HSIR Endsem
HSIR Endsem
net/publication/320274062
CITATIONS READS
0 1,353
1 author:
June Zaccone
Hofstra University
17 PUBLICATIONS 3 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by June Zaccone on 08 October 2017.
Abstract: There aren’t many geniuses in economics. John Maynard Keynes was one. He revolutionized the way we understand how the
economy works, and even how we measure its workings. Those who say "consumers are the main job creators" have absorbed a major
lesson of Keynesian economics But this is not the only one. Though our version has been called Bastard Keynesianism, it has helped to
stabilize the US economy and reduce unemployment in the postwar era. We saw this most recently during the financial crisis, yet the
theory remains controversial. Why? And what opened the theory to attack?
[Slide1] A gold bug newsletter in 2009 put John Maynard Keynes, the most important economist of the
20th century, in the category of wanton revolutionary, a belief shared by other conservatives:
Lord Keynes, along with Vladimir Lenin ranks among the most destructive forces unleashed by World War I. Keynes was a
Fabian socialist who provided intellectual cover for inflationism. He was more subtle than Lenin, more a termite than a thug.
He... author[ed] bogus economic theories that turned classical economics on its head, undermined Western values..., and enslave
us to this day. 1
It is far more plausible that he saved capitalism and liberal democracy. For example, Hitler’s policies had reduced
unemployment to 1% by 1936, while ours was still over 14%. 2 Of course, many capitalists don’t admit they need
saving, at least until a financial crisis. Ironically, the rejection of Keynes and market regulation in favor of
financial globalization, with its crises and austerity, has created conditions for an authoritarian world. 3 My plan is
to describe Keynesian theory and why it met opposition [Slide2] despite its success. Notice the wider swings of
output [black line] and longer recessions [shaded areas] before WW2. I’ll end with the neoliberal counterattack and
updates to Keynes.
Keynes was no socialist, Fabian or otherwise. A biographer reports that he “always thought of himself as a
man of the Left. But the Left to him simply meant the Liberal Party4..... [though] the emergence of a powerful
critic of Establishment policies from within the Establishment was a great boon to the Left.” 5 He was ambivalent
about capitalism. As his colleague Joan Robinson, described him, “Morally and aesthetically, capitalism disgusted
him, while at the same time he felt that the system was the ‘best in sight’ and must be defended.” 6 Though he was
clever at making money, he considered moneymaking merely a means of living “wisely, agreeably, and well,” 7 not
a goal. Pursuing money for its own sake he thought “a somewhat disgusting morbidity.” 8
An advocate of markets, Keynes didn’t dispute the answers to the traditional economic questions of what to
produce, how to produce, and who benefits. To those proposing state ownership of resources, he answered, "there
is no objection to be raised against the classical analysis of the manner in which private self-interest will determine
what in particular is produced, in what proportions the factors of production will be combined to produce it, and
how the value of the final product will be distributed between them," 9 though he considered inequality an
economic impediment. However, he was a practical problem-solver and shifted his position when he saw fit. When
Churchill sent Keynes a cable reading, “Am coming around to your point of view,” Keynes replied, “Sorry to hear
it. Have started to change my mind.” 10
2
A key to understanding Keynes is that unlike most economists today, his major goal was to eliminate
unemployment: the “real problem, fundamental yet essentially simple…[is] to provide employment for
everyone.” 11 His target for unemployment is “the sort of level we are experiencing in wartime ... less than 1%.” 12
He objected to an economy which produced far less than it could, a waste which left millions unemployed in
economies where work is not merely social status, but livelihood.
