Bovis 2005
Bovis 2005
By Christopher Bovis
© Christopher Bovis 2005
Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 2005 978-1-4039-3607-3
All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this
publication may be made without written permission.
No paragraph of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted
save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the
Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence
permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, 90
Tottenham Court Road, London W1T 4LP.
Any person who does any unauthorised act in relation to this publication
may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages.
The author has asserted his right to be identified as the author
of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and
Patents Act 1988.
First published 2005 by
PALGRAVE MACMILLAN
Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS and
175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N. Y. 10010
Companies and representatives throughout the world
PALGRAVE MACMILLAN is the global academic imprint of the Palgrave
Macmillan division of St. Martin’s Press, LLC and of Palgrave Macmillan Ltd.
Macmillan® is a registered trademark in the United States, United Kingdom
and other countries. Palgrave is a registered trademark in the European
Union and other countries.
ISBN 978-1-349-51836-4 ISBN 978-0-230-50144-7 (eBook)
DOI 10.1057/9780230501447
This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully
managed and sustained forest sources.
A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Bovis, Christopher.
Public procurement in the European Union / by Christopher Bovis.
p. cm.
Includes bibliographical references and index.
1. Government purchasing–Law and legislation–European Union
countries. 2. Public contracts–European Union countries. I. Title.
KJE5632.B687 2005
346.2402′3–dc22 2005042933
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
14 13 12 11 10 09 08 07 06 05
to Pine
for taking care of business
This page intentionally left blank
Contents
Foreword xix
Introduction 1
The emergence of public markets and their interface with 1
the common market
The public policy dimension in public procurement 5
Regionalism and public procurement 6
The industrial policy potential in public procurement 9
Public procurement and defence 10
vii
viii Contents
Conclusions 237
Notes 241
Index 287
This page intentionally left blank
Cases before the European Court of
Justice
C-13/68, SpA Salgoil v. Italian Ministry for Foreign Trade [1968] ECR 453.
C-14/68, Wilhem v. Bundeskartellampt [1969] ECR 1 at 27.
xiii
xiv Cases before the European Court of Justice
C-74/76, Ianelli & Volpi Spa v. Ditta Paola Meroni [1977] 2 CMLR 688.
xix
xx Foreword
Introduction
The definition of public procurement is a complex one. It depicts a
series of practices and government actions interacting with public
policy. Public procurement could be best described as the supply chain
system for the acquisition of all necessary goods, works and services
by the state and its organs when acting in pursuit of public interest.
Public procurement constitutes a significant modus operandi in the
public sector arena and it stands as the procedural prerequisite for
the delivery of public services. Apart from reasons relating to account-
ability in public expenditure, avoidance of corruption and political
manipulation, the regulation of public procurement within the
European legal and political systems has acquired a multi-disciplined
dimension. The regulation of public procurement, does not only repre-
sent a best practice in the delivery of public service by the state and its
organs, it most importantly qualifies as an instrument of policy. The
spill-over effects from the deployment of a particular strategy relevant
to the procurement practices of the public sector will have significant
implications for national and international trade patterns as it can
be detrimental to any economic and political integration process a
European Union state is committed to.
contractor, and then the only way to effectively partition the relevant
market would be by reference to its geographical remit. In contrast, as
far as private markets are concerned, the segmentation of the relevant
market (either product or geographical) can only be attributed to
the supply side. The argument goes further to reveal the fact that the
balance of powers between the supply and the demand side are
reversed when superimposed on private or public markets. In the latter,
it is the demand side that has the dominant role in the equation by
dictating terms and conditions in purchases, initiation of transactions,
as well as by influencing production trends (supplies, works and ser-
vices destined for the public sector tend to shift from the traditional
inventory pattern of production to a custom made/built by order one).14
In public markets, concerted practices of the demand side (e.g.
excluding foreign competition, application of buy-national policies,
and application of national standards policies) represent geographical
market segmentation, as they result in the division of the European
public markets into different national public markets. It could also be
maintained that public markets are subject to protection rather than
restriction from competition, to the extent that the latter are quasi-
monopolistic and monopsonistic in their structure. Indeed, the state
and its organs, as contractors possess a monopoly position in the sense
that no one competes against them in their market activities.15 Even in
cases of privatisation, the monopoly position is shifted from the public
to private hands. The situation is slightly different in cases of an open
privatised regime pursuing an operation of public interest. In that case,
it would be more appropriate to refer to oligopolistic competition in
the relevant market. Also in privatised regimes, interchangeability of
supply is very limited, to an extent that monopoly position character-
istics survive the transfer of ownership from public to private hands.
The state and its organs also possess a monopsony position, as firms
engaged in transactions with them have no alternatives to pursue busi-
ness. Access barriers to geographical public markets are erected by
states by means of exercising their discretion to conclude contracts
with national undertakings. This sort of activity constitutes the parti-
tion of public markets in the Community, whereas, apparently, under-
takings operating in private markets must enter into a restrictive
agreement between themselves in order to split up the relevant mar-
kets. Due to their different integral nature, private and public markets
require different control. The control in both cases has a strong public
law character, but while anti-trust regulates private markets, it appears
rather inappropriate for public ones. Anti-trust law and policy is a set
European Integration and Public Procurement 21
That strategy was based on two principal assumptions: the first as-
sumption acknowledged the fact that in order to eliminate preferential
and discriminatory purchasing practices in European public markets, a
great deal of transparency and openness was needed; the second assump-
tion rested on the premise that the only way to regulate public pro-
curement in the Member States in an effective manner was through
the process of harmonisation of existing laws and administrative prac-
tices which had been in operation, and not through a uniform regula-
tory pattern which would replace all existing laws and administrative
practices throughout the Community. The latter assumption indirectly
recognised the need for a decentralised system of regulation for public
procurement in the Community, well ahead of the pronouncement of
the principle of subsidiarity, which was introduced in the European law
jargon some years later by virtue of the Maastricht Treaty on European
Union.
Since harmonisation was adopted as the most appropriate method of
regulation of public procurement in the common market, and the
decentralised character of the regime was reinforced through legisla-
tion, the onus then was shifted to the national administrations of the
Member States, which had to implement the Community principles
into domestic law and give a certain degree of clarity and legitimate
expectation to interested parties. Occasionally, the European Commis-
sion is criticised for not having central powers in order to enforce
public procurement rules, in addition to those already available to it as
the guardian of the Treaty. The critics often refer to the applicability
of competition law and policy of the European Community and the
regime which legally implements it through specific Regulations.
However, although in principle competition law of the European
Community may apply to the award of public contracts,22 the effective-
ness and efficiency of a regulatory regime in the public markets through
basic anti-trust remedies remains a challenge for the law and policy
maker. A rigid regime which is applied through a uniform way across
the common market cannot take into account national particularities
in public procurement. It would probably eliminate any elements
of flexibility envisaged to compensate for the sensitivities arising out
of national legal and policy orders. Public procurement, as the nexus of
transactions in the supply chain of the public sector, does not differ in
principle with the management of purchasing practices in the private
sector, which remains unregulated.
The legal instruments opted for by European institutions to
achieve the objective of flexibility are Directives. Public markets and
European Integration and Public Procurement 27
Introduction
The regulation of public procurement in the European Union intends
to insert a regime of competitiveness in the relevant markets and elim-
inate all non-tariff barriers to intra-community trade that emanate
from preferential purchasing practices favouring national undertak-
ings. Apart from the obvious reasons relating to accountability in
public expenditure, avoidance of corruption and political manipula-
tion, the regulation of public procurement does not only represent a
best practice in the delivery of public service by the state and its
organs, it most importantly qualifies as an instrument of policy.
The existing public procurement regime can be classified into
the public supplies sector,1 the public works sector,2 the public utili-
ties sector3 (entities operating in the water, energy, transport and
telecommunications sectors) and the public services sector. 4 Along-
side the substantive regime, two Compliance Directives provide for
review procedures at domestic levels in relation to public and utilities
procurement respectively.
Utilities procurement
The Utilities Directive 93/38 covers supplies, works and services con-
tracts between a supplier, contractor or service provider and a public
Public Procurement Regulation 39
Procurement of services
The Public Services 92/50 covers contracts between a service provider
(natural or legal persons) and a contracting authority, having as their
objective the provision of services, as defined in the United Nations
Nomenclature of Product and Service Classification.
Under the Services Directive, public services contracts are contracts
which have as their object the provision of services classified in the
Common Product Classification (CPC) Nomenclature of the United
Nations, as a Nomenclature for Classification of Services at Community
level is lacking. The United Nations Common Product Classification
covers almost every conceivable service an undertaking may provide,
although the services description is rather plain.
The Services Directive is the first legal instrument which attempts
to open the increasingly important public services sector to intra-
community competition. It should be mentioned that the Directives
on Public Supplies, Public Works and Utilities contain provisions
where the provision of services is regarded as ancillary to the main
contract under their regime, provided the value of the services are less
than the value of the supplies or works. Such services are covered by
the relevant Directive.
Specific services contracts are excluded from the scope of the Services
Directive. It should be mentioned that not all of these specific exclu-
sions are listed in the amended Utilities Directive 93/38, because they
would not, in any event, fall within the ambit of a defined activity.
Public Procurement Regulation 43
Apart from those contracts which are covered by the relevant provi-
sions of the Works, Supplies and Utilities Directives, and therefore not
considered as services, the other contracts excluded from the Services
Directive and amended Utilities Directive 93/38 are:
relevant market size for the supply side, as well as the relevant
procurement magnitude for a type of contracting authorities on
an annual basis. The fact that through PIN notices contracting
authorities produce only an estimated figure for forthcoming con-
tracts they intend to award, does not absolve them from their
responsibilities in strictly adhering to their publication.69
ii) Invitations to tender. All contracts above the relevant thresholds
should be tendered and the notice containing the invitation to
tender must include the award procedures and the award criteria
for the contract in question.70 The Invitation to tender is the most
important publicity and advertisement requirement for the cre-
ation of transparent and open public markets in the European
Community. The publication of the invitation to tender refers only
to a particular contract or a range of similar contracts of repetitive
nature and provides the supply side with the opportunity to
respond and make an offer in order to meet the needs and require-
ments of the demand side. The invitation to tender is part of
the contractual nexus in the public procurement process between
the relevant contracting authority and the tenderers/candidates
competing for the award of the contract in question. It is through
the invitation to tender that the supply side has a clear view as
to the award procedures and the award criteria contracting author-
ities intend to utilise, thus being able to respond accordingly. The
invitation to tender represents the first step towards the award
of public contracts and failure by contracting authorities to adhere
to the minimum requirements specified in the Directives could
invalidate the whole process.
iii) Contract Award Notices (CAN). This is a form of notification after
the award of the contract of the successful tenderer and the price
of its offer, as well as the reasons for its selection by the contract-
ing authority.71 In principle, Contract Award Notices publicise
the reasoning of contracting authorities during the selection and
award stages of the process, but quite often price information of
the successful tenderers and other candidates is withheld for
reasons of commercial confidentiality. The publication of CAN
notices can be used as an effective indicator in monitoring the pur-
chasing patterns of contracting authorities, as well as in providing
a picture relevant to the tradability of public contracts.
The way in which the value of a contract is calculated is crucial for the
application of the relevant Directive. To ensure that identical calcula-
tion methods are used throughout the Member States of the European
Community and to prevent intentional avoidance of the Procurement
Directives by artificially low contract valuations, the Directives lay
down specific rules.78 Where the contract is to be concluded in the
Public Procurement Regulation 53
• where its term is 12 months or less, the total value for the contract’s
duration;
• where its term exceeds 12 months, the total value for the contract’s
duration, including the estimated residual value of the products;
• where the contract is concluded for an indefinite period or where its
term cannot be defined, the monthly value multiplied by 48.
• where contracts are of a regular nature or are to be renewed over a
given period, the following must be taken into account:
– either the actual aggregate value of similar successive contracts
awarded over the previous 12 months or accounting period,
adjusted where possible for anticipated changes in quantity or
value over the subsequent 12 months;
– or the estimated aggregate value of the successive contracts con-
cluded during the 12 months following the initial delivery or
accounting periods where this exceeds 12 months. In any event,
the choice between these two valuation methods must not be
made with the intention of keeping contracts outside the scope
of the Directive.
important works. These certificates must indicate the value, date and
site of the works and must specify whether they were carried out
according to the rules of the trade and properly completed. Where nec-
essary, the competent authority must submit these certificates direct to
the authority awarding the contracts; a statement of the tools, plant
and technical equipment available to the contractor for carrying out
the work; a statement of the firm’s average annual manpower and
number of managerial staff for the last three years; a statement of the
technicians or technical divisions which the contractor can call upon
for carrying out the work, whether or not they belong to the firm.
On the other hand, in supplies contracts, the references which may
be requested81 must be mentioned in the invitation to tender and are
the following: a list of the principal deliveries effected in the past three
years, with the sums, dates and recipients, public or private, involved
in the form of certificates issued or countersigned by the competent
authority; a description of the undertaking’s technical facilities, its
measures for ensuring quality and its study and research facilities; indi-
cation of the technicians or technical bodies involved, whether or not
belonging directly to the undertaking, especially those responsible
for quality control; samples, descriptions or photographs of the prod-
ucts to be supplied, the authenticity of which must be certified if the
contracting authority so requests; certificates drawn up by official
quality-control institutes or agencies of recognised competence attest-
ing conformity to certain specifications or standards of goods clearly
identified by references to specifications or standards; where the goods
to be supplied are complex or, exceptionally, are required for a special
purpose, a check carried out by the contracting authorities (or on their
behalf by a competent official body of the country in which the sup-
plier is established, subject to that body’s agreement) on the produc-
tion capacities of the supplier and, if necessary, on his study and
research facilities and quality control measures. The provisions cover-
ing the contractors’ eligibility and technical capacity constitute an
exhaustive list.
In principle, there are automatic grounds for exclusion, 82 when a
contractor, supplier or service provider; i) is bankrupt or is being
wound up; ii) is the subject of proceedings for a declaration of bank-
ruptcy or for an order for compulsory winding up; iii) has been con-
victed for an offence concerning his professional conduct; iv) has
been guilty of grave professional misconduct; v) has not fulfilled
obligations relating to social security contributions; and vi) has not
fulfilled obligations relating to the payment of taxes.
