a firm takes to defend or improve its
share or profit position in the industry.
The importance of competitive attack has been widely acknowledged
in such concepts as first-mover advantage (Lieberman & Montgomery,
1988) and competitive initiative (MacMillan, 1982). Underlying such theo-
ries is the notion that, in a world of uncertainty, firms count on the success
of some competitive actions to secure lasting benefits (Wemerfelt & Kar-
nani, 1987). As MacMillan (1982: 43) noted: “To the extent that strategists
can capture and maintain the initiative, their competitors are obliged to
respond, thus being forced to take a reactive role rather than a proactive
role.”
The significance of competitive response lies in the fact that attacks
are rarely made with impunity and that the ultimate effectiveness of an
action depends largely on defenders’ responses (Chen & MacMillan, 1992;
Smith et al., 1992). The need for a firm initiating an attack to consider
potential responses is particularly crucial in intensely rivalrous situa-
tions, in which firms are closely interdependent and in which damaging
countermoves can occur very rapidly (D'Aveni, 1994). In such situations,
the expectation of retaliation will drive competitive decision making.
Thus, a key feature of rivalry is its dynamic and interactive nature (Schell-
ing, 1960; Weigelt & MacMillan, 1988).
Moreover, researchers have shown that actions and responses matter
to performance (Chen & Hambrick, 1995): The greater the number of com-
petitive moves a firm initiates, the better its performance (Young, Smith,
& Grimm, 1994); attackers and early responders gain market share at the
expense of late responders (Chen & MacMillan, 1992); the greater a firm's
tendency to respond, the better its performance (Smith et al., 1991); and
the more responses a firm's actions provoke, the worse its performance
(Chen & Miller, 1994).
110 Academy of Management Review January
This section will use the concepts of market commonality and re-
source similarity to predict the likelihood of attack and the likelihood of
response. Underpinning the prediction are three drivers of competitive
behavior: awareness, motivation, and capability. In general, awareness
is considered a prerequisite for any move, and it is likely to be increased
by both market commonality and resource similarity. Market commonal-
ity will affect a firm's motivation to attack (or respond); resource similarity
will influence attack (or response) capability. Several streams of litera-
ture will be used to show support for these general predictions, mainly
multiple-point competition for market commonality and the resource-
based theory of the firm for resource similarity. In addition, the idea of
competitive asymmetry is introduced, and its implications for rivalry are
discussed.
Figure 2 offers a schematic representation of the linkages between
competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry. The building blocks of compet-
itor analysis—market commonality and resource similarity—influence
the drivers of competitor behavior. These drivers (awareness, motivation,
and capability), in turn, influence the likelihood of competitive attack and
response. The figure also suggests that interfirm rivalry affects organi-
zational outcomes such as economic performance and changes in market
share, although the issue is not specifically addressed in the present
article. The figure then reveals a feedback loop as rivalrous moves alter
the existing positions in commonality and similarity, thereby setting up a
111
esuodsey jo pooyrieNrTe
Ruppung esimoseye
A
A9DRY JO PooYIeNITe Y
Aypuowrmo 1o e
1o1aDyeg
ssuodsey pup uoudy sanneduwion jo s1eauq
sAapoary ungsejup sisA[puy sopedwon
Azpary unnasiu] pup sisi[puy ojedwo) jo ylomawni peaypibajul uy
2 34NO1d
1936
112 Academy of Management Review January
new competitive relationship for the next battle. These relationships are
elaborated and clarified in the next sections.
Finally, in the following propositions about market commonality, re-
source similarity is held constant. Similarly, market commonality is held
constant in presenting propositions on resource similarity. In addition,
multiple-point competition research has identified key market structure
variables (e.g., growth and concentration) for control in empirical testing.
Research on competitive action and response has shown the significance
of the attributes of the attack (e.g., type of action), of the attacker (e.g.,
commitment), and of the defender (e.g., competitor dependence) in pre-
dicting response. These are the factors that must be assumed to be equal
in making the following predictions.
31t should be noted that there may be factors other than market commonality which
affect the degree to which two firms are in direct competition, such as differentiation (Beath
& Katsoulacos, 1991; Hotelling, 1929).
19% Chen 13
MacMillan, 1992; Chen & Miller, 1994). Therefore, the organizational re-
quirements for response would be more manageable for competitors with
resource bases similar to the attacker's than for those with very different
ones, all other things being equal.
