CBDC
CBDC
Introduction
The idea of “Central Bank Digital Currencies” (CBDC) is not a recent development. Some
attribute the origins of CBDCs to Nobel laureate James Tobin 2, an American economist,
who in 1980s suggested that that Federal Reserve Banks in the United States could make
available to the public a widely accessible ‘medium with the convenience of deposits and
the safety of currency.’ It is only in the last decade, however, that the concept of digital
currency has been widely discussed by central banks, economists & governments.
2. Except as currency notes, all other use of paper in the modern financial system, be it
as bonds, securities, transactions, communications, correspondences or messaging – has
now been replaced by their corresponding digital and electronic versions. On anecdotal
evidence, use of physical cash in transactions too has been on the decline in recent years,
a trend further reinforced by the ongoing Covid19 pandemic. These developments have
resulted in many central banks and governments stepping up efforts towards exploring a
digital version of fiat currency. Some of this interest among central banks has been
indigenous in nature for pursuing specific policy objectives – for example, facilitate
negative interest rate monetary policy. Another driver is to provide the public with virtual
currencies, that carry the legitimate benefits of private virtual currencies while avoiding the
damaging social and economic consequences of private currencies.
What is a CBDC?
3. It is important to understand and appreciate what precisely is a CBDC, and to do that
one needs to understand what a currency is and what money is.
What is a currency?
4. Let us start with money. As societies developed from hunters and gatherers material
needs increased – to build a house, wear clothes, make weapons and implements etc.
Since these needs could not be produced individually, people had to purchase them from
others. These purchases were paid initially by barter – a leather skin cloak for a spear,
maybe. As barter had its limits – how many cloaks for a spear – barter got standardized
in terms of metals or cowrie shells. Now people knew the value of both the cloak and the
1
Keynote address delivered by Shri T Rabi Sankar, Deputy Governor, Reserve Bank of India, on July 22nd, 2021
at the webinar organised by the Vidhi Centre for Legal Policy, New Delhi. The views expressed by the speaker
are personal.
2
https://law.stanford.edu/projects/central-bank-digital-currencies-a-transatlantic-perspective/
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
spear in terms of bronze or cowrie shells. This was still barter, as both bronze and shells
had intrinsic value (shells were desired for their beauty). This system evolved over time
into metal currencies. Gold and silver coinage were the offshoot of this system where they
had features of barter (both gold and silver had intrinsic value) as well as money (they
were standardized representation of value). Somewhere along the way people improvised
– instead of actual goods for barter they started using claims on goods, a bill of exchange
in fact. These could be clay tablets in Mesopotamia or, as in China in the eleventh century,
paper currency.
2
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
9. A line of argument that has helped private virtual currencies gain some degree of
legitimacy is that most money in modern societies is in fact already private since they
represent deposit liabilities of private banks. There are two factors that are conveniently
pushed under the carpet. One, deposits are issued by banks under license of the
sovereign issuer of currency (usually the central bank). Two, deposits are accepted by the
public only because they are convertible one-to-one into sovereign currency. A simple way
to understand the distinction is to look at deposits as lending of sovereign currency to
banks by the public, on interest (credit, its opposite side, is lending of sovereign currency
by banks to the public, on interest). Bank deposits are money, certainly, but they have no
independent existence as money, shorn of sovereign authority and the resultant public
confidence. In any case bank deposits are very different from private currencies which (a)
do not have an issuer, and (b) are not convertible one-to-one into the sovereign currency.
10. To sum up, CBDC is the same as currency issued by a central bank but takes a
different form than paper (or polymer). It is sovereign currency in an electronic form and it
would appear as liability (currency in circulation) on a central bank’s balance sheet. The
underlying technology, form and use of a CBDC can be moulded for specific requirements.
CBDCs should be exchangeable at par with cash.
3
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
12. In addition, CBDCs have some clear advantages over other digital payments systems
– payments using CBDCs are final and thus reduce settlement risk in the financial system.