56 Public Procurement in the European Union
without doubt and can achieve better prices for the contracting
authorities when purchasing goods in large volumes. Price reduction
based on economies of scale can bring about substantial cost savings
for the public sector. Open procedures are mostly utilised when the
procurement process is relatively straightforward and are combined
with the lowest price award criterion. On the other hand, competi-
tion in tendering procedures is limited by using the restricted and
negotiated procedures. By definition, the number of candidates that
are allowed to tender is limited (5 in restricted 3 in negotiated proce-
dures respectively), therefore the Directives have attached a number
of conditions for the contracting authorities to justify when they
intend to award their contracts through restricted or negotiated pro-
cedure. Restricted and negotiated procedures are utilised in relation
to the most economically advantageous offer award criterion and
suited for more complex procurement schemes. Although contracting
authorities can freely opt for open or restricted procedures, the latter
should be justified by reference to the nature of the products or ser-
vices to be procured and the balance between contract value and
administrative costs associated with tender evaluation. A more rigor-
ous set of conditions apply for the use of negotiated procedures.
When negotiated procedures with prior notification are used, they
must be justified on grounds of irregular or unacceptable tenders
received as a result of a previous call. Negotiated procedures without
prior notification are restrictively permitted in absence of tenders,
when the procurement involves manufactured products or construc-
tion works purely for research and development, when for technical
or artistic reasons or reasons connected with the protection of exclu-
sive rights a particular supplier or contractor is selected, in cases of
extreme urgency brought by unforseeable events not attributable to
the contracting authorities or when additional deliveries and supplies
or works would cause disproportionate technical, operational and
maintenance difficulties.
All negotiations with candidates or tenderers on fundamental aspects
of contracts, in particular on prices, are prohibited in open and res-
tricted procedures; discussions with candidates or tenderers may be
held, but only for the purpose of clarifying or supplementing the
content of their tenders or the requirements of the contracting author-
ities and provided this does not involve discriminatory practices.106
The need for such a prohibition is clear, since the possibility to negoti-
ate may allow the contracting authority to introduce subjective
appraisal criteria.
Public Procurement Regulation 61
The above list is not exhaustive and the factors listed therein serve as
a guideline for contracting authorities in the weighted evaluation
process of the contract award. The Court reiterated the flexible and
wide interpretation of the relevant award criterion 120 and had no
difficulty in declaring that contracting authorities may use the most
economically advantageous offer as award criterion by choosing the
factors which they want to apply in evaluating tenders,121 provided
these factors are mentioned, in hierarchical order or descending
sequence in the invitation to tender or the contract documents,
so tenderers and interested parties can clearly ascertain the relative
weight of factors other than price for the evaluation process. How-
ever, factors, which have no strict relevance in determining the most
economically advantageous offer by reference to objective criteria
do involve an element of arbitrary choice and therefore should be
considered as incompatible with the Directives.
Framework agreements
The Utilities Directives have introduced a new selection and tendering
procedure, namely framework agreements which is influenced to a
large extent by the benefits of chain supply management and partner-
ship schemes. The Supplies, Works and Services Directives do not refer
to framework agreements. A framework agreement is an agreement
between a contracting authority and one or more suppliers, contractors
or service-providers the purpose of which is to establish the terms, in
particular with regard to prices and, where appropriate, the quantity
envisaged, governing the contracts to be awarded during a given
period. A framework agreement does not possess binding character and
should not be considered as a contract between the relevant parties.122
In practical terms it represents a sort of a standing offer which remains
valid during its time-span. Within the provisions of the Utilities
Directive, when a contracting authority awards a framework agreement
under the relevant procedures which are common to other public con-
tracts covered therein, subsequent individual contracts concluded
under the framework agreement may be awarded without having
recourse to a call for competition. Individual contracts which have
been awarded under a framework agreement are subject to the require-
ment of the publication of a contract-award notice in the Official
Journal. The Directive specifically stipulates that misuse of framework
agreements may distort competition and trigger the application of the
relevant rules, particularly with reference to concerted practices which
lead to collusive tendering.
Public Procurement Regulation 65
Design contests
Under the Services Directive, provision has been made for a fourth type
of award procedure, namely design contests, with particular reference to
planning projects. According to the Services Directive, design contests
are those national procedures which enable the contracting authority
to acquire in the fields of area planning, town planning, architecture
and civil engineering, a plan or a design selected by a jury, after being
66 Public Procurement in the European Union
put out to competition with or without the award of prizes. The award
of design contests, according to the Services Directive must follow
specific rules. The admission of participants to the contest must not be
limited either by reference to the territory or part of a Member State, or
on the grounds that under the law of the Member State in which the
contest is organised, participants would have been required to be either
natural or legal persons. Furthermore, where design contests are
restricted to a limited number of participants, the contracting authori-
ties must lay down clear and non-discriminatory selection criteria
which ensure sufficient and genuine competition among the partici-
pants. The jury must be composed exclusively of natural persons
who are independent. The award criteria for design contests remain
the same with other public contracts (the lowest price or the most
economically advantageous offer)
Concession contracts
The Public Works Directive has adopted a special, mitigated regime for
the award of concession contracts the value of which is 5 million
EURO or more. There are no specific rules as to the way the value of
the contract must be calculated or rules referring to aggregation. For
the award of concession contracts, contracting authorities are obliged
to follow the advertising rules concerning open and restricted proce-
dures for the award of ordinary works contracts. Also, the provisions
on technical standards and on criteria for qualitative selection of
candidates and tenderers do apply. However, the Works Directive does
not prescribe the use of specific award procedures for concession con-
tracts. The Directive presupposes the concession contracts are awarded
in two rounds, such as in the case of restricted procedures or negoti-
ated procedures for works contracts. Nothing, however, prevents con-
tracting authorities from applying a one-round open procedure. The
Directive contains no rules on the minimum number of candidates
who have to be invited to negotiate or to submit a tender. It would
seem that a contracting authority may limit itself to selecting only one
single candidate, provided the intention to award a concession con-
tract has been adequately published. A contracting authority may
under no circumstances refrain from publishing a notice.
Socio-economic considerations
In Beentjes,124 the Court ruled that social policy considerations and in
particular measures aiming at the combating of long term unemploy-
ment could only be part of the award criteria of public contracts, espe-
cially in cases where the most economically advantageous offer is
selected. The Court accepted that the latter award criterion contains
features that are not exhaustively defined in the Directives, therefore
there is discretion conferred on contracting authorities to specify what
would the most economically advantageous offer for them. However,
contracting authorities cannot refer to such measures as a selection cri-
terion and disqualify candidates who could not meet the relevant
requirements. The selection of tenderers is a process which is based on
an exhaustive list of technical and financial requirements expressly
stipulated in the relevant Directives and the insertion of contract com-
pliance as a selection and qualification requirement would be consid-
ered ultra vires. The Court held that a contractual condition relating to
the employment of long term unemployed persons is compatible with
the Public Procurement Directives, if it has no direct or indirect dis-
criminatory effect on tenders from other Member States. Furthermore,
such a contractual condition must be mentioned in the tender
notice.125 Rejection of a contract on the grounds of a contractor’s
inability to employ long-term unemployed persons has no relation
to the checking of the contractor’s suitability on the basis of his
economic and financial standing and his technical knowledge and
ability. The Court maintained that measures relating to employment
could be utilised as a feature of the award criteria, only when they are
part of a contractual obligation of the public contract in question and
68 Public Procurement in the European Union
the external bidder (if successful) must engage the authority’s former
employees on the same conditions as they enjoyed under the authority
itself.
The initial Directive proclaimed its inapplicability in cases where
the undertaking was not in the nature of a commercial venture; this
proviso was interpreted as exclusive of contracting out by government.
The impact of the transfer of undertakings Directive in the context of
public procurement was felt in a landmark decision of the Court,128
which maintained that the Directive does not permit such a limitation.
Thus it became apparent that contracting out by government and
other public authorities was covered, and a transfer of an undertaking
may take place where the government contracts out to the private
sector a function previously carried out in-house129 and vice versa, viz.
where the contracting authority takes back in-house a service formerly
contracted out. The exact circumstance in which a transfer of an
undertaking through contracting out occurs depends upon the transfer
retaining its identity.130 However, the “retention of identity” test can
only be satisfied when the undertaking transferred represents substan-
tially the same or similar activities,131 as well as it relates to a stable eco-
nomic entity.132 The existence of a contractual link or relation between
the parties to a transfer of an undertaking is not a decisive criterion to
establish the applicability of the Directive.133
Serious concerns have been raised over the compatibility of the
public procurement and the transfer of undertakings regimes. It
appeared that there was a clear antithesis between the drivers of two
regimes in achieving savings on the one hand, whilst protecting
employees on the other. However, the Liikenne134 case confirmed the
compatibility of the two regimes.135 The Court’s jurisprudence relat-
ing to the applicability of transfer of undertakings to public procure-
ment has positioned transfers amongst contractual terms and
conditions of a contract, thus obliging contracting authorities to
inform tenderers appropriately, so the latter can factor all relevant
financial consequences to their bid.
Introduction
Subjecting the public procurement legal framework to the scrutiny of
the European Court of Justice has revealed a distinctive pattern. This
pattern is reflected in the Court’s judgements and embraces two
approaches: a positive and at the same time a restrictive interpretation
of the regime. Although at first sight the stance taken by the European
judiciary may seem contradictory, the Court’s bi-focal approach, serves
the European institution’s efforts to strengthen the three principles
(non-discrimination, objectivity and transparency) underlying the regu-
lation of public procurement.1 It is worth mentioning the emphasis
that the legal regime has placed in pursuing these principles in the pre-
amble of the Works Directive …it is necessary to improve and extend the
safeguards in the directives that are designed to introduce transparency into
the procedures and practices for the award of such contracts, in order to be
able to monitor compliance with the prohibition of restrictions more closely
and at the same time to reduce disparities in the competitive conditions faced
by nationals of different Member States.
The positive approach of the Court comprises its attempts to eliminate
discrimination and non-tariff barriers in the fields of technical standards
(product specification and standardisation) and the selection procedures
(quantitative and qualitative suitability criteria). The Court’s jurispru-
dential positivism through the observance of non-discrimination and
objectivity principles epitomises the integral role of public procurement
in the attainment of the fundamental principles of the Treaty, specifically
the right of establishment and the freedom to provide services. On
the other hand, the Court’s restrictive approach serves the principle of
objectivity, with particular reference to the use of the award procedures.
71
72 Public Procurement in the European Union
Award criteria
Two criteria laid down in the Public Procurement Directives provide
the conditions under which contracting authorities award public
contracts: the lowest price or the most economically advantageous
offer.31
The first criterion indicates that, subject to the qualitative criteria
and financial and economic standing, contracting authorities do not
rely on any other factor than the price quoted to complete the con-
tract. The tenderer who submits the cheapest offer must be awarded
the contract. It should be mentioned that the Directives provide for an
automatic disqualification of an “obviously abnormally low offer”. The
term has not been interpreted in detail by the Court and serves rather
as an indication of a “lower bottom limit”.32 The Court, however,
pronounced on the direct effect of the relevant provision requiring
contracting authorities to examine the details of the tender before
deciding the award of the contract. The contracting authorities are
under duty to seek from the tenderer an explanation for the price sub-
mitted or to inform him that his tender appears to be abnormally low
and to allow a reasonable time within which to submit further details,
before making any decision as to the award of the contract.
The debate over the terminology of “obviously abnormally low”
tenders surfaced when the Court held 33 that rejection of a contract
based on mathematical criteria without giving the tenderer an
opportunity to furnish information is inconsistent with spirit of the
Public Procurement Directives. The Court following previous case-
law, 34 ruled that the contracting authorities must give an opportu-
nity to tenderers to furnish explanations regarding the genuine
nature of their tenders, when those tenders appear to be abnormally
low. Unfortunately, the Court did not proceed to an analysis of
the wording “obviously”. It rather seems that the term “obviously”
indicates the existence of precise and concrete evidence as to the
80 Public Procurement in the European Union
maintenance costs and security of supplies. The above list is not exhaus-
tive and the factors listed therein serve as a guideline for contracting
authorities in the weighted evaluation process of the contract award. The
Court reiterated the flexible and wide interpretation of the relevant
award criterion39 and had no difficulty in declaring that contracting
authorities may use the most economically advantageous offer as award
criterion by choosing the factors which they want to apply in evaluating
tenders,40 provided these factors are mentioned, in hierarchical order or
descending sequence in the invitation to tender or the contract docu-
ments,41 so tenderers and interested parties can clearly ascertain the rela-
tive weight of factors other than price for the evaluation process.
However, factors, which have no strict relevance in determining the
most economically advantageous offer by reference to objective criteria
do involve an element of arbitrary choice and therefore should be
considered as incompatible with the Directives.42
A question whether, under the most economically advantageous
offer, each individual award factor has to provide an economic advant-
age which directly benefits the contracting authority, or it is sufficient
that each individual factor has to be measurable in economic terms,
without the requirement that it directly provides an economic advant-
age for the contracting authority in the given contract was put before
the Court in Concordia.43 Through the second interpretation, the
discretion conferred to contracting authorities would permit a wide
range of factors to feature as part of award criteria in public contracts,
without the need to demonstrate a direct economic advantage to a
contracting authority which is attributable to each of these factors.
On the contrary, if each individual factor has to establish a measurable
(in quantifiable terms) economic advantage to the contracting author-
ity, which is directly attributed to its inclusion as part of the award cri-
terion, the discretion of contracting authorities is curtailed, since they
would be required to undertake and publicise in the tender or contract
documents a clear cost-benefit analysis of the relevant factors that
comprise in their view the most economically advantageous offer.
This question intended to provide guidance in order to assess the
integral function of the factors that comprise the most economically
advantageous offer for contracting authorities. Although there is wide
discretion conferred to them in compiling the relevant factors, subject
to the requirements of relevance to the contract in question and their
publicity, their relative importance, in economic terms, remains some-
how unknown. Unfortunately, the Court did not clarify the relevant
points.
82 Public Procurement in the European Union
the state, nor all criteria for the definition of bodies governed by public
law are present. This is particularly the case of non-governmental organ-
isations (NGOs) which operate under the auspices of the central or local
government and are responsible for public interest functions.52 The
Court addressed the lex lacuna through its landmark case Beentjes.53
The Court diluted the rigorous definition of contracting authorities for
the purposes of public procurement law, by introducing a functional
dimension of the state and its organs. In particular, it considered that a
local land consolidation committee with no legal personality, but with its
functions and compositions specifically governed by legislation, part of
the state. The Court interpreted the term contracting authorities in func-
tional terms and considered the local land consolidation committee,
falling within the notion of state, even though it was not part of the
state administration in formal terms.54 The committee in question
depended on the relevant public authorities for the appointment of its
members and its operations were subject to their supervision and it had
as its main task the financing and award of public works contracts.