Furthermore, as often noted in the resource-based work, firm capa-
bility extends the notion of intangible resources to include various orga-
nizational routines developed by the firm (Collis, 1991; Winter, 1987). In
competition, firms would not only be more motivated but also more ca-
pable of reacting easily to those kinds of situations that evoke routine
responses by drawing from the preprogrammed and preestablished rou-
tines that exist inside the firm (Allison, 1971). These preexisting routines
are more likely to be available if a move is initiated by a similar firm,
from both the strategic and resource points of view. In short, defenders
that are most similar to the attacker in their strategic resource endow-
ments will have the greatest potential and capability for retaliation.
Proposition 2b: The greater A's resource similarity with
B, the more likely B is to respond to A’s attack, all else
being equal.
much less transparent. Because of the visibility associated with high mar-
ket commonality, other stakeholders connected with the firm also will be
aware of any competitive challenge and, thus, pressure the firm with
respect to the issues of whether and how to act and react (Pfeffer, 1982,
1987; Porter, 1984).
Proposition 3: Market commonality is a stronger predic-
tor of competitive attack and response than is resource
similarity.
2,000
Mab = ) [Pa/Pa) X (Pu/P)] )
i=1
where M,;, = Market commonality that airline b has with the focal
airline a;
P,; = Number of passengers served by a in route i;
P, = Number of passengers served by a across all routes;
P,; = Number of passengers served by b in route i;
P; Number of passengers served by all airlines in route i;
A route, among the top 2,000 routes, served by both
o
aand b.
Each competitor's market commonality with a focal firm was devel-
oped from a detailed, market-by-market analysis across all their shared
1996 Chen 119
*pepDYs St JewtIo} oy} , ‘00’0, SN1l D PUD BUTPUNOI Jo 8STDISq ,00°0,, USSMIS] UOHIUNSIP SY SXDU O,
“1qBU o} Yo Woxj pool
9q p[noys o[qp} 8y, *9[qD} 8y} Jo do} 8y} SSOIOD pejst| Ip siojedwod sanoedsel 118y} {UWN[Od PUDY-}S] oY} Ul Pa}si| 81D SWLIY [DI0] oY, 5
1y pliop upduewry und- ¥d seurny oieq- 14
SOUIY isemnos- NM SeUNNY JSSMUMON- MN SPUIIIy [Djueunuod- 0D
nysn- sn sourpry ADMpIN- TW puolg- NG
seuruly peyun- YA seury isop DoUeWY- dH seury DYSDIY- SV
SOUIUITY PlIOM SUDIL- ML seury UDIDMDH- VH sourury oyory- OV
UOUDIAY JUOWPS! d seuryIty u1e}spg- v ‘seurily UpOUewWy- Y
Academy of Management Review
NAygg T Iy v
va- S= (500 w
Aojpug samosay
oro m
Sh M>Nz H »
2 10
- S0 8£ -
. <=} g sh
- 1a 0zo < 0z0
vn
20 - 20
MN
(e1dwpxe uD sp seuILY UDOUGUIY Buisf) (o1dwpxa up sp soutty Apmpyy Buisp)
Aypouowrwon jenoW Apuowmo jeRioK
V0 S0 PO S20 020 S0 OLO _sgo 000 v S£0 090 0 0z0 S0 Q10 00009
Chen
RL i - @
da okt
Y
YY s00 dH - 500
W ¥d|
Kypung eamosoy
T oro £ . o= oo
- o ‘OU‘ MN ML
[efe) a sn vn
sto 8 S0
- g3 -
¥a o jozo < YY 0z0
S20
520
(e1dupxe up sn seury 1semyinog bursn) (erdwxe up 8o sautfary Dileq Susn)
1996
Burddoyy 1oineduo)
€ JUNOIL
122 Academy of Management Review January
DISCUSSION
There are two primary purposes for this article. First, it proposes a
new conceptualization of competitor analysis by introducing two firm-
specific and theory-based constructs: market commonality and resource
similarity, which would allow for differentiation among various players
in an industry. Second, it provides theoretical integration between two
important subjects in strategy: competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry.
Using these two constructs, the article presents propositions predicting
competitive attack and response.
