Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation University
Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation University
k
Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation
\
I N NOVATION and TECH NO LOGY in the WORLD ECONOMY
Editors
MARTIN KENNEY
BRUCE KOGUT
2003
2001
,
Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation
University-Industry Technology Transfer Before and
After the Bayh-Dole Act in the United States
Acknowledgments xiii
9 Conclusion x79
Notes 19 3
References 215
Index 229
Tables and Figures
TABLES
FIGURES
xiv gave us many helpful comments on earlier versions of much of the research
contained in this volume. We are especially indebted to Nathan Rosenberg
of Stanford University, who contributed to portions of Chapter 2 and who
played a central role in the early stages of the research project that produced
this volume.
Support for this research was provided by the Andrew W. Mellon Founda¬
tion; the Alfred R Sloan Foundation; the California Policy Seminar; the UC
Presidents Industry-University Cooperative Research Program; the Office of
the Provost at Columbia University; the Division of Research at the Harvard
Business School; the Institute of Innovation, Organization, and Management
at the Haas School of Business, UC Berkeley; and the Mack Center of the
Wharton School at the University of Pennsylvania.
Ivory Tower and Industrial Innovation
I
1
This monograph deals with the relationship between U.S. universities and in¬
dustrial innovation, focusing in particular on the role of patenting and licens¬
ing of academic inventions in supporting “technology transfer” between uni¬
versities and industry. The role of universities in industrial innovation and
economic growth has received considerable fanfare in recent years, as U.S.
universities have expanded their patenting and licensing activities since the
early 1980s. Many observers have attributed this expanded patenting and li¬
censing to the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980, although little hard evidence has been
provided in support of this conclusion. Nor has much evidence been pro¬
duced to support the argument that patenting and licensing of university in¬
ventions are necessary to support the transfer to industry and commercial de¬
velopment of these inventions. Other, more critical accounts of the Bayh-Dole
Act have suggested that the growth in academic patenting and licensing has
changed the “research culture” of U.S. universities, leading to increased se¬
crecy, less sharing of research results, and a shift in the focus of academic re¬
search away from fundamental to more applied topics.
The evidence presented in this volume suggests that the Bayh-Dole Act was
one of several factors that contributed to the growth of patenting and licensing
by U.S. universities during the 1980s and 1990s. The Act provided a strong con¬
gressional endorsement for academic institutions’ involvement in patenting
and licensing research discoveries and simplified the formerly complex ad¬
ministrative processes through which U.S. universities gained title to the in¬
tellectual property resulting from publicly funded research. Even without the
Bayh-Dole Act, however, we believe that university patenting would have
grown significantly during the 1980s and 1990s. As we point out below, many
INTRODUCTION
U.S. universities were active patenters and licensors long before the passage of
the Bayh-Dole Act, and they expanded these activities during the 1970s and
early 1980s in response to advances in biomedical research and changes in
the legal treatment of patents on life forms. It is likely that these and other
universities with less experience in patenting and licensing would have initi¬
ated or expanded these activities even in the absence of the Bayh-Dole Act. In¬
deed, U.S. research universities were an important source of support for the
passage of the Act in 1980, as we note in Chapter 5. Nonetheless, there is little
doubt that U.S. universities now are more heavily and directly involved in
patenting and licensing of research results than at any previous time in their
history.
The Bayh-Dole Act was motivated by the belief that university patenting
would spur and facilitate the transfer of university discoveries to industry for
commercial development. Although the evidence on this point presented in
this volume is at best suggestive rather than definitive, it indicates that research
results and knowledge flow between universities and industry (and we stress
the two-way nature of this flow) through publications by academic researchers,
conference presentations, faculty consulting, and the movement of personnel
between universities and industry, to name but a few channels. Before and
since the Bayh-Dole Act, much of the interaction between universities and in¬
dustry has not involved patenting and licensing.
In some cases, university patenting may indeed aid technology transfer, but
in many cases patenting of an invention by a university is not necessary to sup¬
port the transfer and commercialization of an invention. In these cases, pat¬
ents may produce income for the university (although most patents yield little
licensing income), while creating some risk that restrictive licensing policies
can limit the diffusion and use of an invention or related knowledge. Indeed,
in some fields of research, patenting and licensing could limit the operation
of other channels of mutual influence and interaction.
In short, the issues raised by university patenting and licensing are com¬
plex, and the course of action that is likely to yield the greatest public benefit
(the overriding goal of Bayh-Dole) varies among inventions and fields of tech¬
nology. Nevertheless, for the foreseeable future, U.S. universities (and, it
seems, more and more non-U.S. universities) will be patenting more inten¬
sively. A key challenge for policy concerns the appropriate design of licensing
policies for universities engaged in patenting of inventions financed with pub¬
lic funds to ensure that publicly funded research yields the greatest possible
societal benefit.
The growth in U.S. university patenting and licensing has been con¬
centrated in a relatively narrow set of research fields, notably the biomedical
INTRODUCTION
Although the Bayh-Dole Act and its effects are central issues in the chapters
that follow, our examination of the Acts origins and consequences requires a
broader consideration of the historical evolution of university-industry rela¬
tions and technology transfer in the United States, which we undertake in
Chapters 2-4. American universities have made significant contributions to
technological innovation in industry for well over a century. The Morrill Act
of 1862 was emblematic of an American commitment that universities should
serve the democracy and its citizens. Research at university agricultural ex¬
perimentation stations provided the scientific base for the hybrid corn revolu¬
tion of the 1930s and the postwar years and played a central role in developing
hybrid seed varieties tailored to the particular conditions of individual states.
But U.S. universities’ contributions to the development of the American
economy went well beyond agriculture. Edwin Armstrongs work at Columbia
University laid the basis for vacuum tube-based amplification of electronic
signals, a key contribution to the development of modern radio technology.
Much of the early work in developing computers and lasers, as well as the In¬
ternet, was performed in universities. And universities played leading roles in
the development of a number of important pharmaceuticals.
These historic contributions of U.S. universities to industrial innovation
were made through a diverse array of channels of interaction, all of which
INTRODUCTION
Before and after the Bayh-Dole Act, the licensing revenues of the experi¬
enced academic patenters were dominated by a very small number of “home
run” inventions, most of which were biomedical inventions. This characteri¬
zation also accurately describes the 1985—95 licensing revenues of Columbia
University, which had much less historical experience in patenting and li¬
censing. The unpredictable and infrequent appearance of such “home runs”
means that many U.S. universities active in patenting and licensing of faculty
inventions have found these activities to be unprofitable. Although income is
only one of several motives for pursuing these technology transfer activities, it
figures prominently among the reasons for entry by many universities into
patenting and licensing after 1980. Moreover, greater institutional experience
in managing patenting and licensing may not increase the probability that
such a “home run” will be discovered by a university’s faculty or other re¬
searchers and be disclosed to its licensing office.
The effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on the patenting activities of experienced
academic patenters thus were more modest than many assessments suggest.
Nevertheless, the Bayh-Dole Act facilitated the entry into patenting of a num¬
ber of institutions with little experience in managing patenting and licensing
activities. These novice patenters did indeed receive less heavily cited patents
initially, but by the end of the 1980s their patents were cited no less intensively
than those assigned to “experienced” academic patenters and (like the patents
assigned to “experienced” universities) were more heavily cited than nonaca¬
demic patents in the same classes.
As we noted earlier, the case studies in Chapter 8 seek to examine an im¬
portant assumption animating the drafting and passage of the Bayh-Dole Act,
viz., the belief that patenting was both necessary and sufficient to facilitate the
transfer to industry and commercial development of university inventions. The
case studies indicate that the processes of knowledge exchange and technolog)'
transfer are complex, and the channels through which these processes operate
most effectively differ significantly among different fields of technology. More¬
over, these processes also require a strong “relational” component for their
smooth operation — as we note in Chapters 4 and 8, centralization in university
licensing operations historically has been difficult, because of the need for fre¬
quent interaction between licensing professionals and the faculty inventors.
Another set of assumptions underpinning the design of the Bayh-Dole Act
dealt with the characteristics of the intellectual property for which universities
would seek patent protection. The Act saw patented intellectual property as a
key enabling factor in the process of technology development—without clear
property rights on intellectual property, commercial developers would not
make the investments necessary to bring these inventions to the market. But a
INTRODUCTION
Their focus on training for farmers and workers, along with research oriented
to regional economic development, differentiated American land-grant uni¬
versities from European universities of the late nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries. U.S. public universities, especially those established under the
terms of the Morrill Act, affected the direction of the academic research en¬
terprise during this period to a greater extent than the private Ivy League in¬
stitutions. These characteristics were anticipated in Alexis de Tocquevilles
discussion of attitudes toward science in the young republic:
In America the purely practical part of science is admirably understood and care¬
ful attention is paid to the theoretical portion, which is immediately requisite to
application. On this head, the Americans always display a clear, free, original, and
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
inventive power of mind. But hardly any one in the United States devotes himself
to the essentially theoretical and abstract portion of human knowledge. (i99°>
vol. 2, p. 42)
on the basis of the special needs of their local environment. One consequence
of this approach was that the funding and enrollment of these schools became
heavily dependent on the mores and needs of the local community.3 And as
de Tocqueville indicated, these mores tended strongly to the practical. Partly
because of these utilitarian motives, as well as the demand by many commu¬
nities for colleges or universities, the United States developed a higher educa¬
tion system” that was larger than those of contemporary European nations.
As Trow (1979) points out,
America had established 9 colleges by the time of the Revolution, when 2— Oxford
and Cambridge — were enough for the much larger and wealthier mother country.
The United States entered the Civil War with about 250 colleges, of which over 180
still survive. Even more striking is the record of failure: between the American Rev¬
olution and the Civil War perhaps as many as 700 colleges were started and failed.
By 1880 England was doing very well with 4 universities for a population of 23 mil¬
lion, while the single state of Ohio, with a population of 3 million, already boasted
37 institutions of higher learning ... By 1910 we had nearly a thousand colleges and
universities with a third of a million students —at a time when the 16 universities of
France enrolled altogether about forty thousand students, a number nearly equaled
by the faculty members of the American institutions, (pp. 271-72)
Not surprisingly, the U.S. higher education system enrolled a larger frac¬
tion of the eighteen-to-twenty-two-year-old population than those of any Eu¬
ropean nations throughout the 1900-1945 period. According to Geiger (1986),
roughly 12 percent of this age group was enrolled in U.S. universities and col¬
leges as early as 1928, a sharp increase from 8 percent in 1920. Although the
fraction of this age group enrolled in colleges and universities probably de¬
clined during the Great Depression, Graham and Diamond (1997, p. 24) esti¬
mate that the share reached 12 percent once again by 1940, three times the
4 percent of Europeans in this age cohort enrolled in colleges and universities
in the same year. Not until the 1960s did European enrollment rates exceed
10 percent of the relevant age cohorts, by which time U.S. enrollment rates
within this group were reaching 50 percent (Burn et ah, 1971).
The Morrill Act of 1862 was rooted in these American views about the role
of university research and teaching. The Acts intent was eminently practical,
inasmuch as it was dedicated to the support of agriculture and the mechani¬
cal arts by encouraging the establishment of state-controlled universities
whose long-term prosperity and success depended on their responsiveness to
the demands of the local community. But private universities also depended
on local support throughout much of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries
for their sustenance and growth. Their dependence on local sources of finan¬
cial and political support, combined with the lack of centralized control or
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
the most important such projects was conducted at the Mines Experiment
Station of the University of Minnesota, beginning before World War I and
continuing through the early 1960s. This long-term applied research project
addressed the consequences of the gradual exhaustion of the high-yielding
iron ores in the Mesabi Range. As the supply of these ores declined, re¬
searchers focused on ores of lower iron content, specifically the abundant
deposits of low-quality taconite ore. Although it did not rely on new scientific
knowledge, the solution to innumerable engineering and processing problems
associated with taconite extraction and refinement required decades of exper¬
imentation at the Mines Experiment Station (Davis, 1964).
A final characteristic of the U.S. higher education system that distinguished
it from those of other industrial economies throughout the twentieth century
was the emergence of a unified national market for faculty at U.S. research
universities. The departmental structure of most U.S. universities and colleges
and the emergence of strong disciplinary degree programs and societies by the
late nineteenth century meant that faculty qualifications were established on
the basis of their contributions to disciplinary research rather than their con¬
tributions to a specific institution.4 This interinstitutional mobility, combined
with the strong competition among U.S. universities for prestige, resources,
and students, meant that faculty moved among universities, especially the
most prestigious public and private research universities, more frequently
than was true of faculty in other national systems of higher education. Such
mobility provided a powerful mechanism for the diffusion of new ideas, cur¬
ricula, and research approaches among U.S. universities that was less highly
developed in other national systems of higher education.
Throughout the twentieth century, the U.S. system of higher education has
been distinguished from those of other industrial economies by its large scale,
the high level of autonomy enjoyed by individual universities and colleges, the
dependence by these institutions on local sources of financial and political
support, and the strong competition among universities and colleges for
funds, prestige, faculty, and students. These structural characteristics of U.S.
higher education created powerful incentives for university researchers and
administrators to establish close relationships with industry. They also moti¬
vated university researchers to seek commercial applications for university-
developed inventions, regardless of the presence or absence of formal patent
protection. Finally, the large scale and vocational orientation of many U.S.
universities, combined with the conduct of research within these universi¬
ties, created an effective channel for the rapid dissemination of new research
findings into industrial practice —the movement of graduates into industrial
employment.
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
Electrical Engineering
Chemical Engineering
neers at Standard Oil of New Jersey and MIT faculty who worked to codify,
advance, and disseminate the key tenets of the emergent discipline.6
Much of the collaboration during this period combined joint development
of these new practices in academic and industrial laboratories with relatively
widespread dissemination, particularly through teaching and textbooks. The
Standard Oil refinery in Baton Rouge, Louisiana, also played a key role as an
unofficial external laboratory and employer of a great many of the MIT grad¬
uates and (as consultants) a number of the faculty at MIT in the school of
chemical engineering. In many respects, this collaboration culminated in the
development of fluidized bed catalysis in 1941. Research conducted at MIT
complemented research done in the Baton Rouge refinery; although patents
were an important output of this research activity, the university had no direct
role in managing or licensing this intellectual property.
The key to this style of collaboration was personnel exchange between MIT
and industry through faculty consulting, faculty rotations to and from indus¬
try, and placement of graduates. Personnel exchange brought expertise from
MIT to industry and transferred practical knowledge from industry to acade¬
mia, where it was refined and codified, supporting the development of a
broader engineering discipline. As in many other areas of engineering or sci¬
entific research, access by faculty to industrial facilities was important, as the
scale and type of equipment in industry often were unavailable within the uni¬
versity. The industrial collaborators obtained the ownership of or were as¬
signed the intellectual property resulting from collaboration, and a great deal,
although not all, of the results of the research by academics in the industrial
context was published.
Aeronautical Engineering
20 the usual definition of basic research, which involves a quest for fundamental
understanding. In the traditional natural sciences, such a quest has often been
identified with research with no immediate concern with practical appli¬
cations. But much research in the applied sciences and engineering is quite
basic, since it involves a search for fundamental understanding. Most of the
research in the medical sciences is undertaken with specific practical appli¬
cations in view. Medical studies of carcinogenic processes necessarily involve
research into fundamental aspects of cell biology. All of these lines of inquiry
were classed by the late Donald Stokes (1997) as research in “Pasteurs Quad¬
rant," defined as research that seeks to understand the fundamental physical,
biological, or chemical processes that underpin specific problems, solutions,
or applications.
This selective review of the development of a number of important engi¬
neering disciplines suggests that engineering education in the United States
has consistently attempted to provide reference points for inquiry into the de¬
tails of practical problems. At the same time, however, university research has
provided an intellectual framework for training professional decision-makers,
as Herbert Simon (1969) reminds us:
sciences extended but did not replace the longer-standing tradition in Ameri- 21
can universities of research and education in the service of local industry and
agriculture.
Our discussion thus far has emphasized the distinctive structure of the U.S.
higher education system throughout the late nineteenth and twentieth centu¬
ries and the contrasts between this structure and those of other industrial na¬
tions. In this section, we discuss the dramatic changes in the financing of U.S.
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
22 academic research that occurred in the space of less than a decade in the mid¬
twentieth century. These shifts in the sources of funding for U.S. academic re¬
search created a research infrastructure in U.S. higher education whose scale
and other features also contrasted with those of other industrial economies.
War preparations and the U.S. entry into World War II in December 1941
transformed federal R&D programs and priorities. Overall federal R&D ex¬
penditures (in 1996 dollars) soared from $784.9 million in 1940 to a peak of
$12.4 billion in 1945, including an increase from $279.2 million to $4 billion
(1996 dollars) in Defense Department R&D spending. The success and the or¬
ganizational structure of the massive federal wartime R&D program yielded
several important legacies. The successful completion of the Manhattan Proj¬
ect, whose research budget in the peak years 1944 and 1945 substantially ex¬
ceeded that of the Department of Defense, created a research and weapons
production complex that ushered in the age of truly “big science.” Ironically,
the Manhattan Projects success in creating weapons of unprecedented de¬
structive power contributed to rosy postwar perceptions of the constructive
possibilities of large-scale science for the advance of societal welfare.11
Far smaller in financial terms, but highly significant as an institutional in¬
novation, was the Office of Scientific Research and Development (OSRD), a
civilian agency directed by Vannevar Bush that relied on research contracts
with private firms and universities. The largest single recipient of OSRD
grants and contracts during wartime (and the inventor of institutional over¬
head) was MIT, with seventy-five contracts for a total of more than $886 mil¬
lion (1996 dollars). The largest corporate recipient of OSRD funds. Western
Electric, accounted for only $130 million (1996 dollars) (Pursell, 1979, p. 364).
The contractual arrangements developed by OSRD during the Second World
War allowed the OSRD to tap the broad array of academic and industrial
R&D capabilities that had developed during the interwar period. Members of
the scientific community were called upon to recommend and to guide, as
well as to participate in, scientific research with military payoffs.
The OSRD and other wartime programs transformed the scale and sources
of funding for academic research in the United States. Indeed, the postwar
federal presence within academic research funding assumed a shape that dif¬
fered dramatically from that envisioned by one of the most famous and
influential figures in U.S. science policy during this century, Vannevar Bush.
In response to a request that he had solicited from President Franklin D. Roo¬
sevelt, Bush drafted the famous 1945 report on postwar federal science policy,
Science: The Endless Frontier. Anticipating the analysis of later economists,
Bush argued that basic research was the ultimate source of economic growth
and advocated the creation of a single federal agency charged with responsi-
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
bility for funding basic research in all defense and nondefense areas, includ- 23
ing health. The complexities of postwar domestic politics, as well as Bushs re¬
sistance to congressional oversight of his proposed agency, ultimately doomed
his proposal. Rather than a civilian agency overseeing all of federal science
policy and funding, various mission agencies, including the military and the
National Institutes of Health (NIH), assumed major roles in supporting basic
and applied research. By 1953, more than 86 percent of federal R&D spend¬
ing (5 percent of which supported academic research) was controlled by the
Defense Department and the Atomic Energy Commission.
The transformation of the postwar U.S. research system expanded and trans¬
formed the role of publicly funded research in U.S. universities. Although
Bush s recommendations of a single federal funding agency for basic research
were not implemented and his advocacy of institutional, rather than project,
funding also was ignored, U.S. universities enjoyed significant increases in
federal R&D support during this period. From an estimated level of less
than $150 million in 1935-36, federal support for university research (exclud¬
ing Federally Funded Research and Development Centers [FFRDCs] at uni¬
versities and colleges) grew to more than $2.1 billion in i960 and nearly $14 bil¬
lion in 1995 (Table 2.1; all amounts in 1996 dollars). Federal funding of
academic research, which amounted to no more than 25 percent of total aca¬
demic research support in the mid-i930S, by i960 accounted for more than
60 percent of the total.
The overall academic research enterprise increased almost six-fold in con¬
stant dollars between 1935 and i960 and more than doubled again by 1965 (see
Table 2.1). In 1953, less than a third of all U.S. basic research was performed in
universities and FFRDCs at universities and colleges. By 1995’ however, these
institutions performed 60 percent of U.S. basic research (National Science
Foundation, 1996).12 Increased federal support for university research trans¬
formed major U.S. universities into worldwide centers for the performance of
scientific research, a characterization that applied to only a few U.S. universi¬
ties in a limited number of fields during the prewar years.
In addition to financing an expanded academic research enterprise, federal
support for graduate education and university facilities, especially after the
1958 Sputnik “crisis,” enlarged the pool of scientific personnel and supported
the acquisition of the physical equipment and facilities essential to the per¬
formance of high-quality research. In the case of computer science, federal
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
TABLE 2.1
24
Federal Support for Academic R&D, 1935 and i960 -2000
(millions of 1996 dollars)
SOURCES: Data for 1935, National Resources Committee (1938); data for
i960 and after. National Science Foundation (2001).
istration (NASA) and the Atomic Energy Commission (AEC; later the De¬
partment of Energy), accounted for more than 80 percent of federal support
for academic research in 1954, a share that dropped below 30 percent of the to¬
tal after 1970 (see Table 2.2). During the 1953-60 period, the NIH provided
roughly a third of total federal academic research funding, and since i960
NIEI funding of university research has substantially increased. By the early
twenty-first century, the NIH accounted for more than 60 percent of federally
funded university research.
This enormous postwar federal investment in academic biomedical re¬
search forged stronger links between basic science and clinical applications in
U.S. biomedical research. By combining scientific research with clinical prac¬
tice, the U.S. academic medical center has been able to link science and in¬
novation to a remarkable degree, enabling the rapid collection by scientists of
feedback from practitioners in the development of new medical devices and
procedures, facilitating clinical tests of new pharmaceuticals, and contribut¬
ing powerfully to innovations in both pharmaceuticals and medical devices.
The combination of science and clinical applications in one institution is un¬
usual—as Henderson, Orsenigo, and Pisano (1999) and Gelijns and Rosen¬
berg (1999) point out, most western European medical institutions emphasize
clinical practice and applications more heavily than scientific research. In
contrast, U.S. universities and academic research facilities have maintained
an important presence in the R, as well as the D, of R&D throughout the post¬
war period.
The mission orientation of the major federal funders of academic research
is reflected in the distribution of research funding among fields of science and
engineering. By 1989, for example, more than half of academic research in
TABLE 2.2
SOURCE: National Science Board (2002). Data for 2001 are based on preliminary NSF
estimates.
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
26 science and engineering was in the life sciences. Much of the research funded
by these agencies is appropriately defined as basic research, in that it aimed for
fundamental understanding of the object of study, but it was also positioned
in “Pasteurs Quadrant,” inasmuch as the research was motivated by the desire
to solve practical problems. Since the early 1980s, the central role of the fed¬
eral government in supporting academic research has been supplemented by
increased funding from industry, and university-industry research linkages
have attracted considerable comment. But as we pointed out earlier, these
linkages were well established before World War II. Indeed, the share of uni¬
versity research expenditures financed by industry appears if anything to have
declined during the early postwar period.15 During 1953-58, industry sup¬
ported 8 percent of annual academic R&D spending, on average, a share that
declined to 2.7 percent by 1970, in part as a result of increased federal govern¬
ment funding of academic research. By 1980, industrial support for university
research (excluding university-based FFRDCs) had rebounded to account for
more than 4 percent of academic research spending, and this share increased
further to approximately 7.4 percent by 1998 (National Science Board, 2002).
The structure of federal programs for support of academic R&D reinforced
many of the internationally distinctive characteristics of the U.S. higher edu¬
cation system that were apparent before 1940. The large scale of postwar fed¬
eral funding of academic research and the pluralistic, decentralized structure
of federal R&D programs (even within a single, large R&D-supporting agency
such as the Department of Defense) meant that numerous alternative paths of
R&D were supported in such key technological areas as information technol¬
ogy, biomedical sciences, and materials science during the postwar period.
The ability of federal R&D programs to support broad exploration of alter¬
native applications of fundamentally uncertain technologies proved to be an
important source of U.S. competitive advantage in such embryonic areas as
computer hardware, semiconductors, and, eventually, the Internet (Mowery
and Simcoe, 2002). Equally important, however, was the emphasis on peer re¬
view and interinstitutional competition in virtually all federal programs sup¬
porting academic R&D. The availability of funding from multiple federal
sources, combined with the competitive processes allocating the bulk of this
academic R&D support, powerfully reinforced the interinstitutional auton¬
omy and competition for faculty, students, resources, and prestige that char¬
acterized the pre-1940 U.S. system of higher education. Moreover, the size of
the federal academic R&D budget, as well as the reliance by most federal
agencies on extramural research support rather than public laboratories,
meant that U.S. universities’ research enterprises dwarfed those of other in¬
dustrial economies throughout the postwar period.
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
The “new structure” of U.S. academic R&D in the postwar period had im¬ 27
portant effects for industrial innovation and changed a number of its key char¬
acteristics. Although U.S. universities had played a significant role in indus¬
trial innovation in the pre-1940 U.S. economy, many of their important
contributions were exploited by large, established industrial firms such as
Standard Oil of New Jersey or Du Pont. During the postwar period, however,
relatively new firms, many of which drew on universities for personnel or sci¬
entific and technological knowledge, played central roles in the commercial
exploitation and growth of such “new industries” as computer hardware, semi¬
conductors, computer software, and biotechnology. The economic role of
these new firms in these postwar U.S. industries outstripped the importance
of new firms in other industrial economies, such as Germany and Japan.
Moreover, regions such as California’s Silicon Valley or Massachusetts’s Route
128 enjoyed significant advances in income and employment that were attrib¬
utable in part to the presence of major research universities in these regions.
Thus far we have described the historical origins and development of the U.S.
system of higher education, focusing on the ways in which its scale and struc¬
ture created strong incentives for collaboration between university and indus¬
trial researchers well before the recent growth of university patenting and
licensing. In this section, we summarize a number of recent studies of the
contemporary relationship between university research and industrial innova¬
tion. To what extent do U.S. firms utilize the results of university research as
the source of the technological innovations that they develop and commer¬
cialize, a view of industrial innovation that influenced the drafting of the
Bayh-Dole Act? What importance do industrial managers assign to patenting
and licensing as key channels for the flow of university research findings to in¬
dustrial innovation? How, if at all, do managers’ assessments of these issues
vary among technologies and industries? The studies summarized in this sec¬
tion hed light on these key questions and provide a useful basis for examining
university-industry collaboration and technology transfer.
All of the studies reviewed in this section relied on responses through in¬
terviews or surveys from senior industrial managers in industries ranging from
pharmaceuticals to electrical equipment. The National Research Councils
Government-University-Industry Research Roundtable (GUIRR) (1991) ex¬
amined the contributions of university research to technological innovation,
and Mansfield (1991) surveyed industry managers about the number of their
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
28 recent innovations that either could not have been developed, or could have
been developed only after significant delay, in the absence of recent academic
research. Two other studies relied on large-scale surveys of industrial R&D
managers. The “Yale survey” (results of which are summarized in Levin et ah,
1987) and the more recent “Carnegie-Mellon survey” (summarized in Cohen
et ah, 2002) asked industrial research managers about the nature and scope of
the influence of university research on industrial R&D. The Carnegie-Mellon
survey also asked respondents to describe the most important channels
through which their firms gained access to the results of university research
for application in their industrial innovation strategies. The Yale survey fo¬
cused mainly on large U.S. firms in the late 1970s and early 1980s, while the
Carnegie-Mellon survey focused on a broader range of large and smaller U.S.
firms in the early 1990s, thereby capturing insights from managers well after
the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980.
These studies also highlight the interindustry differences in the relation¬
ship between university and industrial innovation. Respondents in all four of
these studies characterize the biomedical sector, especially biotechnology and
pharmaceuticals, as unusual —university research advances affect industrial
innovation more significantly and directly in this field than is true of other sec¬
tors. Biotechnology firms’ managers quoted in the GUIRR study stated that
they relied on university research as a source of inventions. Managers inter¬
viewed in the GUIRR study, however, differentiated between pharmaceuticals
based on biotechnology and other drugs, stating that university research rarely
was the source of new drugs not based on biotechnology, for which the key
work took place in industry. But university research affected the development
of these nonbiotechnology drugs as well — managers interviewed in the
GUIRR study highlighted a number of cases in which academic research had
illuminated the specific biochemical reactions that pharmaceutical firms
needed to find in searching for new drugs. In other cases, university research
advances permitted companies to make a more efficient assessment of possible
uses for drugs they were testing.
Mansfield (1991) found a similarly strong dependence on academic re¬
search in his survey of pharmaceutical industry managers, who stated that
more than a quarter of the new drugs commercialized by the companies could
not have been developed, or would have been developed only with substantial
delay, without academic research. These managers further asserted that the
development of an additional 20 percent of the drugs introduced by their firms
was substantially aided by academic research.
The nature of the relationship between university and industrial research
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
and innovation in the biomedical sector contrasted with that in other indus¬ 29
tries in both the GUIRR and Mansfield studies. Interviewees from electronics
firms reported in the GUIRR study that universities occasionally made rele¬
vant “inventions” but opined that most such inventions came from nonaca¬
demic research. University research did contribute to technological advances,
but its contributions were largely in the form of knowledge of the fundamen¬
tal physics and chemistry underlying manufacturing processes and product in¬
novation, an area in which training of scientists and engineers figured promi¬
nently, and experimental techniques. Mansfield found that the reported
percentage of new products that were “heavily dependent” on academic re¬
search for their introduction was significantly lower in areas other than phar¬
maceuticals. The executives from the information-processing equipment and
instruments industries reported that 10-15 percent of their innovations
depended on academic research (in the sense defined above in our discussion
of Mansfields work). Respondents from the metals industry estimated that
slightly more than 10 percent of new products and processes would not have
been developed in the absence of recent academic research. Even more strik¬
ing is Mansfields finding that in three industries-electrical equipment,
chemical products, and metal products —at most 6 percent of new products
depended on recent academic research.
The Yale and Carnegie-Mellon surveys of industry R&D executives cor¬
roborate the findings of these other studies concerning the differences in the
relationship between university and industrial research in the biomedical and
other industry sectors. The Yale survey queried R&D managers in industry
about the sources of knowledge that affected innovation in their industries.
Only fifteen of the fifty industries with three or more respondents in the Yale
study rated university research as “important’ or “very important to techni¬
cal advance in their line of business (Table 2.3). Once again, pharmaceuticals
(which had only begun to recognize the significance of biotechnology at the
time the survey was administered in the late 1970s) figures prominently on this
list, but R&D managers in engineering and scientific instruments, semicon¬
ductors, and synthetic rubber also reported that university research was “im¬
portant” or “very important” to their innovative activities. Interestingly, many
of the other industries reporting that university research was important to their
innovative activities are related to agriculture and forestry, prominent bene¬
ficiaries of federally funded university research for much of the twentieth
century.
Another set of questions in the Yale survey asked R&D managers to as¬
sess the importance of specific fields of university science in their industries’
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
30 TABLE 2.3
Industries Rating University Research as
“Important” or “Very Important”
Fluid milk
Dairy products except milk
Canned specialities
Logging and sawmills
Semiconductors and related devices
Pulp, paper, and paperboard mills
Farm machinery and equipment
Grain mill products
Pesticides and agricultural chemicals
Processed fruits and vegetables
Engineering and scientific instruments
Millwork, veneer, and plywood
Synthetic rubber
Drugs
Animal feed
innovative activities (Table 2.4). Virtually all of the fields of university research
that were rated as “important” or “very important” for their innovative activi¬
ties by survey respondents are related to engineering or applied sciences. As
we noted previously, these fields of U.S. university research frequently devel¬
oped in close collaboration with industry.
With the exception of chemistry, very few basic sciences appear on the list
of university research fields deemed by industry respondents in the Yale sur¬
vey to be highly relevant to their innovative activities. But the absence of fields
such as physics and mathematics in Table 2.4 should not be interpreted as in¬
dicating that academic research in these fields does not contribute directly to
technical advance in industry. Instead, these results reflect the fact that fun¬
damental advances in physics, mathematics, and related sciences penetrate
industry gradually. I heir effects on industrial innovation are realized only af¬
ter the passage of considerable time, a characterization very similar to that of
the GUIRR interviewees in the electronics industries. Indeed, in many cases
the effects of advances in these areas of science on industry are realized
through the incorporation of such advances into the applied sciences, such as
chemical engineering, electrical engineering, and material sciences.
I he findings of the Carnegie-Mellon survey (Cohen et al., 2002) concern¬
ing interindustry differences in the importance of university research are sim¬
ilar to those of the Yale survey.16 Although most industries do not assign great
importance to university research as a contributor to their innovation activi-
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
ties, pharmaceuticals stands out among the industries that view university re- 31
search results as important, as do some of the electronics industries. The find¬
ings of the Carnegie-Mellon survey regarding the fields of university research
that industry considered important for innovation also were similar to those of
the Yale survey.
The Carnegie-Mellon survey included a number of additional questions
concerning the ways in which university research influenced the industrial
R&D agenda and the channels through which industry gained access to such
research results. On the first point, the responses summarized in Table 2.5 in¬
dicate that in most industries, university research results play little if any role
in triggering new industrial R&D projects; instead, the stimuli originate with
customers or from manufacturing operations. Here as elsewhere, pharmaceu¬
ticals is an exception —university research results trigger industrial R&D proj¬
ects in a significant number of cases. But industry R&D managers reported
that university research results most often aided problem solving in the course
of a R&D project, rather than affecting the decision to initiate such projects.
The Carnegie-Mellon survey also queried R&D managers about their
use of different types of research from universities and government research
table 2.4
The Relevance of University Science to Industrial Technology
No. of industries
with “relevance”
scores of Selected industries for which the reported
“relevance” of university research was
Field ^5 s=6 large (3s 6)
SOURCE: Previously unpublished data from the Yale Survey on Appropriability and Technological
Opportunity in Industry. For a description of the survey, see Levin et al. (1987).
HISTORICAL OVERVIEW
32 laboratories in their internal innovation activities, and these findings are strik¬
ingly similar to the other data discussed above on the types of knowledge out¬
puts rated by managers as most important for industrial innovation. Respon¬
dents to the Carnegie-Mellon survey reported that general research findings
from “public research” performed in government labs or universities were
used more frequently (on average, in 29.3 percent of industrial R&D projects
in respondents’ firms) than prototypes emerging from these external sources
of research (used in an average of 8.3 percent of industrial R&D projects). In¬
terestingly, research techniques and instruments from these external research
sources were rated as more important in their contributions to industrial
R&D, used in an average of 22.2 percent of projects, than were prototypes.
Respondents from the pharmaceutical industry reported that more than
40 percent of their R&D projects used research findings from universities and
government laboratories, and more than 35 percent used techniques and in¬
struments developed at these sites. But pharmaceutical industry respondents
reported that only 12.3 percent of their industry projects relied on prototypes
developed in university or government research facilities.
A similar portrait of the relative importance of different outputs of univer¬
sity and public-laboratory research emerges from the responses to questions
about the importance to industrial R&D of various information channels
(Table 2.6). Although pharmaceuticals once again is unusual in its assignment
of considerable importance to patents and license agreements involving uni¬
versities and public laboratories, respondents from this industry still rated re¬
search publications and conferences as more important sources of informa-
TABLE 2.5
Rankings of Importance of External Information Sources in
Suggesting New R&D Projects and in Contributing to the
Completion of R&D Projects
% of respondents % of respondents
indicating indicating that
that source source contributed
suggested new to project
Information source R&D project completion
TABLE 2.6
33
Importance to Industrial R&D of Sources
of Information on Public R&D
(including university research)
% of respondents
rating a source as
“moderately” or
“very” important
Information source for industrial R&D
tion. For most industries, patents and licenses involving inventions from uni¬
versity or public laboratories were reported to be of very little importance,
compared with publications, conferences, informal interaction with univer¬
sity researchers, and consulting.
CONCLUSION
This chapter examines the evolution of U.S. university patent policies and
university patenting during the pre-Bayh-Dole era, spanning 1925-80. Al¬
though many of the issues in recent debates about the costs and benefits of uni¬
versity patenting had been articulated by proponents and opponents of uni¬
versity patenting as early as the 1930s, several arguments in favor of university
patenting that figured prominently in these early debates were absent from the
debates over the Bayh-Dole Act in the 1970s and subsequently. Interestingly,
many proponents of university patenting argued in the debates of the 1930s
that universities should avoid a direct role in managing patents and licenses,
an argument that was rarely heard in the debates of the 1970s. The growth of
university patenting and licensing throughout the 1925-80 period also exhib¬
its many of the characteristics of the diffusion of a new organizational phe¬
nomenon, including emulation by universities of one another’s approaches to
patenting and licensing and considerable responsiveness to the demonstration
by some universities of financial gains from licensing of faculty inventions.
Our examination of U.S. university patenting during the 1925-80 period
focuses on the level and technological composition of university patenting
and the characteristics of the universities active in patenting. Although some
universities had begun to patent faculty inventions as early as the 1920s, few
institutions had developed formal patent policies prior to the late 1940s, and
many of these policies embodied considerable ambivalence toward patenting.