The Court in two recent cases applied the functionality test when
requested to determine the nature of entities which could not meet the
criteria of bodies governed by public law, but had a distinctive public
interest remit. In Teoranta,55 a private company established according
to national legislation to carry out business of forestry and related
activities was deemed as falling within the notion of the state. The
company was set up by the state and was entrusted with specific tasks
of public interest, such as managing national forests and woodland
industries, as well as providing recreation, sporting, educational,
scientific and cultural facilities. It was also under decisive administra-
tive, financial and management control by the state, although the day-
to-day operations were left entirely to its board. The Court accepted
that since the state had at least indirect control over the Teoranta’s
policies, in functional terms the latter was part of the state. In the
Vlaamese Raad,56 the Flemish parliament of the Belgian federal system
was considered part of the “federal” state. The Court held that the
definition of the state encompasses all bodies, which exercise legisla-
tive, executive and judicial powers, at both regional and federal levels.
The Raad, as a legislative body of the Belgian state, although under no
direct control by it, was held as falling within the definition of the
state and thus being regarded as a contracting authority. The fact that
the Belgian Government did not, at the time, exercise any direct or
indirect control relating to procurement policies the Vlaamese Raad
was considered immaterial on the grounds that a state cannot rely
Lessons from Jurisprudence 85
relating to public order to define the term needs in the general inter-
est.66 The Court approached the above concept by a direct analogy of
the concept “general economic interest”, as defined in Article 90(2)
EC.67 The concept “general interest” denotes the requirements of a
community (local or national) in its entirety, which should not
overlap with the specific or exclusive interest of a clearly determined
person or group of persons.68 However, the problematic concept of
the specificity of the establishment of the body in question was
approached by reference to the reasons and the objectives behind its
establishment. Specificity of the purpose of an establishment does
not mean exclusivity, in the sense that other types of activities can
be carried out without escaping classification as a body governed by
public law.69
On the other hand, the requirement of non-commercial or industrial
character of needs in the general interest has raised some difficulties.
The Court had recourse to case-law and legal precedence relating to
public undertakings, where the nature of industrial and commercial
activities of private or public undertakings was defined.70 The industrial
or commercial character of an organisation depends much upon a
number of criteria that reveal the thrust behind the organisation’s par-
ticipation in the relevant market. The state and its organs may act
either by exercising public powers or by carrying economic activities of
an industrial or commercial nature by offering goods and services on
the market. The key issue is the organisation’s intention to achieve
profitability and pursue its objectives through a spectrum of commer-
cially motivated decisions. The distinction between the range of activ-
ities which relate to public authority and those which, although
carried out by public persons, fall within the private domain is drawn
most clearly from case-law and judicial precedence of the Court con-
cerning the applicability of competition rules of the Treaty to the given
activities.71
The Court in BFI72 had the opportunity to clarify the element of non-
commercial or industrial character. It considered that the relationship
of the first criterion of bodies governed by public law is an integral
one. The non-commercial or industrial character is a criterion intended
to clarify the term needs in the general interest. In fact, it is regarded as
a category of needs of general interest. The Court recognised that there
might be needs of general interest, which have an industrial and com-
mercial character and it is possible that private undertakings can meet
needs of general interest which do not have industrial and commercial
character. The acid test for needs in the general interest not having an
90 Public Procurement in the European Union
there was a clear antithesis between the drivers of two regimes in achiev-
ing savings on the one hand, whilst protecting employees on the other.
However, the Liikenne100 case, confirmed the compatibility of the two
regimes.101 The Court’s jurisprudence relating to the applicability of trans-
fer of undertakings to public procurement has positioned transfers
amongst contractual terms and conditions of a contract, thus obliging
contracting authorities to inform tenderers appropriately, so the latter
can factor all relevant financial consequences to their bid.
Introduction
The regulation of public procurement in the European Union has been
significantly influenced by the internal market project. The White
Paper for the Completion of the Internal Market1 and the Single
European Act represent the conceptual foundations of the regulation
of public markets of the Member States. The identification of public
procurement as a major non-tariff barrier has revealed the economic
importance of its regulation.2 Savings and price convergence appeared
as the main arguments for liberalising the trade patterns of the
demand (the public and utilities sectors) and supply (the industry) side
of the public procurement equation.3 The economic approach to
the regulation of public procurement aims at the integration of public
markets across the EU. Through the principles of transparency, non-
discrimination and objectivity in the award of public contracts, it is
envisaged that the regulatory system will bring about competitiveness
in the relevant product and geographical markets, will increase import
penetration of products and services destined for the public sector, will
enhance the tradability of public contracts across the common market,
will result in significant price convergence and finally it will be the
catalyst for the needed rationalisation and industrial restructuring of
the European industrial base.4
Parallel with the economic arguments, legal arguments emerged
supporting the regulation of public procurement as a necessary ingredi-
ent of the fundamental principles of the Treaties such as the free move-
ment of goods and services, the right of establishment and the
prohibition of discrimination on nationality grounds.5 The legal
significance of the regulation of public procurement in the common
100
Public Procurement as Economic and Policy Exercise 101
the sui generis nature of public markets and has provided ground for
developing a regulatory system which is strongly influenced by neo-
classical economics, whilst at the same time integrating the relevant
market. Such a system has also strong public law characteristics, to
the extent that it has been branded as droit public de la concurrence.45
A rule of reason
In European Union law, the rule of reason serves as an expansion of
the determined exemptions from a prohibition principle.73 The rule
of reason is a juridical development where the Court interprets the
margins of discretion allotted to an executive authority (Member
States and/or the Commission), as well as the grounds, the limits
and the levels of deviation from a prohibition’s exemptions. For
public procurement, a rule of reason has emerged through the appli-
cation of the most economically advantageous offer criterion. The
Court, through a steady accumulation of case-law adopted a bi-focal
stance: positive yet restrictive. Where the rules allow for discretion,
the Court did not claw back any margin of appreciation from
Member States and their contracting authorities; in fact, in many
instances, it gradually expanded the grounds of flexibility in the
award procedures.
The meaning of the most economically advantageous offer includes
a series of factors chosen by the contracting authority, including price,
delivery or completion date, running costs, cost-effectiveness, profit-
ability, technical merit, product or work quality, aesthetic and func-
tional characteristics, after-sales service and technical assistance,
commitment with regard to spare parts and components and mainte-
nance costs, security of supplies. The above list is not exhaustive and
118 Public Procurement in the European Union
collusive behaviour and the pricing policies that could emerge from
oligopolistic structure. 81 Conspiratorial practices of oligopolists
which supply the public sector could possibly lead to high prices,
perhaps higher than those prior to the restructuring and adjustment
exercise. Furthermore, even if prices of goods, works and services
destined for the public sector would converge and settle at a higher
level, this could result in supra-competitive profits for the oligopo-
lists at the expense of the demand side. Another dimension of the
concentration and oligopolisation of public markets reflects consid-
erable socio-economic considerations. If one is to accept that in-
dustrial restructuring and adjustment emanate from the need to
eliminate sub-optimal overcapacity, the factor of production which
would be affected most is labour. Redundancies and reduction
of workforce often follow market concentration in an attempt to
minimise duplication, or to achieve rationalisation.
It is important here to distinguish high technology industries sup-
plying public procurement markets from more “traditional” ones.
The high-tech group of industries is characterised by strong techno-
logical developments and reinvestment of a considerable amount on
research and development. Such industries include telecommunica-
tions, data-processing equipment, medical equipment, bio-tech and
pharmaceutical products and aerospace. These industries have been
demarcated by high cross-country investment patterns, with an
important presence of Japanese and American interests.82 The group
of traditional industries supplying public procurement markets
includes industries dealing with railway equipment, heavy steel
structures, shipbuilding, vehicles and textiles. Most of these indus-
tries have been national champions 83 and heavily protected from
competition and sustained through public sector purchasing. 84 The
high-tech public procurement industry has a tendency to operate in
several national public procurement markets, thus having a large
share of European production. This could be explained by the high
levels of concentration observed for such industries over the last
decade.85 On the other hand, traditional public procurement indus-
tries have a strong tendency to operate at national level and enjoy
the advantages of being national champions.
The second inherent threat of the process of integrating the public
markets of the European Community reveals the vulnerable position
of small and medium size firms as a consequence of their exposure
to the new regime. Small and medium firms would find it difficult
to sustain existing market shares or penetrate product or geographi-
Public Procurement as Economic and Policy Exercise 123
Introduction
The process of the liberalisation of public procurement in the European
Union has two primary objectives: i) to achieve an open and competitive
regime of public purchasing which would yield substantial savings to the
public sector and ii) to act as a stimulant for the much needed restructur-
ing and adjustment of the European industrial base. When compared
with other advanced integrated economic or political systems, the regula-
tion of public procurement in the European Union has no precedence.
It is not only the aspiration for the creation of a genuinely integrated
public sector market within the Community, but to a large extent it is the
impact of such a regime upon the overall process of European Integration
that deserves further attention. The mechanism of the public purchasing
regulation has revealed a considerable range of socio-economic considera-
tions which interact with the envisaged aims and objectives of the
regime. The public procurement sector in the European Union is by no
means readily receptive to the parameters of any legislative framework.
Rather, it is a forum of well-established socio-economic and legal patterns
which for a long time have served national interests.
One should not expect a dramatic and unprecedented transformation
of the way public procurement has been conducted in the Member
States of the European Union, for two main reasons. Firstly, what has
been asked by European law and policy on public procurement repre-
sents a significant change of the modus operandi of contracting authori-
ties, which quite often have regarded the European rules as a burden.
The unwillingness of public authorities to change well established public
purchasing patterns and practices not only does reflect their reservations
over the financial implications of such an exercise, but mostly their
124
A Critical Assessment of Public Procurement 125
improper use of the award procedures, the Court has maintained the
exceptional character of negotiated procedures and the extremely
onerous obligation of contracting authorities to justify them. It might
be construed from the case law of the Court of Justice that the particu-
lar procedure stipulated by the rules requires some sort of clearance
prior to its utilisation. This is not however the case, as the only form of
official notification by contracting authorities which use negotiated
procedures takes place after the award of the contract in question,
when a notice containing the reasons for having recourse to negoti-
ation should be communicated to the European Commission. This
rather reinforces the exceptional character of the negotiated procedures
rather than their prohibitive use. A number of cases before the
European Court of Justice have clarified the position of European
Institutions vis-à-vis the use of negotiated procedures.
Public monopolies
Public monopolies in the European Union, which in the majority are
utilities, are accountable for a substantial magnitude of procurement,
in terms of volume and in terms of price. Responsible for this are the
expensive infrastructure and high technology products which are ne-
cessary to procure in order to deliver their services to the public. Given
the fact that most of the suppliers to public utilities depend almost
entirely on their procurement and that, even when some degree of pri-
vatisation has been achieved, the actual control of the utilities is still
vested in the state, the first constraint in liberalising public procure-
ment in the European Union is apparent. Utilities, in the form of
public monopolies or semi-private enterprises appear prone to perpetu-
ate long standing over dependency purchasing patterns with certain
domestic suppliers. Reflecting the above observations, the reader
should bear in mind that until 1991, utilities were not covered by
European legislation on procurement.14 The delay of their regulation
can be attributed to the resistance from Member States in privatising
their monopolies and the uncertainty of the legal regime that will
follow their privatisation.
Public monopolies15 operating in the utilities sector (energy, trans-
port, water, telecommunications) have been the target of a sweeping
process of transformation from monolithic and sub-optimal public
corporations to competitive enterprises. These legal or delegated
monopolies have been assigned with the exclusive exploitation of the
relevant services in their respective Member States (production, distri-
A Critical Assessment of Public Procurement 135
bution of water and any form of energy and the provision of telecom-
munications and transport) and very often possess a monopsonistic
position. State controlled enterprises perform a different management
pattern than private ones in their market activities. Profit maximisa-
tion is not their main objective and decision making responds not
only to market forces but mainly to political pressure. Under-
standably, their purchasing behaviour follows, to a large extent, para-
meters reflecting current trends of the industrial policy of the
government in power. It has become apparent that public monopolies
in the utilities sector have sustained industries in Member States
through exclusive or preferential procurement. Preferential and pro-
tectionist purchasing behaviour could not easily withstand the com-
petitive forces under which private firms are exposed. One of the most
important elements of corporate performance is sourcing and the
associated costs. The private firm which is exposed to competitive
forces for its deliverables would be certainly compelled to have
recourse to the most cost-efficient sources. This covers not only pro-
curement but also extends to a wide range of legal and corporate
activities such as sub-contracting, research and development, mainte-
nance services. Sustainability of national champions, or in other terms,
strategically perceived enterprises, could only be achieved through
discriminatory purchasing patterns. The privatisation of public mono-
polies, which absorb, to a large extent or even entirely, the output of
such industries will most probably discontinue such patterns and will
result in industrial policy imbalances as it would be difficult for the
national champions to secure new markets to replace the traditional
long dependency on public monopolies and it would take time and
effort to diversify their activities or to convert to alternative industrial
sectors. Imbalances in social policy (unemployment) will also occur,
as a result of the restructuring of the public monopoly and also the
industries which are dependent on it.
The protected and preferential purchasing frameworks between
monopolies and national champions and the output dependency pat-
terns and secured markets of the latter have attracted considerable
foreign direct investment, to the extent that Community Institutions
face the dilemma of threatening to discontinue the investment flow
when liberalising public procurement in the common market. How-
ever, it could be argued that the industrial restructuring following the
opening-up of the procurement practices of public monopolies would
possibly attract similar levels of foreign direct investment, which
would be directed towards supporting the new structure.
136 Public Procurement in the European Union
MS t i
Introduction
The European Union has finally adopted a new set of rules which
govern the award of public contracts in the supplies, works and
services sectors, as well as in the public utilities1 after a considerable
amount of debate and consultation.2 The new Directives reflect on
the 1996 Commission’s Green Paper on Public Procurement3 and sub-
sequently the 1998 Commission’s Communication. The Directives
have been seen as an integral part of the Commission’s 2000 Work
Programme, which pledges to modernise the relevant legislation for
the completion of the internal market and at the same time implement
the Lisbon European Council’s call for economic reform within the
internal market. The new Public Procurement regime will become oper-
ational by January 31, 2006, when Member States are expected to
transpose the Directives into national law.4 Currently the previous
regime is still applicable.5
The Directives have been based upon two basic premises: simplifica-
tion and modernisation. Drawing on the wealth of experience from three
previous generations of legal instruments, and the Court’s jurispruden-
tial inferences to public procurement regulation, the new Directives
are set to achieve what is perhaps the most challenging objective of
the internal market: fully integrate its public sector and abolish any
remaining non-tariff barriers. The new regime maps also a clear-cut
dichotomy between the public and the utilities sectors respectively.