Imagine a UPI system where CBDC is transacted instead of bank balances, as if cash is
handed over – the need for interbank settlement disappears. CBDCs would also
potentially enable a more real-time and cost-effective globalization of payment systems.
It is conceivable for an Indian importer to pay its American exporter on a real time basis
in digital Dollars, without the need of an intermediary. This transaction would be final, as
if cash dollars are handed over, and would not even require that the US Federal Reserve
system is open for settlement. Time zone difference would no longer matter in currency
settlements – there would be no ‘Herstatt’ risk.
14. India is leading the world in terms of digital payments innovations. Its payment systems
are available 24X7, available to both retail and wholesale customers, they are largely real-
time, the cost of transaction is perhaps the lowest in the world, users have an impressive
menu of options for doing transactions and digital payments have grown at an impressive
4
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
CAGR of 55% (over the last five years). It would be difficult to find another payment system
like UPI that allows a transaction of one Rupee. With such an impressive progress of
digitisation, is there a case for CBDCs?
15. A pilot survey conducted by the Reserve Bank on retail payment habits of individuals
in six cities between December 2018 and January 2019, results of which were published
in April, 2021 RBI Bulletin (please see charts below) indicates that cash remains the
preferred mode of payment and for receiving money for regular expenses. For small value
transactions (with amount up to ₹500) cash is used predominantly.
16. There is thus a unique scenario of increasing proliferation of digital payments in the
country coupled with sustained interest in cash usage, especially for small value
transactions. To the extent the preference for cash represents a discomfort for digital
modes of payment, CBDC is unlikely to replace such cash usage. But preference for cash
for its anonymity, for instance, can be redirected to acceptance of CBDC, as long as
anonymity is assured.
17. India’s high currency to GDP ratio holds out another benefit of CBDCs. To the extent
large cash usage can be replaced by CBDCs, the cost of printing, transporting, storing
and distributing currency can be reduced.
18. The advent of private virtual currencies (VCs) may well be another reason why CBDCs
might become necessary. It is not clear what specific need is met by these private VCs
that official money cannot meet as efficiently, but that may in itself not come in the way of
5
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
their adoption. If these VCs gain recognition, national currencies with limited convertibility
are likely to come under threat. To be sure, freely convertible currencies like the US Dollar
may not be affected as most of these VCs are denominated in US Dollar. In fact, these
VCs might encourage the use of US Dollar, as has been argued by Randal Quarles 3.
Developing our own CBDC could provide the public with uses that any private VC can
provide and to that extent might retain public preference for the Rupee. It could also
protect the public from the abnormal level of volatility some of these VCs experience.
Indeed, this could be the key factor nudging central banks from considering CBDCs as a
secure and stable form of digital money. As Christine Lagarde, President of the ECB has
mentioned in the BIS Annual Report “… central banks have a duty to safeguard people's
trust in our money. Central banks must complement their domestic efforts with close
cooperation to guide the exploration of central bank digital currencies to identify reliable
principles and encourage innovation.”
19. The case for CBDC for emerging economies is thus clear – CBDCs are desirable not
just for the benefits they create in payments systems, but also might be necessary to
protect the general public in an environment of volatile private VCs.
21. At the same time reduced disintermediation of banks carries its own risks. If banks begin
to lose deposits over time, their ability for credit creation gets constrained. Since central banks
cannot provide credit to the private sector, the impact on the role of bank credit needs to be
well understood. Plus, as banks lose significant volume of low-cost transaction deposits their
interest margin might come under stress leading to an increase in cost of credit. Thus, potential
costs of disintermediation mean it is important to design and implement CBDC in a way that
makes the demand for CBDC, vis-à-vis bank deposits, manageable.
3
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/quarles20210628a.htm
6
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
22. There is another risk of CBDCs that could be material. Availability of CBDC makes it easy
for depositors to withdraw balances if there is stress on any bank. Flight of deposits can be
much faster compared to cash withdrawal. On the other hand, just the availability of CBDCs
might reduce panic ‘runs’ since depositors have knowledge that they can withdraw quickly.