He said,
“...the labor of the unemployed is available to increase the national wealth. It is crazy to believe that we
shall ruin ourselves financially by trying to find means for using it and that safety lies in continuing to
maintain idleness.” 13
Once full employment is achieved, markets can be allowed to work freely, and “there is no more reason to
socialize economic life than there was before." 14 However, another comment in his major work, The General
Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, suggested that a “socialization of investment,” including public-
private partnerships, might be necessary to secure full employment. 15
What was the economic orthodoxy against which Keynes was rebelling? It was what he had learned at
university and once used as a practitioner at the highest levels of British academia and government, especially the
British Treasury and as a Bank of England official. 16 What Keynes termed the “classical theory” assumed that the
economy can manage itself. Beset by recession—even the depression of the 1930’s—the economy soon rights
itself. This theory adopted Say’s Law: “supply creates its own demand,” meaning that whatever is produced can
be sold. 17 If there is a surplus of goods, prices fall, leading consumers to buy more and producers to make less. If
savers provide more funds than businesses are willing to invest, interest rates on loans fall, leading to more
investment and less saving. Same with unemployment—wages will fall, so firms hire more workers, while others
leave the job market. Involuntary unemployment, meaning unemployed workers willing to accept the going wage,
is impossible. Nothing need be done. In fact, doing anything will only make things worse. Economists believed
that problems of long-term unemployment arise only if wages are prevented from falling.
Preceding the 1930’s depression, there was too little union power to blame unions; too little regulation to
blame regulation; and too much government support of business to blame government for the disaster. Inequality
was at levels resumed only in the late 1990’s. As the Wall St. Journal described the Coolidge era in 1927, “Never
before, here or anywhere else, has a government been so completely fused with business.” 18
The unfortunate Herbert Hoover had, as a candidate in 1928, promised “a chicken in every pot and an
automobile in every garage,” chicken being a luxury then. 19 Instead, his Administration, faced with economic
collapse and deficits created by falling tax revenues, made depression worse by raising taxes in 1932—“the largest
peacetime tax increase in U.S. history.” 20 It is difficult to imagine now, given our enormous deficits, that there
was such a fear of the modest deficits of the 1930’s. State and local governments raised taxes, too. Hoover had
declared in June 1930: “The Depression is over.” 21 It of course continued until WWII. Roosevelt further increased
3
taxes and cut spending in 1937. This was followed by recession within the Depression. The Federal Reserve
contributed to the fiasco by tightening credit. Clearly, Keynesian policy had not yet been firmly established.
How much did Keynes influence the New Deal? 22 Not a lot. Keynes had sent world leaders a version of
his policy by 1933, 23 and New Deal policy matched some of his recommendations: repair the banks, devalue the
currency, and build public works to stimulate the private sector. 24 But not in scale. When Keynes met President
Roosevelt just over a year later, he had decided that while the New Deal had commendably spent $2.8 billion on
the crisis, it was too little. In an open letter to the president, 25 he estimated that another $2.4 billion was needed
over the next six months—enough to raise the total to the $5 to $6 billion range that Roosevelt had rejected as
“wild.” Roosevelt told Labor Secretary Frances Perkins, “I saw your friend Keynes. He left a whole rigmarole of
figures. He must be a mathematician rather than a political economist.” 26 Roosevelt’s response was probably not
because he didn’t understand the math, but because he did—what was required was politically impossible. Keynes
had described to Perkins the effects of spending: “...a dollar spent on relief by the government was a dollar given to
the grocer, by the grocer to the wholesaler, and by the wholesaler to the farmer, in payment of supplies. With one
dollar paid out for relief or public works or anything else, you have created four dollars’ worth of national
income.” 27 This describes the multiplier effect, an important tool of fiscal policy. [Fiscal policy means taxes or
spending.] Many Conservatives reject it, believing the multiplier is zero because government spending displaces
other spending. 28
The New Deal in fact was not very ideological—its policies were a pragmatic response to crisis. Its most
important early economic policy was putting people directly to work, still a good idea. Harry Hopkins, a social
worker, was put in charge of the Civil Works Administration in the fall of 1933. Hopkins created four million jobs,
mainly in construction, in the few months before it was ended in March 1934. 29
A bold fiscal policy during the Depression faced problems: in 1929, federal spending was under 4 percent
of GDP. To absorb the unemployed, federal spending needed to replace investment, which had collapsed. From
16% of output in 1929, it plunged to 3% of a far smaller output by 1933. 30 The federal share would have had to
rise by a multiple. That was both politically and practically impossible. With federal spending, including transfers
like Social Security, now nearly 21% of output, 31 the government can far more easily manage the economy with
modest fiscal changes. 32 Full employment awaited the military spending of WW 2.