Although the same fundamental principles underlie the liberalisation
of procurement in government and public utilities, their separate regu-
lation reveals a diametrically opposed nature of the contracting author-
ities/entities under these sectors. Over the past two decades, public
145
146 Public Procurement in the European Union
rejected on that ground alone only after consultation with the ten-
derer where the latter is unable to prove, within a sufficient time
limit fixed by the contracting authority that the aid in question was
granted legally. Where the contracting authority rejects a tender in
these circumstances, it must inform the Commission.
According to Article 1.8 of the Public Sector Directive, the term
economic operator covers equally the concepts of contractor, supplier
and service provider. It is used merely in the interest of simplifi-
cation. An economic operator who has submitted a tender is desig-
nated as a “tenderer”. One who has sought an invitation to take part
in a restricted or negotiated procedure or a competitive dialogue is
designated as a “candidate”.
Interestingly, the new utilities regime excludes from its remit con-
tracts awarded to affiliated undertakings. The new Utilities Directive
does not apply to contracts awarded: (a) by a contracting entity to an
affiliated undertaking, or (b) by a joint venture, formed exclusively by
a number of contracting entities for the purpose of carrying out activ-
ities which are covered by the Utilities Directive to an undertaking
which is affiliated with one of these contracting entities. Article 23 of
the new Utilities Directive excludes contracts awarded to an affiliated
undertaking, to a joint venture or to a contracting entity forming part
of a joint venture from the remit of the Directive. Under the utilities
procurement regime, the term affiliated undertaking means any under-
taking the annual accounts of which are consolidated with those of the
contracting entity in accordance with the requirements of the Seventh
Council Directive 83/349/EEC on consolidated accounts14 based on the
Article 44(2)(g) of the EU Treaty. In cases of entities which are not
subject to that Directive, affiliated undertaking means any undertaking
over which the contracting entity may exercise, directly or indirectly, a
dominant influence within the meaning of Article 2(1)(b), or any
undertaking over which the contracting entity may exercise a domin-
ant influence by virtue of ownership, financial participation, or the
rules which govern it.
or of the call for tender and does not risk distorting competition or
causing discrimination. The contracting authorities may specify prices
or payments to the participants in the dialogue.
Framework procurement
According to Article 1.5 of the Public Sector Directive, a framework
agreement is an agreement between one or more contracting author-
ities and one or more economic operators, the purpose of which is to
establish the terms governing contracts to be awarded during a given
period, in particular with regard to price and, where appropriate, the
quantity envisaged.
A Community definition of framework agreements, together with
specific rules on framework agreements concluded for contracts falling
within the scope of the Public Sector Directive, is provided in Article
32. Under these rules, when a contracting authority enters into a
framework agreement in accordance with the provisions of the Public
Sector Directive relating, in particular, to advertising, time limits and
conditions for the submission of tenders, it may enter into contracts
based on such a framework agreement during its term of validity either
by applying the terms set forth in the framework agreement or, if all
terms have not been fixed in advance in the framework agreement, by
reopening competition between the parties to the framework agree-
ment in relation to those terms. The reopening of competition should
comply with certain rules the aim of which is to guarantee the required
flexibility and to guarantee respect for the general principles, in par-
ticular the principle of equal treatment. For the same reasons, the term
of the framework agreements should not exceed four years, except in
cases duly justified by the contracting authorities.
Article 32 is the institutional foundation of framework agreements.
Member States may provide that contracting authorities may conclude
framework agreements. For the purpose of concluding a framework
agreement, contracting authorities must follow the rules of procedure
referred to in the Public Sector Directive for all phases up to the award
of contracts based on that framework agreement. The parties to the
framework agreement must be chosen by applying the award criteria
set in accordance with Article 53.17
Contracts based on a framework agreement must be awarded in
accordance with the procedures laid down in paragraphs 3 and 4 of
Article 32. Those procedures may be applied only between the con-
tracting authorities and the economic operators originally party
to the framework agreement. When awarding contracts based on a
154 Public Procurement in the European Union
Electronic procurement
New electronic purchasing techniques are continually being developed.
Such techniques help to increase competition and streamline public pur-
chasing, particularly in terms of the savings in time and money which
their use will allow. Contracting authorities may make use of electronic
purchasing techniques, provided such use complies with the rules drawn
up under the Public Sector Directive and the principles of equal treat-
ment, nondiscrimination and transparency. To that extent, a tender sub-
mitted by a tenderer, in particular where competition has been reopened
under a framework agreement or where a dynamic purchasing system is
being used, may take the form of that tenderer’s electronic catalogue.
According to Article 1.6 of the Public Sector Directive, a dynamic pur-
chasing system is a completely electronic process for making commonly
used purchases, the characteristics of which, as generally available on
the market, meet the requirements of the contracting authority, which
is limited in duration and open throughout its validity to any economic
operator which satisfies the selection criteria and has submitted an
indicative tender that complies with the specification. In view of the
rapid expansion of electronic purchasing systems, appropriate rules
should now be introduced to enable contracting authorities to take full
advantage of the possibilities afforded by these systems. Against this
background, it is necessary to define a completely electronic dynamic
purchasing system for commonly used purchases, and lay down specific
rules for setting up and operating such a system in order to ensure the
fair treatment of any economic operator who wishes to take part
therein. Any economic operator which submits an indicative tender in
accordance with the specification and meets the selection criteria
should be allowed to join such a system. This purchasing technique
allows the contracting authority, through the establishment of a list of
tenderers already selected and the opportunity given to new tenderers
to take part, to have a particularly broad range of tenderers as a result
of the electronic facilities available, and hence to ensure optimum use
of public funds through broad competition.
The use of dynamic purchasing systems is described in Article 33.
Member States may provide that contracting authorities may use
dynamic purchasing systems. In order to set up a dynamic purchasing
system, contracting authorities must follow the rules of the open pro-
cedure in all its phases up to the award of the contracts to be con-
cluded under this system. All the tenderers satisfying the selection
criteria and having submitted an indicative tender which complies
with the specification and any possible additional documents, must be
156 Public Procurement in the European Union
under the system. To that end they must set a time limit for the sub-
mission of tenders. They must award the contract to the tenderer
which submitted the best tender on the basis of the award criteria set
out in the contract notice for the establishment of the dynamic pur-
chasing system. A dynamic purchasing system may not last for more
than four years, except in duly justified exceptional cases. Contracting
authorities may not resort to this system to prevent, restrict or distort
competition. No charges may be billed to the interested economic
operators or to parties to the system.
Electronic auctions
According to Article 1.7 of the Public Sector Directive an electronic
auction is a repetitive process involving an electronic device for the
presentation of new prices, revised downwards, and/or new values con-
cerning certain elements of tenders, which occurs after an initial full
evaluation of the tenders, enabling them to be ranked using automatic
evaluation methods. Consequently, certain service contracts and
certain works contracts having as their subject-matter intellectual
performances, such as the design of works, may not be the object of
electronic auctions.
Since use of the technique of electronic auctions is likely to
increase, such auctions should be given a Community definition and
governed by specific rules in order to ensure that they operate in full
accordance with the principles of equal treatment, non-discrimina-
tion and transparency. To that end, provision should be made for
such electronic auctions to deal only with contracts for works, sup-
plies or services for which the specifications can be determined with
precision. Such may in particular be the case for recurring supplies,
works and service contracts. With the same objective, it must also
to be possible to establish the respective ranking of the tenderers at
any stage of the electronic auction. Recourse to electronic auctions
enables contracting authorities to ask tenderers to submit new
prices, revised downwards, and when the contract is awarded to the
most economically advantageous tender, also to improve elements
of the tenders other than prices. In order to guarantee compliance
with the principle of transparency, only the elements suitable for
automatic evaluation by electronic means, without any intervention
and/or appreciation by the contracting authority, that is, only
the elements which are quantifiable so that they can be expressed
in figures or percentages, may be the object of electronic auctions.
On the other hand, those aspects of the tenders which imply
158 Public Procurement in the European Union
(a) the features, the values for which will be the subject of electronic
auction, provided that such features are quantifiable and can be
expressed in figures or percentages;
(b) any limits on the values which may be submitted, as they result
from the specifications relating to the subject of the contract;
(c) the information which will be made available to tenderers in the
course of the electronic auction and, where appropriate, when it
will be made available to them;
(d) the relevant information concerning the electronic auction
process;
(e) the conditions under which the tenderers will be able to bid
and, in particular, the minimum differences which will, where
appropriate, be required when bidding;
(f) the relevant information concerning the electronic equipment used
and the arrangements and technical specifications for connection.
The New Public Procurement Regime 159
(a) in the invitation to take part in the auction they must indicate the
date and time fixed in advance;
(b) when they receive no more new prices or new values which meet
the requirements concerning minimum differences. In that
event, the contracting authorities must state in the invitation to
160 Public Procurement in the European Union
take part in the auction the time which they will allow to elapse
after receiving the last submission before they close the electronic
auction;
(c) when the number of phases in the auction, fixed in the invitation
to take part in the auction, has been completed. When the con-
tracting authorities have decided to close an electronic auction in
accordance with subparagraph (c), possibly in combination with
the arrangements laid down in subparagraph (b), the invitation to
take part in the auction must indicate the timetable for each phase
of the auction.
cerned are disabled persons who, by reason of the nature or the seri-
ousness of their impairment, cannot carry on occupations under
normal conditions. The contract notice must make reference to this
provision.
The laws, regulations and collective agreements, at both national
and Community level, which are in force in the areas of employ-
ment conditions and safety at work apply during performance of a
public contract, provided that such rules, and their application,
comply with Community law. In cross-border situations, where
workers from one Member State provide services in another Member
State for the purpose of performing a public contract, Directive
96/71/EC concerning the posting of workers in the framework of the
provision of services 21 lays down the minimum conditions which
must be observed by the host country in respect of such posted
workers. If national law contains provisions to this effect, non-
compliance with those obligations may be considered to be grave
misconduct or an offence concerning the professional conduct of
the economic operator concerned, liable to lead to the exclusion of
that economic operator from the procedure for the award of a public
contract.
Article 45 of the Public Sector Directive deals with the personal situ-
ation of the candidate or tenderer. It provides that any candidate or
tenderer who has been the subject of a conviction by final judgement
of which the contracting authority is aware for one or more of the
reasons listed below, must be excluded from participation in a public
contract:
Member States must specify, in accordance with their national law and
having regard for Community law, the implementing conditions for this
paragraph. They may provide for derogation from the requirement
referred to in the first subparagraph for overriding requirements in the
general interest. For the purposes of this paragraph, the contracting
authorities must, where appropriate, ask candidates or tenderers to supply
the documents referred to in paragraph 3 and may, where they have
doubts concerning the personal situation of such candidates or tenderers,
also apply to the competent authorities to obtain any information they
consider necessary on the personal situation of the candidates or tender-
ers concerned. Where the information concerns a candidate or tenderer
established in a State other than that of the contracting authority, the
contracting authority may seek the cooperation of the competent author-
ities. Having regard for the national laws of the Member State where the
candidates or tenderers are established, such requests must relate to legal
and/or natural persons, including, if appropriate, company directors
and any person having powers of representation, decision or control in
respect of the candidate or tenderer.
and equal treatment and which guarantee that tenders are assessed in
conditions of effective competition. As a result, it is appropriate to allow
the application of two award criteria only: “the lowest price” and “the
most economically advantageous tender”.
To ensure compliance with the principle of equal treatment in the
award of contracts, it is appropriate to lay down an obligation – estab-
lished by case-law – to ensure the necessary transparency to enable all
tenderers to be reasonably informed of the criteria and arrangements
which will be applied to identify the most economically advantageous
tender. It is therefore the responsibility of contracting authorities to
indicate the criteria for the award of the contract and the relative
weighting given to each of those criteria in sufficient time for tender-
ers to be aware of them when preparing their tenders. Contracting
authorities may derogate from indicating the weighting of the criteria
for the award in duly justified cases for which they must be able to
give reasons or where the weighting cannot be established in advance,
in particular on account of the complexity of the contract. In such
cases, they must indicate the descending order of importance of the
criteria. Where the contracting authorities choose to award a contract
to the most economically advantageous tender, they must assess the
tenders in order to determine which one offers the best value for
money. In order to do this, they must determine the economic and
quality criteria which, taken as a whole, must make it possible to
determine the most economically advantageous tender for the con-
tracting authority. The determination of these criteria depends on the
object of the contract since they must allow the level of performance
offered by each tender to be assessed in the light of the object of
the contract, as defined in the technical specifications and the value
for money of each tender to be measured. In order to guarantee equal
treatment, the criteria for the award of the contract should enable
tenders to be compared and assessed objectively. If these conditions
are fulfilled, economic and qualitative criteria for the award of the
contract, such as meeting environmental requirements, may enable
the contracting authority to meet the needs of the public concerned,
as expressed in the specifications of the contract. Under the same
conditions, a contracting authority may use criteria aiming to meet
social requirements in response to the needs of particularly disadvan-
taged groups. Such requirements must be defined in the specifications
of the contract and the disadvantaged groups concerned must be
those intended to receive the works, supplies or services which are the
object of the contract.
168 Public Procurement in the European Union
Postal utilities
Taking into account the further opening up of Community postal ser-
vices to competition and the fact that such services are provided
through a network comprising contracting authorities, public under-
takings and other undertakings, the award of contracts by entities pro-
viding postal services should be subject to the rules of the new Utilities
Directive 2004/18/EC and aim at creating a framework for sound com-
mercial practice which allows for greater flexibility than is offered by
the existing Utilities Directive 93/38. For a definition of the activities
in question, it is necessary to take into account the definitions of
Directive 97/67/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council
of 15 December 1997 on common rules for the development of the
internal market of Community postal services and the improvement of
quality of service.31
Irrespective of their legal status, entities providing postal services are
not currently subject to the rules set out in Directive 93/38/EEC. The
adjustment of contract award procedures to this Directive could there-
fore take longer to implement for such entities than for entities already
subject to those rules which will merely have to adapt their procedures
to the amendments made by this Directive.
Introduction
From a constitutional point of view, the state is under an obligation to
provide a range of services to the public in the form of general infra-
structure, healthcare, education, housing, transport, energy, defence,
social security and policing to name a few. Traditionally, the state,
either in its own capacity or through delegated monopolies and pub-
licly controlled enterprises has engaged in market activities in order to
serve public interest.
The concept of the state encapsulates an entrepreneurial dimension
to the extent that it deploys wealth as policy instrument (dominium).1
However, although entering into transactions with a view to providing
goods, services and works to the public, this type of action by the state
does not resemble the commercial characteristics of entrepreneurship,
in as much as the aim of the state’s activities is not the maximisation
of profits2 but the observance of public interest.