Relatively few universities managed their patent portfolios themselves during
the 1925-70 period, but this situation began to change during the 1970s. In
particular, the 1970s are characterized by considerable growth in patenting by
private U.S. universities. Our data also highlight steady growth in biomedical
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
Just as the post-1970 surge in U.S. university patenting coincided with in¬
creased research collaboration between universities and industry (Henderson,
Jaffe, and Trajtenberg, 1998a), so did the first wave of university involvement
in patenting, which began after World War I. The expanding links between
university and industrial research during the 1920s and 1930s that we discussed
in Chapter 2 triggered a debate among U.S. research university administrators
over patent policy (McKusick, 1948; Palmer, 1934).1
In 1933, the American Association for the Advancement of Science (AAAS)
Committee of Patents, Copyrights, and Trademarks surveyed the different po¬
sitions on the “patent problem,” as it was then known, that faced university sci¬
entists. Among the questions addressed by the committees report (AAAS,
1934) were: “Should [scientists] proceed to obtain patents? What are the ad¬
vantages in doing this? What are the disadvantages?” (p. 7).2
One of the issues the committee considered was whether patenting was
necessary for “technology transfer.” Although a common criticism of aca¬
demic patenting was “that publication or dedication to the public is sufficient
to give the public the results of work of scientists” (AAAS, 1934, p. 9), the re¬
port concluded that this position was naive, for several reasons. Anticipating
an argument made during the 1970s in support of the Bayh-Dole Act, the com¬
mittee opined that “discoveries or inventions which are merely published and
thus thrown open equally to all, unless of great importance to the industry, are
seldom adopted” (p. 9) and that “ordinarily no manufacturer or capitalist
would be willing to-day to risk his money, and expend time and energy in de¬
veloping on a commercial scale a new product or process without being as¬
sured that his investment in developing the invention would be protected in
some measure” (p. 10).3
The committee argued that a scientist could not expect that publication of
the technical details of his invention would yield social benefits, because of
the presence of “patent pirates” who would “wrongfully appropriate his work”
and “deny the public what he thought he gave it,” either by charging monop-
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
oly prices or withholding the invention from use (AAAS, 1934, p. 10). Were the 37
inventor or his university, rather than a “pirate,” to obtain a patent on the in¬
vention, this risk would be reduced.4
A related argument stated that patents on university inventions were nec¬
essary for “quality control” reasons. Patenting of university research advances
would prevent the unsuccessful or even harmful exploitation of university re¬
search advances by unqualified individuals or firms. Patenting of such ad¬
vances by the university, according to this argument, prevented incompetent
exploitation of academic research that might discredit the research results and
the university.5
Proponents of university patenting thus concluded that doing so enhanced
the public good. University patents advanced social welfare by inducing pri¬
vate parties to develop and commercialize university research results, by pre¬
venting “patent pirates” from patenting the research and charging monopoly
prices, and by allowing institutions to ensure that only reputable parties de¬
veloped the research, protecting the reputations of the invention and the uni¬
versity itself.
As we note in Chapter 5, the first of these three arguments (“patents induce
development”) figured prominently in debates about university patent policy
in the 1960s and 1970s (Eisenberg, 1996), which often asserted that commer¬
cialization of a university invention might require that any patented research
results be licensed on an exclusive or semiexclusive basis. Prevention of “pat¬
ent piracy” and protection of universities’ reputations, however, require only
that an institution obtain a patent and license it widely at low or no royalties.
The committee s report also addressed the potentially negative effect of pat¬
ents on the progress of research in fields where advances are cumulative, that
is, the possibility “[t]hat patents will place unfortunate strictures on other men
who subsequently do fundamentally important work in the same field”
(AAAS, 1934, p. 12). The committee acknowledged such dangers, but argued
that universities could avoid them “by permitting the use of patents on liberal
terms .. . [which] is particularly necessary in the case of broad or basic inven¬
tions” (p. 12).
A third class of issues in the committees report dealt with the tension be¬
tween university patenting and the “open science” norms and institutions of
academe (Merton, 1973). Objections to patenting based on this view included
the assertion “that it is unethical for scientists or professors to patent the results
of their work” (AAAS, 1934, p. 8; the committees report indicated that “this ob¬
jection is probably the vaguest and most frequent one raised”). Although the
committee considered the risk that patenting by university scientists would
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
38 hinder communalisin and bias academic inquiry away from basic research, a
concern echoed in more recent debates over university patenting (Dasgupta
and David, 1994), its report dismissed these fears.6
The debates over university patent policies in the 1930s treated medical pat¬
ents as a special case. Opposition to medical patents was widespread, based on
the argument that patents restricted the use of new discoveries and therefore
had no place in the medical community (Weiner, 1986).7 Opponents of med¬
ical patents also expressed concern over perceptions of university profiteering
at public expense in the field of public health (McKusick, 1948)- The AAAS
committee acknowledged the “special” nature of patents in the field of public
health (with little elaboration) but suggested that the benefits of patenting dis¬
cussed above, particularly those associated with using patents as a “quality
control” mechanism, were sufficient to warrant patenting of such discoveries.
Although the AAAS report favored university patenting of faculty inven¬
tions, the committee did not endorse direct involvement by universities in pat¬
ent management, arguing instead that “this can preferably be done by inde¬
pendently organized foundations, holding companies or other suitable
experienced organizations” (AAAS, 1934, p. 14). This position reflected the
reluctance of many U.S. universities during the 1925-70 period to directly
manage patenting and licensing, a reluctance that faded somewhat during
the 1970s.
This review of the early debates about university patenting underscores
the widespread awareness of and interest in patenting by U.S. university sci¬
entists and administrators well before the 1970s and 1980s. The primary moti¬
vation for patenting was the protection of the public interest and the preser¬
vation of academic institutions’ reputations. The prospect of licensing income
influenced the entry by several universities into patenting and licensing dur¬
ing the 1930s and subsequently; but through much of the 1925-80 period,
many academic scientists and administrators preferred to avoid direct in¬
volvement in the management of these patents. These tensions were reflected
in the patent policies adopted by leading pre-1940 institutional patenters and
licensors.
Since one of the forces that sparked the debate over university patenting was
the growth of research collaboration between U.S. universities and industry, it
is not surprising that the first group of universities to become involved with
patents were land-grant institutions, which, as we noted in Chapter 2, con¬
ducted a good deal of applied research of interest to industry and agriculture.
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
TABLE 3.1
University
Formal asserts
systemwide rights to Restrictions
patent nonsponsored on medical
Institution policy research patents Patent management
As we noted in Chapter 2, World War II and the Cold War that followed trans¬
formed the structure of the U.S. national innovation system. Nowhere was this
transformation more dramatic than in U.S. universities. Formerly funded
largely by state governments, the U.S. Department of Agriculture, and indus¬
try, academic research experienced a surge of federal funding. As the growth
in university-industry research links had done during the 1920s and 1930s, in¬
creased federal funding of university research strengthened two motives for
university involvement in patenting. First, the expanded scale of the academic
research enterprise increased the probability that universities would produce
patentable inventions. Second, many federal research sponsors required the
development of a formal patent policy.
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
42 By the late 1940s, virtually all major U.S. universities had developed pa¬
tent policies, a considerable increase from the situation in the late 1930s
(McKusick, 1948). Summarizing his survey of U.S. universities in the late
1950s, Palmer (1962) found that eighty-five institutions had adopted or revised
patent policies during the 1940-55 period; more than half of these new or
revised policies were announced during 1946—55.11 Typically, patents from
government-funded work were governed by the policies of the sponsoring
agency (see below); privately sponsored research was managed on a case-by¬
case basis, although research sponsors often received preferential treatment.
Significant differences nonetheless remained among U.S. universities in their
assertion of rights to faculty inventions and their willingness to pursue patent
licenses.
As in the prewar period, many universities during the 1950s and 1960s out¬
sourced patent management (McKusick, 1948). Data on Research Corpora¬
tion IAAs reveal the dimensions of this trend: as of 1940, only three of the na¬
tions eighty-nine “Research Universities” (as classified by the Carnegie
Commission on Higher Educations 1973 taxonomy; see below for details) had
signed IAAs with the Research Corporation. By 1950, this number had in¬
creased to twenty (Table 3.2), and by the mid-1960s nearly two-thirds of the
Carnegie Research Universities were Research Corporation clients.
Well into the 1960s, U.S. university patent policies and procedures re¬
flected the ambivalence toward patents that was revealed in the debates of the
1930s. Many institutions continued to avoid direct involvement in patent ad¬
ministration, and others maintained a hands-off attitude toward patents alto¬
gether. Columbia’s policy left patenting to the inventor and patent adminis¬
tration to the Research Corporation, stating that “it is not deemed within the
sphere of the University’s scholarly objectives” to hold patents, and Harvard,
table 3.2
Carnegie Research Universities with Research Corporation IAAs
Chicago, Yale, and Johns Hopkins adopted similar positions. All of these uni¬ 43
versities, as well as Ohio State and Pennsylvania, discouraged or prohibited
medical patents. Other universities allowed patents on biomedical inventions
only if it was clear that patenting would be in the public interest.12 This insti¬
tutional ambivalence toward patenting began to change during the 1960s, al¬
though the prohibitions on medical patenting at Columbia, Harvard, Johns
Hopkins, and Chicago were not dropped until the 1970s. The pace of change
accelerated during the 1970s in response to federal initiatives in R&D funding
and patent policy.
Although federal funding of academic research grew during the first postwar
decade, the rate of growth in such support accelerated in the late 1950s, and
the composition of this support shifted in favor of basic research. U.S. univer¬
sities’ share of total U.S. basic research performance (excluding university-
operated Federally Funded Research and Development Centers [FFRDCs])
nearly doubled from 27 percent in 1953 to 50 percent in 1968, while federal
funds for basic research in U.S. universities increased more than five-fold dur¬
ing the 1958-68 period (National Science Board, 2002). The greatest in¬
creases in funding in the late 1950s and 1960s occurred in the biomedical sci¬
ences, funded largely by the National Institutes of Health (NIH) within the
Department of Health, Education, and Welfare (HEW). By 1971, NIH sup¬
ported nearly 37 percent of academic R&D, a share that grew to more than
46 percent by 1981 (Table 2.2). These increases in federal research funding,
especially in biomedical research, transformed the content of academic
research and elevated the salience of patent management issues at many
universities.
Increased federal research funding also broadened the number and char¬
acteristics of U.S. research universities. The interinstitutional concentration
of federal support for university research was high during the 1940s and early
1950s but declined during the 1950-80 period. The share of federal R&D
funds accounted for by the ten leading academic recipients of these funds
shrank from 43 percent in 1952 to 37 percent in 1958 and declined further still
during the 1960s and 1970s (Table 3.3). In the life sciences, where funding was
less institutionally concentrated than overall federal academic research fund¬
ing (Geiger, 1993), the dispersion of funding also grew during the 1960s and
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
TABLE 3.3
Change also occurred during this period in federal patent policies. Before
the 1960s, federal agencies lacked any policy beyond case-by-case negotiations
for dealing with requests from universities for title to inventions resulting from
federally funded research. In the mid-1960s, the Department of Defense
(DOD) began to grant title to inventions resulting from DOD-financed re¬
search to universities with “approved” patent policies, that is, policies that
required faculty to report inventions resulting from sponsored research and
allowed universities to obtain patents on these inventions. As we point out in
Chapter 5, two other federal sources of academic research funding, HEW and
the National Science Foundation (NSF), began to negotiate Institutional Pat¬
ent Agreements (IPAs) with universities in 1968 and 1973, respectively. IPAs
eliminated the need for case-by-case reviews of the disposition of individual
academic inventions resulting from federally funded research and facilitated
licensing of such inventions on an exclusive or nonexclusive basis.
A fourth impetus for increased university involvement in patenting and
licensing resulted from the early successes of Stanford University’s Office of
Technology Licensing (OTL). Niels Reimers, the associate director of Stan¬
ford University’s Sponsored Projects Office and the founding director of
Stanford’s OTL, noted that shortly after he was hired by the university in
1968: “I looked up the income we had from Research Corporation from ’54
to ’67, and it was something like $4,500. I thought we could do a lot better
licensing directly, so I proposed a technology licensing program” (Reimers,
i998)-
Reimers s technology licensing program, which had begun in 1968 as an ex¬
periment, focused more on marketing and less on the administrative and legal
details of patent management. Reimers staffed his licensing program with in¬
dividuals skilled in technology evaluation and marketing, rather than the at¬
torneys who dominated the staffs of most U.S. university licensing programs in
the 1960s. The pilot program increased university licensing income to $55,000
in its first year (more than twelve times what it had earned via its contract with
Research Corporation in the previous thirteen years), the experiment was
judged a success, and Stanford created its OTL in 1970.
All of these developments sparked considerable interest among U.S. uni¬
versities in expanding or establishing university technology licensing offices.
The dimensions of this increased university involvement in patent manage¬
ment and technology transfer during the 1970s are apparent in Figure 3.1,
which shows “entry” into technology transfer activities by year, based on data
from the Association of University Technology Managers (AUTM, 1998).14 As
the figure shows, the number of universities establishing technology transfer
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
46 offices and/or hiring technology transfer officers began to grow in the late
1960s, well before the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act. Although the Act was fol¬
lowed by a wave of entry by universities into management of patenting and li¬
censing, growth in these activities was well established by the late 1970s.
A number of scholars have documented the role of the Bayh-Dole Act in the
growth of patenting and licensing by universities since 1980 (Henderson, Jaffe,
and Trajtenberg, 1998a,b). But Bayh-Dole is properly viewed as initiating the
latest, rather than the first, phase in the history of U.S. university patenting.
And this latest phase is characterized by a higher level of direct involvement
by universities in management of their patenting and licensing activities, in
contrast to the reluctance of many U.S. universities to become directly in¬
volved in patenting prior to the 1970s. Public universities were more active in
patenting than private institutions during much of the pre-Bayh-Dole era, re¬
flecting the strong incentives that they faced to reap the benefits of university
research for local taxpayers and the importance of applied research at many of
these institutions. By the 1970s, however, both public and private universities
had become directly involved in patenting.
In this section, we examine the growth of U.S. university patenting during
1925-80. We provide an overview of the characteristics of active university
patenters and changes in the technological fields of university patents during
figure 3.1 Proportion of Carnegie RUis with > 0.5 FTE technology transfer per¬
sonnel, 1965-95
UNIVERSITY POLICIES AND PATENTING BEFORE BAYH-DOLE
this period. We also consider some reasons for the increased direct involve¬ 47
ment of universities in patent management that became apparent in the 1970s.
Basic Trends
Figure 3.2 plots the number of patents assigned to American universities from
1925 to 1980. Our data cover university patents for every fifth year during 1925-
45 and annual counts for 1948-80.15 During the 1925-80 period, U.S. univer¬
sities’ share of all domestically assigned U.S. utility patents grew from zero to
slightly less than 1 percent. After growing during the 1940s and 1950s, the num¬
ber of university patents remained roughly constant until the 1970s, when uni¬
versity patenting increased significantly. The total number of university pat¬
ents issued during the 1970s alone is 1.5 times the total number of university
patents issued in the previous two decades.16 Although the surge in U.S. uni¬
versity patenting after the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act in 1980 has been
widely noted, Figure 3.2 suggests that university patenting began to grow as a
share of U.S. patenting during the decade prior to Bayh-Dole.
400 -
350 -
300 -
250 -
1-1
<L>
| 200 -
Z
150 -
100 -
50 -
0
o
O'
Issue Year
TABLE 3.4
49
Patenting by U.S. Universities, 1925-45
Total Total
Geiger r6 patents Others patents
California Institute of
Technology 10 Purdue University 13
University of Illinois 7 Washington State University 7
University of Minnesota 7 Iowa State University 6
Stanford University 5 Illinois Institute of Technology 4
University of Michigan 4 Carnegie Mellon University 3
University of Pennsylvania 4 Ohio State University 2
University of Wisconsin 4 University of Kansas 2
University of California 3 Fordham University 1
Cornell University 2 Louisiana State University 1
MIT 2 Saint Louis University 1
Tennessee State University 1
University of Cincinnati 1
University of Iowa 1
University of New Hampshire 1
Other 2
Total 48 Total 46
1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980
Issue Year
* Entrants n Incumbents
250 -
200
I 150
I 100
z
50
iJiJiJiJi
1970 1971 1972 1973
IiJiIi11
1974 1975
Issue Year
1976 1977 1978 1979 1980
Issue Year
□ Other □ Drugs and Medicine
a Mechanical ■ Chemicals
13 Electronic, Optical, Nuclear
400 -
350 -
<D
Issue Year
56 that throughout its history, WARF earned most of its revenues from a handful
of biomedical inventions, and Chapter 4 shows that this was also true for the
Research Corporation from the 1940s to the 1970s. In spite of the reluctance
of many universities to seek such patents prior to the 1970s, medical patents
have been important revenue sources for academic licensors throughout the
twentieth century.
Increased federal financial support for biomedical research during the
postwar era is reflected in the growing share of biomedical patents within
our university patent data during and after the 1970s. Much of the growth in
university patenting during the 1970s occurred in the biomedical area (Fig¬
ure 3.8). Nonbiomedical university patents increased by 90 percent from the
1968-70 period to the 1978-80 period, but biomedical university patents in¬
creased by 295 percent. This rapid growth in biomedical patents also reflected
the expansion of the IPA program associated with the major biomedical fund¬
ing agency (HEW) during the 1970s. The increased share of the biomedical
disciplines within overall federal academic R&D funding, the dramatic ad¬
vances in biomedical science that occurred during the 1960s and 1970s, and
the strong industrial interest in the results of this biomedical research all af¬
fected the growth of university patenting during this period.
CONCLUSION
6o A danger was involved, especially should the experiment prove highly profitable to
the university and lead to a general emulation of the plan. University trustees are
continually seeking for funds and in direct proportion to the success of our experi¬
ment its repetition might be expected elsewhere . . . the danger this suggested was
the possibility of growing commercialism and competition between institutions
and an accompanying tendency for secrecy in scientific work. (Cottrell, 1932, p. 222)
Cottrell approached the Smithsonian Institution, where his plan was em¬
braced by Secretary Charles Walcott but rejected by the Institutions regents,
reflecting their desire to avoid any involvement in patent administration. In¬
stead, a corporation, in which Walcott played an advisory role, was formed to
oversee patenting and licensing. The Research Corporation was founded in
1912 with the assistance of none other than William Howard Taft, then a
Smithsonian regent, in drafting its charter.
Although he originally intended to assign the corporations licensing royal¬
ties to the Smithsonian for the “increase and diffusion of knowledge,” Cottrell
subsequently decided to use the organizations earnings to support scientific
research at institutions other than the Smithsonian. The corporation also
managed the licensing and development of the electrostatic precipitator pat¬
ents, and Cottrell argued that the corporation should assume responsibility for
managing the licensure of donated patents in other technological areas:
The ever growing number of men in academic positions who evolve useful and
patentable inventions from time to time in connection with their regular work and
without looking personally for any financial reward would gladly see these further
developed for the public good, but are disinclined either to undertake such devel¬
opments themselves or to place the control in the hands of any private interests.
(Cottrell, 1912, p. 865)2
In Cottrells view, the purpose of the Research Corporation “was not merely
to produce revenue for scientific research, but to act as a sort of laboratory of
patent economics and to conduct experiments in patent administration” (as
cited in McKusick, 1948, p. 208). From its inception, he envisioned the Re¬
search Corporation as an entity that would develop and disseminate tech¬
niques for managing the intellectual property of research universities and sim¬
ilar organizations.
During its first twenty-five years, the Research Corporation focused on
three activities: (1) designing, manufacturing, and installing electrostatic pre¬
cipitation and other equipment arising from patents that it owned, adminis¬
tered, or purchased; (2) managing patentable inventions from educational or
research institutions that were donated to the corporation; and (3) providing
grants for scientific researchers. The first of these three tasks, however, ac¬
counted for the bulk of the corporations activities during this period.
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
62 independent inventors who sought assistance with the patenting and licensing
of their inventions in fields other than precipitators. Following Cottrells ex¬
ample, several of these scientist-inventors wished to assign their licensing roy¬
alties to the Research Corporation to support its philanthropic activities. The
expanding research collaboration between U.S. universities and industry and
the related growth of science-based industry increased the volume of com¬
mercially valuable academic research in the 1920s and 1930s, resulting in more
and more requests from academic inventors to the Research Corporation for
assistance in the management of patenting and licensing.
Beginning in the late 1920s, the Research Corporation began to accept do¬
nations of patents outside of the precipitation field and received a number of
patents in a diverse array of technical fields.6 Among the most important of
these inventions was the Williams-Waterman process for synthesis of vitamin
B,. Developed in Robert R. Williams’s laboratory at the University of Califor¬
nia in 1932, the Williams-Waterman process was important in the fight against
malnutrition and was immediately recognized to have significant income
potential. Williams and Robert E. Waterman filed for a patent on their new
process with the aid of the Research Corporation, which also assisted the in¬
ventors in the successful prosecution of an interference hearing. The patent
issued in 1935 and was assigned to the Research Corporation.
The Williams-Waterman invention was an important development in the
history of the Research Corporation for several reasons. One of the first in a se¬
ries of public health-related inventions that accounted for a growing share of
the Research Corporations licensing revenues during the next two decades,
the patent was the first “home run” in a field other than electrostatic precipi¬
tation. Income from this and other biomedical patents proved indispensable
to the corporations growth. The corporations involvement in the Williams-
Waterman interference hearing also expanded its activities in nonprecipita¬
tion technologies from administering patents to helping secure them. Like
contemporary university technology licensing offices, the corporation recog¬
nized that it had to assume responsibility for a number of activities in addition
to the administration of patents and licenses.
The Research Corporations reputation in academic patent management
also benefited from its successful management of the precipitation patents, as
well as the marketing efforts of Cottrell, who frequently visited leading col¬
leges and universities to advise administration and faculty on matters of
patenting and to promote the Research Corporations services. In addition, the
Research Corporations research grants to university researchers had produced
a number of potentially patentable inventions by the 1930s. Although they
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
were not obliged to do so, many of these inventors turned to the Research Cor- 63
poration for patent assistance.
Another development that aided the Research Corporations growth was
the increased interest of U.S. universities during the 1930s in the financial re¬
turns from patenting and licensing of faculty inventions. But as we pointed
out in Chapter 3, many U.S. universities in the 1930s avoided direct manage¬
ment of patent prosecution and licensing, in contrast to their embrace of this
role during the 1970s and 1980s. This reluctance was partly due to the politi¬
cal controversy that had erupted over the University of Wisconsin’s patenting
and licensing activities (although these were managed by the Wisconsin
-Alumni Research Foundation), as well as the fact that the scale of the research
enterprise at most universities during this period was too small to justify direct
involvement in patent administration. As the Research Corporation noted,
“University staffs were not equipped to handle such problems —the number
[of patents] arising in any one year at a single institution would be too small to
justify having expert patent personnel” (Research Corporation, 1972, p. 15).
Faculty inventors therefore were encouraged by administrators, colleagues,
and the broader scientific and technological community to work through the
Research Corporation (Palmer, 1948).7
Nevertheless, despite expanded discussions with U.S. universities and in¬
ventors over management of their patents, management of nonprecipitation
patents accounted for a relatively small part of the Research Corporations ac¬
tivities during the 1930s. Although it handled inventions for individual faculty
members and universities on a case-by-case basis, the corporation had no for¬
mal agreements with universities. This situation began to change, however,
with the negotiation of the Research Corporations first Invention Administra¬
tion Agreement (IAA) with MIT in 1937.
As key precipitation patents expired and the market for electrostatic precipita¬
tors declined during the Depression, the Research Corporation sought to de¬
velop new revenue sources.8 In addition to its work with precipitator patents,
the corporation’s management of its portfolio of nonprecipitation patents had
contributed to the development of unique competencies that could be ex¬
ploited for the mutual benefit of the Research Corporation and academic in¬
stitutions, while sustaining Cottrell’s original vision for the corporation as a
source of funding for scientific research. In addition, as the Research Corpo¬
ration argued in a 1972 document, centralized management of patenting and
licensing on behalf of universities by a specialist could be less costly for each
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
to protect these said inventions from misuse and to take such steps against in- 65
fringers as [it] may deem for the best interest of the parties hereto, but with the
general policy of avoiding litigation wherever practicable.” All services were
provided at the expense of the Research Corporation, although the corpora¬
tion assumed no financial responsibility for any additional development costs
for MIT inventions. Any licensing income net of expenses was to be divided
between MIT and the corporation on a 60-40 basis. The Research Corpora¬
tion used its portion of the earnings to support its operating expenses and phil¬
anthropic activities.
The outbreak of World War II cut off the flow of inventions from MIT and
other universities, and the Research Corporation virtually ceased its patent ad¬
ministration efforts.11 Shortly after the return of peace, the corporation re¬
assessed its patent management activities, most of which had involved MIT in¬
ventions, noting that they had produced net losses during the 1937-47 period
(1947 Annual Report, p. 1).12 Although none of the forty MIT inventions and
none of the handful of inventions it was administering for other universities
had yet produced significant returns, the corporation opined that four MIT in¬
ventions had “bright futures” and asserted that “after ten years of trial of the
economic soundness of the type of educational institution patent manage¬
ment agreement initiated in 1937, the soundness of the idea, in spite of the dor¬
mant war years, seems to be confirmed” (1947 Annual Report, p. 1).
Nevertheless, this internal review argued that the scale of the Research
Corporations patent-management operations was too small to be economical,
noting that
the handling of inventions for educational institutions can be successful only if the
service can be rendered to a considerable number of such institutions so that a large
number of potentially valuable inventions can be administered . . . unless a sizable
number of such inventions is available for administration the numerical odds of un¬
successful developments to successful ones would render the management under
such circumstances too great a risk. (1947 Annual Report, p. 3)
By the time the 1947 Annual Report was published, the corporation had begun
a program to attract more university clients to its intellectual property man¬
agement services.
modeled on the MIT agreement, with several hundred other U.S. universities
during the 1940s and 1950s (Figure 4.1). Under the terms of these agreements,
university faculty submitted invention disclosures to the Patent Management
Division, which bore all costs of invention evaluation, patent prosecution, and
licensing. Any royalty income was divided among the academic institution,
the inventor, and the Research Corporation. The Research Corporations
share of the royalties, after deduction of operating expenses, funded its re¬
search grants.
Growth in the number of university clients was paralleled by expansion in
the annual number of inventions disclosed to the Research Corporation (Fig¬
ure 4.2). The average annual flow of disclosures, which never fell below
200 during this period, represented a sharp increase from the average of
roughly 50 disclosures per year received by the corporation (primarily from
MIT) at the time the Patent Management Division was established. But this
increased flow of disclosures did not produce a comparable increase in patents
(Figure 4.3) or gross royalties (Figure 4.4)7 an issue that we discuss in greater
detail below.
As was noted earlier, the Research Corporations Patent Management Divi¬
sion had hoped that its expanded activities in managing university inventions
would increase the corporations licensing income while reducing its reliance
on a small number of donated inventions for the bulk of its income. None¬
theless, the corporations 1951 Annual Report noted that institutional inven¬
tions still accounted for a small share of licensing royalties:
figure 4.3 Patents issued to the Research Corporation, 1947—81
1996 Dollars
[Most revenues] have been derived from agreements covering specific projects; and
not from the over-all patent management contracts. . . the blanket agreements still
have not “paid off.” The corporations experience shows that this is not to be ex¬
pected except over a period of many years, and even then only in a few instances. It
is important only that there be a sufficient number of these “few instances” and to
that end, it is important that more institutional agreements be secured. (1951 An¬
nua/ Report, p. 42)
This problem was a persistent one for the Research Corporation. In 1947, it
had noted that “none of our other [other than MIT] general agreements with
educational institutions to date show any promise of financial return, but we
continue optimistic of future developments, particularly as the number and
scope of such agreements continues to increase” (1947 Annual Report, p. 2).
Although its portfolio of institutional agreements, patents, and licenses grew
during the 1950s, growth in net revenues proved elusive.
sciences.14
Another striking characteristic of the biomedical “home runs” that ac¬
counted for the bulk of the Research Corporation’s income through the early
TABLE 4.1
notes: Income numbers are in 1996 dollars. 4 Nonbiomedical invention. 44 Includes back royalties paid as a result of
infringement suit.
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
1970s was the prominence within this group of donated inventions. The most 71
important invention in the first decade of the Patent Management Division
(although it was donated to the corporation before the establishment of the di¬
vision) was the method for synthesis of vitamin Eh that we discussed earlier.
The corporations most lucrative invention after the expiration of the vitamin
Bj patents was nystatin, an antifungal antibiotic developed by Rachel Brown
and Elizabeth Hazel of the New York State Department of EEealth that the in¬
ventors had donated to the corporation.15 During the 1960s and early 1970s,
nystatin, two other donated biomedical inventions (Edward Kendall’s cortical
hormones and Robert Woodwards reserpine), and one donated agricultural
invention (the Jones-Mangelsdorf hybrid seed-growing process) were the cor¬
porations most important sources of royalty income.
Although donated inventions had been important to the Research Corpo¬
ration’s revenues since the beginning of its patent management activities, the
extent of the corporation’s reliance on donated inventions had increased by
the mid-1960s. This is apparent even if we restrict our attention to the donated
inventions among the top five gross revenue earners, or the donated “home
runs.” Having accounted for 48 percent of total gross royalty revenues in 1955
and 50 percent in i960, the donated inventions among the top five gross reve¬
nue earners accounted for 69 percent of gross royalties in 1965 and 91 percent
in 1970.16 Only after 1975, when the patents on the last of the donated “home
runs” expired, did the entirety of the Research Corporation’s income depend
on inventions administered through institutional IAAs.
72 licensing agreement with RCA in 1957. IBM also entered into negotiations
with the Research Corporation to negotiate a license should Forrester win the
case. But IBM and the corporation failed to agree on royalty rates, and the ne¬
gotiations collapsed. IBM, which had a long history of donating funds and
equipment to MIT, expressed concern to Institute administrators that the Re¬
search Corporation was taking a hard line in the negotiations. Indeed, Pugh
(1984) reports that IBM may have threatened to withhold future funding to
MIT if the Research Corporation did not compromise.
In i960, the Board of Patent Interferences declared Rajchman victorious on
ten significant claims and awarded several narrower claims to Forrester. The
Research Corporation launched a civil action to attempt to recover the ten
claims awarded to Rajchman and initiated a patent infringement suit against
RCA and IBM.18 By this time, the interests of MIT and the Research Corpo¬
ration seem to have diverged; As Pugh (1984, p. 211) describes it:
As the attorneys prepared for the court case, MIT decided that its interests were not
properly represented by Research Corporation. Research Corporation wanted pat¬
ent fees paid over time, based on use, so that a predictable revenue stream would
permit orderly operation of its business. MIT preferred a single payment to help
cover the costs of a building program. Even more importantly MIT was concerned
about its long-term relationship with IBM and the rest of the computer industry.
In 1962, MIT terminated its IAA with the Research Corporation. Under the
terms of the termination agreement, the Research Corporation received a
$1.6 million cash settlement, and MIT retained all residual rights to the pat¬
ents it had assigned to the Research Corporation.
The Forrester case was a pivotal development in the Research Corpora¬
tions history, since it led to the termination of the IAA that had been the foun¬
dation for the corporations patent management activities. But this case also il¬
lustrates the potential conflicts between the incentives of patent management
agents and those of their academic principals. Similar tensions between the
goals of maximizing licensing income and maintaining or deepening rela¬
tionships with industrial firms (relationships that ultimately may prove to yield
substantially more research funding or income) are not uncommon within
contemporary university technology licensing offices and faculties.19
Although the Research Corporation had expanded its operations in the early
postwar period in order to reduce the unit costs of patent management, these
cost savings proved to be elusive. As we noted above, the corporations exper¬
tise in locating licensees and negotiating licensing agreements in one tech¬
nology field appears to have had limited relevance to other; technological
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
areas. Other costs of the corporations operations, such as legal and “visitation” 73
expenses, also grew as its activities and client list expanded. Instead, dis¬
economies of scale and scope increased the Research Corporations operating
costs and reduced net revenues. This section examines several of these sources
of increasing costs, which highlight challenges faced by many contemporary
university technology licensing offices.
Following the cancellation of its agreement with MIT, the Research Corpora¬
tion reorganized its patent management program. Although the corporation
maintained its support for a specialized Patent Management Division that
served multiple institutional clients, the 1963 Annua/ Report argued that the
corporation’s efforts had been “too conservative. In 1963, the corporation ex¬
panded its efforts in patent management and marketing. These intensified
efforts included an increase in staff and greater reliance on technical con¬
sultants (and outside patent counsel) for evaluating and licensing inventions.
The increased reliance on consultants was most pronounced in the mechani¬
cal and electronics fields, where the corporation had developed little exper¬
tise and (as we discuss below) generated little royalty income.20 Figures 4-5
1996 Dollars
versity administrators and inventors, a theme that runs through the corpora- 75
tions history. MIT had insisted that the Research Corporation establish a Bos¬
ton office as a condition of the 1937 Invention Management Agreement. Even
after the corporations Boston office was closed in 1946, Research Corporation
staff continued monthly visits to MIT to evaluate and discuss Institute inven¬
tions through the late 1950s. For the Research Corporation (as for contempo¬
rary licensing offices), patenting and licensing transactions required signifi¬
cant investments of time in the development of close relationships with
inventors and their parent institutions, reflecting the substantial “relational”
component of such transactions. Evaluation of inventions, especially those in
their embryonic stages, requires inventor cooperation, guidance, and equip¬
ment. Inventors also are often more knowledgeable about markets for licenses
and may be willing to contribute consulting assistance to transfer important
know-how along with the patent license. Inventor assistance and cooperation
may be needed to write and prosecute patent applications.24
The importance of these relational aspects of technology licensing opera¬
tions helps explain the role of geographic proximity in markets for technol¬
ogy.25 Indeed, the need for frequent interaction between licensing profession¬
als and university inventors has provided one impetus for the decentralization
of technology licensing offices in large, multicampus university systems such
as the University of California.
The Research Corporations efforts during the postwar period to expand the
number of universities with whom it worked, as well as its more intensive mar¬
keting activities of the 1950s and 1960s, do not appear to have offset the detri¬
mental financial effects of higher operating costs, declining royalties, and the
expiration of key donated patents on home runs. In the face of the imminent
expiration of the last of its lucrative donated patents in 1975, the corporation
noted that
while it is possible that other substantial income producing inventions will become
available in the future, it will be a rare occurrence. Therefore, if the invention ad¬
ministration operation is to continue, total reliance must be put on finding and de¬
veloping commercially viable shared inventions. One consequence of this situation
is that a major effort will be required in the future to develop and enhance rela¬
tionships with universities and faculty inventors. (1974 Annual Report, p. 3)
Unfortunately, this statement overlooked the fact that such efforts had been
under way for more than a decade, with little effect. The “arrival rate” of
highly profitable inventions proved to be unresponsive to the Research Cor¬
poration’s efforts to increase it. This inability to obtain and license additional
“home runs” in the face of growing needs for revenues foreshadows the chal¬
lenges that technology licensing offices and administration at a number of
prominent universities face as patents on key inventions from the early 1980s,
many of which are associated with the rise of biotechnology, begin to expire.
Did the Research Corporation fail to capture more profitable institutional
inventions because its client universities began to “cherry-pick” their faculty
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
The failure to attract highly profitable inventions from its client universities
suggests that the benefits for the Research Corporation resulting from di¬
versification among technologies and institutional clients were limited. De¬
spite increased expenditures on consultants and specialized staff, the corpora¬
tion patented few lucrative inventions. This failure was surprising in view of
the fact that during the 1950s and 1960s, the Research Corporation had access
to the patentable inventions of many of the nations most prominent research
universities.
The effects of slower revenue growth were exacerbated by continued
growth in the corporations total operating costs during the 1960s (Figure 4.7).
Beginning in the mid-1970s, the visitation program and the more aggressive
patent management program were curtailed, and the rate of growth of expen¬
ditures on consultants, legal services, personnel, and travel declined (revealed
in the downward trend after 1975 in consulting, legal, and personnel expenses
in Figures 4.5 and 4.6). . ,
Another source of scale economies that the Research Corporation had
hoped to exploit, dating back to Cottrell’s original vision, was the spreading
of “fixed” costs over a large number of institutions and inventions. Nonethe¬
less its growing client roster failed to prevent the corporation’s total costs per
$7,000,000 -
1996 Dollars
$0 i i i i i i i i i i i i i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—i—r
rv~s lt\ 0n
LT\ LT\ LT\ LT\
O' O O' O' o O' O' O' O' O' O' O' O' O' O' O'
Fiscal Year
FIGURE 4.8 Total costs per Invention Administration Agreement and disclosure,
1951-81
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
invention agreement and per disclosure from increasing, rather than decreas¬ 79
ing, in the late 1960s (Figure 4.8).
By the mid-1970s, the Research Corporations net royalty income had de¬
clined sharply (Figure 4.9), and a “Committee on Goals and Objectives of the
Corporation” was convened to conduct a strategic review. The committees
report concluded in 1979 that “if in the years 1980-1983 forecasts of enhanced
income do not begin to be realized, significant changes in programs will be
necessary” (Research Corporation, 1979, p. 5). In the event, these “significant
changes” included closing the Patent Management Division.31
8o would ultimately increase the demand for its services.32 But the corporations
assistance to U.S. universities in responding to these changes in federal policy
may have hastened its eclipse, as U.S. universities expanded their independent
management of patenting and licensing activities.