One consequence could be that banks would be motivated to hold a larger level of liquidity
which could result in lower returns for commercial banks.
23. In actual fact, notwithstanding the benefits of CBDCs vis-à-vis bank deposits, since CBDCs
are currency and therefore do not pay interest, their impact on bank deposits may actually be
rather limited. Depositors that require CBDCs for transactional purposes are likely to sweep
day end balances to interest-earning deposit accounts.
25. Much recent discussion has focussed on the use of negative interest-bearing CBDCs for
effectiveness of monetary policy, for a specific reason. The extremely low inflationary
environment in many advanced economies has constrained their ability to reduce interest
rates as negative interest rates are not effective because of the shift to cash. However,
monetary transmission of negative policy rates to boost demand would be more effective if
currency itself can carry a negative interest rate. Hence the argument in favour of payment of
negative interest rate on CBDC as an unconventional monetary policy tool to boost spending.
Such steps may need to be taken with care as any instrument that pays interest (positive or
negative) is strictly not a currency.
27. Absorption of CBDCs in the economy is also subject to technology preparedness. The
creation of population scale digital currency system is contingent upon evolution of high speed
7
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
internet and telecommunication networks and ensuring the wider reach of appropriate
technology to the general public for storing and transacting in CBDCs. In developing countries,
lower level of technology adoption may limit the reach of CBDCs and add to existing
inequalities in terms of accessing financial products and services.
29. Generally, countries have implemented specific purpose CBDCs in the wholesale and
retail segments. Going forward, after studying the impact of these models, launch of
general purpose CBDCs shall be evaluated. RBI is currently working towards a phased
implementation strategy and examining use cases which could be implemented with little
or no disruption. Some key issues under examination are – (i) the scope of CBDCs –
whether they should be used in retail payments or also in wholesale payments; (ii) the
underlying technology – whether it should be a distributed ledger or a centralized ledger,
for instance, and whether the choice of technology should vary according to use cases;
(iii) the validation mechanism – whether token based or account based, (iv) distribution
architecture – whether direct issuance by the RBI or through banks; (v) degree of
anonymity etc. However, conducting pilots in wholesale and retail segments may be a
possibility in near future.
Legal Framework
30. Although CBDCs are conceptually no different from banknotes, introduction of CBDC
would require an enabling legal framework since the current legal provisions are made
keeping in mind currency in paper form. Under the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934, the
Bank is empowered to “…regulate the issue of bank notes and the keeping of reserves with a
view to securing monetary stability in India and generally to operate the currency and credit
system of the country to its advantage” (Preamble). The Reserve Bank derives the necessary
statutory powers from various sections of the RBI Act – with respect to denomination (Section
24), form of banknotes (Section 25), status as legal tender (Sec 26(1)) etc. There is a need
8
Speech: Central Bank Digital Currencies: Is this the Future of Money?
to examine consequential amendments to other Acts like The Coinage Act, 2011, FEMA,
1999, Information Technology Act, 2000 etc. Even though CBDCs will be a primarily
technology driven product, it will be desirable to keep the legislation technology neutral to
enable coverage of a variety of technology choices.
Conclusion
31. Introduction of CBDC has the potential to provide significant benefits, such as reduced
dependency on cash, higher seigniorage due to lower transaction costs, reduced
settlement risk. Introduction of CBDC would possibly lead to a more robust, efficient,
trusted, regulated and legal tender-based payments option. There are associated risks,
no doubt, but they need to be carefully evaluated against the potential benefits. It would
be RBI’s endeavour, as we move forward in the direction of India’s CBDC, to take the
necessary steps which would reiterate the leadership position of India in payment
systems.
CBDCs is likely to be in the arsenal of every central bank going forward. Setting this up
will require careful calibration and a nuanced approach in implementation. Drawing board
considerations and stakeholder consultations are important. Technological challenges
have their importance as well. As is said, every idea will have to wait for its time. Perhaps
the time for CBDCs is nigh.
***