Such participation by the state in the relevant market takes place
on behalf of the public and the society as a whole,3 and the whole
process has been described as corporatism.4 In fact, corporatism has
been seen as a market phenomenon which has created a specific
forum for the supply and demand sides. This forum is known as
public markets.5 Public markets, in contrast to private ones, are the
forum where public interest6 substitutes profit maximisation.7 Corpora-
tism has also revealed the dimension of the state as a service provider
to the public and that notion has always been linked with the pro-
curement and subsequent state-ownership of the relevant assets. As a
process of public sector management, corporatism has primarily been
delivered through competitive tendering in order to satisfy the needs
175
176 Public Procurement in the European Union
assumes, the higher the price to be paid by the other party, and vice
versa.
In traditional public procurement transactions the demand side
inevitably undertakes too much risk, as a result of its practices.20 The
award of publicly funded contracts takes place predominately by refer-
ence to the lowest price, which constitutes one of the two permissible
award criteria under the procurement rules (the other being the cri-
terion of the most economically advantageous offer). When contracting
authorities award their contracts by reference to pricing, this would
normally reflect the amount of risk they are prepared to resume.21
There is not any golden rule as to what represents an acceptable risk
transfer in a contract, the latter being private or public, for risk alloca-
tion primarily reflects the parties’ perception of a transaction with
reference to their own criteria. These criteria are often influenced by a
range of parameters such as speculation, fear, certainty, as well as by
a number of qualitative attributes of the parties, e.g. sound forecast and
planning, market intelligence.
On the other hand, value-for-money as the second constituent ele-
ment of a privately financed project should reflect a benchmarked
comparison between public and privately financed models of service
delivery. The comparison should not only take into account factors
such as quality or technical merit, but mainly aspects of sound supply
chain management reflecting efficiency gains, in the sense that the
conclusion of a privately financed project would resemble to a large
extent a contractual arrangement between private parties. Value-
for-money as an element in a PFI deal is a precursor of best purchasing
practice by contracting authorities and also reflects the underlying
competitive elements which are necessary in order to meet the
accountability and transparency standards and principles.22
award procedures (or even the suspension of the conclusion of the con-
tract itself) would be unlikely without a thorough and exhaustive
investigation by the competent anti-trust authorities.
Against this background, the PFI was originally construed as the
process that could bring the public and private sectors closer and break
the mistrust which has surrounded traditional public procurement.
The PFI should not be conceived as a capital facility to the state and its
organs in the process of delivering public services. It should not be
seen as a borrowing exercise by the public sector, as the latter can
acquire capital in much more preferential terms than any private
person. The PFI should be rather conceived as a process of involving
the private sector in the delivery of public services. As such, the PFI
attempts to introduce a contractual element in the delivery of public
services, to the extent that the private sector, as a contractual party
undertakes the responsibility to provide not only an asset but to
deliver its associated functions to the public. Therefore, the PFI has
contributed in changing the traditionally acquisitorial nature of public
sector contracts by inserting a service delivery element.
One of the most important attractions of the PFI has been the ability
of public authorities to classify the relevant transactions as exempted
from the Public Sector Borrowing Requirement (PSBR), thus by-passing
centrally controlled budgetary allocations and cash limits in the public
sector spending. In such a way, the PFI represented a viable solution to
cash-stranded public authorities, which could, independently, proceed
and strike deals that otherwise would not have materialised. Further-
more, the public spending relating to the repayments of the privately
financed transactions would not appear as public debt. By taking pri-
vately financed transactions out of the PSBR balance sheet, the govern-
ment may implicitly have attempted to liberalise public purchasing
from budgetary constraints and public spending capping. It could be
also argued that such an attempt could indicate the beginning of the
end to the institutionalised decision making process and control of
public procurement imposed under the European (and domestic)
public procurement regime.
The paramount implication of not classifying privately financed pro-
jects as public debt could be that such purchasing would not fall under
the annual comprehensive spending review of the government. In fact,
non-inclusion of PFI deals in the PSBR could transform the structure of
public markets24 by reversing the roles and the relative importance of
the demand and supply sides. Indeed, it was originally suggested25 that
the private sector should initiate demand by exploring the overall
Public-Private Partnerships 187
potential and delivery options and then introduce the plan to the
relevant public authority. Such a scenario could also mean dismantling
of public markets and the elevation of private markets26 as the forum
for the pursuit of public interest. However, the practice not to include
PFI projects in the PSBR balance sheet and the assumption that the rel-
evant spending does not represent public debt were often described as
legal and policy acrobatisms.27
where both services and construction work are part of the project.
Finally, it can be characterised as a “concession contract”. The con-
tractual nature of a PFI project is crucial in its procedural delivery
and detrimental in complying with the relevant European procure-
ment rules, as it triggers the applicability of different Directives and
requirements stipulated therein.
authorities can freely opt for open or restricted procedures, the latter
should be justified by reference to the nature of the products or ser-
vices to be procured and the balance between contract value and
administrative costs associated with tender evaluation. A more rigor-
ous set of conditions apply for the use of negotiated procedures.
When negotiated procedures with prior notification are used, they
must be justified on grounds of irregular or unacceptable tenders
received as a result of a previous call. Negotiated procedures without
prior notification are restrictively permitted in absence of tenders,
when the procurement involves manufactured products or construc-
tion works purely for research and development, when for technical
or artistic reasons or reasons connected with the protection of exclu-
sive rights a particular supplier or contractor is selected, in cases of
extreme urgency brought by unforeseeable events not attributable to
the contracting authorities, when additional deliveries and supplies
or works would cause disproportionate technical operational and
maintenance difficulties.
All negotiations with candidates or tenderers on fundamental aspects
of contracts, in particular on prices, are prohibited in open and re-
stricted procedures; discussions with candidates or tenderers may be
held, but only for the purpose of clarifying or supplementing the
content of their tenders or the requirements of the contracting author-
ities and provided this does not involve discriminatory practices.48 The
need for such a prohibition is clear, since the possibility to negotiate
may allow the contracting authority to introduce subjective appraisal
criteria. The European Court of Justice has condemned post tender
negotiations49 and a Declaration on the above subject has been made
by the European Council and the Commission of the European Com-
munities.50 It should be also clear that the selection process must be
completely distinguished from the award process. Quite often, con-
tracting authorities appear to fuse the two basic processes of the award
of public procurement contracts. This runs contrary to legal precedence
of the European Court of Justice.51
In contrast with the above background, when contracting authorities
award PFI projects classified as public works or public services contracts,
they have been urged to have recourse to negotiated procedures.52 The
official line adopted is that a privately financed project could meet all
the conditions imposed by the European public procurement rules for
allowing the negotiated procedures to be used in contract awards and
form a sort of precedence for future projects. Negotiated procedures for
public works and services contracts with prior notification shall be used
Public-Private Partnerships 195
Publicity requirements
The European Public Procurement Directives have established a regime
which inter alia provides a mechanism for all the information needed
to the relevant parties or the public in relation to the award of public
contracts. Contracting authorities are under explicit obligation to
furnish timely a range of information on their own initiative55 or upon
request.56 This obligation is, in principle, extended to all PFI projects
that are awarded under the procurement rules. However, practice has
shown that very little information concerning the award of a PFI con-
tract sees the light of publicity, often being described as “commercially
confidential”. The onus is on the public authority to meet these public-
ity requirements, although the private sector appears extremely reluct-
ant in allowing vital information regarding contractual structures,
financial arrangements, technical specifications, pricing to be in the
public domain. Given the fact that a PFI project is substantially more
complicated than a conventional public procurement equivalent, the
argument of essential or confidential information being made public
appears a valid one.
The Freedom of Information Act in the United Kingdom has implica-
tions for the publicity of PFI contracts, implications which mirror the
obligations of contracting authorities stipulated in the Public Procure-
ment Directives. In particular, a statutory obligation to make public
certain information is proposed. This obligation covers information
relating to reasons for rejection or disqualification and pricing. The
appropriate publicity requirements will be included in the individual
contracts between public authorities and contractors. The above ob-
ligation is intended to apply to all government departments, local
authorities, the National Health Service, and all other public bodies,
while it will also be extended to the privatised utilities and private
organisations which perform public interest functions under contrac-
tual arrangements with the state. An exemption for confidentially
commercial information will apply, provided substantial harm to a
party can be demonstrated.
are not clearly defined and that, in certain cases, they even fall
outside any contractual framework.
This in turn raises problems not only with regard to the principles of
transparency and equality of treatment, but even risks prejudicing the
general interest objectives which the public authority wishes to attain.
It is also evident that the lifetime of the created entity does not gener-
ally coincide with the duration of the contract or concession awarded,
and this appears to encourage the extension of the task entrusted to
this entity without a true competition at the time of this renewal.
In addition, it should be pointed out that the joint creation of such
entities must respect the principle of non-discrimination in respect of
nationality in general and the free circulation of capital in particular.77
Thus, for example, the public authorities cannot normally make their
position as shareholder in such an entity contingent on excessive
privileges which do not derive from a normal application of company
law.78
On the other hand, the creation of an institutional public-private
partnership may also lead to a change in the body of shareholders of a
public entity. In this context, it should first be emphasised that the
changeover of a company from the public sector to the private sector is
an economic and political decision which, as such, falls within the sole
competence of the Member States.79 Community law on public con-
tracts is not as such intended to apply to transactions involving simple
capital injections by an investor in an enterprise, whether this latter
be in the public or the private sector. Such transactions fall under the
scope of the provisions of the Treaty on the free movement of capital,80
implying in particular that the national measures regulating them
must not constitute barriers to investment from other Member States.81
Nevertheless, the provisions on freedom of establishment within the
meaning of Article 43 of the Treaty must be applied when a public
authority decides, by means of a capital transaction, to cede to a third
party a holding conferring a definite influence in a public entity pro-
viding economic services normally falling within the responsibility of
the State.82
When public authorities grant an economic operator a definite
influence in a business under a transaction involving a capital transfer,
and when this transaction has the effect of entrusting to this operator
tasks falling within the scope of the law on public contracts which had
been previously exercised, directly or indirectly, by the public author-
ities, the provisions on freedom of establishment require compliance
with the principles of transparency and equality of treatment, in order
Public-Private Partnerships 203
Introduction
The jurisprudence of the European Court of Justice has indicated
on numerous occasions that public procurement has a multi-faceted
dimension in assisting the process of the common market. In particu-
lar, the Court has demonstrated the pivotal position of public procure-
ment in the process of determining the parameters under which public
subsidies and state financing of public services constitute state aids. In
the centre of the debate regarding the relation between state aids and
the financing of services of general interest, within the broader remit of
the interplay of subsidies and public services, public procurement has
emerged as an essential component of state aids regulation.1 The
European Court of Justice has inferred that the existence of public
procurement, as a legal system and a procedural framework, verifies
conceptual links, creates compatibility safeguards and authenticates
established principles applicable in state aids regulation. Public
procurement in the common market not only does represent the pro-
cedural framework for the contractual interface between public and
private sectors,2 it also reflects on the character and nature of activities
of the state and its organs in pursuit of public interest.3 Public procure-
ment regulation has acquired legal, economic and policy dimensions,
as market integration and the fulfilment of treaty principles are
balanced with policy choices.4
The implications of the debate are important, not only because of
the necessity for a coherent application of state aids regulation in the
common market5 but also because of the need for a legal and policy
framework regarding the financing of services of general interest and
public service obligations by Member States. The significance of the
205
206 Public Procurement in the European Union
Charter of Fundamental Rights. On the other hand, the quid pro quo
approach presents a major shortcoming: it introduces elements64 of the
nature of public financing into the process of determining the legality
of state aids. According to state aids jurisprudence, only the effects
of the measure are to be taken into consideration,65 and as a result of
the application of the quid pro quo approach legal certainty could be
undermined.
Finally, the quid pro quo approach relies on the existence of a direct
and manifest link between state financing and services of general inter-
est, an existence indicated through the presence of a public contract
concluded in accordance with the provisions of the Public Procure-
ment Directives. Apart from the criticism it has received concerning
the introduction of elements into the assessment process of state aids,
the interface of the quid pro quo approach with public procurement
appears as the most problematic facet in its application. The pro-
curement of public services does not always reveal a public contract
between a contracting authority and an undertaking.
The quid pro quo approach appears to define state aids no longer by
reference solely to the effects of the measure, but by reference to cri-
teria of a purely formal or procedural nature. This means that the exist-
ence of a procedural or a substantive link between the state and
the service in question lifts the threat of state aids regulation, irrespec-
tive of any effect the state measure has on competition. However, the
Court considers that to determine whether a State measure constitutes
aid, only the effects of the measure are to be taken into consideration,
whereas other elements95 typifying a measure are not relevant during
the stage of determining the existence of aid, because they are not
liable to affect competition. However, the relevance of these elements
may appear when an assessment of the compatibility of the aid96 with
the derogating provisions of the Treaty takes place. The application of
the quid pro quo approach amounts to introducing such elements into
the actual definition of aid. Its first criterion suggests examining
whether there is a direct and manifest link between the State funding
and the public service obligations. In practice, this amounts to requir-
ing the existence of a public service contract awarded after a public
procurement procedure. Similarly, the second criterion suggests exam-
ining whether the public service obligations are clearly defined. In
practice, this amounts to verifying that there are laws, regulations or
contractual provisions which specify the nature and content of the
undertaking’s obligations.
Although the public procurement regime embraces activities of the
state, which covers central, regional, municipal and local government
departments, as well as bodies governed by public law, and public utilit-
ies, in-house contracts are not subject to its coverage. The existence of
dependency, in terms of overall control of an entity by the state or
another contracting authority renders the public procurement regime
inapplicable. Dependency presupposes a control similar to that which
the state of another contracting authority exercises over its own
The Procurement of Services of General Interest 231
for the purposes of the Public Supplies and Public Works Directives.
As far as utilities are concerned, the GPA applies to entities, which
carry out one or more of certain listed “utility” activities,102 where
these entities are either “public authorities” or “public undertakings”,
in the sense of the Utilities Directive. However, the GPA does not cover
entities operating in the utilities sector on the basis of special and exclu-
sive rights. In many instances, Member States grant special or exclusive
rights in order to ensure the financial viability of a provider of a service
of general economic interest. The granting of such rights is not per se
incompatible with the Treaty. The Court of Justice has ruled that
Article 86(2) EU permits the Member States to confer on undertakings
to which they entrust the operation of services of general economic
interest exclusive rights which may hinder the application of the rules
of the Treaty on competition insofar as restrictions on competition,
or even the exclusion of all competition, by other economic operators
are necessary to ensure the performance of the particular tasks assigned
to the undertakings possessed of the exclusive rights.103 However,
Member States must ensure that such rights are compatible with inter-
nal market rules and do not amount to abuse of a dominant position
within the meaning of Article 82 by the operator concerned. Generally
speaking, exclusive or special rights may limit competition on certain
markets only insofar as they are necessary for performing the particular
public service task. In addition, Member States’ freedom to grant
special or exclusive rights to providers of services of general interest
can also be restricted in sector-specific Community legislation.
general interest, and services for the public at large could be regarded
as state aids, utilise public procurement in different ways. On the one
hand, under the state aids and compensation approaches, public pro-
curement sanitises public subsidies as legitimate contributions towards
public service obligations and services of general interest. From proce-
dural and substantive viewpoints, the existence of public procurement
award procedures, as well as the existence of a public contract between
the state and an undertaking reveals the necessary links between the
markets where the state intervenes in order to provide services of
general interest. In fact, both approaches accept the sui generis charac-
teristics of public markets and the role the state and its organs play
within such markets. On the other hand, the quid pro quo approach
relies on public procurement to justify the clearly defined and manifest
link between the funding and the delivery of a public service obliga-
tion. It assumes that without these procedural and substantive links
between public services and their financing, the financing of public
services is state aids.