The article first contributes to the literature on competitor analysis by
focusing on a very fundamental yet generally ignored issue, the extent to
which firms are in direct competition because of the similarity in their
market profiles and resource endowments. The introduction of market
commonality and resource similarity adds to current efforts in strategy
(resource-based work, in particular), population ecology (Barnett, 1993),
and network theory (Burt, 1987), which attempt, from different theoretical
angles, to provide a more differentiated depiction of the relationships
between firms.
The joint consideration of these two constructs also shows the com-
plementarity of two very prominent but contrasting strategy theories, the
industry structure or Porter’s (1980) theory and the resource-based theory
(Barney, 1991; Peteraf, 1993a), in studying competitive advantage and
competition. This article highlights the significance and usefulness of
applying both the former’s “outside-in” and the latter's “inside-out” per-
spectives for conceptualizing competitors and predicting rivalry.
More important, these two constructs and their underlying theories
are applied to predict attack and response, which reflect rivalry. Through
these propositions, the conceptual linkage between competitor analysis
and interfirm rivalry is made explicit, a vital issue that has remained
largely unaddressed in the literature.
For illustration, this article offers measures of market commonality
and resource similarity, using airlines as an example. The proposed mea-
sures, derived from public data, corresponded highly to the perceptual
competitor ranking provided by industry informants. The convergence of
results using two independent methods provides preliminary support for
the validity of the proposed measures and the underlying constructs
(Campbell & Fiske, 1959; Dess & Robinson, 1984; Schwab, 1980; Venkatra-
man & Grant, 1986).
Implications
There are several research implications. First, the article highlights
the significance of the market in which competitive battles play out and
the importance of comparing the overall market profiles of firms. Strategy
researchers seem to pay limited attention to the market context, instead
focusing on industry, strategic group, or the firm as a unit of analysis.
124 Academy of Management Review January
dustry groups and performance. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Academy
of Management, Atlanta, GA.
Barett, W. P. 1993. Strategic deterrence ameng multiple point competitors. Industrial and
Corporate Change, 2: 249-278.
Barney, . B. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Man-
agement Science. 32: 1231-1241.
Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Man-
agement, 17: 99-120.
Barney, J. B., & Hoskisson, R. E. 1990. Strategic groups: Untested assertion and research
proposals. Managerial and Decision Economics, 11: 187-198.
Bass, B. M. 1983. Organizational decision making. Homewood, IL: Irwin.
Baum, J. A. C., & Korn, H. ]. In press. Competitive dynamics of interfirm rivalry: Linking
structural conditions of competition to patterns of market entry and exit. Academy of
Management Journal.
Baum, J. A., & Singh, J. V. 1992 Organizational niches and the dynamics of organizational
‘mortality. Working paper, New York University.
Beath, I., &Katsoulacos, Y. 1991. The economic theory of product differentiation. Cambridge,
England: Cambridge University Press.
Bernheim, D., & Whinston, M. D. 1390. Multimarket contact and collusive behavior. Rand
Journal of Economics, 21: 1-26.
Bettis, R. A., & Weeks, D. 1987. Financial returns and strategic interaction: The case of
instant photograph. Strategic Management Journal, 8: 549-563.
Boeker, W., Goodstein, J., Stephan, J., & Murmann, P. 1994. The dynamics of market entry:
The role of multipoint competition. Working paper. Graduate School of Business, Co-
lumbia University.
Bowley, A. L. 1924. The mathematical groundwork of economics. Oxford, England: Claren-
don Press.
Burt, R. 1987. Social contagion and innovation: Cohesion versus structural equivalence.
American Journal of Sociology, 92: 1287-1335.
Campbell, D. T., & Fiske, D. W. 1959. Convergent and discriminant validation by the mul-
titrait-multimethod matrix. Psychological Bulletin, 56: 81-105.
Carpenter, G. S., Cooper, L. G., Hanssens, D. M., & Midgley. D. F. 1988. Modeling asym-
‘metric competition. Marketing Science, 7 393-411.
Caves, R. E. 1984, Economic analysis and the quest for competitive advantage. Papers and
Proceedings the 96th Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 74(2): 127
132.
Caves, R. E., & Porter, M. E. 1977. From entry barriers to mobility barriers. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 91: 241-261.
Chen, M.J., & Hambrick, D. C. 1995. Speed, stealth, and selective attack: How small firms
ditfer from large firms in competitive behavior. Academy of Management Journal, 38:
453-482.
Chen, M., & MacMillan, 1. C. 1992. Nonresponse and delayed response to competitive
moves: The roles of competitor dependence and action irreversibility. Academy of Man-
agement Journal, 35: 539-570.