The lack of information also impeded action: concepts and measures of income that we use now were
formulated because of the Depression. Despite these shortcomings, the New Deal accomplished a great deal by
putting millions, including artists and writers, back to work. The structures that its workers created are with us
still. We can visit over a thousand in New York City alone, like Brooklyn College, the Central Park Zoo, or
LaGuardia Airport. 33
After his visit, Keynes noted “this so-called ‘Bolshevik’ administration has saved the capital financial
structure,” called the recovery historically outstanding, and concluded, “The whole difficulty that confronts this
4
liberal Administration is a world problem: can liberalism and democracy last out,—that is the problem everywhere.
Most American business leaders lack imagination and have no apprehension of the problem facing their society, if
it is to survive.” 34
Who was this economist who created a theoretical revolution? [Slide3] Keynes came from privilege at its
best —loving, intelligent and attentive parents who were intellectually and politically engaged, as well as
financially comfortable. His mother, Florence, was a writer, a social reformer active in helping the poor and
unemployed, and a politician. She was the first woman on the Cambridge City Council. 35 His father, John Neville
Keynes, was a renowned economist in his day. Philosopher Bertrand Russell called the son one of the most
intelligent people he had ever known. "Every time I argued with Keynes, I felt that I took my life in my hands and
I seldom emerged without feeling something of a fool." Born in 1883, Keynes showed an early gift for
mathematics. His education included some home schooling, Eton, and Cambridge University, where he earned a
mathematics degree. An early book was A Treatise on Probability. Russell, who co-authored Principia
Mathematica, described it as "undoubtedly the most important work on probability that has appeared for a very
long time." 36 Keynes’s professional career began in 1906, with an appointment to the British civil service. It
quickly bored him. Returning to teach at Cambridge, he first worked on probability theory, and then became an
economics lecturer in a post funded by famed economist Alfred Marshall. 37 In subsequent years, he worked for the
British Treasury, and was its chief representative at the Versailles Conference in 1919 ending WWI. He wrote an
important work, The Economic Consequences of the Peace, criticizing reparations imposed on Germany. “Keynes
brought a glittering array of talents” 38 to his work, combining theoretical brilliance in economic analysis with
practical problem-solving. He described his best ideas as coming “from ‘messing about with figures and seeing
what they must mean.’” 39 His enormous self-confidence, intellect and passionate engagement in social affairs
made him a successful and sought after participant in both academia and government. His personality contained
contradictions: he is described as “by turns charming and insupportable, cutting and kind, snobbish and
unpresuming; the public person is profoundly serious, extraordinarily hard-working, crushingly intelligent.” 40
[Slide4] At the Bretton Woods Conference in 1944, he and Harry Dexter White, representing the US, were
architects of the postwar trading system. US dominance of the agreement partially thwarted the aims of more
stable economies and high employment. 41 Keynes “...was by every account...an enormously persuasive negotiator,
quite willing to settle for the attainable, however distant that might be from the ideal.” 42
Keynes was a member of the famed Bloomsbury group, which included Virginia Woolf, apparently was
bisexual as he had affairs with several of its members, 43 and married in 1925. [Slide5] His wife was Lydia
Lopokova, chosen by Diaghilev for the Ballets Russes. 44 She had danced with Nijinsky and Ashton, married a
bigamist in New York, and had affairs with Igor Stravisky, among others. Her dancing charmed audiences with its
delicacy and ebullience. [Slide6] As a British newspaper described the marriage, “With the exception of Arthur
Miller and Marilyn Monroe, there can have been no odder celebrity couple....” Their snobbish circle ridiculed
5
them. Virginia Woolf wrote, “They say you can only talk to Maynard now in words of one syllable,” though she
later came to admire Lydia’s intelligence and artistry. [Slide7] Lytton Strachey described her as a “half-witted
canary.” 45 Nevertheless, it was clearly a successful love match. 46 E.M. Forster later regretted “how we all used to
underestimate her.” She was a supportive wife, and thought his major work “beautiful like Bach.” “Without her
constant attention and joie de vivre, Keynes might not have made it to Bretton Woods.” 47 Keynes died of a second
heart attack at age 62 in April 1946, shortly after returning from contentious loan negotiations in the US. He
predeceased both of his parents. 48
In economics, Keynes began as a monetarist, believing that the economy could be stabilized by varying
interest rates, a theory unfortunately with us still. However, when British unemployment reached levels as high as
20% in the interwar period, it was clear that monetarism was insufficient. His ideas changed dramatically. He
began advocating public works as early as the 1920’s. His work eventually revolutionized economic theory. It
changed the standard practice of budget balance in favor of deficit spending during economic downturns. Keynes,
at least, expected that they’d be offset with surpluses as inflation threatened. 49 He didn’t acknowledge the work of
predecessors with grace. He refers to earlier underconsumption theories as “liv[ing] on furtively, below the surface
in the underworlds of Karl Marx” and others.
