Theory of Absolute Advantage
Theory of Absolute Advantage
Absolute advantage refers to how a company, country, or region produces a greater quantity of a
product while maintaining the amount of time it takes to produce the product.
When there is absolute advantage, the same quantity of goods are produced using a lesser quantity of
inputs than another company. This increases competition between companies, and can be advantageous
for trade.
It is important to note that absolute advantage looks into the efficiency of production for a single
product.
If a company has a lower absolute advantage, it can produce products and services at a lower absolute
cost per unit, which uses a small number of inputs, or possibly a more efficient process than another
company that produces the same good or service.
The unit cost is a crucial measure to determine operational analysis of a company. Analyzing unit cost is
an effective way to determine if the company is producing content efficiently.
The absolute advantage matters because it determines if a producer can provide goods or services in
greater quantity for the same or lower cost than competing producers.
Additionally, absolute advantage is an effective basis for gains from trade between companies who
produce different goods with different absolute advantages.
Specialization, division of labor, and trade with producers who have different absolute advantages leads
to more gains than production in isolation. It is also related to comparative advantage, which opens up
more widespread opportunities for gains from trade, as well as division of labor.
Adam Smith first developed the idea of absolute advantage in his book, "The Wealth of the Nations." He
used this idea to demonstrate how countries that specialize in producing and exporting certain goods
gain from trade with other countries.
In "Wealth of the Nations," Smith uses labor as the only input. Absolute advantage is determined by
comparison of labor productiveness, so it is possible for a party to have no absolute advantage.
There are several good examples of this in the Chinese economy and the Canadian Economy. The
Chinese economy exports low-cost manufactured goods, and takes advantage of their low unit labor
costs.
The Canadian economy is rich in low cost land, and has an absolute advantage in agricultural production.
Comparative advantage looks at the reduction of opportunity cost, which is the potential benefit gained
by choosing to produce more of one product instead of producing the maximum amount of both
products a country has absolute advantage in.
In the chart below, we see the United States has the absolute advantage in both refrigerators and shoes.
Absolute advantage examines the productivity of workers in each country, answering the question "how
many inputs are needed to produce shoes in Mexico?"
Comparative advantage asks the question in a different way, instead focusing on the output it takes to
produce goods in a country.
It identifies the good where the absolute advantage is relatively larger, or where the productivity
disadvantage is smaller.
Comparative Advantages help countries consider possibilities for trade, and how to maximize production
for profit.
In this situation, the United States has a higher comparative advantage of shoes over refrigerators (1
worker in the US versus 4 in Mexico), and Mexico has a higher comparative advantage of shoes (5
workers in Mexico versus 4 in the US).
If both countries were to continue with their production rates, using 40 workers per good, the United
States would produce 10,000 shoes and 40,000 refrigerators.
Mexico would produce 8,000 shoes, and 10,000 refrigerators, shown in the chart below.
If point A on each graph which is where countries start producing and consuming before trade. At this
point, the United States produces 20,000 refrigerators and 5,000 pairs of shoes.
Mexico produces 4,000 pairs of shoes and 5,000 refrigerators, for a total of 9,000 shoes produced, and
25,000 refrigerators produced.
If each country were to transfer workers toward their area of comparative advantage, this would shift
slightly.
If the US transferred six workers away from shoes to work on refrigerators, the shoe production
decreases by 1,500 units (6/4 x 1,000), and refrigerator production increases by 6,000 (6/1 x 1,000).
If Mexico moves toward their area of comparative advantage, and transfers 10 workers to work on
production of shoes, the production of refrigerators decreases by 2,500 (10/4 x 1,000), and production
of shoes increases by 2,000 pairs (10/5 x 1,000).
This leads to a greater production of goods overall, as shown in the chart below.
This example shows that even though the United States has an absolute advantage in both goods, both
countries can benefit from increased production in their area of comparative advantage. The United
States will then export refrigerators, and import shoes.
Origin
The Theory of Absolute Advantage is one of the earliest economic theories
that explains the benefits of specialisation and international trade between
countries. It was proposed by Adam Smith, the father of modern economics,
in 1776 in his seminal work, "The Wealth of Nations." The theory of absolute
advantage is based on the idea that countries can benefit from trade if they
specialise in producing goods or services in which they have an absolute
advantage over other countries.
0 of 34 secondsVolume 0%
Assumptions
The theory of absolute advantage is based on some assumptions, which are
given below.
There are only two countries in the world (Countries A and B).
Both countries can only produce two goods. (Chairs and tables).
The same resources are used to produce both goods.
Both countries have different factor endowment in terms of the quality
of their resources.
Resources are homogeneous within a country. For example, all the
workers in a country have the same skills, qualifications, productivity,
and motivation.
The factors of production or inputs (such as labor and capital) are not
mobile between countries.
There is constant opportunity cost. (We assume a straight-line
production possibility frontier.)
There is no transportation cost.
There is free trade between trading countries. It means that there are no
trade barriers for international trade.
There is barter trade.
Data Example
Let’s use a data example to better understand the concept of absolute
advantage.
Suppose that each of the countries A and B has 10 workers. Then, In country
A, 10 workers can produce 40 chairs or 20 tables and each worker can produce
4 chairs or 2 tables. While in country B, 10 workers can produce 20 chairs or 40
tables and each worker can produce 2 chairs or 4 tables.
TWO is the total world output produced by both countries. For example, the
total world output of chairs is 30 which is the sum of the outputs of country A
(20) and country B (10).
It can be noted from above two cases, that the total world output (TWO) is
increased due to specialisation. But the problem is that country A does not
have tables and country B does not have chairs. This problem can be solved
through international trade.
The barter exchange rate is the rate at which one country’s goods can be
exchanged with another country’s goods. It is also called the barter terms of
trade. The following points are important.
The opportunity cost table is used to decide the barter exchange rate.
The barter exchange rate must lie between opportunity cost ratios.
The theory assumes that all factors of production are fixed and cannot be
increased or decreased. In reality, factors of production are not fixed and can
be increased or decreased through investment and innovation.
The theory does not account for the impact of government policies, such as
subsidies and taxation, on trade.
The theory does not account for the impact of technological change on trade.
The theory assumes free trade without trade restrictions. In reality, there may
be tariffs, quotas, and other trade restrictions between countries.
The theory assumes a constant opportunity cost, but in reality, the opportunity
cost may not be constant, especially if resources are not homogeneous or if
the production process becomes more complex.
The theory assumes barter trade, but in reality, most international trade is
conducted through monetary exchange.
These examples illustrate how countries can benefit from specialising in the
production of goods in which they have an absolute advantage, and then
trading with other countries to obtain goods in which they do not have an
absolute advantage.
Conclusion
In conclusion, the theory of absolute advantage provides a useful framework
for understanding the benefits of international trade between countries. By
specialising in the production of goods and services in which they have an
absolute advantage, countries can increase their productivity and efficiency
and reduce their production costs. However, the theory has several limitations
and assumptions that must be considered, and it should be compared with
other economic theories, such as the theory of comparative advantage, for a
more complete understanding of the benefits of international trade.