Chen, M.-J., & Miller, D. 1934. Competitive attack, retaliation and performance: An expec-
tancy-valence framework. Strategic Management Journal, 15: 85-102.
130 Academy of Management Review January
Chen, M.-].. Smith, K. G., & Grimm, C. M. 1992. Action characteristics as predictors of
competitive responses. Management Science, 38: 439-455.
Coleman, ]. S. 1387. Microfoundations and macrosocial behavior. In J. C. Alexander et al.
(Eds.), The micro-macro link: 153-173. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Collis, D. J. 1991. A resource-based analysis of global competition: The case of the bearings
industry. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 49-68.
Conner, K. R. 1991. A historical comparison of resource-based theory and five schools of
thought within industrial organization economics: Do we have a new theory of the firm?
Journal of Management, 17: 121-154.
Conner. K. R. 1994. The resource-based challenge to the industry-structure perspective.
Academy of Management Best Paper Proceedings: 17-21.
Cool, K., & Dierickx, I 1993. Rivalry, strategic group and firm profitability. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 14: 47-59.
Cool, K., & Schendel, D. 1987. Strategic group formation and performance: The case of the
U.S. pharmaceutical industry, 1963-1982. Management Science, 33: 1102-1124.
D'Aveni, R. 1994. Hypercompetition: Managing the dynamics of strategic maneuvering. New
York: Free Press.
Day, G. S. 1981. Strategic market analysis and definition: An integrated approach. Strategic
Management Journal, 2: 281-299.
Dess, G. G., & Robinson, R. B., Jr. 1984. Mecsuring organizational performance in the ab-
sence of objective measures: The case of the privately-held firm and conglomerate
business unit. Strategic Management Journal, 5: 265-273.
Dierickx, 1., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive
advantage. Management Science, 35: 1504-1511.
Dautton, J. E., & Jackson, S. B. 1987. Categorizing strategic issues: Links to organizational
action. Academy of Management Review, 12: 76-90.
Edwards, C. D. 1955. Conglomerate bigness as a source of power. Business concentration
and price policy: 331-352. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Making fast strategic decisions in high velocity environments. Acad-
emy of Management Journal, 32; 533-576.
Eliashberg, ]., & Chatterjee, R. 1985. Analytical models of competition with implications for
marketing: Issues, findings and outlook. Journal of Marketing Research, 22: 237-261.
Evans, W. N., & Kessides, I. N. 1994. Living by the "golden rule”: Multimarket contact in the
U.S. airline industry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109: 341-366.
Fiegenbaum, A., & Thomas, H. 19%0. Strategic groups and performance: The U.S. insurance
industry. Strategic Management Journal, 11: 197-215.
mutual forbearance hypothesis in the U.S. airline industry. 1984-1988. Unpublished doc-
toral dissertation, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN.
Gimeno, I., & Woo, C. Y. In press. Hypercompetition in a multimarket environment. The role
of strategic similarity and multimarket contact on competitive de-escalation. Organi-
zation Science.
Glemet, F., & Mira, R. 1993. The brand leader's dilemma. The McKinsey Quarterly, Summer:
3-16.
Hamel, G., & Prahalad, C. K. 1990. Strategic intent. The McKinsey Quarterly. Spring: 36-61.
Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. 1989. Organizational ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Uni-
versity Press.
Harrigan, K. R. 1979, Strategies for declining businesses. Unpublished doctoral dissertation,
Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.
Harrigan, K. R. 1985. An application of clustering for strategic group andlysis. Strategic
Management Journal. 6: 55-73.
Hatten, K. J., & Hatten, M. L. 1987. Strategic groups. asymmetrical mobility barriers and
contestability. Strategic Management Journal, 8: 329-342.
Hatten, K. J., Schendel, D. E., & Cooper, A. C. 1978. A strategic model of the U.S. brewing
industry: 1952-1971. Academy of Management Journal, 21: 592-610.
Heil, O., & Robertson, T. S. 1991. Toward a theory of competitive market signaling: A re-
search agenda. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 403-418.
Helfat, C. 1934. Firm-specificity in corporate applied R&D. Organization Science, 5: 173-184.
Henderson, R., & Cockburn, 1. 1934, Measuring competence? Exploring firm effects in phar-
maceutical research. Strategic Management Journal. 15: 63-84.