In responding to requests for assistance from U.S. universities, the Research
Corporation supported the growth of independent technology transfer opera¬
tions at a number of institutions. By teaching university administrators about
the processes of invention evaluation and administration, the Research Cor¬
poration helped academic institutions develop the capabilities needed to
manage patenting and licensing.33 The corporations 1974 Annual Report
noted that almost every major U.S. university was considering the establish¬
ment of an internal technology transfer office, and the 1975 Annual Report
stated that a growing number of client universities no longer asked the corpo¬
ration to evaluate particularly valuable inventions, choosing instead to man¬
age them internally.34 The potential for significant royalty income in these
fields thus appears to have contributed to growth in cherry-picking by univer¬
sities after the early 1970s, ironically reducing the Research Corporations ac-
cess to university inventions at the same time that the pool of commercially 8i
valuable academic inventions was expanding.
The passage of the Bayh-Dole Act, which the Research Corporation sup¬
ported, was another important factor in the corporations decline. Growth in
independent university technology licensing operations, which accelerated
after the passage of Bayh-Dole, reduced the Research Corporations share of
the market for academic patents. As the number of universities that entered
into patenting and licensing activities increased (see Chapter 3), the Research
Corporations share of all university patents decreased dramatically, as seen in
Figure 4.10.
In a recent review of its patent management activities, the Research Cor¬
poration noted that “the Bayh-Dole Bill, which the foundation strongly sup¬
ported and testified in favor of, curtailed this pioneering initiative as the na¬
tions colleges and universities developed their own technology transfer offices
and staffs of legal and technical experts” (1997 Annual Report, p. 16). Our
analysis above supports this view but suggests that the internal operating and
financial difficulties that ultimately caused the Research Corporation to cur¬
tail its patent management activities predated the passage of Bayh-Dole.
The Research Corporation remained active during the 1980s in the face of
Bayh-Dole and the growth of independent university-based technology trans¬
fer operations, but its importance declined. The ability of the corporation to
compete in this arena was further hindered by its status as a charitable foun¬
dation. In the early 1980s, the Internal Revenue Service ruled that the Re¬
search Corporations technology transfer activities were an “unrelated trade or
business.” As a result, the corporation was prohibited from activities it viewed
as essential to technology transfer, such as investing in start-up companies and
early-stage funding of development activities. In 1987* ^*e corporation closed
the Patent Management Division and transferred all of its activities to an in¬
dependent for-profit organization, Research Corporation Technologies
(RCT), whose purpose is “identifying, developing, and commercializing in¬
ventions for universities, colleges, medical research organizations, and other
non-profit laboratories” (1987 Annual Report, p. 20).
Although the RCT has the same mission as the corporation’s former Patent
Management Division, it uses retained earnings to fund technology transfer
activities rather than scientific research. RCT received half of the Research
Corporations endowment (about $45 million in 1996 dollars) at the time of the
spin-off, as well as the Research Corporations patent portfolio and technology
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
82 transfer staff. The spin-off agreement stipulated that the Research Corporation
would receive a portion of RCT’s net royalty income until the $45 million
transfer in endowment was paid back. Today, the Research Corporation fo¬
cuses exclusively on research grants, which are funded from the returns on its
endowment, the repayment by the RCT of its endowment grant, and philan¬
thropic contributions.
The RCT s Cooperative Program allows academic institutions to use RCT
to evaluate inventions, similar to the Research Corporations Invention Ad¬
ministration Program. The RCT also operates the Benchmark Program,
which allows universities and other institutions to use RCT services on an “as-
needed” basis. According to Gilles (1991), the Benchmark Program is used pri¬
marily for evaluating the inventions of academic clients, with no commitment
to managing any patents, and management of patenting and licensing for in¬
ventions in fields in which the university technology licensing offices lack ex¬
pertise. Very few universities have used RCT s Cooperative Program, and both
the Cooperative and Benchmark Programs are being phased out.
By some measures, the RCT remains a successful technology transfer or¬
ganization: the Association of University Technology Managers s 1996 AUTM
Licensing Survey (attachment E, p. 53) reports that its gross licensing income
amounted to $70 million, more than any U.S. university in that year. About
$45 million of this amount was distributed to the inventors and universities re¬
sponsible for the inventions (see Research Corporation Technologies, 1996,
“Corporate Update”). Nonetheless, the importance of RCT as a technolog)'
transfer agent has diminished considerably, and its activities differ significantly
from those of the Research Corporation.
CONCLUSION
I his brief history of the Research Corporation underscores the points made in
Chapters 2 and 3 concerning the history of U.S. universities’ patenting activi¬
ties during the twentieth century. I he Research Corporation played an im¬
portant role in the growth of these activities during the middle years of this
century and created a portion of the institutional and administrative infra¬
structure for the post-1980 upsurge in patenting and licensing by individual
U.S. universities. Discussions surrounding the foundation of the Research
Corporation, and much of the debate over its early years of operation, antici¬
pated many of the contemporary comments and debates over the desirability
and effects of university technology licensing. Indeed, Cottrell articulated the
prospect argument (Kitch, 1977) for patenting of university inventions in his
1912 assertion that “some minimum level” of protection for the intellectual
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
property resulting from academic research was necessary in order for industry 83
to invest in its subsequent development and commercialization. But Cottrell
was ambivalent about the effects on academic norms and behavior of locating
the responsibility for management of these activities within the university,
fearing the consequences of conflicts of interest and pressures by university ad¬
ministrators to increase the income flowing from patent licenses, an ambiva¬
lence that is notably absent today.
The Research Corporations history illustrates other features of markets for
intellectual property that manifest themselves in many U.S. universities’ cur¬
rent patenting and licensing operations. Although there appear to be advan¬
tages to specialization in patent and license management that reflect the high
fixed costs, benefits of portfolio diversification, and possibilities for efficiency
gains through learning, the history of the Research Corporation suggests that
these benefits are counterbalanced by significant limitations.
In particular, the requirements for specialized knowledge about individual
technology fields and (of equal importance) about the market for licenses in a
given technology field limit the applicability of know-how acquired from
patenting and licensing in one technology field to other fields. The impor¬
tance of geographic proximity in even arms’ length licensing arrangements
also limits the cost savings attainable through centralization of activities in
a single site or organization. These factors contributed to the declining fi¬
nancial performance of the Research Corporation in the 1970s, and they are
apparent in the operation of many contemporary university technology licens¬
ing offices. Licensing managers tend to focus on specific technology areas,
rather than being generalists. A number of universities’ patenting and licensing
offices have been reorganized so as to decentralize their operations, while at
least a few other universities have maintained independent licensing efforts in
different organizational units, such as their medical and engineering schools.
The study also underscores the limits of “pure” licensing agreements to
support the exploitation or commercialization of inventions. From its earliest
days, the corporation had to invest in extensive applications engineering and
in customization of its precipitation technologies, and it found it necessary to
acquire an extensive portfolio of complementary patents. The Research Cor¬
poration also relied on investments in additional development and other com¬
plements to many of the academic patents that it sought to commercialize,
driving up costs and reducing profits. Contemporary university licensing of¬
fices have also found it necessary to make additional investments, in some
cases taking equity stakes in firms founded to exploit their inventions, in order
to pursue commercial development. Needless to say, this expansion of their ac¬
tivities increases costs and risks.
THE RESEARCH CORPORATION AND LICENSING
The effects of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 on university patenting and licensing
cannot be understood without some consideration of the political origins of
the Act itself. The Bayh-Dole Act is rooted in a debate that extends back to the
late 1940s over the disposition of intellectual property resulting from federally
funded research. But an important factor in the drafting and passage of the Act
in 1980 was the growing role of U.S. universities as patenters and licensors. In¬
deed, U.S. universities themselves played a significant role in the passage of
the Act, which can be viewed in part as a response to increased academic
patenting and licensing activity, even as it provided an impetus to expansion
in these activities.
In the following section, we argue that the debates during the late 1970s
over Bayh-Dole included little evidence that patents and exclusive licenses fa¬
cilitate the transfer and commercialization of federally funded academic re¬
search. Moreover, in contrast to the debates about university patenting earlier
in the century that were discussed in Chapter 3, the Bayh-Dole debates de¬
voted little consideration to potential effects of expanded university patenting
and licensing on “open science” and on academic research more generally.
The overriding concern of Bayh-Dole supporters was increased commer¬
cialization of university inventions, and numerous subsequent journalistic ac¬
counts of the “effects of Bayh-Dole,” as well as a number of analyses from gov¬
ernmental agencies, argue that these goals have been met. As we point out
later in this chapter, however, important questions about the positive and neg¬
ative effects of Bayh-Dole, and about what might have happened in the ab¬
sence of the Act, remain unanswered. Subsequent chapters in this volume ad¬
dress a number of these issues.
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
Congress had debated the issue of ownership of patents resulting from pub¬
licly funded research for decades before the passage of Bayh-Dole, and federal
patent policy was a central point of contention during the debates of the 1940s
over the organization of postwar U.S. science and technology policy. One side
of the debate over patent policy was represented by Senator Harley Kilgore
(D-W.Va.), who argued that the federal government should retain title to pat¬
ents resulting from federally funded research and place them in the public do¬
main (Kevles, 1978). According to Kilgore, allowing private contractors to re¬
tain patents represented a “giveaway” of the fruits of taxpayer-funded research
to large corporations, reinforcing the concentration of technological and eco¬
nomic power. The opposing position was articulated by the director of the
wartime Office of Scientific Research and Development, Vannevar Bush, who
argued that allowing contractors to retain patent rights would preserve their in¬
centives to participate in federal R&D projects and to develop commercially
useful products based on government-funded research.1
The postwar debate highlighted the central questions in government pat¬
ent policy for the next three decades. Supporters of the retention of intellec¬
tual property rights by government agencies argued that allowing contractors,
rather than government agencies, to retain title to patents resulting from fed¬
erally funded research favored large firms at the expense of small business.
Moreover, they asserted, such a policy would raise prices for the fruits of
taxpayer-funded research. Supporters of allowing contractors to retain title to
patents resulting from federally funded research argued that failure to do so
would make it difficult to attract qualified firms to perform government re¬
search and that the absence of clear title to intellectual property resulting from
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
The debates over federal patent policy largely ignored U.S. universities during
the 1940s and 1950s. After all, U.S. universities have.never been responsible for
performance of more than 34 percent of federally funded R&D (excluding
university-based Federally Funded Research and Development Centers
[FFRDCs]) during the postwar period and their share of federally funded
R&D exceeded 20 percent only after 1991.4 Moreover, as we noted in Chap¬
ter 3, U.S. universities historically had limited their direct involvement in
patenting and licensing activities.
Federal policy toward patents resulting from publicly funded university re¬
search became a topic of debate after the release in 1968 of reports on the Na¬
tional Institutes of Health’s (NIH) Medicinal Chemistry program by the U.S.
General Accounting Office (GAO) (1968) and by Harbridge House (1968a), a
consulting firm that the Federal Council for Science and Technology (FCST)
commissioned to conduct a study on government patent policy as part of a re¬
view of this issue by the FCST itself.5 Both reports examined the effects of fed¬
eral patent policy on research collaboration between U.S. pharmaceutical
firms and academic researchers in medicinal chemistry. During the 1940s and
1950s, these pharmaceutical firms had routinely screened compounds de¬
veloped by NIH-funded university researchers at no charge.6 In some cases
(depending on the patent policies of particular universities), these pharma¬
ceutical firms received exclusive rights to develop and market the compounds.
In 1962, the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare (HEW) notified
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
88 universities that firms screening compounds must sign formal patent agree¬
ments that prevented the firms from obtaining patents on technologies result¬
ing from NIH funding (GAO, 1968, p. 10). Indeed, the HEW policy further
stated that firms could not obtain patents on inventions in the “field of re¬
search work” supported by NIH funds at a given institution.
The GAO and Harbridge House reports criticized HEW’s patent policy,
arguing that pharmaceutical firms had stopped screening NIH grantees’ com¬
pounds because of the firms’ concerns that the HEW policies could compro¬
mise their rights to intellectual property resulting from their in-house research
(Harbridge House, 1968a, p. II-21; GAO, 1968, p. 11). Both reports recom¬
mended that HEW change its patent policy to clarify the circumstances un¬
der which rights reverted to the government and those under which universi¬
ties could retain title to patents and issue exclusive licenses to firms.
HEW responded to these critical reports in 1968 by establishing Institu¬
tional Patent Agreements (IPAs) that gave universities with “approved tech¬
nology transfer capability” the right to retain title to agency-funded patents.
In addition, the agency began to act more quickly on requests from universi¬
ties and other research performers for title to the intellectual property result¬
ing from federally funded research. Between 1969 and 1974, HEW approved
90 percent of petitions for title, and between 1969 and 1977 the agency granted
IPAs to seventy-two universities and nonprofit institutions (Weissman, 1989).
The National Science Foundation (NSF) instituted a similar IPA program in
1973, and the Department of Defense (DOD) began in the mid-1960s to allow
universities with approved patent policies to retain title to inventions resulting
from federally funded research.
By the beginning of the 1970s, U.S. universities thus were able to patent the
results of federally funded research via agency-specific IPAs or similar pro¬
grams at the DOD as well as through case-by-case petitions. Nevertheless, in
the late 1970s U.S. universities became concerned that HEW might limit their
ability to negotiate exclusive licenses in the department’s IPA programs. These
concerns, along with growing dissatisfaction within Congress and the indus¬
trial community over the lack of uniformity in patent rights to inventions re¬
sulting from federally funded research, provided the immediate impetus for
the introduction in 1978 of the bill that eventually became the Bayh-Dole Act.
As we noted above, HEW’s 1968 revisions in its patent policy expanded the
number of IPAs negotiated with universities and other research institutions
and allowed more universities to obtain patents on NIH-funded inventions on
a case-by-case basis. U.S. universities had become more active in patenting
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
and licensing faculty inventions during the 1970s, especially in the biomedical 89
field (see Chapters 3 and 4), and therefore welcomed these changes in HEW
patent policies.
But these patent policies triggered considerable debate within HEW. In
August 1977, HEWs Office of the General Counsel expressed concern that
university patents and licenses, particularly exclusive licenses, could con¬
tribute to higher health-care costs (Eskridge, 1978). The department ordered
a review of its patent policy, including a reconsideration of whether universi¬
ties’ rights to negotiate exclusive licenses should be curtailed.8 During the en¬
suing twelve-month review by HEW of its patent policies, the agency deferred
decisions on thirty petitions for patent rights and three requests for IPAs.
Thus, although Bayh-Dole is often regarded as being the catalyst for the
growth of university patenting and licensing in the United States, in fact U.S.
universities that were active in patenting and licensing, as well as other uni¬
versities, lobbied for the introduction and passage of the bill. Broad (1979a,
p. 476) notes that in response to HEWs review of its patent policies, “[univer¬
sities got upset and complained to Congress.” And Heaton et al. (2000) note
that a patent attorney from Purdue University and a congressional staffer who
previously worked at the University of Arizona, both of which sought more lib¬
eral policies toward patenting publicly funded research, respectively asked
Senators Birch Bayh (D-Ind.) and Robert Dole (R-Kans.) to introduce the bill.
These and other university licensing officials also aided in drafting portions of
what became the Bayh-Dole Act.9
In September 1978, Senator Dole held a press conference where he criti¬
cized HEW for “stonewalling” university patenting (commenting, “rarely
have we witnessed a more hideous example of overmanagement by the bu¬
reaucracy”) and announced his intention to introduce a bill to remedy the sit¬
uation (Eskridge, 1978, p. 605). On September 13, 1978, Senators Bayh and
Dole introduced S. 414, the University and Small Business Patent Act. The Act
proposed a uniform federal patent policy that gave universities and small busi¬
nesses rights to any patents resulting from government-funded research.10 The
bill lacked provisions that had been included in most IPAs, including the re¬
quirement that a participating university must have an “approved technology
transfer” capability. In contrast to the language of some IPAs between univer¬
sities and HEW, the bill imposed no restrictions on the negotiation by uni¬
versities and other research institutions of exclusive licensing agreements.11
As we noted earlier, many members of Congress had long opposed any
federal grant of ownership of patents to research performers or contrac¬
tors (Broad, 1979b). The Bayh-Dole bill nevertheless attracted little opposi¬
tion. The bills focus on securing patent rights for only universities and small
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
As Eisenberg (1996) has pointed out, however, the data in the Harbridge 91
House and FCST reports did not support this conclusion. The patents exam¬
ined in the Harbridge and FCST studies were drawn primarily from research
funded by the DOD (83 percent of the patents from the Harbridge House
sample and 63 percent of those from the FCST sample), an agency that read¬
ily granted patent rights to research performers. Since these defense contrac¬
tors could and often did seek the rights to patents that they believed might re¬
sult in profitable innovations, it is likely that the patents for which they did not
seek ownership rights had limited commercial potential. It therefore is not sur¬
prising that these patents were not commercialized.
The data in these reports also were based primarily on patents resulting
from government-funded R&D carried out by private firms. As such, they
shed little light on the importance for commercial exploitation of patenting
by universities of inventions funded by the federal government. It is likely, for
example, that the characteristics of federally funded university inventions
differ from those associated with federally funded inventions patented by con¬
tractors, reflecting the fact (among other things) that federally funded aca¬
demic research typically includes more fundamental research and less de¬
velopment activity than do research contracts with industry.
In addition to citing this statistical evidence, supporters of the bill argued
that the characteristics of university inventions made patents and exclusive li¬
censes important for the commercialization of these inventions. According to
these witnesses, most university inventions are embryonic when first disclosed,
requiring significant additional development before they can be commer¬
cially useful. In this view, firms would not invest in these costly development
activities without clear rights to the relevant intellectual property, something
that in many instances would require an exclusive license.16 Other witnesses
suggested that giving title to universities would create incentives for inventors
and institutions to become actively involved in the development and com¬
mercialization of embryonic inventions, anticipating arguments developed
more formally by Jensen and Thursby (2001).
The Bayh-Dole Act was passed overwhelmingly in both the House and the
Senate in the winter of 1980 with minimal floor debate, and President Jimmy
Carter signed the Act into law in December 1980.18 The Acts provisions facil¬
itated university patenting and licensing in at least two ways. F irst, they re¬
placed the web of IPAs and case-by-case petitions with a uniform policy. Sec¬
ond, the Act expressed congressional support for the negotiation of exclusive
licenses between universities and industrial firms for the results of federally
funded research.
The broad political support for university patenting of intellectual
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
92 property, especially that resulting from federally funded research, that was ex¬
pressed in hearings and floor debate on the Bayh-Dole Act contrasts with the
widespread expressions of concern by university administrators and others in
the debates of the 1930s over university patenting and licensing that were dis¬
cussed in Chapter 3. For example, none of the witnesses in these hearings dis¬
cussed the potential risks created by university patenting and licensing for the
“disclosure” and other norms of academic science, nor were any potentially
detrimental effects of patenting and licensing for other channels of university-
industry technology transfer considered.19 Nor did the hearings and floor de¬
bate over Bayh-Dole discuss the political risks for universities of direct in¬
volvement in the management of patenting and licensing that loomed larger
in the debates of the 1930s and 1940s.
In many respects, the central justifications for the Bayh-Dole Act elevated
to the national level the “taxpayer benefit” arguments that were widely used
during the 1920s and 1930s to justify state universities’ involvement in patent¬
ing and licensing. These arguments were especially salient in the economic
environment of the late 1970s, when U.S. global competitiveness (or the lack
of same) had become an important political issue in domestic debate. In a
global economy in which scientific and technological knowledge moved
across national boundaries and could be exploited more easily by non-U.S. en¬
terprises than in previous decades, supporters of the Bayh-Dole Act argued
that U.S. taxpayers would benefit from federal support of academic R&D only
if the results of this research were commercialized, an outcome widely be¬
lieved to be more likely if these results were patented.
1 his argument repeated the justifications of the prewar period for the wide¬
spread involvement of public universities in patenting and licensing —patent¬
ing was essential to the capture by state taxpayers of the benefits of their uni¬
versities’ research activities. But the majority of the inventions whose
licensure was debated during the 1930s had been funded by industrial or state
government sources rather than by the federal government. The invocation by
supporters of Bayh-Dole of these justifications at the national level reflected
the rise to dominance of federal agencies as sources of academic research sup¬
port during the postwar period and implied that both private and public uni¬
versities faced a similar “public service” obligation to patent and license fac¬
ulty inventions in the wake of Bayh-Dole.
The Bayh-Dole Act became effective on July 1, 1981, creating a uniform fed¬
eral patent policy for universities and small businesses that gave them the
rights to any patents resulting from grants or contracts funded by any federal
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
During the late 1990s and early twenty-first century, many commentators and
policymakers portrayed the Bayh-Dole Act as the critical catalyst to growth in
U.S. universities’ innovative and economic contributions. Indeed, the Orga¬
nization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) went so far
as to argue that the Bayh-Dole Act was an important factor in the remarkable
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
Similar characterizations of the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act have been artic¬
ulated by the president of the Association of American Universities,25 the com¬
missioner of the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office,26 and the Technology Re¬
view, edited and published at MIT.27
Remarkably, none of these characterizations of the positive effects of the
Bayh-Dole Act cite any rigorous evidence in support of their claims. This
cavalier treatment of evidence, of course, is not unprecedented in the po¬
litical history of the Act. We noted above that the legislative debates over the
bill’s drafting and passage relied on little if any evidence that patents and li¬
censes are necessary for the commercialization and development of university
technologies.
Scholarly research on the effects of Bayh-Dole has been slower to appear,
reflecting the need for evidence to support such empirical research. We dis¬
cuss this research in greater detail in subsequent chapters as part of our em¬
pirical investigation of U.S. university patenting and licensing before and af¬
ter 1980. Here, we simply highlight the central findings and unresolved issues
raised by this research.
There is little evidence of substantial shifts since Bayh-Dole in the content
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
of academic research, a finding that is not surprising in view of the blurry 1 ines 95
between “basic” and “applied” research in the biomedical sciences that have
been the focus of most of the increased university patenting and licensing
since the 1970s. But current research, which remains quite preliminary in its
findings on this issue, provides mixed support for the argument that patenting
and licensing are necessary for the transfer and commercial development of
university inventions. Other scholarly work (for example, Louis et ah, 2001)
suggests that university patenting and licensing have negatively affected “dis¬
closure norms” of academic research in specific fields, leading to higher lev¬
els of secrecy and less sharing among researchers of early results, but more re¬
search on this issue is needed. Finally, the effects on the research enterprise
itself of any increased assertion by institutional and individual inventors of
property rights over inputs to scientific research have only begun to receive se¬
rious scholarly attention.
Journalistic and policy-oriented accounts of the Bayh-Dole Act thus pre¬
sent little evidence in support of their claims, while scholarly research on the
Act’s effects by other scholars and ourselves reaches a much more tentative and
guarded verdict on the Bayh-Dole Act. Nevertheless, the limited evidence on
the Acts effects (both positive and negative) has not prevented a number of
other OECD governments from pursuing policies that closely resemble the
Bayh-Dole Act.
But patenting and licensing were only one of many channels through 97
which U.S. universities contributed to industrial innovation throughout
the twentieth century, and the surveys of industrial managers discussed in
Chapter 2 suggest that these channels are not the most important ones in most
technological fields. Inasmuch as patenting and licensing are of secondary
importance in most fields, emulation of the Bayh-Dole Act is insufficient and
perhaps even unnecessary to stimulate higher levels of university-industry in¬
teraction and technology transfer. Instead, reforms to enhance interinstitu-
tional competition and autonomy within national university systems, as well
as support for the external institutional contributors to new-firm formation
and technology commercialization, such as venture capital funding, labor
mobility, and other important catalysts for technology commercialization, ap¬
pear to be more important.
Moreover, the impact of Bayh-Dole on the other channels of knowledge
and technology transfer remains unclear, as we have argued above. There are
potential risks to the university research enterprise that accompany increased
involvement by university administrators and faculty in technology licensing
and commercialization, and uncritical emulation of Bayh-Dole in a very dif¬
ferent institutional context could intensify these risks.
CONCLUSION
The Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 was an effect as well as a cause of increased uni¬
versity patenting and licensing in the United States. The debates leading to
passage of the Act included little if any of the substance of previous debates
among university administrators over the desirability of direct institutional in¬
volvement in patenting and licensing. Nor did parties to the debate over the
Bayh-Dole Act draw on the lengthy controversy within the U.S. Congress over
the appropriate policy toward ownership of the intellectual property rights cre¬
ated in federally funded research programs. The relatively noncontroversial
character of the bill and the limited debate surrounding it both seem to have
reflected the broad bipartisan concern within the Congress and executive
branch in the late 1970s over “international competitiveness,” as well as the ris¬
ing tide of faith in the role of strong intellectual property rights to strengthen
the United States in international competition.
A remarkable feature of the debate over Bayh-Dole and much of the cele¬
bratory “analysis” of its effects in the popular press and elsewhere is the lack
of hard evidence to support the claims of proponents and opponents. This
evidentiary vacuum, however, has not prevented the widespread adoption
or serious consideration of similar policies by other industrial-economy
governments.
POLITICAL HISTORY OF THE BAYH-DOLE ACT
98 In the following chapters, we analyze the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act, ar¬
guing that much of what has occurred since 1980 in U.S. university patenting
and licensing might well have occurred without the Act. The surge in univer¬
sity patenting and licensing is as much a result of the long-standing relation¬
ships between U.S. universities and industry, the broader shift toward stronger
intellectual property rights during the 1980s in the United States, and the
transformation of biomedical science as it is a result of the Bayh-Dole Act.
Moreover, the Acts proponents have exaggerated the necessity of patenting
and licensing to support such interactions and technology transfer, even as
they have overlooked potential risks for U.S. universities and for the broader
economy flowing from increased patenting of university research results.
6
Although the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980 is widely cited as the central factor in the
growth of U.S. academic patenting and licensing during the 1980s, its effects
on U.S. research universities and on the U.S. innovation system have been the
focus of little empirical analysis (Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg 1998a,b,
are important exceptions). In this chapter, we examine the patenting and li¬
censing activities of three academic institutions that were the leading recipi¬
ents of licensing and royalty income for much of the 1990s: the University of
California (UC), Stanford University, and Columbia University.1 A combined
analysis of data from these three universities allows us to consider the effects
of these new federal policies on universities such as Columbia, which became
large-scale patenters and licensers only after 1980, and universities that were
active in patenting and licensing well before 1980, such as the University of
California and Stanford. Chapter 7 complements this analysis of individual in¬
stitutions with an examination of the characteristics of the patents issued to all
U.S. universities before and after 1980.
94
O o O' r-
91
S NrHVO o o -H VO 00 O' o
0s rsl ~-* O
£ pa" rsf
NO ^f
fc O'" pa"
pa co 't-
PA
LA,
ON
I
o
r\
On
6,950.5
o NO OO
o
00 o
o NO
Tf r-i ltv O' o o no o
87
92
O'
£ O' la O' la O' *—1 pa
'•t*
00 O'
NO
PA
°° •—^ rN|_ 10
S E £ no" P'f £
o
o
jg
OJD
•£
584.7
la pa >—1 LA
£5 00 OO
rA LA [v. o
99
o
81
$G O' O' O' O' O'
d> Tf rt- NO fA. VO NO
o r-J © PA VO
E ^ rsT E ltv rrC
><
£"
o NO CO o go r- o
e 00
O' O' p'i ■—1 NO
00
O' co coNO o
co
ID N co ia
CO <
LTV ^3" CO N 00 ^t-
O'
E rsf —■T E
-o
o
O LA NO p LA P LA
"gj f'- LA CO CO r- r-
O' O' o O' O' P'i O' r- O'
c o ■—1 CA NO 00
gj NO —^ O' NO
vd £ E E
w
j
CQ d>
< •d
H
’£ o p p o
r- r-»
O' LA Ovj O' r- O'
1- OO I\ PA LA
Osj O'
£ E
e
-S
00
•S'
Gross income from top 5 earners (1996 dollars: 000s)
'£
c
Share of income of top 5 earners associated with
vg
Share of gross income from top 5 earners (%)
,-~G GO JsJJ
GS
_E5
g^'-o<u GO
d>
O JZ3 v> -*-•
O 6 -2 o c .a
T)
vo
r O
®
T3 G
t
0
C
NO
£> O' 2 8 o^ 03
« Vi
g
O' 0 OJ 0J ^
O' W 03
•-I LA co p-^LA v,
d>
.> c/j
w, o
SC (D
G x-v G O c o
S d> 4“* • ■
biomedical inventions (%)
o o
D s^
EB. £ ^
d> : d> '—
1 ^ Vi
E E o
£
c ^ G
S s
o
^ i> g\2 Oh O ^ <u S-.2
S S'-g O o
*s C B o o c^ I d>
T3
NO
I"! ■? ° ^3
D NO
Q d> c d> G O'
r- °
<u c O'
ouES03
O'
^3
O 03
E^ O'
«S O CO
O O 0
o g C B d) d)
d> toe .S _c
——1 E E hJO ^3
d> G-. G_ <u u- 3 4h d»
0 0
00 c
o
O C
<l> <u
0 0
S
<U
0 0 O 0
E
1— .2 Lh So _G c (U d) 0
1-4 V-
03 15 cd 03 03 03 IS
3 Vi co
JG JG JG Vi CA _G JG
CO CO 00 0 C CO OO o
Lh 1— t-M
o O O o
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
103
104 revenues during 1970-95. The share of gross licensing revenues accounted for
by the UC systems “top five” inventions actually decreases throughout the
1970-95 period, from nearly 80 percent in fiscal 1970 to 66 percent in fiscal
1995, having reached a low point of 47 percent in fiscal 1985.
Equally remarkable is the illustration in Table 6.1 of the shift in the UC sys¬
tems “top five” inventions from agricultural inventions (including plant vari¬
eties and agricultural machinery) to biomedical inventions. Among the three
universities in this comparative analysis, only the University of California
maintained a large-scale agricultural research effort. During the 1970s, agri¬
cultural inventions accounted for a majority of the income accruing to the
“top five” UC money-earners. Beginning in fiscal 1980, however, this share be¬
gan to decline, and by fiscal 1995 100 percent of the UC systems licensing in¬
come from its “top five” inventions, accounting for over $40 million in reve¬
nues (in 1996 dollars), was derived from biomedical inventions, up from
19 percent in fiscal 1975. Moreover, and consistent with the discussion of the
previous paragraph, this share increased before the passage of Bayh-Dole in
late 1980: the share of “top five” licensing revenues associated with biomedical
inventions jumped from less than 20 percent in fiscal 1975 to more than 50 per¬
cent in fiscal 1980. The depiction in Figure 6.7 of the share of UC licensing
agreements accounted for by biomedical inventions during 1975—95 as a
three-year moving average similarly shows an increase in this share before the
effective date of Bayh-Dole to a higher level that is sustained through much of
the 1980-95 period.
Stanford University
veloped using University resources” was made mandatory.5 Second, the uni¬ 105
versity established a policy under which “[cjopyright to software developed for
University purposes in the course of employment, or as part of either a spon¬
sored project or an unsponsored project specifically supported by University
funds, belongs to the University” (Stanford University Office of Technology
Licensing, 1994a).6
Faculty disclosure of inventions to university administrators thus was no
more mandatory at Stanford before 1994 than at Columbia before 1984. Nev¬
ertheless, especially during the 1970-80 period, Stanford operated a much
more elaborate administrative apparatus for the patenting and licensing of in¬
ventions than did Columbia. The expanding scale of Stanford’s licensing op¬
erations during the 1970s and 1980s suggests that a substantial share of faculty
inventions were disclosed to the OTL.
Data from the Stanford OTL provide some insight into the patenting and
licensing activities of a major private research university before and after
Bayh-Dole. And similar to the situation at the University of California, these
data suggest that the growth of Stanford s patenting and licensing activities re¬
flected influences other than Bayh-Dole. Figure 6.4 displays trends during
1975-90 in Stanford invention disclosures. The average annual number of dis¬
closures to Stanfords OTL increased from 74 during 1975-79, prior to Bayh-
Dole, to 149 during 1984-88. Figure 6.5 shows the number of patents issued
to Stanford during the 1975-95 period; the average annual number of issued
patents also increased from thirteen during 1975-79 to forty-two during 1984-
88. Although the evidence of a “Bayh-Dole effect” in the annual number of
disclosures (such as the jump in disclosures between 1979 and 1980) is stron¬
ger in the Stanford data than in the UC data, the increase in disclosures be¬
tween 1977 and 1978 indicates that the annual number of invention disclosures
was growing prior to Bayh-Dole.
The data in Figures 6.4 and 6.6 also suggest that the importance of bio¬
medical inventions within Stanfords invention portfolio advances had begun
to expand before the passage of Bayh-Dole. Figure 6.4 indicates that the an¬
nual number of biomedical invention disclosures began to increase sharply
during the 1978-80 period, and the share of all disclosures accounted for by
biomedical inventions (see Figures 6.4 and 6.6) increased steadily from 1977
to 1980, leveling off after 1980 and declining after 1983. The magnitude of
these increases in biomedical inventions prior to Bayh-Dole is more modest
than at the University of California, but the trend is similar.
The Stanford data in Figure 6.7 highlight trends in licensing agreements
that resemble those for the UC system during the same period; biomedical
inventions increased as a share of Stanfords (nonsoftware) licenses during
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
Year of Issue
1975-90, although the upward trend was less pronounced and fluctuated
more widely than in the UC data.7 Table 6.1 indicates that as of fiscal 1980,
slightly more than 40 percent of the income from Stanfords “top five”
inventions was attributable to biomedical inventions, suggesting the con¬
siderable importance of these inventions prior to Bayh-Dole. This share in¬
creased to more than 96 percent by fiscal 1995. Stanfords licensing revenues
grew by almost 200-fold (in constant dollars) during 1970-95, and its “top five”
figure 6.6 Stanford University biomedical disclosures as a percentage of
total disclosures, 1975—90 (3-year moving average)
—Columbia Stanford UC
108 inventions accounted for a larger share of gross income for the 1980-95 period
than do the “top five” UC inventions.
Both Stanford and the UC system thus experienced a shift in the composi¬
tion of their invention and licensing portfolios in favor of biomedical inven¬
tions prior to Bayh-Dole. Bayh-Dole was an important but not a determinative
factor in the growth and changing composition of patenting and licensing ac¬
tivity at these institutions.
In contrast to the data from the University of California, Stanfords inven¬
tion disclosures include a number of software inventions, which account for
10-15 percent of annual disclosures. As is the case at Columbia during the
1980s, most of these inventions were not patented and therefore cannot be
traced through annual patent counts. The importance of software disclosures
in Stanford’s licensing activity expanded during the 1970s and 1980s. Only two
of the forty-one inventions disclosed during 1974-79 (less than 5 percent) that
were licensed within eight years of their disclosure were software inventions,
but this figure increased to more than 20 percent for the 1984-88 period.
Many of these software inventions (for example, the WYLBUR operating sys¬
tem) were licensed on a nonexclusive basis to academic institutions through
Stanfords Software Distribution Center during the 1980s. The majority of
these licenses involved a small, one-time payment by the licensee institution.8
Partly because of the large number of such “site licenses,” the coverage by our
data of Stanford software licensing agreements is spotty, and our estimate of
the share of all Stanford licensing agreements accounted for by software is less
accurate. Nonetheless, like Columbia University, a significant portion of Stan¬
ford’s licensed inventions (at least 10-20 percent of annual licensing agree¬
ments and a smaller share of gross revenues) covered nonpatented inventions
during the 1980s, Bayh-Dole notwithstanding.
Columbia University
faculty over institutional assertion of rights to faculty inventions began in the 109
late 1960s and gained momentum in the 1970s but produced no formal change
in policy until the passage of Bayh-Dole (for a fuller discussion, see Crow
et ah, 1998).
Columbia’s laissez-faire policy toward patenting the results of faculty re¬
search during the three decades following World War II meant that the uni¬
versity had no administrative structure for managing patent matters. Begin¬
ning in the late 1970s, however, the university expanded its involvement in
patent transactions between its inventors and the Research Corporation, cre¬
ated a central archive of potentially patentable inventions, and petitioned gov¬
ernment agencies for title to faculty inventions resulting from federally
funded research. Indeed, Columbia filed a patent application on the Axel co¬
transformation invention, which accounted for the largest share of its licens¬
ing revenues during the post-1981 period, before the passage of Bayh-Dole or
the establishment of a technology transfer office (see Chapter 8 for a more ex¬
tensive discussion of the Axel cotransformation invention and patent). Never¬
theless, fewer than ten patents were issued to Columbia University during
1975-8i-
Columbia changed its policies toward faculty patents and created an ad¬
ministrative apparatus for managing their prosecution and licensing only after
the passage of Bayh-Dole. A new patent policy, which took effect on July 1,1981
(the effective date of Bayh-Dole), stated that Columbia could assert rights to
faculty inventions created within university laboratories or research facilities,
mandated the disclosure of such inventions to the university, and provided for
royalty sharing with the inventor and his or her department. In 1984, this pol¬
icy was published in the university Faculty Ftandbook. In 1989, Columbia’s
policy on reserving rights to the university for faculty inventions was extended
to cover software. Inventions were to be disclosed to Columbia’s technology
transfer office, the Office of Science and Technology Development (OSTD),
which was founded in 1982. OSTD was renamed the “Columbia Innovation
Enterprise” in 1994, and in 2001 its name was changed again, to “Science and
Technology Ventures.”
Figure 6.8 shows the rapid “ramping up” of Columbia invention reports
during the 1980s. Since most academic research programs change only grad¬
ually, the initial surge of invention reports may reflect increased identification
by university administrators (based on a more intensive canvassing of the fac¬
ulty) of potentially valuable inventions derived from research projects already
under way. Almost 75 percent of the 877 invention reports disclosed between
1981 and 1995 are biomedical technologies (that is, biotechnology, medical
devices, pharmaceuticals, and biochemical compounds), and biotechnology
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
8o percent of the revenues of the “top five” inventions during the 1985-95 pe- 111
riod (Table 6.1).11 Moreover, biomedical technologies accounted for most of
the nonsoftware licenses at Columbia between 1983 and 1995 (Figure 6.7).