Let’s look more closely at his major work, The General Theory. Economic theory is important, both in
explaining economic phenomena, and guiding measurement. According to Keynes, income is determined by
spending. This theory is the reason our income and output accounts are measured as they are. 50 During the
Depression, information about the state of the economy was scarce, so Congress asked the Dept. of Commerce to
come up with income measures. It issued the first series of output data and income data by industry and type of
income in 1934, updating the last complete income accounts from 1929. 51 Monthly data were not available until
1938. The first complete output data, including major expenditure categories, appeared in early1942, with a final
version basically in place by 1947. Government officials of the 1930’s had to cope without good or timely
information of what had gone wrong and to what extent programs were effective. Wartime mobilization was done
without good data.
Because income depends on spending, the question is, what determines spending? Total spending is the
sum of spending by each major economic group--households, government, the foreign sector, and businesses.
These categories are chosen because each has a different motivation. Consumer spending depends on many
variables, but our income is the most important. Income includes both earnings and transfer payments like
Social Security. Government spending depends not only on its income, but on politics. Foreign sector
spending, which is exports minus imports, depends on the value of the dollar, and tastes and income here and
abroad. Business spending---investment---depends on expectations of profit from adding capacity, not on profits
from existing plant.
6
Those words--expectations and adding capacity—are significant: they account for the variability of
investment. "Expectations" means that the climate of opinion influences business decisions. Their outcome is
uncertain because the future is unpredictable. This psychological base implies that decisions can change rapidly.
"Profits from adding capacity" means that firms must have a reason to add plant or equipment. Profit on current
sales, however great, won’t induce firms to expand output. This will only happen if they expect that the output
from building more plants or buying new machinery can be profitably sold. So high current profits don't
necessarily mean that firms will make new investments. [A busy, profitable store that served local people in my
modest neighborhood doubled its size and aimed at a higher-income clientele. Within a few months it was gone. It
had doubled costs without increasing customers. The owners had been misled by current profits. ] Summing up,
the motivation for firms to invest requires that something has changed. If sales are not higher than existing plant
can produce, if no new equipment is available that will pay for itself by reducing costs, if a new product is not
available, or if their expectations about the future are no brighter, there is no reason to invest. 52
In Keynesian theory, what equates saving to investment is not the interest rate, as in Classical theory, but
income changes. Neither investment nor saving depends primarily on the interest rate. If consumers save more than
businesses want to invest, then output will fall, reducing household incomes until their saving does match
investment. Investment determines saving rather than the reverse. Though saving is individually rational, it can
cause recession. If households try to save more, and this saving is not offset by spending elsewhere, output will
decline and saving will fall. 53 This is the reason some have said that consumers are the real job-creators. You can
also see how important research and development are to continued high investment. Government is one supporter
of R and D. Transistors, jet engines, computers, 54 the internet--all these were developed through military funding,
and all have inspired important new investments by private firms and new goods to tempt consumers. Keynes
believed that as economies became richer and households saved a larger fraction of income, the chronic problem of
insufficient investment for full employment would become worse. 55 Thus the need for a larger role for public
investment.