In most cases, public procurement connects the activities of the state
with the pursuit of public interest. The subject of public contract and
their respective financing relates primarily to services of general inter-
est. Thus, public procurement indicates the necessary link between
state financing and services of general interest, a link which takes state
aids regulation out of the equation. The existence of public procure-
ment and the subsequent contractual relations ensuing from the pro-
cedural interface between the public and private sectors neutralise state
aids regulation. In principle, the financing of services of general inter-
est, when channelled through public procurement reflects market
value. However, it should be maintained that the safeguards of public
procurement reflecting genuine market positions are not robust and
the foundations upon which a quantitative application of state aids
regulation is based, are not stable. The markets within which the
services of general interest have emerged and are being delivered reveal
little evidence of similarities with private markets. They also do not
render meaningful any comparison with private markets, which pres-
ent competitiveness and substitutability of demand and supply as key
features of their structure. The approach adopted by the European judi-
ciary indicates the presence of marchés publics, sui generis markets where
the state intervenes in pursuit of public interest. State aids regulation
could be applied, as a surrogate system of public procurement, to en-
sure that distortions of competition do not emerge as a result of the
inappropriate financing of services.
234 Public Procurement in the European Union
A new approach
The debate of the delineation between market forces and protection in
the financing of public services took a twist. The Court in Altmark,104
followed a hybrid approach between the compensation and the quid pro
quo approaches. It ruled that where subsidies are regarded as compensa-
tion for the services provided by the recipient undertaking in order to
discharge public service obligations, they do not constitute state aids.
Nevertheless for the purpose of applying that criterion, national courts
should ascertain that four conditions are satisfied: first, the recipient
undertaking is actually required to discharge public service obligations
and those obligations have been clearly defined; second, the parameters
on the basis of which the compensation is calculated have been estab-
lished beforehand in an objective and transparent manner; third, the
compensation does not exceed what is necessary to cover all or part of
the costs incurred in discharging the public service obligations, taking
into account the relevant receipts and a reasonable profit for discharg-
ing those obligations; fourth, where the undertaking which is to dis-
charge public service obligations is not chosen in a public procurement
procedure, the level of compensation needed has been determined on
the basis of an analysis of the costs which a typical undertaking, well-
run and adequately provided with appropriate means so as to be able to
meet the necessary public service requirements, would have incurred in
discharging those obligations, taking into account the relevant receipts
and a reasonable profit for discharging the obligations.
The first criterion which requires the existence of a clear definition of
the framework within which public service obligations and services of
general interest have been entrusted to the beneficiary of compensatory
payments runs consistently with Article 86(2) EC jurisprudence, where
an express act of the public authority to assign services of general eco-
nomic interest105 is required. However, the second criterion which
requires the establishment of the parameters on the basis of which the
compensation is calculated in an objective and transparent manner
departs from existing precedent,106 as it establishes an ex post control
mechanism by the Member States and the European Commission. The
third criterion that the compensation must not exceed what is neces-
sary to cover the costs incurred in discharging services of general inter-
est or public service obligations is compatible to the proportionality test
applied in Article 86(2) EC. However, there is an inconsistency problem,
as the European judiciary is rather unclear on the question whether any
compensation for public service obligations may comprise a profit
element.107 Finally, the fourth criterion which establishes a comparison
The Procurement of Services of General Interest 235
of the cost structures of the recipient on the one hand and of a private
undertaking, well-run and adequately provided to fulfil the public
service tasks, in the absence of a public procurement procedure, inserts
elements of subjectivity and uncertainty that will inevitably fuel more
controversy.
The four conditions laid down in Altmark are ambiguous. In fact they
represent the hybrid link between the compensation approach and
the quid pro quo approach. The Court appears to accept unequivocally
the parameters of the compensation approach (sui generis markets,
remuneration over and above normal market prices for services of
general interest), although the link between the services of general
interest and their legitimate financing requires the presence of public
procurement, as procedural verification of competitiveness and cost
authentication of market prices. However, the application of the public
procurement regime cannot always depict the true status of the
market. Furthermore, the condition relating to the clear definition of
an undertaking’s character in receipt of subsidies to discharge public
services in an objective and transparent manner, in conjunction with
the costs attached to the provision of the relevant services could give
rise to major arguments across the legal and political systems in the
common market. The interface between public and private sectors in
relation to the delivery of public services is in an evolutionary state
across the common market. Finally, the concept of “reasonable profit”
over and above the costs associated with the provision of services of
general interest could complicate matters more, since they appear as
elements of subjectivity and uncertainty.
The principle of the Member States’ autonomy to make policy
choices regarding services of general economic interest equally applies
with regard to financing their provision. Member States enjoy a wide
margin of discretion when deciding whether and how to finance the
provision of services of general economic interest. The financing mech-
anisms applied by Member States include direct financial support
through the State budget, special or exclusive rights, and contributions
by market participants, tariff averaging and solidarity-based financing.
In the absence of Community harmonisation, the main limit to this
discretion is the requirement that such financing mechanism must not
distort competition within the common market. However, other relev-
ant criteria for selecting a financing mechanism, such as the efficiency
of the financial mechanism, its redistributive effects, the long-term
investment of providers on services and infrastructure and finally the
security of service provision could introduce a new debate platform,
236 Public Procurement in the European Union
the new Directives are set to achieve what is perhaps the most challeng-
ing objective of the internal market: fully integrate its public sector and
abolish any remaining non-tariff barriers. The new regime maps also a
clear-cut dichotomy between the public and the utilities sectors respec-
tively. Although the same fundamental principles underpin the liberalisa-
tion of procurement in government and public utilities, their separate
regulation reveals a diametrically opposed nature of the contracting
authorities/entities under these sectors. Over the past two decades public
utilities in the EU Member States have been undergoing a process of
transformation. Their change in ownership from public to private has
stimulated commercialism and competitiveness and provided for the
justification of a more relaxed regime and the acceptance that utilities, in
some form or another represent a sui generis contracting authorities not
in need of a rigorous and detailed regulation of their procurement. The
above dichotomy reflects an insight of current market conditions and
political priorities across the European Union, as well as an indication
that the main emphasis should be placed on attempts to open up the
public sector.
The evolution of public-private partnerships represents a genuine
attempt to introduce the concept of contractualised governance in the
delivery of public services. There is mounting evidence that the role
and the involvement of the state in the above process is under con-
stant review. Public-private partnerships reveal an institutionalised
mechanism in engaging the private sector in the delivery of public ser-
vices, not only through the financing but mainly through the opera-
tion of assets. Efficiency gains, qualitative improvement, innovation,
value-for-money and flexibility appear as the most important ones,
whereas an overall better allocation of public capital resources sums up
the advantages of privately financed projects.
However, public-private partnerships do not alter the character of
the contractual relationship between the private and public sectors, for
such character is predominantly determined by other factors attributed
to the legal order in question. They, instead, bring an end to the
notion of public ownership and introduce the concept of service deliv-
ery in the relevant contractual relationship between private and public
sectors. The private sector is no longer a supplier to the public sector
but rather a partner through a concession or an institutionalised ar-
rangement such as a joint venture between public and private sectors.
It seems that there is a quasi-agency relationship between the private
and public sectors, in the sense that the former provides the relevant
infrastructure and in fact delivers public services on behalf of the latter.
240 Public Procurement in the European Union
241
242 Notes
15. See Denis Swann, The Retreat of the State, Harvester-Wheatsheaf 1988,
Chapter 1–2.
16. See the response of the European Commission to a Parliamentary
Question relating to the powers of a Member State to privatised publicly-
controlled entities, OJ 1997 No C72/82.
17. See S. Arrowsmith, The Legality of Secondary Procurement Policies under the
Treaty of Rome and the Works Directive, Public Procurement Law Review,
1992, Vol. 1. p. 410.
18. See Articles 29(4) and 29(a) of the EC Public Works Directive 71/305;
also Art. 26 of EC Public Supplies Directive 77/62.
19. For a thorough analysis see, J. M. Fernadez Martin and O. Stehmann,
Product Market Integration versus Regional Cohesion in the Community,
European Law Review, 1991, Vol. 16, p. 216.
20. European Commission, Public Procurement: Regional and Social Aspects,
COM (89) 400.
21. Commission of the European Communities, Statistical Performance for
keeping watch over public procurement, 1992.
22. See case Cooperative Vereniging “Suiker Unie” UA v. Commission [1975] ECR
1663, in which the European Court of Justice recognised the adverse
effects of concerted practices in tendering procedures on competition in
the common market. This case appears to have opened the way for the
application of competition law on public procurement in the Commun-
ity. The applicability of Competition Law provisions of the Treaty (Articles
85, 86) in controlling collusive tendering and anti-competitive behaviour
of suppliers, was also the subject of Commission Decision 92/204, OJ 1992
L92/1. It could be argued that competition law and policy applies equally
to private as well as public markets, but the explicit provisions of the
Directives on consortia participation in tendering procedures might limit
the scope of Articles 85, 86 in public procurement.
23. For the constitutional aspects of the application of a Regulation in
domestic legal orders see the reservations of the French Government
after the adoption of the SEA and in particular Art. 100A EC, which con-
stitutes the legal basis of all Public Procurement Directives after 1986
in Kapteyn and Verloren van Themaat, Introduction to the Law of the
European Communities, 2nd ed., 1989, Kluwer-Deventer, pp. 470–479.
24. Reference is made here to the first generation of Public Procurement
Directives: for Public Supplies, EC Directives 70/32 and 77/62 as
amended by Directive 80/767 and 88/295; for Public Works, EC
Directives 71/304 and 71/305 as amended by Directive 89/440. See
Chapter 3 for more details.
25. See the FIDE Congress on The Application in the Member States of the
Directives on Public Procurement, Madrid 1990.
26. COM (84) 717 fin.
27. See case 239/85 Commission v. Belgium [1986] ECR 1473; also case 300/81
Commission v. Italy [1983] ECR 449.
28. See case 102/79 Commission v. Belgium [1980] ECR 1489; also case 147/86
Commission v. Hellenic Republic [1988] ECR 765.
29. European Commission, White Paper for the Completion of the Internal
Market, COM (85) 310 fin., 1985.
Notes 243
49. For the concept of origin of goods and their lawful free circulation in the
Common Market, see Regulation 802/68, OJ English Special Edition
1968 (1), p. 165.
50. This includes the purchase of, on the one hand, services producing
audio-visual works such as films, videos and sound recording, including
advertising and, on the other hand broadcasting time (transmission by
air, satellite or cable).
51. These have been excluded because they are not part of the Community
liberalisation package for the telecommunications services market.
52. This refers to contracts which constitute transactions concerning shares,
for example. In the public sector, it will also include within the derogation
contracts awarded to financial intermediaries to arrange such transactions
because these are specifically excluded from the scope of investment ser-
vices (Category 6 of annex IA). However, this exclusion does not appear in
the Utilities Directive so that contracts for the services of intermediaries
who will make the arrangements for such transactions would be subject to
the provisions of the Utilities Directive.
53. Article 20(2)(b) of amending Utilities Directive 93/38.
54. See COM (90) 372 fin, SYN 293 and COM (91) 322 fin, SYN 293.
55. This practice resembles the market testing process often employed in the
United Kingdom between a contracting authority and an in-house team.
56. An affiliated undertaking, for the purposes of Article 1(3) of the Utilities
Directive, is an undertaking the annual accounts of which are consolid-
ated with those of the contracting entity in accordance with the require-
ments of the seventh Company Law Directive (Council Directive 83/349
(OJ. 1983 L 193/1)).
57. See the explanatory memorandum accompanying the text amending the
Utilities Directive (COM (91) 347-SYN 36 1) which states that this provi-
sion relates, in particular, to three types of service provision within
groups. These categories, which may or may not be distinct, are: the pro-
vision of common services such as accounting, recruitment and manage-
ment; the provision of specialised services embodying the know how of
the group; the provision of a specialised service to a joint venture.
58. OJ 1989 L 395.
59. OJ 1992 L 76/7.
60. Directive 92/13, OJ 1992, L 76/7.
61. See Article 7 of EC Directive 92/13.
62. See Case 188/89, Foster v. British Gas [1990] ECR-1313, in which the
European Court of Justice ruled that a Directive capable of having direct
effect could be invoked against a body which is subject to the control of
the State and has been delegated special powers.
63. This was the view of Advocate General Lenz in case 247/89, Commission
v. Portugal [1991] ECR I 3659.
64. EC Directive 90/531, as amended by EC Directive 93/38, OJ L 199.
65. Article 1(1) of Directive 93/38.
66. Article 1(2) of Directive 93/38.
67. The determination of a genuinely competitive regime is left to the utili-
ties operators themselves. See case, C 392/93, The Queen and H.M. Trea-
sury, ex parte British Telecommunications PLC, OJ 1993, C 287/6. This
is perhaps a first step towards self-regulation which could lead to the
246 Notes
136. See case C-513/99, Concordia Bus Filandia v. Helsingin Kaupunki et HKL-
Bussiliikenn, nyr.
137. See the opinion of Advocate General Mischo delivered on 13 December
2001.
138. Clearly the Advocate General wanted to exclude any possibility of envir-
onmental considerations being part of selection criteria or disguised as
technical specifications, capable of discriminating against tendderes that
could not meet them.
26. Tirole, J. (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, The MIT Press,
Cambridge.
27. See Valadou, La notion de pouvoir adjudicateur en matière de marchés
de travaux, Semaine Juridique, 1991, Ed. E, No. 3; Bovis, La notion et les
attributions d’organisme de droit public comme pouvoirs adjudicateurs dans le
régime des marchés publics, Contrats Publics, Septembre 2003.
28. Flamme et Flamme, Enfin l’ Europe des Marchés Publics, Actualité
Juridique – Droit Administratif, 1989.