In assessing the effects of Bayh-Dole on Columbia University, we lack a
compelling counterfactual: what would have happened in the absence of this
federal law, given the other trends operating in university finances and re¬
search after 1980? We believe industrial interest in Columbia's research re¬
sults, especially in the biomedical area, combined with the prospect of large
licensing revenues, would have led Columbia to develop some administrative
machinery for patenting and licensing in the absence of the Bayh-Dole Act.
Indeed, as we noted earlier, Columbia appears to have been moving in that di¬
rection before Bayh-Dole. Nevertheless, the change in federal policy embod¬
ied in Bayh-Dole may well have catalyzed a more dramatic change in policies,
procedures, and rules than would otherwise have occurred.
Another piece of evidence relevant to an assessment of the effects of Bayh-
Dole at Columbia concerns the significant role of software in Columbia’s post-
1980 licensing activities. Virtually all of the software inventions licensed by
Columbia during the 1980s were protected by copyright, a form of intellectual
property never affected by Bayh-Dole, rather than by patents, the focus of this
federal law. Software licensing was a new form of technology marketing that
resulted from the university’s creation of a technology marketing operation
112 and (like biomedical research) from exogenous changes in the academic
research agenda, rather than from the specific policy shifts embodied in Bayh-
Dole. Moreover, although the arguments for Bayh-Dole stressed the impor¬
tance of exclusive licensing in effective technology transfer and commercial¬
ization, many of Columbia’s licensed inventions, including its biggest single
source of revenues, have been licensed widely on a nonexclusive basis.
In addition to comparing the periods before and after Bayh-Dole for two of
these three universities, we compared data on the disclosure, patenting, and
licensing activities of all three universities for the 1986-92 period to assess in-
terinstitutional similarities and differences after the passage of the Bayh-Dole
Act.12 The data in the top panel of Table 6.2 suggest considerable similarity
among these three universities in the characteristics of their invention disclo¬
sures, though a larger share of Stanford University’s disclosures are licensed
and a larger share of Stanford’s invention disclosures yield positive licensing
income than is true of either Columbia or the University of California.13 Re¬
stricting the focus to biomedical inventions does little to change the conclu¬
sions of this comparison among our three universities (the second panel of
Table 6.2).
The comparison of software inventions for the two universities within our
sample (Stanford and Columbia) that have been active licensors of these tech¬
nologies suggests that software licenses rarely involved patented inventions in
the early post-Bayh-Dole period: 100 percent of the software inventions dis¬
closed at Stanford during 1986-90 and 83 percent of Columbia’s software in¬
ventions disclosed during this period that were licensed within six years of dis¬
closure were not patented.
Another issue for consideration in our comparative evaluation of licensing
in the post-Bayh-Dole era at these three universities concerns the share of in¬
ventions that were licensed through “exclusive” contracts, which we define
here as contracts that are globally exclusive or that contain specific field-of-use
or market restrictions. A relatively high percentage of all inventions that are li¬
censed—as high as 90 percent for UC licenses and no less than 58.8 percent
for Stanford licenses of “all technologies” during this period —are licensed on
an exclusive basis under this definition, and these shares are similar for bio¬
medical inventions. Perhaps because of the weaker formal protection for this
technology (during much of this period, the lack of patent protection), soft¬
ware inventions are less frequently licensed on an exclusive basis: 46 percent
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
Institution
oo
oo oo -o
3
OO l/n ^ o
oo rvi o’ Z rvj o
NO o
CN
K
^3
Os H<\qo <! t~^ r-
r\ iri 4 O N Z fA O
NO O
LO
on
co ~o
3
C> < O CO < Tf-
rj- Z fv> Qv Z rvi r—*
vO O'
O
C O; N VO O
^3
Z Z rvj iX CAV LAN
^ C
N ro f-H "=t" r<v Tt-
C S ,o
<U ^
•3 CO
c2
5U <n o o o
£ 6 "t LA i*' OvJ LAN tJ-
_ o rsj r^j VO N OO
S "o
o .£
rr> o ^
oow~*
MD
W o
K co
CQ O
< •2 |
H c E-<
£ *" c
kH ^ o
£
oo : ~o
1 c
<5k) o
"T3 '.£ J3
C C ^
'5 n <D
V
x-v
r—i
ID
"S
v&
K g
O 3
CO
SJ •— o
CO &
C .2 JS Vi
^3 JD
G
C "ca
^3 Oh G >
Oh rc .2 -o
o «
"T3 ^ •- <D n ^
•2 .y CO3
'2
c
c c G
<D <u <D --1 ■
Oh'-
nJ > CJ Oh 42
vg. 03 -g
bjDi^T tuD C -2
3 a w>
,o _G
■s^ +H E e K-
as <y 03 -+-j
O 03 v—✓
I—
o "3 2
<D G <D a
Oh ^
C CO
•—H 3 G <u
G \ '-o
■fr <U <D O
y <D "rj
co
£n W)G3 d£ 2 cd G
s « CD
G <D
c J2 15 co O
*5 •Si 3 O DJ
ID
J= 8
on •—
q 42 42
cyo o a o o CkJO CD G G
£* CO OO CO CD
2 C H-H03
H—•
03
■■§ 5 Q D I Oh Oh
if "-r^r^r
'■a T3 <—I <N fA g LA VO h
c
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
for access to the essential intellectual property (see Chapter 8 for additional
discussion of the role of exclusive licenses in specific cases of university-
industry technology transfer).
The data on the intensity and yield of the technology marketing activities at
the University of California and Stanford suggest that in the first decade after
the passage of the Act, these “incumbent” universities’ technology transfer
efforts intensified moderately and their yield declined. Did these changes in
their patenting and licensing activities reflect a shift in the characteristics of
Stanford and UC research in response to the Bayh-Dole Act? The possible
effects of Bayh-Dole on academic research, especially on the mix of funda¬
mental and more applied research activities within universities, has been the
focus of a growing body of empirical research.
One analysis of this issue by Thursby and Thursby (2002) used nonpara-
metric linear programming techniques to disaggregate the contributions to
growth in university commercial activity between 1994 and 1999 into those at¬
tributable to changes in the nature of academic research and those attributa¬
ble to changes in other factors, including universities’ propensities to file pat¬
ent applications and firms’ propensities to license university inventions. These
authors cannot reject the hypothesis that the content of faculty research
shifted during the 1994-99 period, but their analysis suggests that most of the
recent growth in university patenting and licensing is largely attributable to
other changes, particularly the increased propensity of universities to file for
patents, instead of some shift in academic research toward applied topics.
Another body of empirical work on university patenting and licensing com¬
pares the characteristics of individual researchers who do and do not patent. If
academic patenting has indeed “crowded out” basic research, faculty who are
relatively intensive patenters should have fewer (or fewer significant) publica¬
tions in leading basic research journals. But the limited empirical research on
this issue reveals few such differences between faculty who patent and faculty
who do not. The analysis of fifty-five “star” academic scientists in biotechnol¬
ogy by Zucker, Darby, and Armstrong (1994) found that faculty with patents
were the authors of a significantly larger number of publications that were
cited by other papers (and therefore deemed more scientifically important)
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
118 than faculty who did not patent. Similar results for faculty in nonbiomedical
research are reported byAgrawal and Henderson (2002) in their analysis of pat¬
ents and publications by faculty members in two MIT engineering depart¬
ments. Agrawal and Henderson found no evidence of a negative relationship
between the extent of patenting and publication by the faculty members in
their sample. Indeed, the number of patents obtained by an individual faculty
member was positively related to the quality of his or her publications, as mea¬
sured by the number of times they are cited in subsequent publications. Pre¬
liminary work by Stephan etal. (2002), based on data from a 1995 National Sci¬
ence Foundation survey of doctoral-degree recipients, also finds a positive
relationship between the number of patents and publications by individual
faculty members.
Still other scholars have examined various characteristics of academic pat¬
ents to determine any changes in the content of academic research activities
after the Bayh-Dole Act. The analysis of post-1980 academic patenting by Hen¬
derson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995, 1998a) found that these intensified post-
Bayh-Dole efforts to market faculty inventions were associated with the issue
to U.S. universities of patents that were less “important” and less “general,”
based on the patterns of citations to these patents. Moreover, these scholars
also found that experienced academic licensors’ post-1980 patents declined
somewhat in quality, as measured by the “importance” and “generality” (de¬
fined below) of these patents. As Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995) ar¬
gue, these changes in the characteristics of U.S. universities’ post-1980 patents
“may reflect changing motives within the university research community or
shifts in the focus of university research from basic to more applied work” (p. 1;
see also Foray and Kazancigil, 1999).
Our analysis of this issue in this chapter follows the approach of Hender¬
son, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995, 1998a) and Trajtenberg, Henderson, and
Jaffe (1997) in examining the importance and generality of UC and Stanford
patents before and after Bayh-Dole and comparing these characteristics of
UC, Stanford, and Columbia patents after 1980. Although we examine a sim¬
ilar set of characteristics of these universities’ patents, we employ a slightly dif¬
ferent “control population” of patents (see below). Our “before and after”
analysis of UC and Stanford patents uses the year in which the invention was
first disclosed as the key datum in classifying faculty disclosures and any asso¬
ciated patents as falling into the pre-Bayh-Dole or post-Bayh-Dole eras. We
further categorize patented disclosures by the date of the patent application.
Our data for the University of California and Stanford thus contain: (1) dis¬
closures and patents for which the disclosures and patent application occurred
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
during and after 1970 and the issue of the patent occurred before 1981 (the year
during which the Bayh-Dole Act went into effect); (2) disclosures and patent
applications that occurred during or after 1981 and before 1993; and (3) inven¬
tions disclosed after 1970 and prior to 1981, for which patent applications were
filed during or after 1981 and before 1993.20
We also include Columbia University patents in our analysis of the post-
Bayh-Dole era. Although we define Columbia as an “entrant” academic
patenter, reflecting the fact that this university developed an active patenting
and licensing policy only after 1980, as mentioned earlier, Columbia did
accumulate a modest portfolio of fewer than ten patents during the 1975-80
period.
Henderson and colleagues use patent-citation measures in their analysis of
university patents. When the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office grants a pat¬
ent, the patent examiner includes a list of all previous patents constituting
“prior art.” This list is made public as part of the publication of the patent at
the time it issues. The examiner is aided in compiling this list by the patent
applicant, who is legally bound to provide with the application a list of all
“prior art” of which he or she is aware. Citations of prior patents can thus serve
as an indicator of the technological lineage of new patents, much as biblio¬
graphic citations indicate the intellectual lineage of academic research.
Our analysis of UC, Stanford, and Columbia patents focuses on “forward
citations” to these patents, defined as the number of citations received by each
patent following its issue. Citations to patents typically peak four to five years
after the date of issue of the cited patent. As a result, data on citations to more
recently issued patents will be “right-truncated,” that is, more recent patents
will be underrepresented in the citations data. In order to address this prob¬
lem, our dataset includes only citations to patents that occurred within six
years of the year of issue of the patent, and our sample includes only patents
issued between 1975 and 1992. Our dataset also includes a control sample of
nonacademic patents for each of these three universities, spanning the same
time period and replicating the distribution of the UC, Stanford, and Co¬
lumbia patents among patent classes. We matched one nonuniversity patent
with each university patent, based on the patent class and application date of
the relevant university patent.21 Citations to patents in the control sample also
are restricted to those occurring within six years after the year of issue.
We used the number of citations to a patent during the six years following
its issue as a measure of the importance of the patent, based on the assump¬
tion that citations form an index of the influence over subsequent inventive
activity of the cited patent. The number of observations for our UC, Stanford,
O'
Tt_
r- o -t-
OO N OO
rg
u Tf O' ^
C^)
co
D ir\ O'
-S
.2
Q Zg
•2 r^.
^5 JB3 vO
O
g U
-5o
T3
O u2 jv\ o rw
^3 c
ca r^4 —< O'
C o
tn
cq
K U rr\
t
r<v
N
xj-
ia
5 D
cn
.g*
£
v— .2
vd
w E i 2
__p
CQ O o
< U
H o
2<u "H
>
£c o
cr\
r-
r-
O OJ rv\
K C/5
50
•js
O C^i
rrv LT\
t}-
•£ D O'
rvl
i*
C
o
v*
ii, °° «
v2^
£
=a v §:
£ v/ =a "
R v/ | cx
cx
O' IA CU OJ
"—' Q-rvi ■+- rvj
c®; ••o' C O'
O O'
• 2 ^ 00 _
SS2v/ S.w
^.av
£ “ T3 _ ^ '-O r—H
-*—1™ <L>G O£ O^
“O ^ OO
J3 2
I s.’S H « A\
c£ Q Q
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
NOTES: Standard errors in parentheses. Unequal variances assumed. Asterisks denote significance in difference in means tests (t-statistics) between university and
* *• Vr
* r-s Vr Vr
VO rA 0 VO rA AJ LA O O LA
rA rs| pH vq r-; O Al O aa OO
LA t< O' r4 OO Al’ rA rA rA.
*tf
V-
e
o
O
OJO O O rA VO O Al Al a vo Al o o
ia rA LA tJ- r—( LAN rs)
.S O tJ- O' rA
'O ~5 rA rA LA LA Ml) rA t}- ai Tf
c
w o
J
CQ
<
O LAN ^1“ Tf- O'
Tf- rsj —(
o I I I i
^t- vd
^3
o C
^3
~2 42
^3 # *
* *
§ LA LA rA VO Al LA 00 A O r- r-
vq O' O' rA Al cq O O' c>
£ eg LA* 06 r4 VO vd A A4 Al rA rA. rj-
p > 0.05; * p > 0.10.
•S
£5
# *
,—v «• #
VO so rA 1—1 't- Al rA rA LAS O'
'"—w O LA O' rA Al 0^ A LA —* r-
£ O rA A- LA A LA vd^ A4 A rA rA
c
^3
c
0
Al
O'
"ct
corresponding control group samples:
O'
LA
IA
la <U
> *v
QO ^
_>
•4-J Cn “O A A A. °<3
C
<D
v/
. ,
Cu
ex
Co
C a •
‘
o
A
• _-.
‘5 —•
OO
c
A\
'" d)
03 O' H3 (U
o °° D
k-. o
&jDr-Ho
O' ^
CX„ a — CD _C
C 3 • •* OO
c
o ai «-A\ 33
co
O
-*- 43 A\ nj
A\ ^
*5 2 O'
3-C
CO 03 C £
(L)
c <u ■ ?? c <u rrs
O —
•is'
co
3 c
<D
A\ 1-2
•.5 c — 03 • j2 O ex-2
c°a V/ al D ,—i ^ 03 03 3 a t 3
CX '
CX•
■ ra O
_ .y to oo ^ e o o c o
03
ex •2~g^
e-o. ^2 ab^vE &
■g - V cxai
WO O-
:§ .y -2 oo
rt £ _,
ts cx^LT v 42 42
O .3 00 Sx C TO O' C
U 03 o
S O? O O'
ex S3 ■ i i O' <0 <L) -*-< Ca <l)
c c ^
£ V V/ Q £5 A\ .22 V V/ D £03
V/ s.103 V 1l
Oh Oh
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
greater citation rates for Columbia patents could reflect a less selective ap¬ 123
proach to patenting during the early years of Columbia’s licensing activities,
reflecting its limited experience in patenting in the early years of the Office of
Science and Technology Development.25 We discuss the possible effects of en¬
try following the Bayh-Dole Act by inexperienced institutional patenters on
post-1980 overall academic patent “quality” in Chapter 7.
The results of our tests for the significance of differences between the mean
citation rates of the UC and Stanford biomedical patents and their respective
nonacademic patent control samples indicate that the higher citation rates for
these academic patents are statistically significant (at the 5 percent level) in
the post-1980 period only for the University of California (the higher number
of citations to UC biomedical patents for the “middle period” is weakly signifi¬
cant, at the 10 percent level). The mean number of forward citations for Stan¬
ford nonbiomedical patents significantly exceeds that for their control samples
for all three periods, while the citation frequencies for UC nonbiomedical pat¬
ents are significantly greater (at the 5 percent level) than those in the control
sample only once, for the post-1980 period.26 The results for Columbia during
the post-1980 period indicate no significant differences in citation frequencies
with the patents in the Columbia control sample, but there is no evidence that
these Columbia patents are significantly less heavily cited than those in its
control sample.
These results must be interpreted with considerable caution, in view of the
small number of observations for some time periods. The fact that significant
differences in importance between the university and control sample bio¬
medical patents’ citations are relatively infrequent is interesting in view of the
importance of biomedical patents within the patenting and licensing activities
of Stanford and the University of California before and after Bayh-Dole. But
these data provide no indication of any decline in the importance of these uni¬
versities’ patents, relative to our control samples of nonacademic patents, after
the Bayh-Dole Act. If anything, these data suggest that the UC and Stanford
patents’ relative importance increased, rather than declined, after the Bayh-
Dole Act. Although these results do indicate that the patents applied for dur¬
ing the 1980s by Columbia, a university that did not patent significantly prior
to Bayh-Dole, were less “important,” relative to all nonacademic patents, than
those of Stanford and the University of California during this period, they do
not suggest that Columbia’s patents were significantly less important than
those in its control sample.27
Table 6.6 presents data on the generality of UC, Stanford, and Columbia
patents before and after Bayh-Dole. The more widely cited a patent outside
of its “home” patent class, the greater its generality and, arguably, the more
r—I LTN
^ It
lr\ Tf-
I I I I 't Tt
o o c6 o
NOTES: Standard errors in parentheses. Unequal variances assumed. Asterisks denote significance in difference in means tests (t-statistics) between university and
3
00
-Cl
2 o IA o OO Tf O'
O la ^ h- rA VO rr\ c<\ rf- rj-
o o o o o o o o o o o’ o
is
c
o
O
cuo VO O O' t"- rr\ >—i rvj cr\ \o -OsJ r^J r/>
rrv tJ- vo cr\ \Q tJ- Tt" Tf- rf- -f ~t~ ^
.£
£3 OOOOOO o o o o o o’
c
o
-CL
CO
2
L.
o I I
r-i Cf\
LTN Tt“ I I cf'
rTN
Tt“
O
o o
K
CJ
c
r- .—' h- 0s rw vo N ^ -t h- N
-+-J
l/-\ c-g -rj- T1“ \0 t}~ r<v tJ-
r*> Tf
c2 o o o o o o 666666
£
"o ■— ’t O' N N t O' vO ltn rv\ r^\
tJ- -q- LTN rt- LTN
TABLE 6.6
O
O CO O O O O 0 0*0000
co
c I I LTs r^- I I c^v Tj-
-S o o O O
oo
VO <—I VO LTV Tf
LTN^L^^-VOrJ- Tt- Tf Th
666666
O
responding control group samples: *’s p > 0.05; * p > 0.10.
o
£>
CO N N O VO rA ^ 1" <-• N r^.
rrv rj~ *0 u^n ^~ ^ ^ 't
666666 666666
c
ID
V O'
LTN o
<31 cc °o r^. Q^J
o ^ W coj;
c 43 ^ oo
C O'T) C o& CL O'
<^> <—1 QJ <L> CL
O 03
£A g 2 oo 4-- r-sj S;a\ § A\ A\
0-.QS
■?- C .K C O 3 C -2 c
£\! O 4M OJ C> P O 4- o
OO A\ *XS C3
£ aj OO O'
S.w - <sj 03 <U r—H
^ o
,> ^ .2 to OO
3
£ CL S.2 V •2 ^
CL CL
T3 TO CL^nJ CLOvl
I ^ & sr— V (D O ^ 00
a OO ^ £o
v C30 ^ 03 O 03 O'
O
o
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
where for patent i, k is the index of patent classes and N, the number of differ¬
ent classes to which the citing patents belong. This measure can be computed
for only those patents with at least one citation, and the sample in Table 6.6
accordingly differs slightly from that in Table 6.5. As in our measure of im¬
portance, we restrict forward citations to those occurring during the first six
years following the issue of the patent. Higher values of GENERAL, indicate
that a patent is relevant to subsequent inventive activities in a broader range of
technological fields.
As a measure of “dispersion” of patent citations, GENERAL, is inherently
biased —the more citations a patent receives, the greater the likelihood that
these citations will be spread across a larger number of patent classes. More¬
over, this bias is greater for patents with a small number of citations. There¬
fore, we employ the following correction (Hall, 2002):
g, = ([jtzj)general
where N, is the number of forward citations to patent i during the first six years
following the issue of the patent. All reported results for generality incorporate
this correction for bias.
The data in Table 6.6 indicate that the mean generality measures for over¬
all UC, Stanford, and Columbia patents are higher than those for their re¬
spective control sample patents, with the exception of UC patents applied for
and issued before 1981.28 There is no evidence in Table 6.6 of any decline in
generality, relative to the control sample of nonacademic patents, in the UC
and Stanford patents in the post-Bayh-Dole era. The differences in mean gen¬
erality between the overall UC and Stanford patents and their respective con¬
trol samples are statistically significant (at the 5 percent level) for the post-1981
period. The mean generality score of the post-1981 Columbia patents also is
significantly higher (at the 5 percent level of significance) than the similar
score for the patents in its control sample.
Overall, the results of this analysis of the importance and generality of Stan¬
ford, UC, and Columbia patents yield conclusions that differ from those of
Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995^ x99^a)’ w^° analyzed a larger sample
of U.S. university patents. Importantly, these scholars also found a decline in
the importance and generality of the patents assigned to the universities that
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
126 occupied the top decile of the post-1980 patent distribution (using patents
from 1988), a group that included the University of California and Stanford as
well as other U.S. universities with considerable pre-1980 patenting experi¬
ence. Why do we find little or no evidence of declines in the importance or
generality of these universities’ patents after the Bayh-Dole Act? First, our
sample of university patents is small, although this should limit the statistical
significance of any differences between the university and nonacademic pat¬
ent samples. Another possible explanation for the different results is the use
by Henderson and colleagues of a shorter time series of forward citations than
we use in this analysis. Their results thus may be affected more heavily by
“truncation bias.”29 Our empirical results also ignore the effects of entry by
other universities, other than Columbia, into patenting and licensing after the
passage of the Bayh-Dole Act on the characteristics of the overall U.S. aca¬
demic patent portfolio. Although Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1998a)
acknowledge that entry into patenting by less experienced institutions could
account for their results, they are not able to test for the effects of entry after
1980 by inexperienced universities on overall academic patent quality. We un¬
dertake such a test in the next chapter.
CONCLUSION
The effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on U.S. research universities have received
extensive rhetorical attention but modest empirical analysis. In this chapter,
we have used an invaluable byproduct of the Act, the systematic records of the
faculty inventions, patents, and licenses compiled by three leading U.S. re¬
search universities, in an analysis of some of the Acts effects at these institu¬
tions. Our data on the University of California and Stanford University suggest
that for universities already active in patenting and licensing, Bayh-Dole re¬
sulted in expanded efforts to market academic inventions. The Act also led
Columbia University, along with many other research universities formerly in¬
active in this area, to enter into large-scale patenting and licensing of faculty
inventions.
But several additional factors in addition to Bayh-Dole stimulated the post-
1980 upsurge in patenting and licensing at U.S. research universities, and it is
difficult to separate their effects from those of the Act. These additional factors
were especially influential in biomedical research. In particular, by the mid-
1970s, biomedical technology, especially biotechnology, had increased signifi¬
cantly in importance as a productive field of university research that yielded
research findings of great interest to industry. The feasibility of technology li¬
censing in biotechnology was advanced by the Diamond v. Chakrabarty deci-
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
sion, and broader shifts in U.S. intellectual property rights policy increased 127
the economic value of patents and facilitated patent licensing. The expanded
patenting and licensing activities of a number of U.S. universities during the
1970s provided an important political impetus for the drafting and passage of
the Bayh-Dole Act, as we pointed out in Chapter 5.
An array of developments in research, industry, and policy thus combined
to increase U.S. universities’ activities in technology licensing, and Bayh-
Dole, while important, was not determinative. Even without the Bayh-Dole
Act, the evidence presented in this chapter suggests that U.S. universities
would have increased their patenting and licensing activities during the 1980s
and 1990s. Indeed, our data indicate such growth before Bayh-Dole at the two
universities in our study active in patenting and licensing before its passage. At
Columbia, internal discussions of the feasibility of expanded institutional
patenting of faculty research results were well under way by 1980, and a key
patent application was filed before the passage of Bayh-Dole. The act never¬
theless hastened the entry into patenting and licensing by many universities
(such as Columbia) that had formerly avoided these activities.
By the end of the first decade of Bayh-Dole, these three universities display
remarkable similarities in their patent and licensing portfolios, as illustrated
by the data in Tables 6.1 and 6.2 and Figure 6.7. A very small share of all
patented inventions account for the majority of gross licensing revenues at all
three universities. Moreover, these leading earners are concentrated in the
biomedical area, a technology field characterized by relatively strong patents
that are economically significant (Levin et ah, 1987). A second important area
of licensing at two of these three universities, however, is software, for which
formal patent protection is less important.
Our analysis of the effects of Bayh-Dole on the content of academic re¬
search and the importance of the patents assigned to the University of Cali¬
fornia and Stanford University produced no evidence of significant change in
the characteristics of the academic research disclosures received by these uni¬
versities’ technology licensing oEces. Nor did our analysis of the pre- and post-
Bayh-Dole patents assigned to these two universities reveal any decline in the
importance or generality of these universities’ patents after Bayh-Dole, in con¬
trast to the findings of Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995, 1998a) for a
larger sample of U.S. academic patents. The patents of a major post-1980 en¬
trant,” Columbia University, also are no less important or general than those
within a matched sample of nonacademic patents.
How do we reconcile a finding that citation-based measures of UC and
Stanford patents reveal no decline in importance after Bayh-Dole with our
conclusion that both the University of California’s and Stanford’s technology
PATENTING AND LICENSING AT U.C., STANFORD, AND COLUMBIA
128 licensing operations appear to have experienced a decline in “yield,” that is, a
decline in the share of licenses yielding positive revenues? Fundamentally,
these two sets of indicators measure different characteristics of the invention
and patent portfolios of these universities. Along with other scholars, we in¬
terpret patent citations as measures of the importance of the contribution to
inventive knowledge of a given patent. But this contribution may or may not
be correlated with the willingness of an industrial firm to pay for a license for
this patent. The extent of correlation between licensing revenues and patent
citations remains an important question for future research.
A number of observers have expressed concern that the upsurge of patent¬
ing and licensing has been associated with significant change in the character
of university research toward applied questions and away from basic research.
As we noted in Chapter 3, however, the shift in U.S. universities’ patenting ac¬
tivity toward biomedical research on its face cannot be interpreted as a shift
away from fundamental research — after all, much of the research that gener¬
ated these biomedical patents is fundamental in nature. In addition, the ef¬
fects of any change in university research “culture” and norms wrought by
Bayh-Dole appear to be limited to relatively few units of these research uni¬
versities. Increased post-1980 patenting and licensing activity has affected a
relatively small number of departments and institutes at Columbia University,
the only one of our three universities for which we have data on the depart¬
mental origins of invention disclosures. Were they available, similar data from
Stanford and the UC system would likely support a similar conclusion.
7
The preceding chapters analysis of the effects of the Bayh-Dole Act on the
patenting and licensing activities of the University of California (UC), Stan¬
ford University, and Columbia University found that the “importance” and
“generality” of the post-Bayh-Dole patents of our two universities with consid¬
erable pre-1980 experience in patenting (Stanford University and the Univer¬
sity of California) was stable after the Bayh-Dole Act, a conclusion that con¬
trasts with the results of Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1995,1998a). These
different conclusions from similar analyses of university patenting motivate
this chapters analysis, which examines the effects on overall U.S. university
patenting of expanded patenting by less experienced academic institutions af¬
ter the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act in 1980.
Although Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1998a) suggest that increased
patenting after 1980 by smaller institutions may have been partly responsible
for declines after 1980 in the importance and generality of overall U.S. aca¬
demic patents, they are not able to control explicitly for the effects of expanded
patenting by such institutions after 1980. And one of the most important char¬
acteristics of U.S. university patenting during the 1980s was precisely the en¬
try into these activities of many universities that had been inactive or mini¬
mally active patenters before 1980.
Since Chapter 6 suggests that Bayh-Dole had modest effects on the patent¬
ing activities of two leading “incumbent” institutions, this analysis of the
effects of entry on overall U.S. university patenting enables us to consider
an area in which the effects of Bayh-Dole may be more pronounced. This
chapter also extends our analysis of the importance and generality of the
patents assigned to experienced university patenters before and after 1980
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
demic patents improved relative to nonacademic patents. The second part of 131
this chapter examines such “university learning” in greater detail, seeking to
understand whether and why the importance (based on citations to these pat¬
ents) of the post-1980 patents issuing to less experienced academic patenters
has improved during the 1980s and 1990s.
We find little evidence of strong “learning curve” effects, as neither cumu¬
lative patenting nor the (relatively) early establishment of a technology trans¬
fer office explains these improvements. Links with the Research Corporation
during the pre-Bayh-Dole era also exercise little influence over changes dur¬
ing the 1980s and 1990s in these characteristics of incumbent and entrant in¬
stitutions’ patents. Inasmuch as these observable sources of learning exercise
little influence, we conclude that a broader process of learning, based on
spillovers among universities and the strengthening of professional networks
among university licensing officers, may account for the convergence in im¬
portance between the patents of incumbent and entrant universities.
We first examine the characteristics of all U.S. university patents during 1975—
92 in an analysis of the effects on academic patenting of entry into patenting
activities after 1980 by universities with limited patenting experience. As in
Chapter 6, we use forward citations to U.S. university patents, defined as the
number of citations received by each patent following its issue. We include
only citations to patents that occurred within six years of the year of issue of
the patent and examine patents issued between 1975 and 1992. We also con¬
structed a control group of patents that included one nonacademic patent for
each patent in our academic patent database. Each nonacademic control pat¬
ent was chosen so as to match as closely as possible the corresponding aca¬
demic patents U.S. Patent and Trademark Office technology class (at the
three-digit level) and its date of application.1 Citations to patents in the con¬
trol sample were restricted to those occurring within six years after the year
of issue.
Our academic patent dataset includes all patents assigned to U.S. universi¬
ties other than Stanford, the University of California, and Columbia during
1975-92. Within this dataset, we distinguished among three categories: (1) uni¬
versities with at least ten patents that were applied for after 1970 and issued
during 1975-80 (“high-intensity” incumbents); (2) universities with at least
one but less than ten patents applied for after 1970 that issued during 1975-80
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
132 (“low-intensity” incumbents); and (3) universities with no patents issued dur¬
ing the 1975-80 period and at least one patent issued during 1980-92 that was
applied for after 1980 (“entrants”). Our definitions of “entrant” and “incum¬
bent” universities are intended to separate the effects on patent importance
and generality of increased patenting after Bayh-Dole by active pre-1980
patenters from increased post-1980 patenting by other institutions.
Table 7.1 contains information on the annual number of patents issuing to
these three groups of universities during the 1975-92 period that were applied
for after 1970, demonstrating the shrinking share of the “high-intensity” pre-
1980 academic patenters after the passage of Bayh-Dole. The “high-intensity”
patenters’ share declines from more than 85 percent during 1975-80 to less
than 65 percent by 1992. The “low-intensity” pre-1980 patenters, by contrast,
increase their share of all academic patents from 15 percent in 1981 to almost
30 percent in 1992. And entrants increase their share of overall academic
patenting from zero in 1980 to more than 6 percent by 1992.
Tables 7.2-4 present the results of separate regressions of importance and
generality for the patents assigned to academic institutions in each of these
three categories, covering 1975-91 for the “high-” and “low-intensity” incum¬
bents and 1981-91 for the entrants.2 Negative binomial regression results are
reported for models in which importance is the dependent variable. Our
analysis of generality uses a tobit specification, since the dependent variable
(generality) is truncated at a lower limit of zero and an upper limit of one.3
Each specification is estimated for a dataset covering the patents of the rele¬
vant academic institutions and those in the control sample of nonacademic
patents. We control for year effects and interact a dummy variable denoting
academic patents with a dummy for the application year —the reported coef¬
ficients are those for the interaction terms for 1975-91. We present results for
overall academic patents as well as for biomedical and nonbiomedical patents.
The results for our analysis of each of these three samples of academic pat¬
ents display contrasting patterns of importance and generality.4 The “high-
intensity” incumbents exhibit consistently more important and more general
patents, relative to nonacademic patents, throughout the 1975-91 period than
do the other two groups of universities (Table 7.2). Thirteen of the seventeen
interaction coefficients in column 2 for the overall patent sample associated
with this group of universities are positive and statistically significant at the
5 percent level, indicating that for most of this period (and increasingly so dur¬
ing the 1980s), these institutions’ patents were cited more intensively than
those in the matched industrial sample. As was true in Chapter 6’s analysis of
UC, Stanford, and Columbia patents, the differences in importance between
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
Total
patents 7,564 2,266 434 10,264
NOTES: High-intensity incumbents have 10 or more issued patents applied for prior to 1981 and after 1970;
low-intensity incumbents have fewer than 10 issued patents applied for prior to 1981 and after 1970; and
entrants have no issued patents applied for prior to 1981 and after 1970.
NOTES: Standard errors in parentheses. Year dummies not reported. Sample excludes patents from the
University of California, Stanford, and Columbia. ** p < 0.05 * p < 0.10
TABLE 7.3
Regression Coefficients for Low-Intensity Incumbent X Application Year
Log
Likelihood -10980 -3893 -7056 -3745 -1285 -2436
NOTES: Standard errors in parentheses. Year dummies not reported. Sample excludes patents from the University of
California, Stanford, and Columbia. ** p < 0.05 * p < 0.10
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
136 this group of institutions yield positive and statistically significant (at the
5 percent significance level) year-coefficients for eight of the seventeen years.
Finally, the results for 1981-91 for the entrant population of institutions also in¬
dicate lower levels of importance (only one year interaction is positive and sta¬
tistically significant at the 5 percent level in Table 7.4) and generality (also one
significant interaction coefficient), relative to nonacademic patents, than
those accounted for by the “high-intensity” pre-1981 patenters.
These results broadly corroborate our findings in Chapter 6 concerning the
TABLE 7.4
Regression Coefficients for Entrant University X Application Year
NOTES: Standard errors in parentheses. Year dummies not reported. Sample excludes patents from the
University of California, Stanford, and Columbia. p<o.o5 * pco.io
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
Why might universities with less experience in patenting and licensing tend
to receive patents that are less heavily cited? Conversations with licensing of¬
ficers at several research universities and other field research suggested the
possibility that inexperienced universities adopted an indiscriminate policy
toward patenting as they entered into this activity after passage of the Bayh-
Dole Act. In this view, many entrant universities sought patents for faculty in¬
ventions with little evaluation of the market for licenses for these inventions.
As these entrant institutions encountered rising costs and stagnant licensing
revenues, many of them became more selective in their patenting activities.
Other research showing a correlation between licensing revenues and cita¬
tions for licensed university patents (Sampat and Ziedonis, 2003, and the work
cited therein discuss the links between citations and other measures of the pri¬
vate economic value of patents) suggests that patents that are more heavily
cited are more likely to yield positive licensing revenues.
Accordingly, the analysis in this section tests the possibility that entrant uni¬
versities, possibly motivated by the prospect of higher licensing revenues, grad¬
ually became more selective in their patenting activities, effectively “learning
to patent.” Any such increase in the selectivity of their patenting should be re¬
vealed in shifts in the patent portfolios of entrant universities to include more
heavily cited patents. Our analysis in this section examines post-Bayh-Dole
patents issued to all institutions designated as Research or Doctoral Universi¬
ties in the Carnegie Commission on Higher Educations 1973 and 1993 reports
(Carnegie Commission on Higher Education, 1973, 1993). Specifically, our
dataset includes the 10,881 patents issued to these universities that were ap¬
plied for between 1981 and 1992 and granted before 1994. We compare these
patents to one another and to a matched control sample of patents, con¬
structed as in the previous section.6 Our analysis tests for any narrowing dur¬
ing the 1981-92 period in the gaps in importance between the patents of more
and less experienced pre-1980 academic patenters.
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
Specification
We first compare the number of citations to academic patents with the cita¬
tions to patents in our nonacademic control sample. The count nature of
the dependent variable makes it necessary to utilize a negative binomial spe¬
cification in this and related analyses.8 Our base specification includes
dummy variables for application year cohorts (1981-83, 1984-86, 1987-89,
and 1990-92), university patents applied for in these years (L/N7V8l8?,
UNIVs486, UNIV^, and UNIVgo92), and patent classes. The patent class
dummy variables span the 303 classes in our sample.