What made the acceptance of Keynesian policy and the relatively egalitarian growth of the postwar period
possible? Several things: first, the Depression delegitimized capitalism and its economic model. Keynesian theory
explained why that model had failed, and provided an alternative. The 1937 slump, which resulted from a return to
“sound finance,” provided a test, dramatically illustrating that cutting spending and increasing taxes could make
unemployment worse. 56
WWII was also a test: the economy flourished, supporting both the war and [Slide8] the highest
consumption ever achieved. Note the black bar measuring consumption rises to the 1929 level by 1941, then
continues to exceed it right through the war. And it’s understated because soldiers’ consumption is included in
government spending. [Slide9] All despite debt [blue line] now considered ruinous--up to 120% of output.
Postwar, the unparalleled global competitiveness of US companies made them willing for a time to share rising
7
output per worker with a militant labor force. The threat of unionization and the expectation of a rising standard of
living extended benefits gained by unions to a wider labor force. Our succeeding history suggests that this era was
an aberration.
Many analysts worried about a postwar recession and return to high unemployment. Our government had
adopted Keynes’s idea of compulsory saving, that is, war bonds and taxation, not only deficit spending, to finance
the war. This good advice helped to stem both inflation and a postwar slump. 57 Transition to a postwar economy
was fairly smooth, thanks to war bonds and pent-up demand for consumer goods, but problems were visible early.
[Slide10] Despite the Marshall Plan and enormous recovery needs from the Depression and war shortages, the US
suffered a minor recession in 1949, with unemployment rising to 7% for part of the year. Wartime output reached
a historic maximum in 1944, not reached again until 1951, the first full year of the Korean War, 58 and a tripled
military budget.
Muting Conservative opposition to public spending meant finding projects which don’t compete with the
private sector. Public housing competes with private; publicly financed medicine competes with private insurers;
unemployment payments increase worker bargaining power. One answer was found in military spending, which,
far from competing, supports the private sector—providing markets, supporting R and D, and protecting foreign
markets and assets. 59 Keynes had described the utility of useless output to economic progress: “Just as wars have
been the only form of large-scale loan expenditure which statesmen have thought justifiable, so gold-mining is the
only pretext for digging holes in the ground which has recommended itself to bankers as sound finance.” 60
In 1949, the success of the Chinese revolution and Soviet test of an atomic bomb, large Communist parties
in Europe, rising anti-colonial movements in the Third World, and a challenging though weak Soviet Union [SU],
raised concerns about maintaining supremacy of the US economic model. Our chronic insufficiency of spending
was an important weakness shaping policy. Conservative economist Milton Friedman’s economic dictum was
"There is no free lunch." In contrast, a colleague, Soviet expert Lynn Turgeon, described the US and the SU,
respectively, as the Free Lunch Economy and the No Free Lunch Economy. By this he meant that the US usually
has sufficient unused production capacity and unemployed workers to increase output without more machines or
workers, i.e., the US could have a free lunch; the SU could not--it was always operating close to full capacity. This
difference meant that the real cost to the US of providing foreign aid and building a formidable military, the lost
alternative goods and services, was far less than for the SU. In fact, for the US this cost is usually not just zero, but
negative--that is, our standard of living improves as a consequence of higher spending. Our chronically underused
capital and labor means, for example, that filling a non-existent "missile gap" helped our economy, but meant a
sacrifice for the Russians. The US situation was obvious to some policy-makers. For example, Dean Acheson, at
that time Assistant Secretary of State, testified in 1944:
“You don't have a problem of production. The United States has unlimited creative energy. The important thing is markets.
...You must look to foreign markets.” 61
8
Military Keynesianism, as it is called, has been one way of getting assent to government spending on machines and
research, thereby supporting economic growth. [Slide11] Military spending as a share of GDP reached a peak of
nearly 40% during World War 2, and postwar peak of 15% during the Korean War. The Soviets always were using
a larger fraction of their output for military, about 60% during WW 2. Our proposed military budget for next year,
including such items as veterans’ affairs and homeland security, is $1.1 Trillion, 62 about 6% of GDP. Though the
share has diminished, the military buys 10% of factory output. 63 The recent budget increase alone is enough to pay
tuition for every public university student in the country, with billions to spare. 64
Conceptually, the policy began with NSC 68, in 1950, 65 a secret document of the National Security
Council declassified in 1975. Its argument was that military spending would harm Soviet growth while enhancing
ours.