Hotelling, H. 1929. Stability of competition. Economic Journal. 39: 41-57.
Jacobson, R. 1992. The “Austrian” school of strategy. Academy of Management Review, 17:
782-807.
Karnani, A., & Wernerfelt, B. 1985. Multiple point competition. Strategic Management Jour-
nal, 6: 87-96.
Kiesler, S., & Sproull, L. 1982. Managerial response to changing environments: Perspectives
on problem sensing from social cognition. Administrative Science Quarterly. 27: 548—
570.
Kotler, P., & Armstrong, G. 1989. Principles of marketing. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Lant, T. K., Milliken, F. I., & Batra, B. 1992. The role of managerial learning and interpre-
tation in strategic persistence and reorientation. Strategic Management Journal, 13:
585-608.
Lehmann, D. R., & Winer, R. W. 1990. Analysis for marketing planning. Homewood, IL:
Trwin.
Lieberman, M. B., & Montgomery, D. B. 1988, First-mover advantages. Strategic Manage-
‘ment Journal. 9: 41-58.
Ma. H.. & Jemison, D. 1934. Effects of spheres of influence and differentials in firm resources
and capabilities on the intensity of rivalry in multiple market competition. Paper pre-
sented at the annual meeting of the Academy of Management, Dallas, TX.
MacMillan, 1. C. 1982. Seizing competitive initiative. Journal of Business Strategy. 2(4): 43—
57.
MacMillan, 1. C., McCaffery, M. L., & van Wijk, G. 1985. Competitor's responses to easily
imitated new products: Exploring commercial banking product introductions. Strategic
Management Journal, 6: 75-86.
132 Academy of Management Review January
Mahoney, ., & Pandian, J. 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of stra-
tegic management. Strategic Management Journal., 13: 363-380.
McGee, J., & Thomas, H. 1986. Strategic groups: Theory, research. and taxonomy. Strategic
Management Journal, 7: 141-160.
McGrath, R., MacMillan, L. C., & Venkataraman, S. 1995. Defining and developing compe-
tence: A strategy process paradigm. Strategic Management Journal, 16: 251-275.
Miller, D., & Chen, M.-]. 1994, Sources and consequences of competitive inertia: A study of
the U.S. airline industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39: 1-23.
Mondey, J., Cook, ., Hooks, M. ., & Chant, C. 1987. The encyclopedia of the world’s com-
mercial and private aircraft. New York: Crescent Books.
Montgomery, C. A. 1985. Product diversification and market power. Academy of Manage-
ment Journal, 28: 789-798.
Nayyar, P. 1933. One the measurement of competitive strategy: Evidence from a large mul-
tiproduct U.S. firm. Academy of Management Journal, 36: 1652 1669.
Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Wiley.
Peteraf, M. A. 1993a. The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view.
Strategic Management Journal, 14: 179-191.
Peterat, M. A. 1993b. Intraindustry structure and response toward rivals. Journal of Mana-
gerial and Decision Economics, 14: 519-528.
Pieffer, ]. 1982. Organizations and organization theory. Cambridge, MA: Harper & Row.
Pleffer, ]. 1987. A resource dependence perspective on intercorporate relations. In M. S.
Mizruchi & M. Schwartz (Eds.), Intercorporate relations: The structure analysis of busi-
ness: 25-55. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Pletfer, ., & Salancik, G. R. 1978. The external control of organizations: A resource depen-
dence perspective. New York: Harper & Row.
Porac, J. F.. & Thomas, H. 1990. Taxonomic mental models in competitor definition. Acad-
emy of Management Review. 15: 224-240.
Porac, ]. F., & Thomas, H. 1994. Cognitive categorization and subjective rivalry among
retailers in a small city. Journal of Applied Psychology. 79: 54-66.
Porter, M. E. 1973. The structure within industries and companies’ performance. Review of
Economics and Statistics, 61: 214-227.
Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competi-
tors. New York: Free Press.
Porter, M. E. 1984. Strategic interaction: Some lessons from industry histories for theory and
antitrust policy. In R. B. Lamb (Ed.), Competitive strategic management: 415-445. En-
glewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive advantage: Creating and sustaining superior performance.
New York: Free Press.
Porter, M. E. 1991. Towards a dynamic theory of strategy. Strategic Management Journal,
[Special issue] 12: 95-118.
Porter, M. E. 1992. The competitive advantage of nations. New York: Free Press.