The next step in our analysis is a comparison of the importance of aca¬
demic patents with patents in our nonacademic control sample. Next, we test
for differences in average citation rates of entrant universities’ patents with
those issued to incumbent universities and with our nonacademic control pat¬
ents by inserting additional dummy variables denoting patents assigned to
entrant universities in these application-year cohorts (ENT8l8y ENTS4S6,
ENT8?g9, and ENTgoi)2). Finally, to assess whether our various “learning mech¬
anisms” influence the characteristics of patents issued to entrant universities,
we identify three characteristics of entrant universities: (1) the existence of a
contractual relationship with the Research Corporation, (2) above-median lev¬
els of cumulative 1980-86 patenting, and (3) the assignment of at least a single
half-time employee (0.5 FTE) to formal technology transfer activities during
1980-86. We also include a set of dummy variables indicating patents as¬
signed to experienced entrants in each application-year cohort (EXPENT8l8 ,
EXPENT8486, EXPENT8?89, and EXPENT90g2) to compare the number of cita¬
tions to the patents of entrant universities with each of these characteristics
with those of patents assigned to entrants lacking these characteristics. A more
detailed discussion of our econometric specifications is contained in the ap¬
pendix to this chapter.
lable 7.5 reports results of negative binomial regressions for the full sample
of university and control group patents. Table 7.6 reports similar results
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
for biomedical patents only, and Table 7.7 reports results for nonbiomedical 139
patents. In each table, Model 1 represents the base specification, which in¬
cludes application year and class dummies, as well as the UNIV dummy
variables (UNIV8l83~UNIV9092). Model 2 adds the ENT dummy variables,
and Models 3-5 separately add each of the sets of EXPENT dummy
variables. Table 7.8 reports results from Wald tests of entrant university pat¬
ent importance relative to control group patent importance for Model 2 (see
the appendix for the description of these tests). For expositional clarity, we
do not report coefficients for the application year and patent class dummy
variables.
We first compare the importance of patents assigned to incumbent and en¬
trant universities during the early post-Bayh-Dole period (1981-86) and sepa¬
rately examine biomedical and nonbiomedical patents from these universities
during this period. We then analyze changes in the importance of patents is¬
sued to entrant universities during the 1980s and consider sources of learning
that could explain observed improvements.
For entrants
For entrants with above For entrants
who were median with early
Add ENTt active RC patenting in establishment
Variables Base model to base model clients 1981-86 ofTLOs
NOTES: Absolute value ofz-statistics in parentheses. Application year dummy variables and patent class
dummy variables included in all specifications (not reported). Coefficient for UNIVr is fa; coefficient for
ENTr is fa; coefficient for EXPENTt is <t>v (see appendix). * significant at 5% level "“significant at 1% level
applied for during the 1984—86 period. In Table 7.7, entrants’ patents re¬
ceive significantly fewer citations than incumbents’ patents in each of the
two cohorts of patents applied for before 1987 (see below for more discussion
of improvements in the importance of entrants’ patents during the later
1980s).11
The fact that incumbents enjoy a greater “importance advantage” for
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
For entrants
For entrants with above For entrants
who were median with early
Add ENTt active RC patenting in establishment
Variables Base model to base model clients 1981-86 ofTLOs
NOTES: Absolute value of z-statistics in parentheses. Application year dummy variables and patent class
dummy variables included in all specifications (not reported). Coefficient for UNJVT is fo coefficient for
ENTt is &r; coefficient for EXPENTt is cfo- (see appendix). * significant at 5% level ** significant at 1% level
For entrants
For entrants with above For entrants
who were median with early
Add ENTt active RC .patenting in establishment
Variables Base model to base model clients 1981-86 ofTLOs
NOTES: Absolute value of /-statistics in parentheses. Application year dummy variables and patent class
dummy variables included in all specifications (not reported). Coefficient for UNIVT is fa; coefficient for
ENTt is fa; coefficient for EXPENTt is tfa- (see appendix). * significant at 5% level *" significant at 1% level
Our analysis thus far suggests that post-Bayh-Dole entrants into academic
patenting received less important patents, on average, during the 1981-86 pe-
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
riod than did more experienced incumbents. If their lack of institutional ex¬ M3
perience in patenting is responsible for the lower importance of entrant uni¬
versities’ patents, then expanded patenting by these universities could result in
institutional learning that narrowed the differentials between more and less
experienced institutional patenters. Learning by entrants could also improve
the importance of entrants’ patents relative to the control patents. Accord¬
ingly, in this section we test for changes during the 1980s and early 1990s in the
“importance differential” between entrants’ and incumbents’ patents and be¬
tween entrants’ and control-groups’ patents.
Within our overall sample (Table 7.5), the importance of entrants’ patents
was significantly lower than the importance of incumbents’ patents for patents
applied for during 1981-86 (Model 2), but these differentials are statistically
insignificant for patents applied for during 1987-92. Nonbiomedical patents,
where the incumbent-entrant importance differential was most pronounced
during the 1981-86 period, display similar changes in importance (Model 2 of
Table 7.7). These findings suggest that in nonbiomedical fields, where the ini¬
tial post-Bayh-Dole patent importance differences were most significant, en¬
trant institutions narrowed the gap in importance between their patents and
those of incumbent institutions for patents applied for during 1987-92.
We also examined changes in the “importance differentials” between en¬
trant university patents and control group patents and report these results in
Table 7.8. The results in Table 7.8 suggest that entrant-university patents were
not significantly more highly cited than control-group patents during the early
post-Bayh-Dole period (Wald test statistics are not significant for the patents
applied for in either the 1981-83 or 1984-86 period). Wald statistics also
are not significant in separate tests for differences in importance between
TABLE 7.8
NOTES: Coefficient for UNIVT is ft; coefficient for ENTt is ft Chi-square statistics for
Wald tests of (ft + ST = o) in parentheses (see appendix). * significant at 5% level
*4 significant at 1% level
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
144 entrants’ and incumbents’ biomedical patents and for these groups’ nonbio¬
medical patents. But entrant-university patents applied for during 1987-89
and 1990-92 were more highly cited on average than the corresponding con¬
trol group patents for both the overall sample and the nonbiomedical sub¬
sample. Entrant biomedical patents applied for during 1990-92 were also
more highly cited than the corresponding control group patents.
Overall, these data suggest that the “importance” of incumbent-university
and entrant-university patents applied for during the later 1980s and early
1990s converged to a considerable extent. Moreover, this convergence reflects
improvement in the importance of entrants’ patents, rather than declines in
the importance of incumbents’ patents.12 Convergence is most marked for
nonbiomedical technologies, where the differences between the importance
of incumbents' and entrants’ patents applied for during 1981-86 were greatest.
In most of our specifications, the importance of entrants’ patents also im¬
proved relative to that of the nonacademic controls in the later cohorts of pat¬
ents (those applied for after 1986). Taken together, these results suggest that en¬
trant universities do indeed seem to have learned to patent during the 1980s.
146 86 period tended to receive fewer citations, on average, than did other en¬
trants’ patents.
For the full sample, patents issued to more experienced entrants during
1987-89 and 1990-92 received significantly fewer citations than did the pat¬
ents issued to less experienced entrants during these periods (Model 4 of
Table 7.5). Similarly, within the biomedical and nonbiomedical subsamples,
there is no evidence that entrants with higher levels of pre-1987 patenting had
more important patents after 1987, as the “learning curve” hypothesis would
imply. These findings suggest that cumulative experience in patenting does
not account for the improvements in importance of entrants’ patents observed
after the mid-1980s.
Finally, we examined the effects on the importance of entrants’ patents of
the establishment after 1980 of formal TLOs. Using Association of University
Technology Managers (AUTM, 1994) data, we coded EXPENT to equal 1 for
entrant universities that had established a formal TLO (that is, reported allo¬
cating at least one 0.5 FTE to the management of technology transfer, patent¬
ing, and licensing activities) by 1986. The results of our analysis of the effects
of establishing a TLO during 1981- 86 on the importance of entrants’ post-1986
patents are reported in Model 5 in Tables 7.5-7. Table 7.5 suggests that for the
overall sample of patents, early establishment of a TLO did not improve pat¬
ent importance relative to entrants that did not establish TLOs prior to 1987.
The EXPENTg7g9 coefficient is negative and significant in Table 7.5, and the
coefficient for EXPENT9Qg2 is not significant. For biomedical technologies, the
coefficient for EXPENT8y8g is not significant in Table 7.6. For nonbiomedical
technologies, the EXPENT8y89 coefficient is negative and significant, and the
coefficient for EXPENTgog2 is not significant in Table 7.7.
These results suggest that early establishment of a TLO after Bayh-Dole
was not correlated with receiving more important patents during the 1987-92
period. Indeed, the establishment of a TLO during 1980-86 actually is asso¬
ciated with less important patents during the 1987-89 period. Although not
definitive, these findings are consistent with anecdotal evidence that some
universities initially assigned persons with little knowledge or skill in patent
and licensing management to these activities when they established formal
TLOs and that simply bestowing the title of technology licensing officer on an
inexperienced administrator was not sufficient to generate important patents.
In some cases, the establishment of a formal office of technology licensing
may have been an outcome, rather than a cause, of “learning to patent.”
Although we are not able to test for their effects, other forms of organiza¬
tional learning may have enabled entrants to improve the importance of their
patents. Organizations can learn from the experiences of others directly (for
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
example, consulting, personnel transfer, and conferences) and indirectly (for 147
example, monitoring of others and informal discussions with colleagues).
Both of these channels appear to have been important means for entrant uni¬
versities to learn to manage patenting and licensing. For example, Niels
Reimers, founder of Stanford University’s Office of Technology Licensing in
1969, served as a consultant to a number of entrant and incumbent universi¬
ties’ TLOs during the 1980s and disseminated information on procedures that
were successful at Stanford to other institutions.
Anecdotal evidence of personnel transfer among universities suggests an¬
other channel for interinstitutional knowledge diffusion and learning. In the
late 1980s, Columbia University recruited the former director of the technol¬
ogy transfer program at Iowa State University, an institution with a long history
of patenting. The AUTM, founded in the mid-1970s, also appears to have dis¬
seminated information on “best practice” through its conferences and profes¬
sional meetings of university technology transfer personnel.
Entrant universities also learned from informal communication and inter¬
action within the broader community of technology licensing officials during
the 1980s. Following an initial wave of less selective patenting during 1981-85,
Columbia University adopted the practice of patenting only when a probable
licensee could be located, based on guidance from other institutions with
greater experience in patenting.14 Columbia’s adoption of this and other poli¬
cies resulted from informal discussions with directors of other university
TLOs. Similar informal communications and interactions may have con¬
tributed to improvements in the “quality” of entrants’ patents during the 1980s
and early 1990s.
Indeed, from the earliest days of their involvement in patenting and licens¬
ing, U.S. universities have drawn on and learned from the experiences of oth¬
ers in selecting the inventions they sought to patent and in the overall man¬
agement of patenting and licensing activities (Chapter 3; Sampat and Nelson
2002). This trend appears to have continued after Bayh-Dole; Feldman et al.
(2002) suggest that universities have emulated one another in the use of equity
investments as part of their technology transfer strategies during the 1990s.
Seen against these historical and contemporary accounts, it would be surpris¬
ing if universities did not “learn to patent via informal channels, professional
networks, and other mechanisms.
CONCLUSION
where Appt is a dummy variable that equals 1 for all patents with application
year t, UNIV is a dummy variable that equals 1 for all university patents, Class,
is a dummy variable that equals 1 for all patents in patent class c, and at, /3t, and
yt are coefficients. Our reported results aggregate the application year dummy
variables into four groups: t = 8183, t = 8486, t — 8789, and t = 9092 for ap¬
plication years 1981—83,1984—86, 1987—89, and 1990—92, respectively. I he
patent class dummy variables span the 303 classes in our sample.
The conditional mean for the number of citations to the sample of non-
academic control patents in year t = T is:
E(Citations\Control Sample) = E(Citations\AppT = 1, UNIV = 0, Class,)
= exp (aT + 2cycClassc) (2)
Similarly, the conditional mean for the number of citations to university pat¬
ents in year t — T is:
E(Citations\University Sample) = E(Citations\AppT = 1, UNIV= 1, Class,)
— exp (aT + ft T + 2]cycClassc) (3)
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
150 The ratio of equations (2) and (1) is the “proportional difference” between the
number of citations to academic patents and the number of citations to the
control patents in year T, or exp(^T). We test for differences between the num¬
ber of citations to university and control group patents in year T by testing
whether = o. Such a test indicates whether academic patents applied for in
year T received significantly more citations than the corresponding sample of
nonacademic control patents applied for in that year.
To compare the importance of entrant universities’ patents with those
issued to incumbent universities and with our nonacademic control patents,
we insert a dummy variable, ENT, that identifies entrant universities in equa¬
tion (1), making the conditional mean function:
E(Citations\App„ UNIV, ENT, Classc)
f li,[a,App, + p,(App, * UNIV) 1
\ + 8,(Appt * ENT)] + XcTcClassJ
(4)
where ENT equals 1 for all entrant universities and zero for incumbent uni¬
versities and controls, and St is the coefficient for the Appt*ENT interaction
term. Equations (5-7), respectively, calculate the mean number of citations to
patents in the entrant, incumbent, and control patent samples for the applica¬
tion year t = T:
E(Citations\Entrant)
= E(Citations\AppT = 1, UNIV = 1, ENT = 1, Classc)
= exp(o:r + (3T + 8T + 'Z^^lass,)
E(Citations\I ncumbent)
= E(Citations\AppT = 1, UNIV = 1, ENT = 0, Class,)
= exp(ar + (3t + 2c~ycClassc)
E(Citations\Control Sample)
= E{Citations\AppT = 1, UNIV = 0, ENT = 0, Class,)
= exp(ar + Scy ,Classc) ^
Dividing equation (5) by equation (6) yields the proportional difference be¬
tween the number of citations to issued patents applied for by entrants and ci¬
tations to those applied for by incumbents in year t = T, or exp(<5T). Similarly,
the ratio of equations (6) and (7) is the proportional difference in citations
between incumbent and control patents (exp(/?T)), and the ratio of equa¬
tions (5) and (7) is the proportional difference in citations between entrants
and control patents, or exp(/?T + Sr). Testing for the significance of the first two
differences (exp(<ST) and (exp(/?T)) requires a standard Z-test. We use a Wald
test of the linear restriction (3j + <5^ = o to analyze the difference in citation
rates between entrant and control sample patents.
EFFECTS OF ENTRY AND EXPERIENCE ON U.S. UNIVERSITY PATENTING
To assess whether our various “learning mechanisms” influence the char¬ 151
acteristics of patents issued to entrant universities, we constructed three
dummy variables, EXPENT, that each equal r for experienced entrants cor¬
responding to: (1) the existence of a contractual relationship with the Research
Corporation, (2) above-median levels of cumulative 1980-86 patenting, and
(3) the assignment of at least one 0.5 FTE to formal technology transfer
activities during 1980-86. Adding EXPENT and the coefficient <fit to equa¬
tion (4) yields the following conditional mean function:
E(Citations\App„ UNIV, ENT, EXPENT, Classc)
' J,,[a,App, + pt(Appt * UNIV)
exp
+ 8,(App, * ENT)
+ (f),(Appt * EXPENT)]
I
,+ ^cycClcLSSc (8)
Technology Transfer?
154 case, the efforts of established firms to exploit the university invention were
aided by the inventor. In the fifth case, by contrast, the licensees required no
assistance from the inventor.
The heterogeneity within this small sample of cases underscores the need
for caution in generalizations about the nature of the technology transfer
process and the role of formal intellectual property rights in that process.
This heterogeneity also highlights the importance of flexibility in the tech¬
nology management policies and practices of universities — for example, tech¬
niques or policies that are effective in biomedical fields may be less effective
in electronics.
METHODOLOGY
The five cases discussed in this chapter are not random samples of the popula¬
tion of inventions at Columbia or the University of California, reflecting their
origins in separate research projects focusing on different aspects of the uni¬
versity technology transfer process (see Colyvas et al., 2002; Lowe, 2001). These
five case studies are not a representative sample of the full array of technologies
covered by either the patent portfolios or the “invention disclosure portfolios”
of Columbia University and the University of California. Moreover, all of these
five inventions were patented and attracted industrial interest from either es¬
tablished or start-up firms, something that is not true of the majority of inven¬
tions disclosed at either institution. The cases thus overrepresent relatively
“important” inventions, patented inventions, and successful technology trans¬
fer efforts at both universities. Nonetheless, interviews with university licens¬
ing officers and inventors, as well as our previous analysis of university inven¬
tion and patenting data, led us to conclude that these cases provide an accurate
depiction of the university patenting and licensing process.
The three cases from Columbia are drawn from a broader project that over¬
sampled licensed inventions that produced positive licensing revenues (see
Colyvas et ah, 2002). Indeed, two of the three Columbia inventions discussed
in this chapter have produced more licensing revenues than all but a few in¬
ventions licensed by any U.S. university since the passage of the Bayh-Dole
Act. The Columbia sample thus is biased in favor of particularly successful
patented inventions. All of the Columbia inventions also are in the biomed¬
ical field, which, as noted in Chapter 6, accounts for the majority of Colum¬
bia licensing revenues.
The two UC cases focus on inventions licensed by inventor-founded start¬
up firms and are drawn from a sample of inventions that was selected ran¬
domly to match the distribution of all inventor-founded start-ups at the Uni-
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
Cotransformation
Cotransformation is a process that allows for the transfer of genes into mam¬
malian cells. Researchers use the cotransformation process to identify regula¬
tory sequences controlling gene transfer, to define mechanisms of gene ex¬
pression, and to understand gene function. Biotechnology firms also use the
process to produce protein-based drugs. Columbia University s patents on the
cotransformation process and resulting products were based on research by
Richard Axel of Columbia’s College of Physicians and Surgeons and have
been among the most profitable academic inventions during the past two
decades, producing more than $370 million in gross royalties since 1983
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
156 (1996 dollars). The cotransformation patents have been licensed by many
firms and are used to produce an array of important genetically engineered
pharmaceuticals.
Research History
Research on gene transfer techniques dates back to the 1940s, but the field was
revolutionized in the 1970s with the development of recombinant DNA meth¬
ods by researchers at Stanford and the University of California. Using these
methods, researchers could for the first time control precisely which genes
were transferred from one cell to another. Recombinant DNA technology also
allowed researchers to tailor DNA to examine gene expression. Prior to re¬
combinant DNA, little was known about the regulatory sequences controlling
gene expression (Marx, 1980).
Progress in gene transfer research in the 1970s was impeded by the fact that
relatively few cells took up the genes transferred into them by these methods,
making it difficult to pinpoint the transformed cells. A major contribution to
the transfer problem was provided in a series of papers published between 1977
and 1979 by Axel and colleagues that described the “cotransformation process”
for inserting genes into mammalian cells.2 The method involved transferring
a gene of interest together with a marker gene that could be used by re¬
searchers to identify and isolate certain cells as the cells attached to the DNA,
enhancing the efficiency of mammalian gene transfer. The Axel cotransfor¬
mation process was widely viewed as a major advance in gene transfer (Marx,
1980).
ported Axels research, for title to any patents that might be granted and re¬ 157
quested the authority to grant an exclusive license. The NIH granted Colum¬
bia’s petition for title but denied the university authority to negotiate an ex¬
clusive license.
As we noted in Chapter 6, Columbia established the Office of Science and
Technology Development (OSTD) in 1981, and OSTD assumed control of ad¬
ministration of the Axel patent application in 1982. The first of five patents on
cotransformation was issued in 1983, well after the publication of Axel’s papers
describing cotransformation, and Columbia’s patents eventually covered the
process, the production of specific proteins, and the use of specific markers.
Academic researchers and firms had been using Axel’s cotransformation
process in their labs since the publication of his first paper on the topic in 1977
(Fox, 1983). Accordingly, the research community was not pleased when Co¬
lumbia was granted a patent. Harvard University molecular biologist James
Barbosa noted in 1983:
The [cotransformation] patent’s process has been in use all over the academic world
since ’77 . . . It’s been such a boon in getting mammalian cell gene transfer off the
ground that it has almost become a laboratory reagent. . . that the process has been
patented just doesn’t seem right. And as far as policing industry’s use of it, I don’t see
how Columbia will do it. The way a company makes a product is proprietary infor¬
mation. (“Axel Patent Claims Mammalian Cell Transfer,” 1983, p. 5)
158 uncertainty over Columbia’s ability to enforce the patent, these firms opted to
license the cotransformation technology because of the relatively low royalty
rates offered by Columbia, whose licensing officers stated that the university
pursued a relatively low royalty rate “in order to encourage the use of the tech¬
nology” (“Columbia University rDNA Patent Licensing,” 1984, p. 4).4 Another
series of warning letters produced more licensees, and by December 2000
thirty-four firms had licensed the Axel cotransformation technology.
Cotransformation was an embryonic technology, and its use for the produc¬
tion of specific proteins of commercial quantity and quality required addi¬
tional experimentation and research. These development efforts continued af¬
ter the invention was licensed on a nonexclusive basis. Exclusivity was not
necessary to induce firms to commercialize a product based on the university
technology, perhaps because drugs produced with the cotransformation pro¬
cess could themselves be patented.
Another interesting feature of the exploitation of this technology is the lack
of interaction between the inventor and Columbia’s licensees. Each of the li¬
censee firms employed scientists whose training and research experience en¬
abled them to understand and exploit cotransformation based on the descrip¬
tion of the process in Axel’s published papers. As a result, the inventor did not
have to work with licensees to transfer his know-how or to otherwise convey
important tacit information on the characteristics and applications of co¬
transformation. The inventions technical details were sufficiently codified,
the papers by Axel and colleagues communicated enough of these details,
and the “absorptive capacity” of industrial firms (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990)
was sufficiently well developed for industrial researchers to pursue the com¬
mercial development of cotransformation without direct involvement by Axel
or colleagues.
Since 1984, Columbia’s cotransformation licensees have used the process to
produce pharmaceuticals used in the treatment of a wide range of diseases,
some of which have approached blockbuster status. Columbia has earned over
$370 million (1996 dollars) in gross royalties on the cotransformation patents
since 1983, making cotransformation one of the highest-grossing university in¬
ventions in the post Bayh-Dole era.
Summary
Gallium Nitride
i6o from industrial researchers, and much of the technology transfer in this case
flowed from industry to the research university, rather than vice versa.
Research History
Research on GaN first began in the late 1960s in the laboratory of a prominent
researcher at RCAs Princeton labs, Jacques Pankove. Recognizing consider¬
able potential for GaN, major industrial firms such as IBM, Bell Labs, and
Matsushita had initiated research on GaN and related semiconductors by the
early 1970s, and a number of patents issued by the mid-1970s to these corpora¬
tions. By the early 1980s, however, many of these corporate research efforts had
been abandoned because of limitations in the materials that could be used for
substrates, among other technical problems (Kahaner, 1995). Further basic re¬
search on new materials for substrates and new crystal-growing processes was
necessary to develop GaN technology for commercial applications. These
technical hurdles, combined with reductions by several of these industrial
firms in their central corporate research laboratories during the 1980s, reduced
industrial interest in the family of Class III-V semiconductors to which GaN
belonged.
As GaN projects were being dropped elsewhere, two Japanese researchers,
Isamu Akasaki of Matsushita and Shuji Nakamura of Nichia Chemical, con¬
tinued work (independently of one another) on GaN, receiving over fifty U.S.
patents on GaN and related research through July 2002. Akasaki had worked
for a number of years on related research at Matsushitas research labs. After
meeting Pankove at conferences and visiting Pankoves lab, Akasaki launched
a GaN research program at the Matsushita Research Institute, where he was
the head of the Fundamental Research Laboratory and general manager of
the Semiconductor Department. Akasaki continued his work on GaN after
moving to a faculty position at Nagoya University in 1981. Nakamura, who
was employed by Nichia Chemical, a small Japanese maker of phosphors for
cathode-ray tubes and fluorescent lighting, began research on GaN in the
mid-1980s. He initiated his work on GaN at a time when researchers at large
electronics firms and several universities had begun work on zinc selenide-
based semiconductors, which seemed to have considerable potential for blue-
LED applications and were better understood than GaN.
Although zinc selenide materials were similar in structure to GaN and
were believed to be more feasible to produce, researchers in corporate labs
and U.S. universities failed to produce LEDs based on these materials that
could last longer than a few hundred hours, making them impractical for com¬
mercial use. These failures in zinc selenide R&D meant that Akasakis and
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
Nakamuras successes with GaN renewed the interest of several companies 161
and university scientists in GaN by the early 1990s. But Nakamura had a sub¬
stantial technological lead and produced the first modern prototype GaN-
based blue LED in his lab in 1994.7
Figure 8.1 presents data on the assignees for GaN patents granted between
1972 and 1998 in order to depict the relative importance of industrial, aca¬
demic, and independent inventors during this period in the development of
GaN technology. The most interesting finding from the figure is the impor¬
tant role of industrial, rather than academic, researchers as patentees during
the first decade of this technology’s development. Of 14 GaN-related patents
issuing during 1972-82,11 were assigned to corporations, 2 were assigned to in¬
dividual inventors, and only 1 was assigned to an academic institution.8 Dur¬
ing the later 1980s and 1990s, however, this picture changed somewhat; 29
of the 105 GaN patents issued during 1983-98 were assigned to universities.
Industrial patenting remained dominant during 1983-98, but the share of
GaN patents assigned to academic institutions roughly doubled, from 14 per¬
cent to nearly 28 percent. It is hardly surprising that industry dominated GaN
162 patenting throughout the development of this technology, but the timing of
the expansion in academic patenting is surprising. Rather than dominating
the early stages of GaN patenting, patenting by academic researchers appears
to have followed that of industrial researchers. The flow of knowledge and
technology—in this case, at least —appears to have been as much from in¬
dustry to universities as the reverse.
All but three of the GaN-related patents assigned to universities between
1983 and 1994 covered inventions by Akasaki at Nagoya University.9 Two of the
other three university patents were for inventions by Pankove, who had ac¬
cepted a faculty position at the University of Colorado in 1985.10 The flow of
patentable research relevant to GaN into universities from industry during the
1980s thus was facilitated by the movement of Akasaki and Pankove from in¬
dustry to academic positions.11
One industrial assignee for several of the GaN patents issuing in the early
1990s was Cree Research, a firm founded in 1987 that had licensed patents
from North Carolina State University that covered silicon carbide materials
for wafers and electronic devices. Cree Research, which played an important
role in the exploitation of GaN patents developed at UC Santa Barbara
(UCSB) (see below), had begun a research program during the 1990s to im¬
prove crystal growth methods and manufacturing processes that could be ap¬
plied to GaN.
Nakamuras research and prototype attracted the interest of Steven Den-
Baars and Umesh Mishra of UCSB. DenBaars and Mishra began to investi¬
gate GaN applications in lasers and microwave transistors that had been over¬
looked by other researchers. As Mishra recounted during an interview:
When Mishra and DenBaars decided to establish a laboratory at UCSB for 163
the study of GaN and related research, financial gifts from Hughes provided
“seed funding” for the lab, with no formal agreements governing the disposi¬
tion of intellectual property produced by Mishra, DenBaars, or other re¬
searchers. Additional research funding was provided by grants from the Na¬
tional Science Foundation and the Office of Naval Research, as well as from
a Japanese LED manufacturer, Stanley Electric, that eventually took options,
but no licenses, on inventions from the UCSB lab.
The UCSB research facility proved to be quite productive. During the 1995 —
2001 period, Mishra and DenBaars published 223 papers and received twelve
patents on twenty-one invention disclosures based on GaN, GaAs, and related
projects in their laboratories. The dozen patents received by the UCSB re¬
searchers highlight the substantial commercial interest in their results, since
UC licensing officers at that time rarely filed patent applications without
strong signals of commercial interest in the technology, including a willing¬
ness by an industrial optionee or licensee to underwrite the patent prosecu¬
tion costs.
Established firms funded at least a portion of the patent prosecution fees
for several of Mishras and DenBaars’s inventions. In other cases, industrial
firms (including some that had been active in GaN research in the 1970s)
signed “secrecy agreements” with the University of California that allowed
them to conduct technical evaluations of the inventions for which the Uni¬
versity of California had filed patent applications. But the significant indus¬
trial interest in the UCSB research on GaN did not translate into licensing
agreements. In a recent interview, DenBaars (2000) stated that the lack of in¬
terest by established industrial firms in licensing the UCSB GaN patents re¬
flected long-standing R&D practices in the electronics industry: “We were fil¬
ing patents at the university, pretty aggressively at first . . . and the university
was marketing those patents, but our past experience has been with university
patents that large companies generally are not interested in licensing. They’re
interested in doing it themselves.”
In fact, few of Mishras and DenBaars’s inventions were licensed to es¬
tablished firms, although Siemens, Hewlett-Packard, Matsushita, Toshiba,
LumiLEDS (a joint venture between Agilent Technologies and Phillips), and
other large firms all had mounted substantial R&D programs by 2000 to de¬
velop GaN applications. Although twenty-three firms reviewed the UCSB
inventions, only one license (to Cree Research) had been executed as of
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
164 March 2002. Moreover, Cree negotiated its license with UCSB only after it
had acquired a firm founded by Mishra and DenBaars (see below).
Part of the difficulty in marketing these patents was the early stage of de¬
velopment of the inventions. The UCSB patents covered processes that were
small-scale prototypes of those needed for commercial production volumes,
and considerable uncertainty remained about the “scalability” of the manu¬
facturing processes used for their production. The UCSB researchers cited the
importance of personal experience with the technology, rather than formal in¬
tellectual property, as the key source of competitive advantage. As DenBaars
(2000) explained:
Especially in the semiconductor business . . . the basic way big companies get at
your technology, is to get the know-how, and that’s done by hiring your students.
Then [the technology] is in the public domain. The most important thing, at least
in the semiconductor field, is know-how . . . and all of the amassed knowledge dur¬
ing the course of your Ph.D. So, the students are the most important resource we
have. I’d say they’re much more valuable than the patents.
Fred Blum, and hired several graduate students who had worked in the 165
Mishra-DenBaars labs. After initial negotiations with the university, the in¬
ventors’ new firm did not complete an option or license agreement for the
GaN patents that were based on Mishras and DenBaarss research.
Widegap Technologies/Nitres initially relied on funding from established
firms and government grants. Hughes Electronics and General Electric, re¬
spectively, provided matching funds for a Small Business Innovation Research
(SBIR) grant and a National Institute of Standards and Technology’s Advanced
Technology Program (ATP) grant. Widegap/Nitres also received federal re¬
search grants from the Air Force, the Office of Naval Research, the Defense
Advanced Research Projects Agency, the Ballistic Missile Defense Organiza¬
tion, and the U.S. Army.
The uncertainty associated with the embryonic nature of the new firm’s
GaN technology appears to have limited funding for Nitres from venture cap¬
italists or the equity markets. According to Blum (2000):
We didn’t even approach any VC’s [venture capitalists] initially. We raised angel
funding, but that was through my professional relationships with industry execu¬
tives in the Los Angeles area. We didn’t want VC money initially because they want
to see a prototype too soon, and the technology was still too fragile. If they don’t see
a product coming up soon in the process, VC’s get worried and can put unreason¬
able pressure on the company.
UCSB provided a valuable asset for Nitres’s GaN research during the ini¬
tial years by renting university “cleanroom” space to the firm. According to
DenBaars and Mishra, the firm’s financial constraints and the exorbitant costs
of constructing or acquiring a “cleanroom” meant that Nitres would have
been unable to operate without the UCSB research space.
Cree Research acquired Nitres in March 2000, after Nitres had developed
commercial-level prototypes of some of its technology and had completed the
development projects funded by its initial federal grants. By early 2002, Cree
had released several GaN-based products, including green and blue LEDs for
the commercial market, as well as applications for military and telecommu¬
nications. As of mid-2002, however, the University of California had yet to re¬
ceive any royalty payments from Cree on the GaN licenses.
Summary
The GaN case, like that of the Axel cotransformation patents, is one in which
patents per se appear to have been relatively unimportant for university-
industry technology transfer. In both cases, the existence or absence of a
patent on the key inventions did not affect the development by industry of
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
Xalatan
Research History
167
University Patenting and Licensing
Bito had originally planned only to publish his research results and gave little
thought to commercialization. But in the course of submitting a grant renewal
application in 1982, he learned that Columbia’s post-Bayh-Dole patent policy
required him to report his research advances to the university’s technology
transfer office. Following discussions with the OSTD at Columbia, Bito hied
an invention report in 1982 on “[t]he use of eicosanoids and their derivatives
for the treatment of ocular hypertension and glaucoma,” a disclosure based on
the research that he had published in 1977 and 1981. Columbia applied for a
patent on the use of PGs for treatment of ocular hypertension and glaucoma
in 1982, and the patent issued in 1986. Columbia subsequently applied for and
received two other patents on the technology.
Even before the first patent had issued, Columbia began to seek licensees
for the invention. Despite a significant marketing effort by Bito and Colum¬
bia, however, there were no takers, perhaps because of the widespread view
among industry experts that PGs were harmful to the eye. In a recent inter¬
view, Bito recalled that prospective industrial licensees were reluctant to con¬
template the use of PGs in the human eye, arguing, “It’s crazy. You can’t put
prostaglandins in the eye,” and a leading eye expert called Bito’s idea “next to
ridiculous” (quoted in Gerth and Stolberg, 2000). Substantial additional re¬
search was required to determine whether and how the technology could be
useful in humans, and few industrial firms saw significant commercial poten¬
tial in Bito’s research advance.
In 1983, however, the Swedish firm Pharmacia agreed to exclusively license
the technology at the urging of a friend of Bito’s who had developed a cataract
treatment for the firm. Carl Camras, a student and colleague of Bito’s who was
instrumental in developing the invention, later noted that if Lazio Bitos
friend hadn’t done wonders for Pharmacia ... no one would have picked it up”
(“Columbia Innovation Enterprise: A Special Report,” 1996, p. 1). The un¬
certainty surrounding the feasibility and commercial potential of Bito’s treat¬
ment meant that the strong patent protection and exclusive licenses negoti¬
ated with Pharmacia were important in the commercialization of Xalatan.
168 Bito and Pharmacia occurred in the firm’s labs in Uppsala, Sweden, where re¬
searchers worked to understand the operation of PGs in treating glaucoma.
Bito also continued his research at Columbia with funding through a research
agreement between his university and Pharmacia.
By 1991, researchers at both Columbia and Phamacia had developed con¬
siderable confidence in the commercial prospects for the PG-based glaucoma
treatment, and by 1994 Pharmacia began to consider submitting its product to
the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) for clinical testing and ap¬
proval. But the 1995 merger between Pharmacia and Upjohn, a large U.S.
pharmaceuticals firm, slowed the development of this technology. The new
management team did not assign a high priority to the project, and Bito noted
in a later interview that this “was a very stressful process, because after a good
team had brought the product to fruition, the new people in the management
of the merged company lacked familiarity with it” (“Columbia Innovation
Enterprise: A Special Report,” 1996, p. 4).
By this time, a number of other pharmaceutical firms had approached Bito
and Columbia, expressing interest in obtaining a sublicense from Pharmacia
for the development of the PG-based glaucoma treatment for fields of use
other than those being pursued by the Swedish firm. Faced with evidence that
Pharmacia had scaled down its efforts to develop the glaucoma treatment since
its merger with Upjohn, Bito urged Columbia to require Pharmacia to permit
such a sublicense. The university conveyed Bito’s sentiments to Pharmacia
and encouraged the firm to reinvigorate its commercialization efforts. Perhaps
because of this encouragement from its academic licensor, Pharmacia-Upjohn
began to move forward on commercialization of Xalatan, and the product ob¬
tained FDA approval in 1996. Sales of Xalatan grew rapidly following its com¬
mercial introduction and by FY2001 accounted for more than $740 million
(1996 dollars), making Xalatan the worlds top-selling glaucoma medication. In
the last year (2000) for which data on royalties were available, Columbia
earned almost $20 million in gross royalties from Xalatan (1996 dollars).
Summary
The Xalatan case differs from the Axel cotransformation and GaN cases in that
patents appear to have been important to the transfer and commercialization
of this technology. In part, the importance of patents reflected the fact that this
invention resembled the “prototypes” discussed by Jensen and Thursby
(2001) a lengthy and costly period of development was necessary to bring this
invention to market. And the inventor’s know-how and involvement were in¬
dispensable to this development process, in contrast to the cotransformation
patents. But the Xalatan case illustrates another issue in exclusive licensing
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
agreements for university patents that also appears in the soluble CD4 case dis¬ 169
cussed below. Although a firm may be willing to sign an exclusive licensing
agreement with the university (and although most such agreements include
“due diligence” or “best efforts” clauses that commit a licensee to invest in the
development of an invention), it is difficult for any licensor, let alone an aca¬
demic licensor, to ensure that their licensee will undertake the costly process
of technology development in a timely fashion.
The Ames II Tests are an assay based on the Ames Tests that were developed
in the late 1960s and early 1970s by Bruce Ames at UC Berkeley. The original
Ames Tests were bacteria-based assays used to determine whether a test sub¬
stance has mutagenic potential (the potential to cause mutation in cells). Mu¬
tagenic properties serve as simple proxies for the carcinogenic potency of the
tested substance, and the original Ames Tests are widely used in the pharma¬
ceutical, cosmetics, and food industries in basic product-safety testing. The
Ames II Tests were based on research conducted by Pauline Gee and Dorothy
Maron, two researchers in Ames’s laboratory, two decades after the develop¬
ment of the original Ames Tests.
The commercialization of the Ames II Tests provides an interesting con¬
trast with the commercialization of the original Ames Tests, developed before
Bayh-Dole, which were not patented and were published in the scientific jour¬
nals. As a result, firms and research labs were able to implement the Ames
Tests without any licenses. In contrast, the Ames II Tests were published but
also were covered by two patents and required licenses for their adoption. The
research behind the Ames II Tests was published in the Proceedings of the Na¬
tional Academy of Sciences in 1994, one year after the first patent application
was filed in October 1993 (Gee, Maron, and Ames, 1994) and three years be¬
fore the filing of a second patent application on the invention by the Univer¬
sity of California. The commercialization processes for the Ames and Ames II
Tests also differed from one another in that inventor involvement was crucial
to the development of the Ames II Tests, unlike the original Ames Tests. One
of the Ames II Tests’ inventors participated in the foundation of a firm devoted
to commercialization of the tests and played an active role as an adviser to
other firms seeking to apply this technology.