... in contrast to ours, [the capabilities of the Soviet world] are being drawn upon close to the maximum possible extent. .…. No
matter what efforts Moscow might make, only a relatively slight change in the rate of increase in overall production could be
brought about. 66
Its economic thesis, that military spending would be good for the US economy and bad for the Soviets, helped to
shape Cold War strategy. 67
Though Keynesian theory has been controversial for much of its history, for a time even Richard Nixon
proclaimed, “We are all Keynesians now.” The theory was accepted not only because of its success, but because
the most controversial parts were ignored or misinterpreted. Those that undercut support for inequality and policies
that implied long-term problems, like the socialization of investment, were dropped.
Keynes believed any return above cost of production, called economic rent, was unwarranted. Here he is in
the Classical tradition. Smith and Ricardo despised rent-receivers, like landlords whose rents rose only because
larger populations forced the use of less fertile land. Keynes considered capital artificially scarce, and proposed
eliminating both its scarcity and the return based on it. This would leave returns to skill, risk and entrepreneurship,
all productive. Keynes advocated driving the interest rate to zero. 68 His theory removed a major buttress for
inequality—saving, rather than necessary, impedes capital formation. He said, “One of the chief social
justifications of great inequality...is, therefore, removed.” 69
In our day, rents proliferate, like high prices for coops near the Met Breuer, 70 or corporate managers using
profits to buy company stock to drive up its price rather than investing. Rentier activities like oil, real estate and
minerals get tax privileges. 71 Returns exceeding the growth rate promote inequality. 72 A Harvard Business Review
article reports that rents have risen at the expense of both the wage and capital share. 73 In the opinion of Nobelist
Angus Deaton, “rent-seekers like the banking and the health-care sectors just might [kill capitalism].” Rent-
seeking slows growth: “All that talent is devoted to stealing things, instead of making things,” he says. 74
Also damaging to the theory were reinterpretations, like the early and successful attempt to make
the General Theory compatible with classical theory, called the neoclassical synthesis. 75 This combined watered-
down Keynesian macroeconomics with classical micro, like wage setting. Most notable in this effort was Paul
9
Samuelson, first economics Nobelist and author of a highly popular textbook, published in1948. 76 Joan Robinson,
a distinguished economist and colleague of Keynes, called this school “Bastard Keynesians,” 77 many now called
New Keynesians. 78 Some, like Paul Krugman, claim the problem of recession is sticky wages: “...shortfalls in
overall demand would cure themselves if only wages and prices fell rapidly in the face of unemployment. In
reality prices don’t fall quickly....” 79 This contradicts Keynes—he pointed out that falling wages would make
matters worse by reducing consumer spending. Further, the successful expansion of the postwar era led
economists to treat the theory as merely a short-term remedy for business cycles. A British Labour official
described this “Keynesian consensus” as “thinking...of our economic difficulties as arising from... market failures,
irrationalities,... inflexibilities, ... and the like—as events that are somehow abnormal.... This ...is profoundly
misleading. ....The whole history of capitalist society reveals nothing if not the unwelcome normalcy of such
events.” 80 Editors of a Marxist journal add,
"This sanitized version ... dropped much of the concern with inequality and social spending....Bastard
Keynesians proclaimed that, with smart government policies, the system would work beautifully. The stagflation
of the 1970s demolished this belief and left establishment Keynesianism largely discredited. ...it increasingly was
framed as the cause of capitalism’s growth problems, not the cure.” 81
Keynesian theory proved inadequate to the counterattack for other reasons. Michal Kalecki pointed out the
political problem in 1943. 82
The assumption that a government will maintain full employment in a capitalist economy if it knows how to do it is fallacious.