Prescott, I. E., & Smith, D. C. 1987. A project-based approach to competitive analysis. Stra-
tegic Management Journal, 8: 411-423.
Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. 1990. Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable
competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review. 15: 88-102.
Reger, R. K., & Huff, A. S. 1993. Strategic groups: A cognitive perspective. Strategic Man-
agement Journal. 14: 103-124.
19% Chen 133
Rumelt, R. P. 1974. Strategy. structure and economic performance. Boston: Harvard Univer-
sity Press.
Rumelt, R. P. 1984. Toward a strategic theory of the firm. In R. Lamb (Ed.), Competitive
strategic management: 556-570. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Schelling, T. C. 1960. The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Scherer, F. M., & Ross, D. 19%0. Industrial market structure and economic performance.
Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Schuler, R. S., & Jackson, S. E. 1987. Linking competitive strategies with human resource
management practices. Academy of Management Executive, 1: 207-219.
Schwab, D. P. 1980. Construct validity in organizational behavior. In B. M. Staw & L. L.
Cummings (Eds.), Research in organizational behavior, vol. 2: 3-43. Greenwich, CT: JAI
Press.
Scott, J. T. 1982. Multimarket contact and economic performance. Review of Economics and
Statistics, 64: 368-375.
Smith, K. G., Grimm, C. M., & Gannon, M. ]. 1992. Dynamics of competitive strategy. New-
bury Park, CA: Sage.
Smith, K. G., Grimm, C. M., Gannon, M. J., & Chen, M.-. 1931. Organizational information
processing, competitive responses and performance in the U.S. domestic irline indus-
try. Academy of Management Journal, 34: 60-85.
Smith, F. L., & Wilson, R. L. 1995. The predictive validity of the Karnani and Wernerfelt
model of multipoint competition. Strategic Management Journal, 16: 143-160.
Snow, C., & Hambrick, D. C. 1980. Measurirg organizational strategies: Some theoretical
and methodological problems. Academy of Management Review, 5: 527-538.
Strebel, P. ]. 1983. The stock market and competitive analysis. Strategic Management Jour-
nal, 4: 279-291.
Taneja, N. K. 1989. Introduction to civil aviation. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
Teece, D. ]., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1991. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management.
Working paper, University of California, Berkeley.
Teece, D. ]., Rumelt, R., Dosi, G., & Winter, S. 1994. Understanding corporate coherence:
Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 23: 1-30.
Tversky, A. 1977. Features of similarity. Psychological Review, 84: 327-352.
Venkatraman, N., & Grant, J. H. 1986. Construct measurement in organizational research: A
critique and proposal. Academy of Management Review. 11: 71-87.
Weigelt, K., & MacMillan, I. C. 1988. An interactive strategic analysis framework. Strategic
Management Journal. [Special issue] 8: 27-40.
Weitz, B. A. 1985. Introduction to special issue on competition in marketing. Journal of
Marketing Research, 22: 229-236.
Wemnerfelt, B. 1984. A resource based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal. 5:
171-180.
Wernerfelt, B., & Karnani, A. 1987. Competitive strategy under uncertainty. Strategic Man-
agement Journal, 8: 187-194.
Wilke, J. R. 1990. Push into PCs: NCR is revamping its computer lines in wrenching change.
Wall Street Journal, June 20: Al, A8.
Winter, S. G. 1987. Knowledge and competence as strategic assets. In D. J. Teece (Ed.), The
competitive challenge: 159-184. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
134 Academy of Management Review January
Young, G., Smith, K. G., & Grimm, C. M. In press. Antecedents of firm-level competitive
activity and performance: Austrian and industrial organization perspectives. Organi-
zation Science.
Young, M. A. 1987, Sources of competitive data for the management strategist. Strategic
Management Journal, 10: 285-293.
Zahra, S. A., & Chaples, S. S. 1993. Blind spots in competitive analysis. Academy of Man-
agement Executive, 7(2): 7-28.
Zajac, E. 1., & Bazerman, M. H. 1991. Blind spots in industry and competitor analysis: Im-
plications of interfirm (mis)perception to strategic decisions. Academy of Management
Review, 16: 37-46.
Ming-Jer Chen received his Ph.D. from the University of Maryland. He is an associ-
ate professor in the Division of Management of Organizations at the Graduate
School of Business, Columbia University. His research interests include organiza-
tional strategy, competitive dynamics, competitor analysis, and global competition.