Research History
Bruce Ames publicly announced his original Ames Tests in 1975 and soon rec¬
ognized the importance of his invention for academic and industrial research.
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
170 Although the original Ames Tests were not patented, the assays were available
from the University of California’s E. Salmonella Mutagenicity Test Resource
Center for a small administrative fee.12 According to the Mutagenicity Cen¬
ters website, more than 3,000 industrial and academic labs have used the
Ames Tests, and many firms and labs manufacture their own strains.13 The
standard version of the Ames Tests exposes a test substance, such as a pharma¬
ceutical molecule, cosmetic, or food, to a strain of Salmonella typhimurium
bacteria that has been chemically modified to no longer manufacture an
amino acid, histidine, that is necessary for growth. Once mixed with the sub¬
stance being tested, some of the strains of bacteria will mutate and grow, just
as a nonmodified, or “wild type,” bacteria would. Since only mutated strains
of bacteria are able to manufacture histidine and grow, a count of the fre¬
quency of growing colonies of bacteria within the tested material provides a
rough index of the material’s.mutagenic properties. If the test substance’s in¬
teraction with the bacteria leads to considerable mutation and growth of the
bacteria, the substance may have strong mutagenic properties and could be
harmful to consumers.
The original Ames Tests provided little information on the characteristics
of the mutagenic properties of the tested substance. During the late 1980s,
however. Gee and Maron began work on an enhanced version of the Ames
Tests that utilized bacteria that had been genetically modified to produce spe¬
cific mutations. By 1992, Gee and Maron had developed the Ames II Tests,
which provided additional information on the mutagenic properties of a test
substance by enabling researchers to determine which genes in the test bacte¬
ria were affected after exposure to a new material or substance.
professor Spencer Farr, a former postdoctoral fellow in the Ames laboratory, 171
began discussions with Gee about commercializing her invention. Financed
by two venture capitalists, Farr had founded a firm to develop and commer¬
cialize his own invention, a gene profiling assay, and he recognized consider¬
able commercial potential for the Ames II Tests as a complementary prod¬
uct.14 Farr invited Gee in 1993 to join his fledgling enterprise, Xenometrix, and
Gee left academia to join the firm. Xenometrix licensed two patents related to
her invention from UC.
According to Gee, Xenometrixs licenses for the Ames II Tests patents aided
the firm’s efforts to raise capital, but the inventors knowledge and experience
with the invention were necessary to commercialize the Ames II Tests. As Gee
(2001) recounted: “The value is not just the patent. . . My experience is in¬
tangible, whereas IP is tangible, and we can wrap legal language around the
IP in our agreements. Clearly what you want is both, but the IP’s protection is
necessary in case someone tries to steal our technology.”
The importance of Gee’s knowledge and experience for development of
the Ames II Tests was underscored by the efforts of Xenometrixs European dis¬
tributor, Xenometrix GmbH, to replicate the Ames II Test strains. By the mid-
1990s, Xenometrix GmbH was concerned about maintaining a sufficient sup¬
ply of the bacterial strains and requested that Xenometrix train the distributor’s
scientists on the techniques used to grow the bacteria. The distributor’s labo¬
ratory scientists spent a week at Xenometrixs U.S. headquarters, undergoing
intensive training in the techniques and equipment needed to grow these bac¬
terial strains. But after nearly a year of effort, the distributor’s European scien¬
tists were unable to produce a supply of strains that met the company’s speci¬
fications and could be sold to customers. In response, Gee spent several days
at the distributors European labs and produced roughly two years’ supply of
the bacteria.
By early 2001, the Ames II Tests had achieved limited commercial success.
Xenometrix continued its development efforts, but Farr had departed to start
another firm, Phase One. In early 2001, Discovery Partners International ac¬
quired Xenometrix to expand sales of the firms two main product lines, Farrs
profiling assay and the Ames II Tests. 1 he University of California has earned
almost $130,000 in royalties on its licenses for the Ames II Tests, although a
substantia] portion of the royalty payments (nearly $50,000) has been delayed
or forgiven to ensure sufficient cash flow for Xenometrix to maintain opera¬
tions (all in 1996 dollars).
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
172
Summary
Soluble CD4
Soluble CD4 is a prototype for an AIDS drug that inhibits viral entry and in¬
fection. Since CD4 is a receptor for HIV (the virus that causes AIDS), a syn¬
thetic, soluble CD4 can “mop up” HIV before it invades healthy cells. The
idea of a soluble version of CD4 emerged from university and industrial labo¬
ratories in the mid-1980s, a period during which rapid growth in the number
of AIDS cases in the United States created a strong demand for better AIDS
treatments. Soluble CD4 was widely viewed as a product with considerable
commercial potential. The Boston Globe referred to soluble CD4 as “one of
the hottest —though still preliminary —ideas in AIDS treatment since AZT,
the only AIDS drug so far approved” (Foreman, 1988, p. 41), and Anthony
Fauci, a leading AIDS expert, noted at an NIH meeting: “We are all very in¬
terested in this. It works very well in the test tube, [and] there appears to be an
excellent scientific basis to proceed” (Perlman, 1987, p. Ai). Despite this en¬
thusiasm, as of 2001 no soluble CD4-based AIDS treatment had been ap¬
proved for commercial use.
Research History
HIV virus could be “decoyed” into attaching itself only to cells into which the 173
CD4 receptor had been inserted.
These experimental results were published in 1985 and led Axel and one of
his graduate students, Paul Maddon, to consider the therapeutic benefits of a
soluble form of genetically engineered CD4. Although their discoveries gen¬
erated enthusiasm among scientists and pharmaceutical firms, uncertainty re¬
mained about the feasibility of CD4-based AIDS treatments. First, the effects
of soluble CD4 on the overall human immune system were unknown. A sec¬
ond concern was the possibility that the body would produce antibodies
against the CD4 decoys, provoking an autoimmune reaction. Third, some sci¬
entists were skeptical that CD4 was the only receptor for HIV, since HIV is ca¬
pable of infecting cells in the brain and immature blood cells in the bone mar¬
row that lack CD4 receptors. By the mid-1980s, soluble CD4 treatments had
not been tested in animals, let alone humans, and the invention was little
more than an idea with significant but uncertain commercial potential.
In March 1986, Axel and Maddon submitted two invention disclosures based
on their CD4 research to the OSTD at Columbia. The first disclosure covered
isolation of the gene encoding CD4, and the second disclosure dealt with the
method for producing soluble CD4. The university filed patent applications
on both disclosures in August of that year, and patents issued in 1992. OSTD
began discussions with potential licensees about the CD4 invention in 1987,
and at least six firms expressed interest in licensing the CD4 technologies from
Columbia.
The evolution of Columbia’s licensing strategy for soluble CD4 illustrates
the costs and benefits of exclusive licensing arrangements for early-stage in¬
ventions. Significant additional research was needed to develop a soluble
CD4-based treatment, and any licensee therefore faced considerable risk and
uncertainty about the ultimate commercial feasibility and financial returns
associated with the technology. These high risks, as well as the need for signifi¬
cant additional investments to bring a CD4-based treatment to market, meant
that some form of exclusivity in licensing the CD4 technologies might be nec¬
essary to attract an industrial licensee. But OSTD also faced great uncertainty
about the performance and prospects for commercial success of prospective li¬
censees, especially if any such license was an exclusive one. As a result, OSTD
sought to license several firms and scientific teams that could pursue different
approaches to development of a CD4-based product.
Columbia originally planned to grant a coexclusive license to three firms:
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
174 Biogen, Genentech, and SmithKline Beecham, each of which had been work¬
ing on soluble CD4-based treatments since shortly after Axel’s successful
cloning of the CD4 receptor (Axel had participated in SmithKline Beecham’s
work in this area). But before the final agreements with these three firms were
finalized, Paul Maddon, Axel’s graduate student, founded a firm (Progenies
Pharmaceuticals) to develop a soluble CD4-based treatment and requested
that Columbia add him to the list of coexclusive licensees. Columbia con¬
vinced the other three licensees to modify the draft license agreements, and
Progenies Pharmaceuticals was added to the list of licensees in 1989.
Following the publication by Axel and colleagues of their paper in 1985 con¬
firming that they had cloned the CD4 receptor (Maddon et ah, 1985) and be¬
fore the Columbia license agreements were signed, numerous firms had begun
research on a soluble CD4-based HIV treatment (Foreman, 1988). In De¬
cember 1987, scientists from Genentech published a paper in Science report¬
ing positive results, and scientists from Biogen, SmithKline Beecham, the
Dana Farber Institute, and the Basel Institute of Immunology each published
papers on their respective research on soluble CD4 in Nature later that month.
A contemporary press article observed, “[T]he nearly simultaneous appear¬
ance of five major papers in such a novel area of research is a sign not only
of the intense competition in AIDS research, but also of the tremendous
commercial promise that drugs for AIDS portend”(Foreman, 1988, p. 41). By
the summer of 1988, researchers from several other firms, including Becton-
Dickinson, Genelabs, and Ortho Pharmaceuticals, had published research pa¬
pers on soluble CD4-based treatments.15 In September 1988, seven NIH re¬
searchers reported in Nature that they had developed a poison that, when
combined with CD4, latched on to HIV and killed it; later that year they an¬
nounced plans to license this technology (known as “CD4- PE”) exclusively to
Upjohn Pharmaceuticals (“Licensing Plan for AIDS Drug Draws Fire,” 1988).
By 1989, the first year in which Columbia’s license agreement was in effect,
the race to develop soluble CD4 was well under way and involved numerous
firms and labs other than the Columbia licensees. The presence of several
nonlicensee firms in the race indicates either that the scope of Columbia’s pat¬
ent was narrow and the firms believed that they were not infringing the
Axel/Maddon patents or that the returns to a commercially successful prod¬
uct based on infringement of the patents were so great that industrial devel¬
opers believed that a mutually agreeable and profitable settlement with Co¬
lumbia University could be negotiated in the event of litigation.16
The development activities of these nonlicensee firms also provide evi-
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
dence that licenses for the Columbia/Axel patents were not necessary to sup¬ D5
port development efforts. Nonlicensee firms engaged in research on CD4 ap¬
parently believed that they had other means of appropriating the returns from
their R&D, including patents on any products developed for clinical trials. It
is also noteworthy that only two of the firms in the race to develop soluble
CD4 (SmithKline Beecham and Progenies) enlisted the direct participation
of the university inventors (Axel and Maddon, respectively) in their develop¬
ment efforts. In this case, like that of cotransformation, the university inven¬
tors evidently did not have a monopoly on the tacit knowledge needed to de¬
velop the invention, something that is further corroborated by the large
number of papers on this topic that have been published by scientists in non¬
licensee firms and in other research laboratories.
The enthusiasm surrounding soluble CD4 began to wane by 1990, the year
after Columbia had signed the license agreements for the Axel/Maddon pat¬
ents. Biogens and Genentech’s soluble CD4-based products showed little ef¬
ficacy in Phase I clinical trials, and high development costs, along with pre¬
dictions of high manufacturing costs, led these two firms and SmithKline to
scale back their research on CD4. By 1995, each of these firms’ licenses had
been terminated by Columbia, and only the Columbia start-up licensee, Pro¬
genies, continued efforts to develop a soluble CD4-based treatment.
Before they dropped out of the commercialization race, Biogen, Smith-
Kline, and Genentech had invested substantial funds in research on soluble
CD4, and two of these firms had begun clinical trials. Ultimately, however, no
commercial product was developed under the coexclusive license. In 1995,
Progenies, which by this time was recognized as the leader in soluble CD4-
based treatments, announced plans for clinical trials of its soluble CD4-based
therapy.17 In 1996, the firm renegotiated its license agreement with Columbia,
acquiring exclusive rights for the development of a soluble CD4-based prod¬
uct. In 1996, Progenies disclosed the existence of a second receptor, CC-CKR-
5, for the AIDS virus, a scientific discovery that meant that CD4 was necessary
but not sufficient for HIV to bind to cells. Progenies currently has several drug
candidates based on soluble CD4 and decoy CC-CKR-5 receptors in clinical
trials.
Since the CD4 breakthrough was announced, an alternative approach,
antiretroviral therapy, has been widely adopted for treatment of HIV-infected
individuals. Nevertheless, interest in Progenies’ drug candidates, and in
“entry inhibitors” more generally, remains high.18 As of December 1999, how¬
ever, Columbia had earned less than $10,000 in sales-based royalties (1996 dol¬
lars) from the Axel-Maddon patents, since a CD4-based therapy has yet to be
commercialized.19
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
176 Summary
CONCLUSION
Chapter 5 pointed out that a key premise underpinning the Bayh-Dole Act is
the belief that patenting and licensing are necessary to facilitate the develop¬
ment and commercialization of publicly funded university inventions. Al¬
though the Act does not mandate that universities follow any single specific
policy in patenting and licensing faculty inventions, university administrators
and technology licensing officers frequently assume that the technolog}' trans¬
fer process is essentially similar in different technologies and industries. But
these case studies reveal great heterogeneity within even a small sample of
technologies. There are significant differences among these cases in the role
of intellectual property rights in inducing firms to develop and commercial¬
ize university inventions, in the role of the inventor in postlicense develop¬
ment and commercialization, and in the relationship between academic and
industrial research activities in different technical fields.
Patents and an exclusive license were important to successful commercial¬
ization in one of these five cases (Xalatan), but in at least two cases (cotrans¬
formation and GaN) it seems likely that development and commercialization
would have gone forward without a patent on the university invention. In
these cases, other means of appropriability, such as specialized knowledge or
the prospect of a patent on downstream inventions, were sufficient to induce
firms to invest in development and commercialization. The case of soluble
CD4 also illustrates the difficulties that university licensing officers face in se¬
lecting among prospective licensees when the ultimate commercial prospects
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
of the invention and the commercialization capabilities of the licensees are 177
highly uncertain.20
The cases also reveal considerable differences in the extent of inventor in¬
volvement and the role of the inventor in development and commercializa¬
tion. In at least two cases (soluble CD4 and cotransformation), one or more of
the licensee firms had little or no interaction with the inventor, since firms had
sufficient experience and internal expertise in the field of the invention or had
strong relationships with external scientists with such experience. In these
cases, the knowledge and know-how gap between the university inventor and
a would-be industrial commercializer was relatively small, reflecting previous
investments by the industrial firm in internal capabilities and external moni¬
toring of scientific developments.21 But two other inventions discussed in this
chapter (GaN and Ames II) were developed and commercialized by start-up
firms in which inventors played a central role.
The nature of feedback between industrial and academic research differs
among these cases. Bayh-Dole was implicitly based on an assumption of a “lin¬
ear model” of innovation, in which universities perform basic research with
little concern for application and private firms invest in applied research and
commercialization. In this view, patent-based incentives are essential to link
universities, inventors, and industry in the commercialization process. As we
pointed out in Chapter 2, however, this assumption does not accurately de¬
scribe university-industry interactions, before or after Bayh-Dole, in many
technical fields. Indeed, in most of the cases discussed in this chapter, there
was considerable overlap between the scientific and industrial communities
in the nature of research activities (including publication). Consistent with
the work of Zucker and colleagues on biotechnology (Zucker, Darby, and
Armstrong 1994), in these cases technology transfer from universities to firms
took place via a range of channels, including labor mobility and research col¬
laboration. Moreover, in two cases (GaN and CD4) university research itself
built in part on research that originated in industry. There is also little evi¬
dence of significant delays in the disclosure or publication by academic re¬
searchers of their research advances. All of these inventions were the subject
of published papers, and in a majority of the cases the publications appeared
before patent applications were filed.
The research discussed in Chapter 2 highlights significant differences
among industries in the influence of academic research on industrial innova¬
tion as well as in the channels through which these influences operate. This
research also suggests significant interindustry differences in the importance
of patents as vehicles for knowledge transfer among firms or between univer¬
sities and industry and further reveals significant differences among industries
WHAT HAPPENS IN UNIVERSITY-INDUSTRY TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER?
178 in the importance of patents and licenses as channels for the transfer of knowl¬
edge and technology between universities and industry. These case studies do
suggest, however, that patents may be important for start-up firms in their
search for financing. Consistent with previous studies, the evidence from our
small sample of cases suggests that university patenting and licensing were
more important for the biomedical inventions than for the one electronics in¬
vention we studied. But these cases also reveal considerable heterogeneity in
the technology transfer process among biomedical technologies.
These differences among inventions, industries, and technical fields can be
accommodated by flexibility in universities’ patenting and licensing practices.
University licensing offices have at their disposal a number of contractual ar¬
rangements to facilitate technology transfer, including secrecy agreements,
options, licenses, material transfer agreements, and equity investments. To the
extent that universities choose among these instruments carefully, and with
the objective of facilitating use and commercialization rather than maximiz¬
ing royalty income, patents and licenses can advance the mission of university-
industry technology transfer while maintaining the other important missions
of public and private universities in the United States.
9
Conclusion
true of the post-1980 period. Moreover, many universities chose not to manage 181
patenting and licensing themselves. Chapter 4 discussed the role of the Re¬
search Corporation, founded by Frederick Cottrell, a University of California
faculty inventor who wished to use the licensing revenues from his patents to
support scientific research, in managing university patents and licensing dur¬
ing much of the period between 1935 and 1980. But even in these early de¬
cades of patenting and licensing, biomedical technologies accounted for a dis¬
proportionate share of licensing revenues for the Research Corporation and
other early university licensors, such as the Wisconsin Alumni Research
Foundation.
The decade of the 1970s, as much as or more so than the 1980s, represented
a watershed in the growth of U.S. university patenting and licensing. U.S. uni¬
versities expanded their patenting, especially in biomedical fields, and as¬
sumed a more prominent role in managing their patenting and licensing
activities, supplanting the Research Corporation. Agreements between indi¬
vidual government research funding agencies and universities also con¬
tributed to the expansion of patenting during the 1970s. Private universities
in particular began to expand their patenting and licensing rapidly during this
decade.
Expanded interest by U.S. universities in patenting and licensing academic
inventions and growing concern over U.S. economic competitiveness during
the late 1970s combined to produce the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980, which also was
influenced by a broader federal effort during this period to rationalize and
simplify policy governing the disposition of patent rights resulting from feder¬
ally funded research. As we noted in Chapter 5, the Act did not legalize any¬
thing that previously had been prohibited by federal law or regulation, but it
obviated the need for universities to negotiate agreements with individual
agencies or petition for patent rights on a case-by-case basis and reduced un¬
certainty about the direction of government patent policy. Since the trend
toward increased academic patenting and licensing (including patenting of
government-funded research) predates the passage of Bayh-Dole, the Act’s
most important effect arguably was its provision of a congressional endorse¬
ment of patenting and licensing (including exclusive licensing) as appropriate
activities for universities and public laboratories.1
The Bayh-Dole Act is widely credited (or blamed) for the growth in uni¬
versity patenting since 1980. As we have noted, U.S. university patenting had
begun to grow before the passage of the Act, and the patent propensity of
U.S. universities (patents per dollar of academic R&D spending) grew steadily
throughout the post-1945 period with no sharp break in trend after 1980. The
growth of university patenting during the 1970s and 1980s also was affected by
CONCLUSION
184 fields and techniques of science in areas of interest to their constituents in agri¬
culture, medicine, and industry. In some cases, university patenting has facil¬
itated technology transfer. But in many cases, transfer does not depend on the
possession by universities of intellectual property rights.
volves the disclosure and publication of the details of a given invention and in 185
some circumstances may reveal as much as a technical paper concerning the
details of an invention.
There are two broad areas for concern over the effects of increased patent-
ing by U.S. universities. The first deals with the extension of patenting since
the 1970s to cover artifacts formerly viewed as “science”: ideas, materials, and
techniques that themselves represent important inputs into the scientific re¬
search process. We emphasize that this extension of the realm of patenting is
only partially attributable to the Bayh-Dole Act; it reflects a set of broader
changes in overall U.S. policy toward intellectual property rights. The second
area for concern deals with the policies adopted by university patentholders
toward the licensing of these patents. These policies can affect both the diffu¬
sion and use of important scientific and technological advances funded by
public resources, and they may also pose significant political risks for univer¬
sities of the sort discussed by university administrators in the debates of the
1930s and 1940s. We discuss each of these risks below.
186 in order to protect the patentability of these findings. This survey also found
that 9 percent of respondents had denied other scientists’ requests for access
to their research results. In a follow-up survey by members of this research
team conducted in 2000, 73 percent of respondents working in genetics indi¬
cated that difficulties in obtaining access to data or materials had slowed sci¬
entific progress in this field (Campbell et al., 2002).
The study by Campbell et al. (2002) highlights another potential effect of
academic patenting and licensing —greater restrictions on access by re¬
searchers to inputs for scientific research. If scientific research relies on access
to many patented technologies held by different owners, that is, where there
are numerous potential claimants to particular lines of product development
or research, the transaction costs of obtaining access to these rights may slow
research (Heller and Eisenberg, 1998). One indicator of these increased trans¬
actions costs is the growing reliance by universities and industry on formal li¬
censing contracts and material transfer agreements for the sharing of research
materials (for example, Eisenberg, 2001; Rai and Eisenberg, 2003).2
In these cases, the research outputs are important inputs to a flow of future
research as well as useful inputs for those who are trying to solve practical
problems. Accordingly, the economic benefits from such research advances
are likely to be greater if they can be available to all those working to advance
knowledge and practice in the area. Will such liberal dissemination eliminate
any incentives for researchers to pursue such research, by reducing the ability
of researchers to control or to profit from the use of their findings? We think
not, since the primary reward mechanism for most publicly funded academic
research is based on publication and priority of discovery (Dasgupta and
David, 1994).
Several changes in the U.S. patent system, rather than in the Bayh-Dole
Act, might reduce impediments to scientific research resulting from increased
university patenting. First, the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office could adopt
a more skeptical policy toward patents on discoveries that largely cover natu¬
ral phenomena, for example, by requiring that the applicant make a strong
case that the subject matter of the patent application or patent is “artificial.”
Although these distinctions are difficult to articulate at a general level and
even more difficult to apply on a case-by-case basis, we believe that a more re¬
strictive policy on such patents could reduce any erosion of the “scientific
commons.”
Second, a stricter interpretation of the meaning of “utility” or usefulness
might limit patenting of inputs to science. This issue is particularly important
for patent applications that argue that the research result in question can be
employed to achieve something obviously useful —a case for usefulness once
CONCLUSION
removed. But the problem here is that the patented “invention” then is useful 187
mainly as an input for future research and represents generic knowledge or
technology that is most useful if kept in the public domain. A stricter inter¬
pretation here would require a more compelling demonstration of significant
progress toward a particular practical solution than appears to be employed at
present.
Third, patent applicants often make claims in their applications that are far
broader than any results they actually have achieved. There are obvious ad¬
vantages to the patentee of being able to control a wide range of possible sub¬
stitutes to what has actually been achieved, but there are also advantages to so¬
ciety as a whole from limiting any obstruction of a field of technological
innovation that may result from broad claims.
More extensive patenting by researchers from industry and academia alike
of inputs to science, as well as the greater efforts of universities to support
patenting and licensing of at least some research discoveries that previously
would have been disseminated through publication, is creating a more com¬
plex landscape of intellectual property rights for scientific research. Indeed,
the risks that academic researchers may knowingly or unknowingly infringe
patents in the course of their fundamental research cannot be dismissed. His¬
torically, academic researchers have been protected from exposure to in¬
fringement litigation or damages by the “research exemption.” There is a long
history of statements by judges that use of a patented invention or advance in
pure research is not a violation of a patent. University researchers and admin¬
istrators have relied on a de facto research exemption in opposing efforts by
patentholders to threaten university researchers with infringement lawsuits,
and U.S. industry historically has granted university researchers a de facto re¬
search exemption in many areas.
The research exemption has never been embodied in law, and the fact that
much of U.S. university research is focused on practical objectives as well as
on the goal of advancing basic understanding, has long complicated univer¬
sity administrators’ arguments for a research exemption. But U.S. universities’
recent efforts to seek patents and licensing agreements for research findings
that previously were placed in the public domain also have changed the situ¬
ation and may increase the reluctance of industry executives to maintain such
a policy. In some fields, such as research materials and tools, university and in¬
dustrial researchers now are competitors as much or more so than collabora¬
tors, and industry researchers are often required to obtain licenses to use
patented university research results. Facing such demands from universities,
industrial research managers see no reason why they should not make similar
demands on universities (Eisenberg, 2001). Many of the obstacles to a research
CONCLUSION
188 exemption thus reflect the changes that have transformed universities from re¬
search collaborators to commercial competitors in some fields. As we note be¬
low, this shift in perceptions of the role of universities reflects their behavior
with respect to licensing and litigation for the patents in their portfolios, rather
than academic patenting per se.
An additional blow to the research exemption came from the 2002 decision
of the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit in Madey v. Duke, which es¬
sentially denied the existence or validity of an academic “exemption” from
patent infringement suits. The decision also hints at some change in the per¬
ception of university research by at least some members of the federal judici¬
ary in response to the increased patenting and licensing activities of U.S. uni¬
versities. Ruling on an infringement suit filed by an academic researcher
against Duke University, the court argued that basic and applied research was
part of the “central business” of a university. Since universities benefited fi¬
nancially and otherwise from their research activities, the court argued, it was
reasonable under the law for a patentholder to require that the university take
out a license before using patented material in research.
The Madey v. Duke decision has great potential to impede the progress of
academic research in fields in which patenting has grown in frequency and
has increasingly covered inputs to research.3 If this decision is not overturned
by the U.S. Supreme Court, legislation will be necessary to restore this ex¬
emption. As of mid-2003, however, neither a judicial reversal nor a legislative
solution seems likely. Indeed, if Congress views universities as entities that
profit from their research, both publicly and privately funded, the prospects
for a legislative research exemption could be quite dim. Dreyfuss (2003) pro¬
poses granting a research exemption to university researchers who agree not to
patent research results that rely on patented material. But the Dreyfuss pro¬
posal would require many universities to revise their policies toward patenting
and licensing the results of academic research.
Another solution to the potential problems created by the patenting of sci¬
entific research tools has been proposed by Rai and Eisenberg (2001), who sug¬
gest that the Bayh-Dole Act be amended to strengthen federal agencies’ dis¬
cretion and ability to limit the patenting or restrictive licensing of critically
important scientific discoveries. As the authors note, the National Institutes of
Health (NIH) has on several occasions relied on exhortation to limit re¬
searchers’ patenting of large strands of primary human genomic DNA, and the
NIH has limited the restrictive licensing agreements for embryonic primate
stem cells. Using amendments to the Bayh-Dole Act to create a more trans¬
parent mechanism for such intra-agency deliberations, including advice from
a board of distinguished industry and academic scientific researchers for each
CONCLUSION
agency, could improve the accountability and predictability of this process, 189
while strengthening the legal basis for something that is presently an ad hoc
procedure. But this proposal also may require considerable change in univer¬
sity licensing policies. Indeed, many universities might well oppose any pro¬
posal granting greater authority to federal research funding agencies to con¬
strain their freedom in the field of licensing.
As we note in our discussion of licensing policies, U.S. universities may
well encounter greater political or judicial hostility if they do not through their
actions (as opposed to their rhetoric) recognize that as public institutions
whose research is largely funded by the public, they have a responsibility for
encouraging their research results to be used as widely as possible. The issues
of “research freedom,” universities’ political standing, and licensing policies
are intertwined, and no politically feasible solution to these problems can fail
to address all of them.
CHAPTER 2
industry-funded and -performed basic research is likely not to be sustained through the
195
economic downturn of 2000—2001, although no reliable current data are available as of
this writing.
13. The best known of these was the GI Bill, which provided substantial financial
support to all veterans who enrolled in college-level educational programs; others in¬
clude graduate fellowships supported by NSF and AEC funds, training fellowships
from the National Institutes of Health, and the National Defense Education Act
fellowships.
14. See National Research Council (1982); Okimoto and Saxonhouse (1987). Sharp
(1989) argues that the less prominent role played in scientific research by European
universities has contributed to the slower growth of small biotechnology firms: “A re¬
searcher at a CNRS laboratory in France, or at a Max Planck Institute laboratory in
Germany, is the full time employee of that institution. As such his/her prime respon¬
sibility is to public, not private science. Moreover, as a full time employee, he/she will
not find it easy to undertake the ‘mix’ of research frequently undertaken by an Ameri¬
can professor, who combines an academic post with consultancy in the private sector.
Indeed the tradition of funding US academic posts for only nine months of the year,
expecting the academic who wishes to carry out research in the summer to raise re¬
search funds to meet the remaining three months of salary, explicitly encourages the
entrepreneurial academic. In stark contrast, his/her German opposite number at a
Max Planck Institute will find all research costs, including staff and equipment, met as
part of institutional overheads. The opportunity cost of leaving such a research envi¬
ronment for the insecurity of the small firm is all the greater since, once off the aca¬
demic ladder in West Germany, it is more difficult to climb back on again. The same
goes for the opposite number in France, and with the additional disincentive that
French researchers are civil servants and dropping out of the system means both losing
security of tenure/accumulated benefits and difficulty in re-entry should the need
arise. In the circumstances, it is not perhaps so surprising that few spin-offs from pub¬
lic sector research arise, nor, for that matter, that in Europe most such spin-offs are to
be found in the UK, where the organisation of academic science most closely matches
that of the US. In the UK, it is notable that—with the exception of Celltech and the
Agricultural Genetics Company (AGC) —most of the spin-offs from biotechnology
have come from the universities” (pp. 12-13).
15. One might instead argue that the weakening of university-industry research link¬
ages during a significant portion of the postwar period was the real departure from his¬
torical trends. Hounshell and Smith (1988) cite a 1945 memo from Elmer Bolton, di¬
rector of what was to become the Du Pont Company’s central research laboratory, that
made a case for greater self-reliance by the firm in its basic research: “Three things were
necessary: Du Pont had to strengthen its research organizations and house them in
modern research facilities; the company’s existing processes had to be improved and
new processes and products developed; and fundamental research, which will serve as
a background for new advances in applied chemistry, should be expanded not only in
the Chemical Department but should [also] be increased in our industrial research
laboratories and the Engineering Department.’ Bolton stressed that it was no longer
‘possible to rely to the same extent as in the past upon university research to supply this
NOTES TO CHAPTER 3
196 background so that in future years it will be necessary for the Company to provide this
knowledge to a far greater extent through its own efforts.’ To ‘retain its leadership’ Du
Pont had ‘to undertake on a much broader scale fundamental research in order to pro¬
vide more knowledge to serve as a basis for applied research’” (p. 355). Swann (1988,
pp. 170-81) also argues that research links between U.S. universities and the pharma¬
ceuticals industry weakened significantly in the immediate aftermath of World War II,
in part as a result of vastly increased federal funding for academic research in the
health sciences.
16. As we noted, the survey by Cohen, Nelson, and Walsh (2002) included queries
about the importance of different channels for access to research within universities
and government laboratories, issues not covered in the Yale survey. These differences
between the surveys may produce some differences in responses to the Yale and
Carnegie-Mellon surveys, although this issue merits further analysis.
chapter 3
1. McKusick (1948) suggests that “at the beginning of the Depression decade . . .
[t]wo different factors had turned university attention to the patent problem: first, a
steady growth of research sponsored cooperatively by industry demanded a generally
applicable policy toward resulting patents, and, secondly, spectacular inventions on
university campuses demanded immediate concern with patent policy” (p. 212). He ar¬
gues in addition that the frequency of such “spectacular inventions” increased dra¬
matically over the 1930s. Sevringhaus (1932), Gregg (1933), Henderson (1933), and Gray
(1936) all provide contemporary accounts of these debates.
2. The report, titled The Protection by Patents of Scientific Discoveries, deals
with patents on “scientific discoveries” generally, not just discoveries made in uni¬
versities. But most of the discussion is concerned with patenting by universities and
other nonprofit institutions, as opposed to patenting by scientists working in firms
or independently.
3. The committee's cautious language indicates an awareness that, in some in¬
stances, commercial development could proceed apace without patent protection, a
distinction that was largely ignored in the debates that led to the passage of Bayh-Dole.
See Eisenberg (1996) and Chapter 5 for further discussion.
4. The committee quoted Hoskins and Wiles (1921), who argued that “there is at
large a type of engineer commonly called a ‘patent pirate,’ who thrives by monopoliz¬
ing the practical applications of the abstract discoveries of others. The patent pirate is
a menace to industry and a parasite on the community. Nothing would so hamper his
activities as to have the real discoverer take out broad patents in every case” (p. 691).
5. The committee’s report quoted Sevringhaus (1932, pp. 233-34): “The public is
thereby protected against certain ruinous types of exploitation. Assurance can be
gained that technical processes are used in dependable ways. Even the publicity may
be kept on a satisfactorily high plane.”
6. Specifically, the report discussed concerns “that patenting will involve scientists
in commercial pursuits and leave little them little time for research” (p. 9), “that
NOTES TO CHAPTER 3
patenting leads to secrecy” (p. 11), “that a patent policy will lead to a debasement of re¬ 197
search” (p. 11), and “that the policy of obtaining patents will lead to ill feeling and per¬
sonal jealousies among investigators” (p. 13).
7. The AAAS committee s report characterized the following argument by Zinsser
(1927) as typical: “The invention of an improvement in the mechanism of automobiles,
or of a shoe-buckle, concerns matters of convenience or luxury, and can be dispensed
with easily by those who are forced to do without them. The relief of the sick and the
prevention of unnecessary sorrow by the maintenance of individual and public health
are matters in a different category. As soon as we are in possession of the knowledge of
principles or methods which can contribute to these purposes their free utilization be¬
comes a public necessity; and any procedure which inhibits their most rapid and ef¬
fective application to the needs of the community would seem to us as unjustified as
the cornering of the wheat market or the patenting of the process of making bread”
(p. 154). The widespread reluctance to patent biomedical discoveries is especially par¬
adoxical in view of the fact that biomedical patents proved to be one of the leading
sources of licensing revenues for U.S. universities before and after the Bayh-Dole Act.
8. Citing the example of Frederick Banting and Charles Best of the University of
Toronto, inventors of insulin-production techniques who patented their discovery,
Steenbock noted that they sought patent protection for their inventions to ensure that
“the public is protected against the manufacture of poor preparations and is also pro¬
tected against the extortionate charges” and to “avoid the possibilities of misusing their
discovery which not only would have retarded the further development and use of this
product, but would also have resulted in causing untold suffering among diabetic pa¬
tients” (cited in Apple, 1996, p. 36). Apple (1989) argues that Steenbock also wished to
patent his invention in order to prevent margarine producers from acquiring the pro¬
cess, thus protecting the regions dairy interests (WARF was sued by the federal gov¬
ernment in 1943 over ^ refusal to license margarine producers). Blumenthal, Epstein,
and Maxwell (1986) conjecture that Steenbock was motivated by the experiences of his
colleague Dr. Stephan Babcock, who had developed a method for determining the but-
terfat content of milk (see Chapter 2) and, as was then standard practice, did not file for
patent protection on the invention. But the absence of a patent meant that Babcock
could not prevent low-quality producers from flooding the market with “Babcock
testers,” eventually discrediting the method altogether.
9. Spencer (1939) reports that by 1936, the Steenbock patents had earned more than
$6.7 million (in 1996 dollars) for WARF.
10. “During the last decade, the number of universities which have adopted well de¬
fined policies in regard to inventions made by their employees, or with the aid of uni¬
versity equipment, has steadily increased. Additionally, there are today many other uni¬
versities actively considering the adoption of a ‘Patent Policy’ and it is likely that
another ten years will see such a policy in every school in the country that offers scien¬
tific or engineering courses” (Spencer, 1939, p. 1).
11. Of these 85 policies, 3 were adopted prior to 1930; 6 between 1931 and 1935; 12 be¬
tween 1936 and 1940; 19 between 1941 and 1945; 25 between 1946 and 1950; and 20 be¬
tween 1951 and 1955.
12. Columbia’s policy thus stated that “it is recognized, however, that there may be
NOTES TO CHAPTER 3
198 exceptional circumstances where the taking out of a patent will be advisable in order
to protect the public. These cases must be brought to [the university administration]
for its consideration and approval” (cited in Palmer, 1962, p. 175).
13. The Research Corporations actions reflected its declining financial viability, as
revenues lagged behind operating costs. As we note in Chapter 4, the corporation’s ac¬
tivities in this area appear to have contributed to its eventual demise.
14. Entry is defined as the first year during which AUTM member institutions re¬
ported devoting at least one 0.5 FTE to officially designated “technology transfer” ac¬
tivities (see Chapter 7 for further discussion of this measure).
15. The population of university assignees includes the uilion of all assignees desig¬
nated as “universities” in the Case Western—NBER U.S. Patents database (see Hall,
Jaffe, and Tratjenberg, 2001) and all institutions designated as Research or Doctoral
Universities in the Carnegie Commissions 1973 report. To collect patents assigned to
these universities, we searched the U.S. Patent and Trademark Offices annual reports
for patents assigned to these institutions from 1920 to 1965 (there were none in 1920,
other than patents assigned to the Research Corporation), the DIALOG Corporations
Patents/CLAIMS database for patents from 1963 to 1980, and the Case Western-
NBER database for patents from 1975 to 1980. Searches of multiple sources for the
1963-65 and the 1975-80 periods produced similar results. Unless otherwise specified,
“university patents” refers to this entire sample of patents.