29. On the issue of public interest and its relation with profit, see cases
C-223/99, Agora Srl v. Ente Autonomo Fiera Internazionale di Milano and
C-260/99 Excelsior Snc di Pedrotti Runa & C v. Ente Autonomo Fiera
Internazionale di Milano [2001] ECR 3605; C-360/96, Gemeente Arnhem
Gemeente Rheden v. BFI Holding BV [1998] ECR 6821; C-44/96, Mannes-
mann Anlangenbau Austria AG et al. v. Strohal Rotationsdurck GesmbH
[1998] ECR 73.
30. See Bovis, The Liberalisation of Public Procurement in the European Union
and its Effects on the Common Market, Ashgate, 1998, Chapter 1.
31. Monopsony is the reverse of monopoly power. The state and its organs
often appear as the sole outlet for an industry’s output.
32. See Article 26(1)(a) of Directive 93/36; Article 30(1)(a) of Directive 93/37;
Article 34(1)(b) of Directive 93/38; Article 36(1)(b) of Directive 92/50.
33. The thresholds laid down by the Directives are as follows:
EURO 5 m for all work and construction projects (Article 3(1) of
Directive 93/37; Article 14(c) of Directive 93/38).
EURO 200,000 for supplies contracts within the European Union (Article
5(1)(a) of Directive 93/36) and
EURO 136,000 for supplies contracts from third countries (Article 5(1)(c)
of Directive 93/36) which participate in the WTO Government Procure-
ment Agreement.
EURO 600,000 for supplies of telecommunication equipment under the
Utilities Directive (Article 14(b) of Directive 93/38) and ECU 400,000 for
all other supplies contracts awarded by public utilities (Article 14(a) of
Directive 93/38).
EURO 200,000 for services contracts (Article 7(1) of Directive 92/50).
34. See Bovis, An Impact Assessment of the European Community’s Public
Procurement Law and Policy, Journal of Business Law, Issue 5, 1999.
35. See the recital of Directive 89/440, OJ L 210/1 1989 amending the origi-
nal Works Directive 71/305 concerning co-ordination of procedures for
the award of public works contracts, stating that “it is necessary to
improve and extend the safeguards in the Directives that are designed
to introduce transparency into the procedures and practices for the
award of such contracts, in order to be able to monitor compliance with
the prohibition of restrictions more closely and at the same time to
reduce disparities in the competitive conditions faced by nationals of
different Member States”.
36. The demand side often omits risk assessment tests during the evaluation
process. The Directives remain vague as to the methods for assessing
financial risk, leaving a great deal of discretion in the hands of contract-
ing authorities. Evidence of financial and economic standing may be
Notes 257
Guézou, Droit de la concurrence et droit des marches publics: vers une notion
transverale de mise en libre concurrence, Contrats Publics, Mars 2003.
46. See Jacquemin and de Jong, European Industrial Organization, Macmillan,
1997; Möschel, Competition Law from and Ordo Point of View, in Peackock
and Willgerodt, German Neo-Liberals and the Social Market Economy,
Macmillan, 1989.
47. See Commission Interpretative Communication on the Community law
applicable to public procurement and the possibilities for integrating social
considerations into public procurement, COM (2001) 566, 15 October
2001. Also, Commission Interpretative Communication on the Commun-
ity law applicable to public procurement and the possibilities for integrat-
ing environmental considerations into public procurement, COM (2001)
274, 4 July 2001.
48. See European Commission, Special Sectoral Report no 1, Public Procure-
ment, Brussels, November 1997.
49. See European Commission, Public Procurement: Regional and Social
Aspects, COM (89) 400.
50. The legislation on public procurement in the early days clearly allowed
for “preference schemes” in less favoured regions of the common market
which were experiencing industrial decline. See Articles 29(4) and 29(a)
of the EC Public Works Directive 71/305; also Art. 26 of EC Public
Supplies Directive 77/62. Such schemes required the application of
award criteria based on considerations other than the lowest price or the
most economically advantageous offer, subject to their compatibility
with Community Law in as much as they did not run contrary to the
principle of free movement of goods and to competition law considera-
tions with respect to state aids. Since the completion of the Internal
market (1992) they have been abolished, as they have been deemed
capable in contravening directly or indirectly the basic principle of non-
discrimination on grounds of nationality stipulated in the Treaty of
Rome.
51. For a thorough analysis see, Fernadez-Martin and Stehmann, Product
Market Integration versus Regional Cohesion in the Community, European
Law Review, Vol. 16, 1991.
52. See Bovis, The Liberalisation of Public Procurement in the European Union
and its Effects on the Common Market, op. cit.
53. European Commission, Public Procurement: Regional and Social Aspects,
COM (89) 400.
54. Commission of the European Communities, Statistical Performance for
keeping watch over public procurement, 1992.
55. See case C-74/76, Ianelli & Volpi Spa v. Ditta Paola Meroni [1977] 2 CMLR
688.
56. See case C-18/84, Commission v. France, 1985, ECR 1339; case 103/84,
Commission v. Italy, 1986, ECR 1759; also, case C-244/81, Commission v.
Ireland, 1982, ECR 4005.
57. See Bovis, Public Procurement as an Instrument of Industrial Policy in the
European Union, Chapter 7, in T. Lawton (ed.), Industrial Policy and
Competitiveness in Europe, Macmillan Publishers, 1998; Fernadez Martin
and Stehmann, Product Market Integration versus Regional Cohesion in the
Community, op. cit.
Notes 259
73. See the application of the rule of reason to the principle of free move-
ment of goods and also the competition law principle prohibiting cartels
and collusive behaviour.
74. Case 31/87, Gebroeders Beentjes v. The Netherlands, op. cit., paragraph 19.
75. Case C-324/93, R. v. The Secretary of State for the Home Department,
ex parte Evans Medical Ltd and Macfarlan Smith Ltd [1995] ECR 563, where
the national court asked whether factors concerning continuity and
reliability as well as security of supplies fall under the framework of
the most economically advantageous offer, when the latter is being
evaluated.
76. See paragraph 22 of Beentjes.
77. See paragraph 37 of Beentjes.
78. See Directive 77/62, OJ C 61/26 [1977], as amended by Directive 98/50,
OJ L 132 [1998] and consolidated by Directive 2001/23 OJ L 82/16
[2001]. For a comprehensive analysis of the implications of transfer of
undertakings in public procurement see Case C 29/91, Dr Sophie
Redmond Stichting v. Bartol [1992] ECR 3189; Case C 382/92, Commission
v. United Kingdom [1994] ECR 2435; Case 24/85, Spijkers v. Gebroders
Benedik Abbatoir CV [1986] ECR 1123; Case C 209/91, Rask v. ISS
Kantinservice [1993] ECR 5735; Case C 392/92, Schmidt v. Spar und
Leihkasse der fruherer Amter Bordersholm, Kiel und Cronshagen [1994] ECR
1320; Case C 392/92, Schmidt v. Spar und Leihkasse der fruherer Amter
Bordersholm, Kiel und Cronshagen [1994] ECR 1320; Case C 48/94, Rygaard
v. Stro Molle Akustik [1995] ECR 2745; Case C-324/86, Tellerup [1998] ECR
739.
79. See Case C-513/99, Concordia Bus Filandia Oy Ab v. Helsingin Kaupunki
et HKL-Bussiliikenne [2002] ECR 7213.
80. The applicability of Competition Law and Policy of the Treaty (Articles
85, 86) in controlling collusive tendering and anti-competitive behav-
iour of suppliers, was the subject of Commission Decision 92/204, OJ
1992 L92/1.
81. See C. Bovis, Business Law in the European Union, Chapter 3, Sweet and
Maxwell, 1997.
82. Thomsen, S. and Nicolaides P. (1991), The evolution of Japanese Direct
Investment in Europe: Death of a Salesman, Royal Institute of International
Affairs, London.
83. The term implies a firm with more than a third of its turnover made in
its own country and has enjoyed formal or informal government protec-
tion. The term has been defined by Abravanel, R. and D. Ernst (1992),
Alliance and acquisition strategies for European national champions, The
McKinsey Quarterly, No. 2, pp. 45–62.
84. Abravanel, R. and D. Ernst (1992), Alliance and acquisition strategies for
European national champions, The McKinsey Quarterly, No. 2, pp. 45–62.
85. Davies, S. and B. Lyons (1993), The EC Industrial Organization Data
Matrix, Mimeo.
86. See European Commission, SMEs participation in public procurement in the
European Community (SEC(92) 722). European Commission Action Pro-
gramme for SMEs (COM (86) 445); (b) Public Procurement: Regional and
Social Aspects (COM (89) 400); (c) Promoting SME Participation in the
Community (COM (90) 166).
262 Notes
87. See European Commission, SME TASK FORCE: SMEs and Public Procure-
ment, Brussels 1988. European Commission, Pan European Forum on
Sub-Contracting in the Community, Brussels 1993.
88. See Council Decision 80/271, OJ 1979 L 71/1 and Council Decision 87/
565, OJ 1987, L 345/24. Also the Agreement on Government Procure-
ment as a result of the negotiations during the GATT Uruguay Round
which was signed on April 15, 1996. The new Government Procurement
Agreement (GPA), after ratification by its signatories, is in force since
January 1, 1996.
89. European Commission, Statistical Performance for keeping watch over public
procurement, 1992.
Ing.A. Bellini & Co. S.p.A. v. Belgian State [1987] ECR 3347; case C-89/92,
Ballast Nedam Groep NV v. Belgische Staat [1994] 2 CMLR; case C-5/97,
Ballast Nedam Groep NV v. Belgische Staat, judgement of 18 December
1997; case C-176/98, Holst Italia v. Comune di Cagliari, judgement of
2 December 1999.
16. Articles 44 to 46 govern the conduct of the procedure for Verification of
the suitability and choice of participants and award of contracts, Criteria
for qualitative selection, and Suitability to pursue a professional activity.
17. Article 53 refers to the award criteria being the most economically
advantageous offer or the lowest price. When the award is made to
the tender most economically advantageous from the point of view of
the contracting authority, various criteria linked to the subject-matter
of the public contract in question, for example, quality, price, technical
merit, aesthetic and functional characteristics, environmental character-
istics, running costs, cost-effectiveness, after-sales service and technical
assistance, delivery date and delivery period or period of completion.
When the award criterion refers to the lowest price only, no other
factors should play a part.
18. See OJ L 13, 19.1.2000, p. 12.
19. See OJ L 178, 17.7.2000, p. 1.
20. See Regulation (EC) No 761/2001 of the European Parliament and of
the Council of 19 March 2001 allowing a voluntary participation by
organisations in a Community eco-management and audit scheme
(EMAS) (OJ L 114, 24.4.2001, p. 1).
21. See OJ L 18, 12.1.97, p. 1.
22. See OJ L 336, 23.12.1994, p. 1.
23. See Council Directive 2000/78/EC of 27 November 2000 establishing a
general framework for equal treatment in employment and occupation
(OJ L 303, 2.12.2000, p. 16).
24. See Council Directive 76/207/EEC of 9 February 1976 on the implemen-
tation of the principle of equal treatment for men and women as regards
access to employment, vocational training and promotion, and working
conditions (OJ L 39, 14.2.1976, p. 40). Directive amended by Directive
2002/73/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council (OJ L 269,
5.10.2002, p. 15).
25. See OJ L 351, 29.12.1998, p. 1.
26. See OJ C 195, 25.6.1997, p. 1.
27. See OJ L 358, 31.12.1998, p. 2.
28. See OJ C 316, 27.11.1995, p. 48.
29. See OJ L 166, 28.6.1991, p. 77. Directive as amended by Directive
2001/97/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of
4 December 2001 (OJ L 344, 28.12.2001, p. 76).
30. See OJ L 336, 23.12.1994, p. 1.
31. See OJ L 15, 21.1.1998, p. 14. Directive as last amended by Regulation
(EC) No 1882/2003 (OJ L 284, 31.10.2003, p. 1).
32. According to Article 68(2), for the adoption of a Decision the
Commission shall be allowed a period of three months commencing on
the first working day following the date on which it receives the
notification or the request. However, this period may be extended once
266 Notes
the Telaustria case, the Court stated that “[the] obligation of transparency
which is imposed on the contracting authority consists in ensuring, for the
benefit of any potential tenderer, a degree of advertising sufficient to enable
the services market to be opened up to competition and the impartiality of pro-
curement procedures to be reviewed”. See Case C-324/98. See also ruling of
30 May 2002, also Case C-358/00, Deutsche Bibliothek, ECR I-4685. These
principles are also applicable to other State acts entrusting an economic
service to a third party, as for example the contracts excluded from the
scope of the Directives owing to the fact that they have a value below
the threshold values laid down in the secondary legislation (Order of the
Court of 3 December 2001, Case C-59/00, Vestergaard, ECR I-9505), or
so-called non-priority services.
68. Spain (law of 23 May 2003 on works concessions), Italy (Merloni law of
1994, as amended) and France (Sapin law of 1993) have nonetheless
adopted such legislation.
69. i.e. those listed in Annex IA of Directive 92/50/EEC and Annex XVIA of
Directive 93/38/EEC.
70. i.e. Directives 93/37/EEC, 92/50/EEC and 2004/18/EC.
71. For example, it may apply when the works are to be carried out in a geo-
logically unstable or archaeological terrain and for this reason the extent
of the necessary work is not known when launching the tender proce-
dure. A similar derogation is provided for in Article 11(2) of Directive
92/50, and in Article 30(1)(b) of Directive 2004/18/EC.
72. Article 29 of Directive 2004/18/EC.
73. Article 23 of Directive 2004/18/EC and Article 34 of Directive
2004/17/EC.
74. The Member States use different terminology and schemes in this
context (for example, the Kooperationsmodell, joint PPPs, Joint
Ventures).
75. Note that the principles governing the law on public contracts and con-
cessions apply also when a task is awarded in the form of a unilateral act
(e.g. a legislative or regulatory act).
76. When planning and arranging such transactions, the test involving the
use of the standard forms – which include the elements indispensable
for a well-informed competition, – also demonstrate how difficult it can
be to find an adequate form of advertising to award tasks falling within
the scope of the law on public contracts or concessions.
77. Participation in a new undertaking with a view to establishing lasting eco-
nomic links is covered by the provisions of Article 56 relating to the free
movement of capital. See Annex I of Directive 88/361/EEC, adopted in the
context of the former Article 67, which lists the types of operations which
must be considered as movements of capital.
78. See Judgements of the Court of 4 June 2002, Case C-367/98, Com-
mission v. Portugal, ECR I-4731; Case C-483/99, Commission v. France,
ECR I-4781; and Judgements of 13 May 2003, Case C-463/00, Com-
mission v. Spain, ECR. I-4581; Case C-98/01, Commission v. United
Kingdom, Rec. I-4641. On the possible justifications in this framework,
see Judgement of the Court of 4 June 2002, Case C-503/99, Commission
v. Belgium, ECR I-4809.
Notes 275
79. This follows from the neutrality principle of the Treaty in relation to
ownership rules, recognised by Article 295 of the Treaty.
80. Article 56 ff. of the EC Treaty.
81. See Communication of the Commission on certain legal aspects
concerning intra-EU investment OJ No C 220, 19 July 1997, p. 15.
82. See, on these lines, the Judgement of the Court of 13 April 2000, Case
C-251/98, Baars, ECR I-2787.
83. See the FIDE Congress on The Application in the Member States of the
Directives on Public Procurement, Madrid 1990.
84. One the most notorious features of the existing PFI process is the
abysmally lengthy negotiation stage and the prolonged pre-contractual
arrangements. This represents a considerable (recoverable) cost which
would be reflected in the final deal. See Financial Times, 24/07/98,
where its was reported that lengthy negotiations due to the lack of
clear guidelines and standard contractual forms presented a serious
deterrent factor in concluding PFI contracts. The average PFI gestation
period is 18 months compared with 2 months in traditional public
procurement contracts.
85. A serious set back for the Private Finance Initiative in the United
Kingdom was the report of the Accounting Standards Board (The Tweedie
Report – September 1998) which criticised the practice of the HM Treasury
not to include PFI deals in the Public Sector Borrowing Requirement
(PSBR) balance sheet. The report condemned such practices and urged
the government, for the sake of legal certainty and good public sector
management and accounting to issue new guidelines for future PFI pro-
jects and treat them in the same way as traditional public procurement
spending.
86. Prior to 1997, there was considerable uncertainty as to the legal position
of the parties to a privately financed project. The relevant legislation did
not provide in concreto for the rights and obligations of the private sector
and threatened with ultra vires agreements concluded between certain
public authorities (local authorities and health trusts) and the private
sector. It was unclear whether these authorities had explicit or implied
powers to enter into such contracts, a situation which left privately
financed transactions in limbo. As a consequence, the National Health
Service (Private Finance) Act 1997 and the Local Government Act (Contracts)
1997 have been enacted in order to clear all legal obstacles. Both acts
have introduced a “clearance system” where the relevant authorities
must certified a prospective PFI deal with the government, checking not
only its vires but the whole commercial viability and procedural delivery
mechanism of a privately financed contract.
and finally the relevant provisions which embrace the award of works
contracts subsidised directly by more than 50 per cent by the state within
the scope of the Directive [Article 2(1)(2) of Directive 93/37].
31. See Bovis, The Liberalisation of Public Procurement in the European Union
and its Effects on the Common Market, Chapter 1, op. cit. footnote 10.
32. See case C-107/98, Teckal Slr. v. Commune di Viano [1999] ECR I-8121.
33. This type of dependency resembles the Court’s definition in its ruling on
state controlled enterprises in case 152/84 Marshall v. Southampton and
South West Hampshire Area Health Authority [1986] ECR 723.
34. C-237/99, Commission v. France [2001] ECR 934.
35. See case C-380/98, The Queen and H.M. Treasury, ex parte University of
Cambridge [2000] ECR 8035.
36. See paragraph 25 of the Court’s judgement as well as the Opinion of the
Advocate General, paragraph 46.
37. See Freeman, Extending Public Law Norms through Privatization, 116
Harvard Law Review, 2003, p. 1285 et seq. Freeman argues that privatisa-
tion does not curtail the remit of the state. On the contrary it enacts a
process of “publicisation”, where through the extension of public law
norms to private undertakings entrusted with the delivery of public
services the state maintains a dominant position in the dispersement
of governance. Also, along the same lines see Frug, New Forms of
Governance, Getting Public Power to Private Actors, 49 UCLA Review 2002,
p. 1687.
38. Corporatism has been deemed as an important instrument of industrial
policy of a state, in particular where procurement systems have been
utilised with a view to promoting structural adjustment policies and
favour national champions. See Bovis, The Choice of Policies and the Regula-
tion Public Procurement in the European Community in T. Lawton (ed.)
European Industrial Policy and Competitiveness: concepts and instruments,
Macmillan Publishers, 1998.
39. Alongside privatisation, the notion of contracting out represents a
further departure from the premises of traditional corporatism. The
notion of contracting out is an exercise which aims at achieving poten-
tial savings and efficiency gains for contracting authorities, when they
test the market in an attempt to define whether the provision of works
or the delivery of services from a commercial operator could be cheaper
than that from the in-house team. Contracting out differs from privati-
sation to the extent that the former represents a transfer of undertaking
only, whereas the latter denotes transfer of ownership. Contracting out
depicts a price-discipline exercise by the state, against the principle of
insourcing, where, the self-sufficient nature of corporatism resulted in
budgetary inefficiencies and poor quality of deliverables to the public.
See Domberger and Jensen, Contracting Out by the Public Sector: Theory,
Evidence, Prospects, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Winter 1997.
40. Classic example of such approach is the views of the UK Government in
relation to the involvement of the private sector in delivering public ser-
vices through the so-called Private Finance Initiative (PFI), which attempts
to create a framework between the public and private sectors working
together in delivering public services. See in particular, Working Together
280 Notes
(ACOSS) [2001] ECR I-09067. Case Case C-280/00, Altmark Trans GmbH
and Regierungsprδsidium Magdeburg v. Nahverkehrsgesellschaft Altmark GmbH
and Oberbundesanwalt beim Bundesverwaltungsgericht [2003] ECR 1432.
63. See Opinion of Advocate General Jacobs in Case C-126/01, Ministre de
l’economie, des finances et de l’industrie v. GEMO SA [2003] ECR 3454.
64. For example the form in which the aid is granted (See cases C-323/82
Intermills v. Commission [1984] ECR 3809, paragraph 31; Case C-142/87
Belgium v. Commission, cited in note 18, paragraph 13; and Case 40/85
Belgium v. Commission [1986] ECR I-2321, paragraph 120, the legal status
of the measure in national law (See Commission Decision 93/349/EEC of
9 March 1993 concerning aid provided by the United Kingdom Govern-
ment to British Aerospace for its purchase of Rover Group Holdings over
and above those authorised in Commission Decision 89/58/EEC autho-
rising a maximum aid to this operation subject to certain conditions (OJ
1993 L 143, p. 7, point IX), the fact that the measure is part of an aid
scheme (Case T-16/96, Cityflyer Express v. Commission [1998] ECR II-757),
the reasons for the measure and the objectives of the measure ((case
C-173/73 Italy v. Commission [1974] ECR 709; Deufil v. Commission
[1987] ECR 901; Case C-56/93 Belgium v. Commission [1996] ECR I-723;
Case C-241/94 France v. Commission [1996] ECR I-4551; Case C-5/01
Belgium v. Commission [2002] ECR I-3452) and the intentions of the
public authorities and the recipient undertaking (Commission Decision
92/11/EEC of 31 July 1991 concerning aid provided by the Derbyshire
County Council to Toyota Motor Corporation, an undertaking produc-
ing motor vehicles (OJ 1992 L 6, p. 36, point V.).
65. See case C-173/73 Italy v. Commission [1974] ECR 709, paragraph 27; Deufil
v. Commission [1987] ECR 901; Case C-56/93 Belgium v. Commission [1996]
ECR I-723 paragraph 79; Case C-241/94 France v. Commission [1996]
ECR I-4551, paragraph 20; and Case C-5/01 Belgium v. Commission [2002]
ECR I-3452, paragraphs 45 and 46.
66. See Case 156/77, Commission v. Belgium [1978] ECR 1881.
67. A similar approach is followed for maritime transport. See The European
Commission’s Guidelines on State aid to maritime transport, OJ 1997
C 205.
68. See Article 2 of Regulation 2408/92.
69. Such public service obligations may be imposed on scheduled air ser-
vices to an airport serving peripheral or development regions in its terri-
tory or on a thin route to any regional airport in its territory provided
that any such route is considered vital for the economic development of
the region in which the airport is located.
70. See Article 4 (1) (h) of Regulation 2408/92 OJ L 240 1992 on access for
air carriers to intra-Community air routes.
71. The development and the implementation of these schemes must be
transparent. The Commission would expect the selected company to
have an analytical accounting system sophisticated enough to apportion
the relevant costs (including fixed costs) and revenues.
72. See Case 173/73, Italian Government v. Commission [1974] ECR 709.
73. See Cases C301/87 France v. Commission [1990] ECR I-307; Case C142/87
Belgium v. Commission [1990] ECR I-959.
Notes 283
82. See Case C-360/96, Gemeente Arnhem Gemeente Rheden v. BFI Holding BV,
op. cit.
83. Cases C-223/99, Agora Srl v. Ente Autonomo Fiera Internazionale di Milano
and C-260/99 Excelsior Snc di Pedrotti Runa & C v. Ente Autonomo Fiera
Internazionale di Milano, op. cit.
84. See Bazex, Le droit public de la concurrence, RFDA, 1998; Arcelin, L’enter-
prise en droit interne et communautaire de la concurrence, Paris, Litec, 2003;
Guézou, Droit de la concurrence et droit des marchés publics: vers une notion
transverale de mise en libre concurrence, Contrats Publics, Mars 2003.
85. See Joined Cases C-83/01 P, C-93/01 P and C-94/01 Chronopost and
Others [2003], not yet reported; see also the earlier judgement of the CFI
Case T-613/97 Ufex and Others v. Commission [2000] ECR II-4055.
86. See Evans, European Community Law of State Aid, Clarendon Press,
Oxford, 1997.
87. C-44/96, Mannesmann Anlangenbau Austria AG et al. v. Strohal Rotations-
durck GesmbH, op. cit. footnote 9. See also the analysis of the case by
Bovis, in 36 CMLR (1999), pp. 205–225.
88. According to Advocate General Léger in his Opinion on the Altmark case,
the apparent advantage theory occurs in several provisions of the Treaty,
in particular in Article 92(2) and (3), and in Article 77 of the EC Treaty
(now Article 73 EC). Article 92(3) of the Treaty provides that aid may be
regarded as compatible with the common market if it pursues certain
objectives such as the strengthening of economic and social cohesion, the
promotion of research and the protection of the environment.
89. See case C-173/73 Italy v. Commission [1974] ECR 709; Deufil v. Com-
mission [1987] ECR 901; Case C-56/93 Belgium v. Commission [1996] ECR
I-723; Case C-241/94 France v. Commission [1996] ECR I-4551; Case
C-5/01 Belgium v. Commission [2002] ECR I-3452.
90. For example the form in which the aid is granted, the legal status of the
measure in national law, the fact that the measure is part of an aid
scheme, the reasons for the measure, the objectives of the measure and
the intentions of the public authorities and the recipient undertaking.
91. For example certain categories of aid are compatible with the common
market on condition that they are employed through a specific format.
See Commission notice 97/C 238/02 on Community guidelines on State
aid for rescuing and restructuring firms in difficulty, OJ 1997 C 283.
92. According to Article 26 of Directive 93/36, Article 30 of Directive 93/37,
Article 34 of Directive 93/38 and Article 36 of Directive 92/50, two crite-
ria provide the conditions under which contracting authorities award
public contracts: the lowest price or the most economically advantageous
offer. The first criterion indicates that, subject to the qualitative criteria
and financial and economic standing, contracting authorities do not
rely on any other factor than the price quoted to complete the contract.
The Directives provide for an automatic disqualification of an “obvi-
ously abnormally low offer”. The term has not been interpreted in detail
by the Court and serves rather as an indication of a “lower bottom
limit” of contracting authorities accepting offers from the private sector
tenderers See Case 76/81, SA Transporoute et Travaux v. Minister of Public
Works [1982] ECR 457; Case 103/88, Fratelli Costanzo S.p.A. v. Comune di
Notes 285
Milano [1989] ECR 1839; Case 295/89, Impresa Dona Alfonso di Dona
Alfonso & Figli s.n.c. v. Consorzio per lo Sviluppo Industriale del Comune di
Monfalcone [1991] ECR 2967.
93. An interesting view of the lowest price representing market value bench-
marking is provided by the case C-94/99, ARGE Gewässerschutzt, op. cit.
footnote 9, where the Court ruled that directly or indirectly subsidised
tenders by the state or other contracting authorities or even by the con-
tracting authority itself can be legitimately part of the evaluation
process, although it did not elaborate on the possibility of rejection of
an offer, which is appreciably lower than those of unsubsidised tender-
ers by reference to the of abnormally low disqualification ground.
94. The meaning of the most economically advantageous offer includes a
series of factors chosen by the contracting authority, including price,
delivery or completion date, running costs, cost-effectiveness, profitabil-
ity, technical merit, product or work quality, aesthetic and functional
characteristics, after-sales service and technical assistance, commitments
with regard to spare parts and components and maintenance costs,
security of supplies. The above list is not exhaustive.
95. For example the form in which the aid is granted, the legal status of the
measure in national law, the fact that the measure is part of an aid
scheme, the reasons for the measure, the objectives of the measure and
the intentions of the public authorities and the recipient undertaking.
96. For example certain categories of aid are compatible with the common
market on condition that they are employed through a specific format.
See Commission notice 97/C 238/02, OJ 1997 C 283 on Community
guidelines on State aid for rescuing and restructuring firms in difficulty.
97. See case C-107/98, Teckal Slr v. Comune di Viano [1999] ECR I-8121.
98. See Council Directive 83/349, OJ 1983 L193/1.
99. The explanatory memorandum accompanying the text amending the
Utilities Directive (COM (91) 347-SYN 36 1) states that this provision
relates, in particular, to three types of service provision within groups.
These categories, which may not or may not be distinct, are: the provi-
sion of common services such as accounting, recruitment and manage-
ment; the provision of specialised services embodying the know how of
the group; the provision of a specialised service to a joint venture. The
exclusion from the provisions of the Directive is subject, however,
to two conditions: the service-provider must be an undertaking affiliated
to the contracting authority and, at least 80 per cent of its average
turnover arising within the European Community for the preceding
three years, derives from the provision of the same or similar services to
undertakings with which it is affiliated. The Commission is empowered
to monitor the application of this Article and require the notification of
the names of the undertakings concerned and the nature and value
of the service contracts involved.
100. The determination of a genuinely competitive regime is left to the util-
ities operators themselves. See case, C 392/93, The Queen and H.M.
Treasury, ex parte British Telecommunications PLC [1996] ECR I-1631.
This approach by the Court is reflected into the current proposals of
the Public Procurement Directives to disengage from the relevant
286 Notes
287
288 Index