16. It is noteworthy that the increase in university patenting over the 1970s occurred
while overall U.S. patenting was decreasing. Indeed, U.S. universities’ share of domes¬
tically assigned U.S. patents grew from 0.2 percent in 1963 to 0.7 percent in 1979, be¬
fore the passage of the Bayh-Dole Act.
17. Data on total academic R&D were obtained from National Science Board
(2000), Appendix Table 4-4.
18. As we discussed above, two Ivy League institutions—Princeton and Colum¬
bia-signed IAAs with the Research Corporation by 1940. Some patents emanating
from these universities between 1940 and 1945 may have been assigned to the Research
Corporation.
19. Data in Fishman (1996) suggest that MIT generated more patents than any other
private university in 1940 and 1945, although under its IAA the patents were assigned to
the Research Corporation rather than to MIT.
20. Stanford signed an IAA with the Research Corporation in the early 1950s.
21. These calculations exclude Research Corporation patents.
22. To collect patents for these institutions, we classified multicampus universities
by the maximum ranking of any campus in the system, a procedure that is necessary
because patents are typically assigned at the university, not the campus, level. This pro¬
cedure yielded 89 unique Research Universities (49 RUis and 40 RU2S) and 73 Doc¬
toral Universities. Within these groups, 79 of the Research Universities (all 49 of the
RUis, 30 of the RU2S) and 40 of the Doctoral Universities had at least one patent dur¬
ing the 1948-80 period.
23. The basic trends discussed below for “incumbent” and “entrant” university
patenters are not affected by using different threshold values for the number of patents
in defining these groups.
24. Of the 40 universities that had IPAs during the 1970s, 23 had an IPA only with
NOTES TO CHAPTER 4
chapter 4
1. Since Cottrell was a member of this committee, the similarity in views is not
surprising.
2. In a 1911 speech before the American Chemical Society, Cottrell argued that
without an entity charged with advertising, licensing, and developing academic in¬
ventions, such inventions might well fail to find any commercial applications: “[A] cer¬
tain amount of intellectual by-products are going to waste at present in our colleges and
technical laboratories all over the country. There is a great deal of work that is being
developed to a practical or semi-practical standpoint that dies right there because the
men ... do not want to dip into the business side of technology and go out into practi¬
cal fields and the work has not come to the point of economic usefulness that is de¬
sired” (quoted in Cameron, 1993, p. 166).
3. After 1912, Cottrell was no longer active as an inventor in the precipitation field.
Beginning in 1911, he served as chief physical chemist at the U.S. Bureau of Mines, ris¬
ing to become director of the bureau. He subsequently was director of the Fixed Ni¬
trogen Research Laboratory of the U.S. Department of Agriculture during the 1922-27
period, where he oversaw the successful reverse engineering of the Haber-Bosch pro¬
cess that underpinned the synthetic ammonia industry (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1998).
In 1935, Cottrell founded Research Associates to conduct research in other fields, but
this endeavor collapsed in 1938. Cottrell devoted the last decade of his life to research
on nitrogen fixation (Cameron, 1993).
4. From the “Correspondence A-Z: 1918” folder in the Research Corporation col¬
lection at the Smithsonian Institution Archives.
5. The corporation acted “as the intermediary between the inventor and the manu¬
facturer, which can subject alleged discoveries inventions to practical tests and render
a judicial opinion to the manufacturer which can be regarded as trustworthy” (New
York Sun, July 24,1917).
6. Nonetheless, the 1950 Annual Report noted that “although there was always the
expectation that another precipitation business might evolve from these projects, none
did so, and from a financial point of view at least, the operations were distinctly un¬
successful” (p. 39).
7. A 1922 report by a Committee of the Association of Land Grant Colleges on pat¬
ent policies at Engineering Experiment Stations noted that educational and research
institutions are not in a position to do commercial business, such as would be involved
in owning patents, to defend the patent owned, or even to negotiate successfully for the
disposal of rights under patents. Unbusinesslike methods in handling patents by edu¬
cational institutions would hinder rather than promote discoveries or inventions. It will
be necessary to have some outside organization handle the details with reference to the
NOTES TO CHAPTER 4
200 disposition of the patents. The Research Corporation of New York has organized to
handle the patents of those who are not in a position to exploit them” (Committee on
Uniform Patent Policies in Land Grant and Engineering Experiment Stations, 1922,
P- 234)-
8. A September 3, 1937, letter from the Research Corporations president, Howard
Poillon, to the president of MIT, Karl Compton, notes that “our important precipita¬
tion patents are expiring, and we are trying to develop new activities of such type that
will permit us to use all of our staff, when, due to competition, our precipitation busi¬
ness will be decreased” (MIT Archives, “Research Corporation” AC125, Folder 57-12).
9. This section is based on the discussions in Fishman (1996) and Etzkowitz (1994).
10. MIT Patent Committee Statement of Patent Procedure. MIT Archives, AC64,
Box 1.
11. On the advice of Karl Compton, the Research Corporation opted not to handle
patents resulting from National Defense Research Council (NDRC) and OSRD re¬
search. The first reason was fear of litigation: since much of the federal research effort
during World War II funded parallel research efforts in specific technology fields by
several research organizations, Compton predicted that “these particular fields will be
the subject of some exceedingly active patent litigation after the war in order to un¬
tangle the various claims for priority.” Second, because so much of MIT’s wartime re¬
search centered around large Institute laboratories that were staffed by scientists and
engineers from all over the world, at the end of the war “many of the inventors will scat¬
ter over the world and not be readily able to advise in case of Patent Office actions or
other cases when their services are essential. In such cases the Corporation would be
called on to employ others who may be expert in the subject, which will be both costly
and time consuming” (MIT Archives, “Research Corporation” AC125, Folder 57-10).
This latter concern anticipates some of the problems with centralized patent manage¬
ment that we discuss below.
The Research Corporations reduced activities during wartime also reflected the
fact that many of its staff members took leaves to aid in the war effort. An especially se¬
rious loss was the departure of the head of the Boston office, Carroll Wilson, who went
to work at the Office of Scientific Research and Development as Vannevar Bush s chief
of staff.
12. On the other hand, the Research Corporation-MIT relationship had not
yielded significant returns to MIT either by this time. See Fishman (1996).
13. “Its further, and even larger responsibility, was to extend and expand this phase
of the Corporations activities, to further develop the concept of handling the patent
problems of educational institutions, and to do so in a manner that would add funds
available to the Corporation for its program of grants-in-aid, that is, operate at a profit”
(1951 Annual Report, p. 40).
14. Similar concerns led several other Research Corporation client universities to
administer their nonbiomedical patents in-house, rather than submit them to the cor¬
poration, during the 1950s.
15. From its commercial introduction in the mid-1950s until the expiration of the fi-
NOTES TO CHAPTER 4
nal patent in 1975, nystatin was the Research Corporations biggest single source of cu¬ 201
mulative licensing income.
16. When revenues from hybrid seed corn, which during this period included pay¬
ments of back royalties as a result of a legal settlement, are excluded from this calcula¬
tion for 1970, the share of royalties accounted for by donated inventions declines to
82 percent.
17. Forresters invention resulted from his involvement in the Whirlwind computer
project, originally funded by the U.S. Navy to produce a flight simulator.
18. According to its 1968 Annual Report (p. 37), the Research Corporations policy
“requires that it resort to litigation when patents assigned are believed to be infringed,
and negotiation cannot bring about recognition of its rights.” This commitment to lit¬
igation as a matter of policy (rather than discretion) reflects another cost of large-scale
patent administration: the need to defend all patents (even marginal ones) in order to
avoid developing a reputation of being “soft” and thus inviting future infringement.
19. Another example of such conflicts that involves a clash between university ad¬
ministrators and faculty is the recent litigation between two UC faculty inventors
(Jerome Singer and Lawrence Crooks) and the UC system over the terms of the li¬
censing agreement for these inventors’ MRI patents. Singer and Crooks filed suit
against the University of California, accusing the university of negotiating very low li¬
censing fees with Pfizer Medical Systems in exchange for the firm’s financial support
of UC research activities. The inventors were awarded $2.3 million in back royalties in
a 1996 jury verdict that was upheld on appeal in 1997 (Chiang, 1997).
20. The difficulty of transferring expertise across technology fields is seen in this
statement from the 1968 Annual Report (p. 6): “The evaluation of invention disclosures
is increasingly more complex each year. Not only is the available literature, both tech¬
nical and patent, rapidly increasing, but technology itself is ever more complicated and
requires more concentrated study for proper understanding and evaluation. Only
through considerable use of outside consultants and patent attorneys were we able to
handle this volume. Even so the average time required to complete an evaluation and
the average number of disclosures in process at any given time was [sic] slowly increas¬
ing. The technological areas where these effects were most marked were in the me¬
chanical and the electrical-electronic fields.”
• 21. Legal costs here include expenditures on attorneys for evaluation services and
for patent prosecution, as well as litigation expenses. The latter category also con¬
tributed to the increased costs of patent management over the 1960s and 1970s.
22. This expanded visitation program was motivated by more than simply the cor¬
poration’s desire to maintain close links with academic inventors. During this period,
the Research Corporation also was expanding its efforts to assist universities in adapt¬
ing to changes in government patent policy, as we discuss below.
23. The corporation noted in 1966 that “the result from increased visitation program
and the wider dissemination of information about our patent assistance services has
been a steady increase in the number of inventions submitted for evaluation ... In spite
of the addition of one associate in the past two years, this increased load has required a
substantial increase in the use of technical consultants and patent attorneys. It appears
NOTES TO CHAPTER 4
202 certain that this activity will result in a substantial increase in retained income from in¬
ventions submitted under our agreements with institutions” (1966 Annual Report, p. 3).
These efforts also required more technical experts, and during 1968-73 the technical
staff of the invention administration program nearly tripled (1978 Annual Report, p. 25).
24. See also Jensen and Thursby (2001) on the importance of inventors’ tacit knowl¬
edge for technology transfer. As Lowe (2002) points out, this need for inventor involve¬
ment also is an important reason for the foundation by university inventors of firms to
commercialize their inventions.
25. Lamoreaux and Sokoloff (2002) emphasize the importance of geographic prox¬
imity in the growth of invention intermediaries, who were concentrated in regions of
the United States with relatively high proportions of independent inventors in the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. The analysis of data from the 1970s and 1980s
by Mowery and Ziedonis (2001) found that geographic proximity plays a more promi¬
nent role in the licensing of university patents than in the “knowledge spillovers” rep¬
resented by citations to university patents.
26. The corporation noted that “responsibility for carrying out the procedures must
be assigned unequivocally to an individual or an office in the administrative branch of
the institution” (Marcy, 1978, p. 5).
27. The Research Corporations 1968 Annual Report (p. 3) noted that “royalties re¬
ceived by Research Corporation from the institutional inventions is [sic] only about
one-third the expense of serving these institutions.”
28. Unfortunately, we can say little about cherry-picking by faculty members at
client universities (as opposed to by the universities themselves) without collecting
considerably more data that would enable us to identify the characteristics of all pat¬
ents held by these individual faculty members based on searching for their names in
the records of the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office.
29. Although withholding of valuable inventions by clients is never mentioned as a
possible cause of the lack of profitability of the institutional patent program during the
numerous discussions of this problem in the annual reports of the 1950s and 1960s, the
issue is discussed frequently in the corporations annual reports during the 1970s.
30. As a further check on the degree to which clients were cherry-picking, we com¬
pared the quality of the Research Corporations patents and the independent patents
by client universities by using the number of subsequent citations to a patent as a proxy
for the quality of the patent. For each of the six years discussed above, we regressed the
number of citations received after its issue by a patent on technological field dummies
and a dummy variable indicating whether the patent was assigned to the Research Cor¬
poration or to one of its client universities. In none of the years was the coefficient on
the “assignee” dummy statistically significant at conventional levels. Indeed, the only
year at which the coefficient was significant even at the 15 percent level is 1975; in that
year the sign is negative, suggesting that clients’ patents were of higher “quality” than
those assigned to the Research Corporation. The results of this analysis suggest little ev¬
idence of systematic cherry-picking behavior before the mid-1970s, consistent with the
discussion above.
31. Among the other alternatives considered but not adopted in 1979 was restriction
of the invention administration program to a limited set of technological fields. This
NOTES TO CHAPTER 5
proposal, which reflected a loss of confidence in the feasibility of cost reductions 203
through a technologically diversified patent licensing program, was not adopted be¬
cause “it would mean losing contact with other disciplines and narrowing our interface
within the scientific community” (Research Corporation, 1979, p. 83).
32. The Corporations 1964 Annual Report (p. 46) noted that “the program of more
frequent visits to institutions with which Research Corporation has patent agreements,
begun in 1963, was continued throughout 1964 and at an expanded pace in the latter
months of the year as the result of institutions accepting the foundations offer of assis¬
tance in matters relating to the new Government patent policies.”
33. “Our staff members have been making themselves freely available to these ad¬
ministrators during the year, and have undertaken to establish mutually helpful rela¬
tionships with as many of these key research administrators as possible” (1967 Annual
Report, p. 9).
34. Entry into patenting during the 1970s was dominated by institutions that were
not active Research Corporation clients or that were not Research Corporation clients,
that is, those with little or no history of patenting. This characteristic of entrant insti¬
tutions once again suggests that increased interinstitutional dispersion of funding,
rather than cherry-picking, inefficiencies at the corporation, or increased enthusiasm
for patenting, drove institutional entry into this activity during the 1970s.
35. With this point in mind, it is interesting to note that the survey of university li¬
censing officers in Jensen and Thursby (2001) reported that “revenue” was rated as “ex¬
tremely important” by nearly 75 percent of the respondents, ranking as the most im¬
portant objective of university licensing offices in their survey.
CHAPTER 5
1. See, for example, Bush (1943) and Bush’s testimony on the Kilgore bill, portions
of which are reprinted in U.S. Department of Justice (1947)- Most of the debate over
this issue occurred during congressional hearings on Kilgore s proposal for postwar sci¬
ence policy. Although Bush actively opposed the provisions in the Kilgore bill that
would give title to the government, his own proposal for postwar science policy (out¬
lined in Science: The Endless Frontier) avoided specifics, recommending only that “the
public interest will normally be adequately protected if the Government receives a
royalty-free license,” that is, if contractors retain title (“Letter of Transmittal” in Bush,
r945). Although the disagreements during the Bush-Kilgore debates centered on the ef¬
fects of government patent policy on private contractors, Bush also supported patent¬
ing by university researchers, as we noted in Chapter 2.
2. NASA administrator T. Keith Glennan, commenting on the differences between
NASA and DOD policies, observed that “two such contradictory patent policies, fol¬
lowed by government agencies working in closely related fields of research and devel¬
opment, can be detrimental to the kind of cooperation that we must have from indus¬
try” (“Glennan Asks Review of NASA Patent Policy,” 1959, p. 33)-
3. Memorandum and Statement of Government Patent Policy, 28 Federal Register
10,943-46 (1963); Memorandum and Statement of Government Patent Policy, 36 Fed¬
204 4. See also National Science Board (2002), Table 4-3. Universities and colleges (ex¬
cluding federally funded R&D Centers) performed 6 percent of federally funded R&D
in 1953, the first year for which the National Science Foundation has published data.
This share had grown to more than 33 percent of federal R&D spending by 2000.
5. President Kennedy’s 1963 “Memorandum on Government Patent Policy” had
charged the FCST with analyzing the effects of different patent policies on utilization
and commercialization of government funded research.
6. The firms screened these compounds for potential biological activity.
7. HEW had instituted an IPA program in 1953, and eighteen universities had ne¬
gotiated IPAs with the agency by 1958. But after 1958, no additional requests for IPAs
were approved by HEW because “opinions of responsible agency officials differed con¬
cerning the value of such agreements” (GAO, rg68, p. 24). Pharmaceutical companies
also complained that these IPAs were ambiguous about the scope of exclusive rights
that licensees could retain.
8. The purpose of the HEW review was “to make sure that assignment of patent
rights to universities and research institutes did not stifle competition in the private sec¬
tor in those cases where competition could bring the fruits of research to the public
faster and more economically” according to the testimony of Comptroller General
Elmer Staats during the Bayh-Dole hearings (U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary,
1979a, p. 37)•
9. A patent attorney formerly employed by Purdue University, Norman Latker, was
also the chief architect of the changes in HEW’s patent policies in 1968 and was fired
from HEW after denouncing the agency’s subsequent review of these policies. He re¬
turned to the HEW’s patent office in 1978, after his dismissal was overturned by a civil
service review board on procedural grounds. Reporting on these events in Science,
Broad (1979a, p. 476) noted: “The reinstatement is timely. Support is now building for
the Bayh-Dole patent bill, and Latkers return to the HEW is seen by many university
researchers and patent transfer fans, to whom Latker is something of a hero, as a shot
in the arm for their cause.”
10. Identical legislation (H.R. 2414) was introduced in the House of Representatives
by Rep. Peter Rodino (D-N.J.) in 1979.
11. Another IPA restriction dropped in the Dole-Bayh bill was the requirement that
grantees and contractors try first to offer nonexclusive licenses. According to an
anonymous aide to Senator Bayli who was quoted by Henig (1979, p. 281), “‘It’s too
hard and inefficient a process. Universities don’t have the financial capability to beat
the bushes and try to find someone who is willing to accept a license on a non¬
exclusive basis.’”
12. A contemporary account noted that limiting the bill to universities and small
businesses was “a tactical exclusion taken to ensure liberal support” (Henig, 1979,
p. 282). A Senate aide commented, “We’d like to extend [the policy] to everybody
but if we did the bill would never have a chance of passing” (Broad, 1979b, p. 474). The
original bill also included several provisions designed to defuse criticism that it would
lead to “profiteering” at the expense of the public interest, including a recoupment pro¬
vision requiring that institutions pay back a share of licensing income or sales to fund¬
ing agencies. The final version of the Bayh-Dole Act eliminated this provision “because
NOTES TO CHAPTER 5
there was no agreement on whether the funds would be returned to the agencies or to 205
general revenue, or how the collection and auditing functions would be conducted”
and “fears that the costs of the infrastructure required to administer such a program
would exceed the amounts collected.” See http://www.nih.gov/news/oyoioiwyden.htm.
13. For example. Dole opened the Senate Judiciary Committees hearings on the
bill by observing that “the damaging impact of the Federal patent policy on the econ¬
omy is dramatic. That we have lost our leadership role to Japan in the field of elec¬
tronics and shipbuilding is no accident” (U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary,
x979a, P- z8)-
14. See Harold Bremer, “Public Patents, Public Benefits?” submitted with his testi¬
mony during the Senate Judiciary Committees Bayh-Dole Hearings (U.S. Senate
Committee on the Judiciary, 1979a).
r5. See, for example, the opening statements by Senators Bayh, Dole, and Orrin
Hatch (R-Ut.), as well as the testimony by Elmer Staats, Walter Syniuta, and Betsy
Ancker-Johnson (U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 1979a).
16. See, for example, the testimony by Hector Deluca, Frederick Andrews, and
Harold Bremer during the Senate Judiciary Committees Bayh-Dole Hearings (U.S.
Senate Committee on the Judiciary, 1979a).
17. The Senate Judiciary Committees report on S. 414 noted: “A number of wit¬
nesses also pointed out to the committee that when government agencies retain title to
inventions made by nonprofit organizations or small business contractors there is ab¬
solutely no incentive for the inventor to remain involved in the possible development
of the patentable discovery. Virtually all experts in the innovation process stress very
strongly that such involvement by the inventor is absolutely essential, especially when
the invention was made under basic research where it is invariably in the embryonic
stage of development” (U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary, i9798> P- 22)-
r8. Much of the floor debate in both chambers focused on whether large businesses
should be allowed to retain rights to patents resulting from federal contracts. Rep. Rob¬
ert Kastenmeier (D-Wis.), a supporter of extending rights to large business contractors,
noted that “rather than hold hostage [the] non-controversial areas [that is, allowing uni¬
versities and small businesses to retain title], I think we have no real option but to move
forward with this [the bill as amended] and send it to the White House” (U.S. House
of Representatives, 1980, p. 30560.) The original bill passed by the House (H.R. 6933)
contained the same provisions as the Senate bill introduced by Senators Bayh and Dole
but also allowed large firms to obtain “field of use” exclusive licenses for inventions de¬
veloped with government funds. Senate amendments to this bill eliminated that pro¬
vision, and the House subsequently passed a bill identical to that passed by the Senate.
19. A journalist covering the hearings observed that although the Dole-Bayh bill is
receiving nearly unprecedented support, some congressional aides point out that it still
leaves unanswered fundamental questions about patents in general and patents on uni¬
versity campuses in particular” (Henig, 1979, p. 284).
20. For details, see the Council on Government Relations (1999).
21. Memorandum to the Heads of Executive Departments and Agencies: Govern¬
ment Patent Policy, Pub. Papers 252 (February 18, 1983); Executive Order 12591
(4/10/87); codified at 3 C.F.R. 221.
NOTES TO CHAPTER 6
206 22. Trademark Clarification Act of ^84, PL 98-620. Among other things, this
amendment also allowed contractors at Government Owned, Contractor Operated
Labs (GOCOs) to retain title to federally funded inventions.
23. According to Katz and Ordover (1990), at least fourteen congressional bills
passed during the 1980s focused on strengthening domestic and international protec¬
tion for intellectual property rights, and the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit,
created in 1982, has upheld patent rights in roughly 80 percent of the cases argued be¬
fore it, a considerable increase from the pre-1982 rate of 30 percent for the federal
bench.
24. “Regulatory reform in the United States in the early 1980s, such as the Bayh-
Dole Act, have [sic] significantly increased the contribution of scientific institutions to
innovation. There is evidence that this is one of the factors contributing to the pick-up
of US growth performance” (OECD, 2000, p. 77).
25. “In 1980, the enactment of the Bayh-Dole Act (Public Law 98-620) culminated
years of work to develop incentives for laboratory discoveries to make their way to the
marketplace promptly, with all the attendant benefits for public welfare and economic
growth that result from those innovations. Before Bayh-Dole, the federal government
had accumulated 30,000 patents, of which only 5% had been licensed and even fewer
had found their way into commercial products. Today under Bayh-Dole more than 200
universities are engaged in technology transfer, adding more than $21 billion each year
to the economy” (Hasselmo, 1999, p. 3).
26. “In the 1970s, the government discovered the inventions that resulted from pub¬
lic funding were not reaching the marketplace because no one would make the addi¬
tional investment to turn basic research into marketable products. That finding re¬
sulted in the Bayh-Dole Act, passed in 1980. It enabled universities, small companies,
and nonprofit organizations to commercialize the results of federally funded research.
The results of Bayh-Dole have been significant. Before 1981, fewer than 250 patents
were issued to universities each year. A decade later universities were averaging ap¬
proximately 1,000 patents a year” (Dickinson, 2000, p. 2).
27. The Bayh-Dole Act turned out to be the Viagra for campus innovation. Uni¬
versities that would previously have let their intellectual property lie fallow began fil¬
ing for and getting patents at unprecedented rates. Coupled with other legal economic
and political developments that also spurred patenting and licensing, the results seems
nothing less than a major boon to national economic growth” (Zacks, 2000).
chapter 6
Technology Transfer Archives), “The possibility of developing a formal patent policy 207
and program was first considered in the University in the Thirties. But the idea did not
achieve full impetus until the war years when the Federal Government began to spon¬
sor research in the University on a large scale and inventions began to be made under
research contracts.”
3. The “Patent Board” was a committee of UC faculty and administrators charged
with oversight of the Patent Office. As revised in 1973, the “University Policy Regarding
Patents” states that “an agreement to assign inventions and patents to The Regents of
the University of California, except those resulting from permissible consulting activi¬
ties without use of University facilities, shall be mandatory for all employees, academic
and nonacademic.” The policy statement goes on to emphasize that “the Regents is
[sic] adverse to seeking protective patents and will not seek such patents unless the dis¬
coverer or inventor can demonstrate that the securing of the patent is important to the
University.” This latter sentiment notwithstanding, UC administrators were actively
seeking patent protection for faculty inventions by the mid-1970s, as the historical data
of the Office of Technology Transfer show.
4. These “independent” licensing offices, which continue to pay a portion of their
revenues to the state government, are in charge of invention disclosures (along with
any revenues or expenses associated with these disclosures) occurring after their foun¬
dation. The UC Office of Technology Transfer, however, continues to collect and re¬
port data on disclosures, patents, and licenses from all UC campuses.
5. Almost simultaneously with this shift in university patent policy, an internal study
by the OTL Advisory Board in 1993 recommended that “OTL need not be constrained
by the principle of‘preference for non-exclusive licensing’” (Stanford University Of¬
fice of Technology Licensing, 1994b, p. 2).
6. Reflecting faculty sensitivity over assignment to the university of all ownership of
all copyrighted material produced under university sponsorship, Stanfords OTL ex¬
empted ownership of books, articles, popular nonfiction, novels, poems, musical
compositions, or other works of artistic imagination which are not institutional works”
from the policy governing software (Stanford University Office of Technology Licens¬
ing, 1994b, p. 1).
7. Figure 6.7 excludes licenses for the Cohen-Boyer patents, which were managed
by Stanfords OTL on behalf of the UC system and Stanford University. Strictly speak¬
ing, since the revenues from these licenses are split between the UC system and Stan¬
ford University, the licenses also should be allocated between the two institutions. Ex¬
clusion of this heavily licensed invention thus understates the growth in the biomedical
share of Stanford and UC licensing agreements during the 1980s in Figure 6.7.
8. Some indication of the relative magnitudes of licensing revenues from these site
licenses," which for some years were administered by the OTL Software Distribution
Center, is given by the following data cited in the 1988-89 report of the OTL, which
separated software licensing revenues into those derived from direct software distri¬
bution through OTL’s Software Distribution Center ($453,581 from 515 use licenses)
and from royalties paid by commercial distributors ($420,000 from 40 distribution
licenses to software firms, computer companies, and publishers)” (Stanford Uni¬
versity Office of Technology Licensing, 1990, p. 4). Unfortunately, we have been
NOTES TO CHAPTER 6
208 unable thus far to consistently separate software licenses between these two channels
of distribution.
9. Portions of this section are based on Crow et al. (1998).
10. Biotechnology inventions accounted for 45 percent of the biomedical inventions
that resulted in patents and nearly 70 percent of the biomedical inventions that were
licensed.
11. Columbia also experienced growth in the number of licenses for software in¬
ventions during the 1980s (a measure that heavily weights inventions licensed on a
nonexclusive basis). Software licenses account for well over 50 percent of Columbia li¬
censing agreements after 1988; the majority of these licenses (420 of a total of 648) were
associated with one software invention. In addition, and similar to the situation at Stan¬
ford University (see below), more than 300 of the 420 licensees for this software inven¬
tion were academic institutions.
12. In order to deal with the problems of “truncation bias” while accommodating
the fact that our data end in 1997, we have imposed a six-year “trailing window” on our
invention disclosures. In other words, the analysis includes issued patents or licenses
only if these events occur within six years after the date of disclosure of the invention.
This convention is used to avoid unfairly biasing the indicators of “productivity” in fa¬
vor of older disclosures, which have much longer time periods during which to pro¬
duce patents or licenses.
13. As we noted earlier, a large percentage of Stanfords software licenses cover low-
royalty “site licenses” at other academic institutions, which may well raise the shares of
Stanford disclosures that yield licensing income without necessarily having a signifi¬
cant effect on overall licensing income. In addition, the Stanford invention disclosures
and licensing data contain a large number of agreements covering “clones” of various
pieces of genetic material —such agreements are less common in the Columbia or UC
data for the period covered by this analysis. These licenses are somewhat more formal
than Materials Transfer Agreements and often involve the payment of modest licens¬
ing fees. But as with the Stanford software licenses, including these agreements in our
data increases the share of disclosures that are licensed or that yield licensing income
without having much effect on overall licensing income.
14. See the case study of Cohen-Boyer in the National Research Council workshop,
Intellectual Property Rights and Research Tools in Molecular Biology (National Re¬
search Council, 1997).
15. Data on Stanford patent applications are unavailable, and we therefore are able
to compute measures using patent applications only for the University of California.
Because the analysis reported in Table 6.3 examines two earlier time periods than
Table 6.2, we used a longer, eight-year “trailing window” (see Note 12; we include only
issued patents or license agreements within eight years following the invention disclo¬
sures) to compare the yield and productivity of Stanford and UC patenting and li¬
censing before and after Bayh-Dole.
16. Since the UC disclosure and licensing data largely exclude software inventions,
the most nearly comparable Stanford data are those excluding software inventions and
licenses.
17. The data on Stanford licenses are incomplete, as was noted earlier. Moreover,
NOTES TO CHAPTER 6
the licensing income data are reported on a fiscal year basis and license agreements on 209
a calendar year basis, making it difficult to reconcile these data. We have attempted to
adjust the licensing income and agreements data to address this incompatibility, but
the data for Stanford in the last line of Table 6.3 should be treated with caution.
r8. This share is essentially stable, however, when software inventions are added to
the sample, reflecting the inclusion within the Stanford software licensing data of nu¬
merous academic “site licenses,” each of which produced a small but positive licens¬
ing income.
19. For example, average income per license may have increased in the second pe¬
riod, although the skewed distribution of the licensing income of both the Stanford
and UC technology transfer offices means that any such changes are likely to be small.
See Sampat and Ziedonis (2003) for an analysis of the relationship between the level of
licensing revenues at the University of California and Columbia and the characteris¬
tics of these universities’ licensed patents.
20. This third subset of our data is intended to separate those faculty disclosures that
occurred before Bayh-Dole could affect the content of academic research but whose
commercial promotion by universities (that is, through filing patent applications and
seeking licensees) occurred after the effective date of the Act. Unfortunately, the small
size of this sample of patents reduces the power and significance of our tests of statisti¬
cal significance for any differences among the characteristics of the three subsets of
patents.
21. Our control samples are constructed differently from those of Henderson, Jaffe,
and Trajtenberg (1995, 1998a). They used as their control sample a 1 percent random
sample of all U.S. patents granted during the time period covered by their university
patent sample. In contrast, our control sample matches each university patent with a
nonuniversity patent from the same patent class with an application date at or near the
date of application for the university patent.
22. Our definition of biomedical patent classes is based on Technology Assessment
and Forecast reports published by the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office that identify
three-digit patent classes and subclasses related to medical and biomedical technolo¬
gies. For a more detailed description of this taxonomy, see Ziedonis (2001).
23. In another analysis not reported because of space limitations, we subdivided the
post-1981 period into three subperiods of equal length in order to test for more signifi¬
cant reductions in the importance of Stanford and UC patents during the late 1980s.
Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1998a) find that the greatest reduction in impor¬
tance in their sample of academic patents, especially those assigned to the leading aca¬
demic patenters, occurs late in the 1980s. Our tests for differences in the means of the
university and control patent samples, however, reveal no significant differences.
24. Interestingly, the corrected results reported in the errata appendix to Trajten¬
berg, Henderson, and Jaffe (1997) find that the importance (measured in terms of the
number of forward citations) of academic patents, relative to those from corporate in¬
ventors, declines between 1975 and 1980, before the Bayh-Dole Act. 1 Ins finding is
broadly consistent with our conclusion that Bayh-Dole per se had little measurable ef¬
fect on the relative importance of academic and nonacademic patents. ;
" 25. Any such effect was significant during only the early years of Columbia s
NOTES TO CHAPTER 7
210 patenting and licensing activities, since by 1986-90 the share of disclosures resulting
in issued patents and the share of disclosures that result in licenses yielding positive roy¬
alty income are fairly similar at Columbia, the University of California, and Stanford,
as we noted earlier in this chapter.
26. We also examined the number of UC and Stanford patents from all three sub¬
periods that yielded no citations during the six years following their issue in an effort
to replicate the analysis in Henderson, Jaffe, and Trajtenberg (1998a) of “losers.” Here,
too, we find no consistent trend. “Zero-citation patents” account for 22 percent and
18 percent, respectively, of the UC and Stanford patents for period 1 in Tables 6.5 and
6.6; 16 percent and o percent of the UC and Stanford patents in period 2; and 11 per¬
cent and 8 percent of the UC and Stanford patents in period 3.
27. We also tested, but do not report results, for the significance of year-specific ef¬
fects on the relative importance of these academic and nonacademic patents, using a
negative binomial specification. We find no significant decline in the importance of
these three universities’ patents relative to nonacademic patents during the post-1980
period.
28. Stanford s middle period biomedical patents also display a lower mean gener¬
ality score than do their control patents, and UC nonbiomedical patents applied for
and issued before 1981 also exhibit slightly lower mean “generality scores” than do their
respective control samples.
29. Sampat, Mowery, and Ziedonis (2003) empirically analyze the effects of trun¬
cation bias on measures of change in university patent quality after Bayh-Dole.
chapter 7
1. As we pointed out in Note 21 in the previous chapter, the patent control samples
used in our analysis are constructed differently from those of Henderson, Jaffe, and
Trajtenberg (1995,1998a).
2. Our construction of the academic patent dataset yields a small number of obser¬
vations for 1992, and we accordingly omit this year from the results reported in
Tables 7.2-4.
3. Specifically, we estimate a “double” tobit model with an lower limit of zero and
an upper limit of 1.
4. We also ran probit regressions that examined the number of patents assigned to
universities in these three groups that received no citations in the first six years follow¬
ing their issue. Henderson, Jaffe, and I rajtenberg (1998a,b) use this “zero-citation” mea¬
sure as another measure of change in the characteristics of university patents. The re¬
sults of these probit regressions were broadly similar to those reported in Tables 7.2-4.
5. Our findings of differences in significance in importance and generality among
the “high-intensity” incumbent, “low-intensity” incumbent, and “entrant” subsamples
and their respective control groups could be affected by differences in standard errors
due to the various sizes of the three subsamples. To check the robustness of our results,
we conducted but do not report similar regressions combining all three subsamples
and obtained broadly similar results to those reported in Tables 7.2-4.
NOTES TO CHAPTER 7
6. Our matching algorithm used to generate the control sample generated the same 211
control patent for 307 university patents. We thus have 10,574 different control patents
matched with our 10,881 university patents.
7. Lanjouw and Schankerman (1998) suggest that five-year citation windows are suf¬
ficient to construct meaningful measures of a patents “importance.”
8. We also conducted Poisson regressions but tested for and found evidence of
overdispersion, suggesting that the negative binomial model is more appropriate.
9. We also conducted but do not report probit regressions comparing the probabil¬
ity that an academic and nonacademic patent is ever cited within five years of issue us¬
ing the same university and control group samples. Point estimates of the coefficients
for ENT8l83 and ENT8486 in this analysis imply a marginal effect of about -0.05 (that is,
entrants’ patents applied for during 1981-83 and 1984-86 were approximately 5 per¬
cent less likely to be cited at all than were incumbents’ patents).
10. Unreported probit regression results for biomedical patents indicate that en¬
trants’ patents applied for during 1984- 86 were significantly less likely (at the 5 percent
level) to be cited than were incumbents’ patents. This difference was not statistically
significant, however, for entrant-university and incumbent-university patents applied
for during 1981-83.
11. In unreported probit regressions for nonbiomedical patents, entrants’ patents ap¬
plied for during 1981—83 are significantly less likely to be cited at all than are the simi¬
lar patents of incumbent universities (at the 5 percent level), but this differential be¬
comes smaller and statistically insignificant for patents applied for during 1984-86.
12. Improvement in entrants’ patent importance could reflect changes in funding
patterns. For example, if the average importance of patents in an institution’s patent
portfolio is correlated with the size of its research budget, increases in their research
budgets could lead to an improvement in the importance of entrant universities’ pat¬
ents in the absence of “learning.” There is little empirical support for this hypothesis,
and we do not test it here. Nevertheless, Geiger and Feller (1995) found evidence of in¬
creased interinstitutional dispersion in federal funding of university research during
the 1980s, and higher dispersion may well have benefited universities with less pre-1980
experience in patenting. Geiger and Feller (1995) found that growth during the 1980s
in funding dispersion was greatest in biomedicine, a field in which we find little evi¬
dence of improvement in the importance of entrants’ patents. Although it merits addi¬
tional analysis, this evidence provides little support for a “dispersion hypothesis in ex¬
plaining the increased measured importance of entrant universities’ patents during the
late 1980s. ,
13 In separate regressions (not reported), we analyze the average importance ot an
institution’s patents at time t as a function of cumulative patenting experience for the
entire 1975-92 period. These regressions did not reveal a relationship between cumu¬
lative patenting and patent importance.
14 Michael Crow, personal communication, September 28, 2000.
15. We also conducted but do not report the results of regression specifications us¬
ing interaction terms for individual application years and patent technology classes.
These regressions produced results similar to those from regressions where application
NOTES TO CHAPTER 8
212 years were aggregated into three-year intervals. The first application year dummy and
first patent class dummy were omitted to avoid perfect multicollinearity.
chapter 8
1. Similar results are reported in Thursby and Thursby (2002), based on a survey of
112 firms that licensed university inventions between 1993 and 1997.
2. Two important publications describing the process were Wigler et al. (1977) and
Wigler et al. (1979).
3. Since Columbia did not have a technology transfer office in early 1980, the
General Counsel’s office handled all potentially patentable inventions disclosed to the
university.
4. Columbia’s low royalty rates for a key “research process” patent resemble the li¬
censing policies followed by Stanford in its licensing of the Cohen-Boyer patents de¬
veloped by researchers at the University of California and Stanford University.
5. Niels Reimers, the first head of Stanford’s Office of Technology Transfer and
manager ofthe licensure of Cohen-Boyer, subsequently noted, “[W]hether we licensed
it or not, commercialization of recombinant DNA was going forward. As I mentioned,
a nonexclusive licensing program, at its heart, is really a tax . . . [b]ut it’s always nice to
say ‘technology transfer’” (Reimers, 1998).
6. Materials similar to GaN that are based on aluminum and indium have similar
properties and are now used in many of the same applications listed above as a result
of the research effort discussed below. Although we focus on GaN, research in this area
included research on a class of related semiconductors that included these cousins,
namely Class III-V.
7. Blue GaN LEDs had been produced previously —Pankove himself had devel¬
oped a prototype earlier. But Nakamura’s prototype is widely credited as the first GaN
LED with significant commercial potential.
8. “GaN-related patents” were selected through a text-based search for “gallium ni¬
tride or GaN in the title or abstract of all U.S. patents issuing during 1972-98.
9. Akasakis patents issued in 1983 and 1984 are largely based on his work at Mat¬
sushita, since the patents were applied for during the same year Akasaki accepted his
university position.
10. The other university patent issuing during 1983-94 was assigned to Harvard
University and covered a thin film process that could be used for GaN as well as other
Class III-V compounds.
11. Another significant instance of industrial knowledge flowing into academia oc¬
curred in 2000, when Nakamura accepted a position at UC Santa Barbara.
12. I11 2002, responsibility for the distribution of the Ames Tests assays was shifted to
Xenometrix, the start-up firm that commercialized the Ames II Tests. Xenometrix has
maintained the original UC distribution policies for these Ames Tests, policies that in
many respects resemble the Materials lransfer Agreements widely used by academic
and industrial research laboratories.
13. http://ist-socrates.berkeley.edu/mutagen/salmut_facil_core.html.
14. Gene profiling is the process of collecting information on gene activity after ex-
NOTES TO CHAPTER 9
chapter 9
1. Indeed, Howard Bremer, former patent counsel for the Wisconsin Alumni Re¬
search Foundation (WARF) and president of the Association of University Technology
Managers (AUTM) during 1978-79, acknowledged in a statement celebrating the
“technology transfer harvest” following Bayh-Dole that the growth of patenting of fed¬
erally funded academic research began not with Bayh-Dole but with the NSF and
HEW Institutional Patent Agreements (IPAs) in the 1960s and 1970s, and he notes that
“in fact, that law is often looked upon as a codification of the terms and provisions of
the IPAs” (Bremer, 2001).
2. In June 1998, a report of the NIH Working Group on Research Tools raised con-
NOTES TO CHAPTER 9
214 cerns about difficulties scientists and institutions faced in getting access to patented
biomedical research tools developed with federal funds. In response to these concerns,
in the “Technology Transfer Commercialization Act of 2000,” Congress added a “tech¬
nical amendment” to Bayh-Dole, noting that federally funded inventions should be li¬
censed “without unduly encumbering future research and development” (Roumel,
2003). The effects of this change in the language of the Bayh-Dole Act on academic
patenting and licensing practices remain unclear.
3. Walsh, Arora, and Cohen (2003) argue that the reliance by academic researchers
and research administrators on a de facto research exemption from infringement suits
has been an important “working solution” to problems arising from the potential as¬
sertion by patentholders of rights over research materials, tools, and similar inputs for
the scientific research process. The authors conclude that the Madey v. Duke decision,
if not reversed judicially or legislatively, “could well chill some of the ‘offending’ bio¬
medical research that is conducted in university settings” (p. 56).
References
Agrawal, A., and R. Henderson. 2002. “Putting Patents in Context: Exploring Knowl¬
edge Transfer from MIT.” Management Science 48: 44-60.
American Association for the Advancement of Science (AAAS). 1934. The Protection by
Patents of Scientific Discoveries: Report of the Committee on Patents, Copyrights, and
Trademarks. New York: Science Press.
Apple, R. D. 1989. “Patenting University Research.” Isis 80: 375-94-
_1996. Vitamania: Vitamins in American Culture. New Brunswick, N.J.: Rutgers
University Press.
Arrow, K. 1962. “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention.” In
R. R. Nelson, ed., The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Association of University Technology Managers (AUTM). 1994. The AUTM Licensing
Survey: Executive Summary and Selected Data, Fiscal Years 1993, 1992, and 1991.
Norwalk, Conn.: AUTM.
_ 1996. AUTM Licensing Survey 1996, Survey Summary. Norwalk, Conn.: AUTM.
_ j998. AUTM Licensing Survey 1998, Survey Summary. Norwalk, Conn.:
AUTM.
_2000. The AUTM Licensing Survey: FY1999. Norwalk, Conn.: AU TM.
“Axel Patent Claims Mammalian Cell Transfer.” McGraw Hills Biotechnology
Newswatch 3 (1983): 5.
Barrett, P. 1980. “Harvard Fears Congress May Not Pass Patent Bill. Harvard Crimson,
October 7.
Ben-David, J., 1968. Fundamental Research and the Universities. Paris: OECD.
Blum, F. 2000. Telephone interview.
Blumenthal, D., E. Campbell, M. Anderson, N. Causino, and K. Louis. 1997. With¬
holding Research Results in Academic Life Science: Evidence from a National Sur¬
vey of Faculty.” Journal of the American Medical Association 277: 1224-29.
REFERENCES
216 Blumenthal, D., S. Epstein, and J. Maxwell. 1986. “Commercializing University Re¬
search: Lessons from the History of the Wisconsin Alumni Research Foundation.”
New England Journal of Medicine 314:1621-26.
Bok, D. Beyond the Ivory Tower. 1982. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Bremer, H. 2001. “The First Two Decades of the Bayh-Dole Act as Public Policy.” Pre¬
sentation to the National Association of State Universities and Land Grant Col¬
leges. Available from World Wide Web: http://www.nasulgc.org/COTT/Bayh
-Dohl/Bremer_speech.htm.
Broad, W. 1979a. “Patent Bill Returns Bright Idea to Inventor.” Science 205: 473-76.
-1979b. “Whistle Blower Reinstated at HEW.” Science 205: 476.
Bryson, E. 1984. “Frederick E. Terman: Educator and Mentor.” IEEE Spectrum
(March): 71—73.
Burn, B. B., P. G. Altbach, C. Kerr, and J. A. Perkins. 1971. Higher Education in Nine
Countries. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Bush, V. 1943. “The Kilgore Bill.” Science 98: 571-77.
- 1945- Science: The Endless Frontier. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Print¬
ing Office.
Cameron, F. 1993. Cottrell: Samaritan of Science. Tucson, Az.: Research Corporation.
Campbell, E. G., B. R. Clarridge, M. Gokhale, L. Birenbaum, S. Hilgartner, N. A.
Holtzman, and D. Blumenthal. 2002. “Data Withholding in Academic Genetics:
Evidence from a National Survey.” Journal of the American Medical Association
287: 473-80.
Camras, C. B., and L. Z. Bito. 1981. “Reduction of Intraocular Pressure in Normal and
Glaucomatous Primate (Aotus Trivirgatus) Eyes by Topically Applied Prostaglandin
F2 Alpha.” Current Eye Research 1: 205-9.
Camras, C. B., L. Z. Bito, and K. E. Eakins. 1977. “Reduction of Intraocular Pressure
by Prostaglandins Applied Topically to the Eyes Of Conscious Rabbits.” Investiga¬
tive Ophthalmology and Visual Science 16:1125-34.
Carnegie Commission on Higher Education. 1973. ^ Classification of Institutions of
Higher Education: A Technical Report. Berkeley, Calif.: Carnegie Commission on
Higher Education.
- !993- A Classification of Institutions of Higher Education; A Technical Report.
Berkeley, Calif.: Carnegie Commission on Higher Education.
Caves, R., H. Crookell, and P. Killing. 1983. “The Imperfect Market for Technology
Licenses.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 45: 249-67.
“CD4-PE40 Exotoxin Conjugate in Trials; Other CD4 Conjugates in Development.”
Antiviral Agents Bulletin (March 1992): 69.
Chase, M. 1988. “Group Enters Field Studying CD4 for AIDS.” Wall Street Journal,
June 3.
Chiang, H. 1997. Court Reinstates Royalty Award to UC Professors.” San Francisco
Chronicle, December 2.
Cohen, W. M., R. Morida, and R. Goe. 1994. “University-Industry Research Centers in
the United States. Pittsburgh: Center for Economic Development, Carnegie-
Mellon University.
Cohen, W. M., R. Florida, L. Randazzese, and J. Walsh. 1998. “Industry and the Acad-
REFERENCES
emy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause of Technological Advance.” In R. Noll, ed., 217
Challenges to the Research University. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Cohen, W. M., and D. A. Levinthal. 1990. “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on
Learning and Innovation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128-52.
Cohen, W. M., R. R. Nelson, and J. P. Walsh. 2002. “Links and Impacts: The Influence
of Public Research on Industrial R&D.” Management Science 48: 1—23.
“Columbia Innovation Enterprise: A Special Report.” Reporter 7 (1996).
“Columbia University rDNA Patent Licensing.” Blue Sheet 27 (1984): 3-4.
Colyvas, J., M. Crow, A. Gelijns, R. Mazzoleni, R. R. Nelson, N. Rosenberg, and B. N.
Sampat. 2002. “How Do University Inventions Get into Practice?” Management
Science 48: 61—72.
Committee on Uniform Patent Policies in Land Grant and Engineering Experiment
Stations. 1922. “Report of the Committee on Uniform Patent Policies.” Proceedings
of the Association of Land Grant Colleges and Universities: 283-84.
Cottrell, F. 1911. “The Electrical Precipitation of Suspended Particles.” Journal of In¬
dustrial and Engineering Chemistry 3: 542-50.
-1912. “The Research Corporation, an Experiment in the Public Administration
of Patent Rights.” Journal of Industrial and Engineering Chemistry 4: 864-67.
- 1932. “Patent Experience of the Research Corporation.” Transactions of the
American Institute of Chemical Engineers 26: 222-25.
- 1937- “The Social Responsibility of the Engineer.” Journal of the Western Soci¬
ety of Engineers 42: 65-77.
Council on Government Relations. 1999. The Bayh-Dole Act: A Guide to the Law and
Implementing Regulations. Available from World Wide Web: http://www.cogr.edu/
bayh-dole.htm.
Crow, M. M., A. C. Gelijns, R. R. Nelson, H. J. Raider, and B. N. Sampat. 1998. “Re¬
cent Changes in University-Industry Research Interactions: A Preliminary Analysis
of Causes and Effects.” Unpublished working paper, School of International and
Public Affairs, Columbia University, New York.
Dasgupta, P., and P. David. 1994. “Towards a New Economics of Science.” Research
Policy 23: 487-521.
David, P. A., and D. Foray. 1995. “Accessing and Expanding the Science and Technol¬
ogy Knowledge Base.” STI Review 16:13-68.
David, P. A., D. C. Mowery, and W. E. Steinmueller. 1992. “Analyzing the Economic
Payoffs from Basic Research.” Economics of Innovation and New Technology 2:
73-90.
Davis, E. W. 1964. Pioneering with Taconite. St. Paul: Minnesota Historical Society.
DenBaars, S. 2000. Personal interview.
Department of Health and Human Services. 2001. NIH Response to the Conference Re¬
port Request for a Plan to Ensure Taxpayers’ Interests Are Protected. Bethesda, Md.:
National Institutes of Health. Available from World Wide Web: http://www.nih
.gov/news/oyoioiwyden.htm.
Dickinson, Q. Todd. 2000. “Reconciling Research and the Patent System.” Issues in
Science and Technology 16: 27-31.
“Dr. Cottrell and the Research Corporation.” Scientific Monthlv 22 (1926): 181-86.
REFERENCES
2i8 Dreyfuss, R. 2003. “Varying the Course in Patenting Genetic Material: A Counter-
Proposal to Richard Epstein’s Steady Course. " New York University School of Law,
Public Law and Legal Theory Research Paper Series, Research Paper No. 59.
Eisenberg, R. S. 1996. “Public Research and Private Development: Patents and Tech¬
nology Transfer in Government-Sponsored Research.” Virginia Law Review 82:
1663-1727.
-2001. “Bargaining over the Transfer of Proprietary Research Tools: Is This Mar¬
ket Emerging or Lading?” In D. L. Zimmerman, R. C. Dreyfuss, and H. First, eds.,
Expanding the Bounds of Intellectual Property: Innovation Policy for the Knowledge
Society. New York: Oxford University Press.
Eskridge, N. 1978. “Dole Blasts HEW for ‘Stonewalling’ Patent Applications.” Bio¬
science 28: 605-6.
Etzkowitz, H. 1994. “Knowledge as Property: The Massachusetts Institute of Technol¬
ogy and the Debate of Academic Patent Policy.” Minerva 32: 383-421.
Evenson, R. E. 1982. “Agriculture.” In R. R. Nelson, ed., Government and Technical
Progress: A Cross-Industry Analysis. New York: Pergamon.
Executive Office of the President. 1983. “Memorandum to the Heads of Executive De¬
partments and Agencies: Government Patent Policy, February 18,1983.”
Federal Council on Science and Technology (FCST). 1978. Report on Government
Patent Policy, 1973-1976. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Feldman, M., I. Feller, J. E. L. Bercovitz, and R. Burton. 2002. “Equity and the Tech¬
nology Transfer Strategies of American Research Universities.” Management
Science 48:105—21.
Fishman, E. A. 1996. “MIT Patent Policy 1932-1946: Historical Precedents in
University-Industry Technology Transfer.” Ph.D. diss., University of Pennsylvania.
Flexner, A. 1968 [1930]. Universities: American, English, German. London: Oxford Uni¬
versity Press.
Foray, D., and A. Kazancigil. 1999. “Science, Economics and Democracy.” Man¬
agement of Social Transformation (MOST) Discussion Paper 42. Prepared for
UNESCO World Conference on Science 1999.
Foreman, ]. 1988. “Scientists Race to Create AIDS Virus ‘Decoy’: Crucial Issues Re¬
main, but Interest Is Intense in Using Fake Receptors.” Boston Globe, January 11.
Fox, J. 1983. “Columbia Awarded Biotechnology Patent.” Science 221: 933.
Furter, W. F., ed. 1980. History of Chemical Engineering. Washington, D.C.: American
Chemical Society.
Gee, P. 2001. Personal interview.
Gee, P., D. M. Maron, and B. N. Ames. 1994. “Detection and Classification of Muta¬
gens: A Set of Base-Specific Salmonella Tester Strains.” Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences 91: 11606-10.
Geiger, R. 1986. To Advance Knowledge: The Growth of American Research Universities,
1900-1940. New York: Oxford University Press.
- 1993- Research and Relevant Knowledge: American Research Universities Since
World War II. New York: Oxford University Press.
Geiger, R., and I. Feller. 1995. “The Dispersion of Academic Research in the 1980s.”
Journal of Higher Education 65: 336-60.
Gelijns, A., and N. Rosenberg. 1999. “Diagnostic Devices: An Analysis of Comparative
REFERENCES
Levine, D. O. 1986. The American College and the Culture of Aspiration, 1915-1940. 221
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
“Licensing Plan For AIDS Drug Draws Fire.” 1988. Seattle Times, October 25.
Liebeskind,}. 2001. “Risky Business: Universities and Intellectual Property.” Academe
87. Available from World Wide Web: http://www.aaup.org/publications/Academe/
oiSO/sooilie.htm.
Little, A. D. 1933. Twenty-five Years of Chemical Engineering Progress. New York: Van
Nostrand.
Louis, K., L. Jones, M. Anderson, D. Blumenthal, and E. Campbell. 2001. “Entrepre¬
neurship, Secrecy, and Productivity: A Comparison of Clinical and Non-Clinical
Life Sciences Faculty.” Journal of Technology Transfer 26: 233-45.
Lowe, Robert A. 2001. “The Role and Experience of Start-ups in Commercializing
University Inventions: Start-up Licensees at the University of California.” In
G. Libecap, ed., Entrepreneurial Inputs and Outcomes. Amsterdam: JAI Press.
- 2002. “Entrepreneurship and Information Asymmetry: Theory and Evidence
from the University of California.” Unpublished working paper, Haas School of
Business, University of California-Berkeley.
Maddison, A. 1987. “Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist Economies: Tech¬
niques of Quantitative Assessment.” Journal of Economic Literature 25: 649-98.
Maddon, P. J., D. R. Littman, M. Godfrey, D. E. Maddon, L. Chess, and R. Axel. 1985.
“The Isolation and Nucleotide Sequence of a cDNA Encoding the T Cell Surface
Protein T4: A New Member of the Immunoglobulin Gene Family.” Cell 42: 93-104.
Mansfield, E. r99r. “Academic Research and Industrial Innovations.” Research Policy
20: 1-12.
Marcy, W. 1978. “Patent Policy at Educational and Nonprofit Scientific Institutions.”
In W. Marcy, ed., Patent Policy: Government, Academic, and Industry Concepts.
Washington, D.C.: American Chemical Society.
Marx, J. r98o. “Gene Transfer Moves Ahead.” Science 210:1334-36.
Mazzoleni, R., and R. Nelson. 1998. “The Benefits and Costs of Strong Patent Protec¬
tion: A Contribution to the Current Debate.” Research Policy 27: 274-84.
McKusick, V. 1948. “A Study of Patent Policies in Educational Institutions, Giving Spe¬
cific Attention to the Massachusetts Institute of Technology.” Journal of the Franklin
Institute 245: 193-225.
Merges, R., and R. Nelson. 1994. “On Limiting or Encouraging Rivalry in Technical
Progress: The Effect of Patent Scope Decisions.” Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization 25: 1-24.
Merton, R. K. 1973. The Sociology of Science : Theoretical and Empirical Investigations.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mishra, U. 2001. Personal interview.
Mowery, D. C. 1981. “The Emergence and Growth of Industrial Research in American
Manufacturing, 1899-1945.” Ph.D. diss., Stanford University.
_1983. “The Relationship Between Intrafirm and Contractual Forms of Industrial
Research in American Manufacturing, 1900-1940.” Explorations in Economic His¬
tory 20: 351-74-
_ 1999. The Evolving Structure of University-Industry Collaboration in the United
REFERENCES
States: Three Cases, in Research Teams and Partnerships: Trends in the Chemical Sci¬
ences. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.
-2002. “The Changing Role of Universities in the 21st Century U.S. R&D Sys¬
tem.” In A. H. Teich, S. D. Nelson, S. J. Lita, eds., AAAS Science and Technology
Policy Handbook. Washington, D.C.: American Association for the Advancement of
Science.
Mowery, D. C., R. R. Nelson, B. N. Sampat, and A. A. Ziedonis. 1999. “The Effects of
the Bayh-Dole Act on U.S. University Research and Technology Transfer: An Analy¬
sis of Data from Columbia University, the University of California, and Stanford
University.” In L. Branscomb and R. Florida, eds., Industrializing Knowledge. Cam¬
bridge: MIT Press.
- 2001. “The Growth of Patenting and Licensing by U.S. Universities: An
Assessment of the Effects of the Bayh-Dole Act of 1980.” Research Policy 30:
"-ng.
Mowery, D. C., and N. Rosenberg. 1993. “The U.S. National Innovation System.” In
R. R. Nelson, ed., National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis. New York:
Oxford University Press.
-1998. Paths of Innovation: Technological Change in 20th-Century America. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Mowery, D. C., and B. N. Sampat. 2001a. “Patenting and Licensing University Inven¬
tions: Lessons from the History of the Research Corporation.” Industrial and Cor¬
porate Change 10: 317-55.
- 2001b. “University Patents, Patent Policies, and Patent Policy Debates, 1925-
1980.” Industrial and Corporate Change 10: 781-814.
Mowery, D. C., B. N. Sampat, and A. A. Ziedonis. 2002. “Learning to Patent: Institu¬
tional Experience and the Quality of University Patents.” Management Science 48:
73-89.
Mowery, D. C., and T. Simcoe. 2002. “The Origins and Evolution of the Internet.” In
D. Victor, B. Steil, and R. R. Nelson, eds., Technological Innovation and National
Economic Performance. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Mowery, D. C., and A. A. Ziedonis. 1998. “Market Failure or Market Magic? Structural
Change in the U.S. National Innovation System.” STI Review 22: 101-36.
- 2001. “The Geographic Reach of Market and Nonmarket Channels of Tech¬
nology Transfer: Comparing Citations and Licenses of University Patents.” Na¬
tional Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8568.
Mowery, D. C., and R. R. Nelson, eds. 1999. Sources Of Industrial Leadership: Studies
of Seven Industries. New York: Cambridge University Press.
National Research Council. 1982. “Research in Europe and the United States.” In
Outlook for Science and Technology: The Next Five Years. San Francisco: W. H.
Freeman.
- 1997. Intellectual Property Rights and Research Tools in Molecular Biology.
Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press.
National Resources Committee. 1938. Research—A National Resource. Vol. 1. Wash¬
ington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
National Science Board. 1996. Science and Engineering Indicators: 1996. Washington,
D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
REFERENCES
-2000. Science and Engineering Indicators: 2000. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬ 223
ernment Printing Office.
- 2002. Science and Engineering Indicators: 2002. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
National Science Foundation. 1958. Funds for Scientific Activities in the Federal Gov¬
ernment: Fiscal Years 1953 and 1954. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing
Office.
-1980. National Patterns of Science and Technology Resources: 1980. Washington,
D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
- 1994- National Patterns ofR&D Resources: 1994. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
-1996. National Patterns ofR&D Resources: 1996. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
- 1998. National Patterns ofR&D Resources: 1998. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
-2000. National Patterns ofR&D Resources 2000. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
-- 2001. National Patterns ofR&D Resources 2001. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov¬
ernment Printing Office.
Nelson, R. R. 1959. “The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research.” Journal of
Political Economy 67: 297-306.
- 1984. High-Technology Policies: A Five-Nation Comparison. Washington, D.C.:
American Enterprise Institute.
-1992. “What Is ‘Commercial’ and What Is ‘Public’ About Technology, and What
Should Be?” In N. Rosenberg, R. Landau, and D. C. Mowery, eds., Technology and
the Wealth of Nations. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
-, ed. 1982. Government and Technical Progress: A Cross-Industry Analysis. New
York: Pergamon.
- 093 • National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Nelson, R. R., and P. Romer. 1997. “Science, Economic Growth, and Public Policy.”
In B. L. R. Smith and C. Barfield, eds., Technology, R&D, and the Economy. Wash¬
ington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Noble, D. F. 1977. American by Design. New York: Knopf.
Office of Technology Transfer. 1997. Annual Report: University of California Technol-
ogy Transfer Program. Oakland: University of California Office of the President.
Okimoto, D., and G. Saxonhouse. 1987. “Technology and the Future of the Economy.”
In K. Yamamura and Y. Yasuba, eds., The Political Economy of Japan. Vol. 1, The
Domestic Transformation. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2000. A New
Economy? Paris: OECD.
-2002. Benchmarking Science-Industry Relationships. Paris: OECD.
Palmer, A. M. 1934. “University Patent Policies and Procedures.” Journal of the Patent
Office Society r6: 96-13^
_ J947- “Patents and University Research.” Law and Contemporary Problems 15:
680-94.
REFERENCES
233-34-
Shane, S. 2002. “Selling University Technology.” Management Science 48: 61-72.
Sharp, M. 1989. “European Countries in Science-Based Competition: The Case of
Biotechnology.” Designated Research Center Discussion Paper 72, Science Policy
Research Unit, University of Sussex, Brighton, U.K.
Simon, H. A. 1969. The Sciences of the Artificial. Cambridge: MIT Press.
The State of Academic Science: The Universities
Smith, B. L. R., and J. J. Karlesky. 1977.
in the Nation’s Research Effort. New York: Change Magazine Press.
Spencer, R. 1939. University Patent Policies. Chicago: Northwestern University Law
School.
Stanford University Office of Technology Licensing. 1983- Annual Report. Stanford,
Stanford University.
_1994a. Copyrightable Works and Licensing at Stanford. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford
University.
1994b. Office ofTechnology Licensing Guidelines for Software Distribution. Stan¬
Stata Corporation.
REFERENCES
226 Stephan, P. E., S. Gurmu, A. J. Sumell, and G. Black. 2002. “Patenting and Publish¬
ing: Substitutes or Complements for University Faculty?” Unpublished working pa¬
per, Georgia State University, Atlanta.
Stern, N. 1981. From ENIAC to Univac. Bedford, Mass.: Digital Press.
Stokes, D. E. 1997. Pasteur’s Quadrant: Basic Science and Technological Innovation.
Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Swann, J. 1988.Academic Scientists and the Pharmaceutical Industry: Cooperative Re¬
search in Twentieth-Century America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Thursby, J., R. Jensen, and M. Thursby. 2001. “Objectives, Characteristics and Out¬
comes of University Licensing: A Survey of Major U.S. Universities.” Journal of
Technology Transfer 26: 59-72.
Thursby, J., and M. Thursby. 2002. “Who Is Selling the Ivory Tower? Sources of
Growth in University Licensing.” Management Science 48: 90-104.
Tocqueville, A. de. 1990. Democracy in America, trans. by P. Bradley. New York:
Vintage.
Trajtenberg, M., R. Henderson, and A. B. Jaffe. 1997. “University Versus Corporate Pat¬
ents: A Window on the Basicness of Inventions.” Economics of Innovation and New
Technology 5:19-50.
Trow, M. 1979. “Aspects of Diversity in American Higher Education.” In H. Cans, ed.,
On the Making of Americans. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
- 1991. “American Higher Education: ‘Exceptional’ or Just Different.” In B. E.
Shafer, ed., Is America Different? A New Look at American Exceptionalism. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Trune, D., and L. Goslin. 1998. “University Technology Transfer Programs: A Profit/
Loss Analysis.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 57:197-204.
Trustees of Columbia University in the City of New York. 1944. “Statement of Research
Policy and Patent Procedures.” Columbiana Library, “Patents” folder, Columbia
University, New York.
U.S. Congress Joint Economic Committee. 1999. Entrepreneurial Ehmamism and the
Success of U.S. High-Tech: Joint Economic Committee Staff Report. Washington,
D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Department of Health Education and Welfare. 1974. DHEW Obligations to In¬
stitutions of Higher Education and Selected Nonprofit Organizations, FY1965-1972.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare.
Investigation of Government Patent Practices and
U.S. Department of Justice. 1947.
Policies: Report and Recommendations of the Attorney General to the President.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO). 1968. Problem Areas Affecting Usefulness of
Results of Government-Sponsored Research in Medicinal Chemistry: A Report to the
Congress. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
-1995. University Research: Effects of Indirect Cost Revisions and Options for Fu¬
ture Changes. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. House of Representatives. 1980. Floor Debate on H.R. 6933. Congressional
Record, 96th Congress, Second Session, November 21: 30556-60.
REFERENCES
U.S. Office of Management and Budget. 1963. “Memorandum and Statement of Gov¬ 227
ernment Patent Policy.” Federal Register 28: 10943-46.
- 1995- The Budget of the United States Government for Fiscal 1996. Washington,
U.S. Patent and Trademark Office. 1998. U.S. Colleges and Universities —Utility Patent
Grants, 1969-1998. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Senate Committee on the Judiciary. 1979a. S. Rpt. 96-480 Accompanying S. 414,
the University and Small Business Patent Procedures Act. Washington, D.C.: U.S.
Government Printing Office.
- 1979b. The University and Small Business Patent Procedures Act: Flearings on
S. 414, May 16 and ]une 6. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Senate Subcommittee of the Senate Select Committee on Small Business. 1963.
Walsh, J. P, A. Arora, and W. M. Cohen. 2003. “Research Tool Patenting and Licens¬
ing and Biomedical Innovation.” In W. M. Cohen and S. Merrill, eds., The Patent
System in the Knowledge-Based Economy. Washington, D.C.: National Academies
Press.
Wigler, M., S. Silverstein, L. S. Lee, A. Pellicer, Y. Cheng, and R. Axel. 1977. “Transfer
of Purified Herpes Virus Thymidine Kinase Gene to Cultured Mouse Cells. Cell
11: 223-32.
stein, and R. Axel. 1979. “Transformation of Mammalian Cells with Genes from
Wildes, K. L., and N. A. Lindgren. 1985. A Century of Electrical Engineering and Com¬
puter Science at MIT, 1882—1982. Cambridge: MIT Press.
228 Firm Strategy and Public Policy.” Ph.D. diss., Haas School of Business, University
of California-Berkeley.
Zinsser, A. 1927. “Problems of the Bacteriologist in His Relation to Medicine and the
academic patents: citations, 138-39; effect Ames II Tests: commercialization of, 172;
of, on basic research, 117-18; entrants vs. development of, 169,170,172; research
academic research: Bayh-Dole Act effects Ames Tests: description of, 170; University
ASET (consortium), 96
agriculture: applied research in, 38; univer¬
Atanasoff, John, 19
of Science (AAAS) patent policy report,
23O Axel cotransformation patent: before Bayh- patents, 209024; on technology transfer,
Dole Act, 109; Columbia University pat¬ 117, 206025, 206026, 206027; on univer¬
ents covering, 157; income for Columbia sity patenting, 36,46, 85,126; on univer¬
University, 166; licensing structure of, sity research culture, 128
113; as major advance in gene transfer, Bayh-Dole bill, 88-92; debate over, 20301;
156; nonexclusive licensing of, 159 issues ignored during arguments, 205018,
Axel-Maddon patents, royalties from, 175 205019; issues ignored during debate on,
AZT, 172 19603; non-exclusive licenses, 204011
Ben-David, J., 12
Babcock, Stephan, 19708 Bercovitz, J. E. L., 147
Babcock test, 11,19708 Best, Charles, 19708
Banks, B. A., 199025 Biogen, 174,175
Banting, Frederick, 19708 biomedical discoveries, reluctance to pat¬
Barbosa, James, 157 ent, 19707
Basel Institute of Immunology, 174 biomedical inventions: biotechnology
basic research, 10, 30; academic patents inventions as portion of, 208010; growth
effect on, 117—18; vs. applied research, in number of, 102—3; increase in patent¬
117; agency funding of, 26; classification ing of, 50; licensing income from, 55,
of, 19-20, 26; driving patenting and li¬ 127; reports of, at Columbia University,
censing, 95; federal funds for, 43; as fo¬ 109-10
cus of Bayh-Dole Act, 206026; growth in, biomedical patents: class identification of,
194-95012; by industry, 195-96015; in 209022; of entrant universities, 51, 53;
linear model of innovation, 177; in medi¬ generality analysis of, 132; growth in
cal sciences, 21,128; as source of eco¬ number of, 35-36,103; home-runs, 69;
nomic growth, 22-23, Hi *n U.S. univer¬ of incumbent universities, 51; MRI pat¬
sities, 20 ents, 201019;vs- nonbiomedical patents,
Bayh, Birch, 89, 90 patent importance of, 139
Bayh-Dole Act: amendments to, 188, 21402; biomedical research, federal funding of, 25
assumptions of, 27,153,177; becomes ef¬ biomedical sciences, 43,182
fective, 92-93; before and after data, 115; biotechnology inventions: broad patents in,
as catalyst for university patenting, 89, 93; feasibility of licensing, 126; as portion
93-94; emulation of, 95-97,179, of biomedical inventions, 208010; uni¬
206024; encouragement of entrant uni¬ versity research effect on, 28
versities, 137; growth in university patent¬ Birenbaum, L., 186
ing attributed to, 36, 46,181; impact on Bito, Laszlo, 166,167,168
Research Corporation, 84; incentives for Black, G., 118
inventor involvement, 153; issues ignored Blum, Fred, 165
during arguments, 92; justifications for, Blumenthal, D., 55,185,186,19708
92; limitations of, removed, 93; origins Bolton, Elmer, 195-96015
of, 85; passage of, 91; policy shifts in, 112; Boston Globe, 172
political history of, 86-93; provisions of, Bremer, Howard, 21301
91; role of, 179 Britain, 96
Bayh-Dole Act effects, 93-95; on academic Broad, W., 89
research, 85, 92,117,148,184, 209020; on Brown, Edmund G. Jr., 206-702
disclosure numbers, 105; on patenting Brown, Rachel, 71
and licensing, 52,129; on relative impor¬ Burton, R., 147
tance of academic and nonacademic Bush, Vannevar, 19, 22-23, 64, 86
INDEX
Jaffe, A. B., 118,119,121,125,126,127,129, at Yale University, 20601. See also cherry- 235
1997725, 209021, 209024, 21004, 210026 picking
Japan, 96 linear model of innovation, 34,177
Japanese universities, 96 Little, Arthur D., 16
Jensen, R., 91,152,168, 203035 Lodge, Sir Oliver, 59
Jones-Mangelsdorf patent, 71 Louis, K., 185
low-intensity incumbents: importance and
Kastenmeier, Robert, 205018 generality among, 21005; regression
Katz, M. L., 206023 coefficients for, i35(tab)
Kendall, Edward, 71 LumiLEDS, 163
Kennedy, John F., 87, 20405
Kilgore, Harley, 86 Maddon, Paul, 173,174
Kilgore bill, 20301 Madey v. Duke, 188, 21403
Kitch, E. W., 59 magnetic core memories, 71
klystron, 15 mainframe computers, 24
knowledge-based economy, 183 Manhattan Project, 22
knowledge spillovers, 202025, 202027 Mansfield, E., 27,28-29
Koch, Robert, 21 march-in rights, 93
Maron, Dorothy, 169,170
Lamont-Doherty Earth Observatory, 110 Matsushita, 160,163
Lamoreaux, N., 202025 Mauchly, John, 18,19
Lanjouw, J. O., 21107 Maxwell, J., 55,19708
large corporations vs. small business, 86, McKusick, V., 40,19601
204-5012, 205018 Medical Education in the United States
lasers and microwave transistors, 162 and Canada (Flexner, Abraham), 21
Latker, Norman, 20409 medical patents, 19707; opposition to, 38;
learning and learning curve: by entrant as revenue source, 56. See also biomed¬
universities, 130,131,137,143,145,147; by ical patents
networking, 147; and research budget, medical sciences, 21
211012 Memorandum on Governmental Patent Pol¬
ents, 155-56; decline in yield of, 116; dur¬ engineering curricula established, 14;
ing depression era, 63; distribution of, and IBM relationship, 72; patent policy
65; at Florida State University, 20601; of, 64; relationships with industry, 17; Re¬
and home-run patents, 84; and patent ci¬ search Corporation and Invention Ad¬
ministration Agreement (IAA), 63-65;
tations, 128; shift from focus on, 84; from
site licenses, 207—808, 208013; from sol¬ wartime R&D expenditures, 22
uble CD4 treatments, 213019; at Stanford MIT IAA with Research Corporation, 63-
65; MIT IAA cancellation, 71-72; MIT’s
University, io2(tab), 106,112, 20601; at
University of California, io2(tab), 104, Forrester patent, 84; origins of, 20008
112, 20601; from university patenting, 127; molecular biology, development of, 44
INDEX
public vs. private universities: growth pat¬ IBM, 72; net royalty income, 79(fig); op¬
ent management role of, 52; university erating costs growth, 77; origins of, 59-
patent policies of, 46,49 60; patent management, 40, 61; patent
Purdue University: research foundation at, management costs growth, 72-73; patent
management scale of, 65; patent reve¬
40
nues source, 56; patents issued to,
68(fig); patents of, 53; patent withhold¬
Quaker Oats, 39
ing, 77, 2027129; purpose of, 60; relation¬
R&D projects: external information ship with entrants, 138; reliance on bio¬
medical patents, 69; role of, 181; share of
sources in, 32(tab)
U.S. university patents, 8o(fig); Stanford
Rai, A. T., 188
income from, 45; support to Research
Rajchman, Jan, 71, 72
Corporation Technologies (RCT), 81-
RCA, 71
82; total costs per IAA, 78(fig); total oper¬
Reagan, Ronald, 93
ating costs, 78(fig); universities trained in
recombinant DNA method, 156, 21205
patent management by, 75-76; visitation
Reimers, Niels, 147, 21205
and marketing efforts of, 73-75; World
Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute (RPI), 14
War II effects on, 65. See also cherry-
Report on Government Patent Policy (1978),
picking; electrostatic precipitators; MIT
90 r ... IAA with Research Corporation; Patent
research: commercialization of, 15; publi¬
Management Division
cation of, 17
INDEX
university-industry research links: charac¬ and basic research, 38; before the Bayh-
teristics of, 179; growth of, 184; postwar, Dole act, 35-57; benefits and risks of,
184-92; characteristics of, 137-47; co¬
195015; prewar, 41
transformation, 156-58; difficulties with,
University of Akron, 12
199-200/17; direct involvement of uni¬
University of California: Ames II Tests, roy¬
versities in, 46-47; dispersion and entry
alty payments for, 171; before and after
in, 50-53; entry, importance and gener¬
patent analysis, 118; biomedical disclo¬
ality in, 131-37; entry and experience, ef¬
sures, io3(fig); biomedical inventions of,
fects of on, 129-48; gallium nitride, 163-
103; biomedical patents, 103; biomedical
64; growth of, 47-48, 50, 56,182,198/116;
technology license share, io7(fig); Board
INDEX
'
.
*