[With] permanent full employment, ‘the sack’ would cease to play its role as a disciplinary measure.... The workers would get
out of hand and the captains of industry would be anxious ‘to teach them a lesson.’ ...big business and rentier interests... would
probably find more than one economist to declare that the situation was manifestly unsound. 83
Economic genius requires deep understanding of the structure and dynamics of a system constantly
changing. This is hard: the originator of Quantum Theory told Keynes that “he had thought of studying
economics, but had found it too difficult.” 84 It is easier to be a great physicist than a great economist. Economic
analysis, however brilliant, is historically-bound, and eventually undermined by changes that contradict its
assumptions. Adam Smith’s prescient description of an emerging market system is now irrelevant. In his time,
government-granted monopolies like the East India Company were the only source of market control. Excluding
them would not produce a completely level playing field, but would be close enough to self-regulating markets.
New producers could enter an industry and undermine a monopoly firm’s market power. Governments still grant
monopolies through patents, but there are other sources of market power, like technology, political influence or
sheer size. A company like Goldman Sachs can use these to influence its markets.
Keynes’s theory is also time-bound. Globalization and finance have changed the way policy works. Both
undermine the effectiveness of fiscal policy. Rising incomes fund more imports, for example, undercutting
government stimulus. The financial sector’s revenues may be used for unproductive investment, like the leveraged
buyout 85 of the now bankrupted Toys R US. The unleashed financial sector gave us three crises in the last thirty
10
years 86 and is far more powerful than in the 1930’s, when New Dealers could regulate it. Not now. Despite the
worst crisis since the Depression in 2008, the system is still at risk. 87
Some theorists have updated Keynes’s work on finance. [Slide12] According to Hyman Minsky’s
financial-instability hypothesis, a long period of stability, like the postwar, obscures the potential for instability. In
fact, it creates conditions for the next crisis by inducing businesses to take on more risk, risk that can only be
justified by extravagant hopes. Expansion generates optimism and talk about the “death of the business cycle.” In
the 1990s, the “new economy” was supposed to have killed the business cycle by cementing faster productivity
growth. The dot.com bubble collapsed in 2000. In the 2000s, better monetary policy was credited with taming the
business cycle. Ben Bernanke, at that time on the Fed Board, called the low-wages, low inflation regime of Federal
Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan “the Great Moderation. 88 This is the Minsky cycle at work. Businesses became
more confident about the future and exercised less caution in taking out loans. 89 That bubble collapsed in late
2007.
Moreover, optimism infects all economic actors—regulators, businesses, banks, and home-buyers.
Economists, intoxicated by years of stability, supposed that they were permanent. Here is the 2003 assessment of
then president of the American Economic Association, Robert Lucas, a long-time anti-Keynesian:
[the] central problem of depression prevention has been solved, for all practical purposes....There remain important gains... from
better fiscal policies, but ... these are gains from providing people with better incentives to work and to save, not from better fine-
tuning of spending flows. 90
Minsky’s policies to prevent depression include government as employer of last resort to maintain both jobs and
profits; and the Federal Reserve regulating financial institutions by anticipating changes that might affect stability
rather than waiting to respond to disaster. 91
The most important attack on Keynes and the welfare state was neoliberalism. 92 Inspired by 19th century
laissez-faire, neoliberals advocate privatization, deregulation, free trade, and limited government, especially social
93
welfare spending. In Margaret Thatcher’s aphorism, “there is no society, only individuals.” A German
sociologist describes it as “a demobilization ...of the entire post-war machinery of democratic participation and
redistribution.” 94
What gave us this new economic regime? The corporate counterattack and shift in economic philosophy
began in 1971 with a memo by the soon to be Supreme Court justice Lewis Powell, and with the collapse of
Bretton Woods, beginning then. 95 The memo urged businesses to seek power and use it “aggressively.” 96 This was
a reaction to the progressive changes of the sixties. Post-Bretton Woods, international currency values changed
from fixed to fluctuating rates. Volatility of foreign-exchange rates created profit opportunities for Wall Street. 97
A phenomenal shift in policy began between 1978 and 1980. 98 In 1978, China began liberalizing its
command economy; Thatcher became British Prime Minister and Paul Volcker 99 became head of the Federal
Reserve in 1979; and Reagan became President in 1980. Their policies curbed labor power, deregulated the
economy and accelerated financial deregulation. 100 The Clinton Administration freed finance from New Deal
11
restraints in the 1990’s, inspired by his Treasury Secretary, Robert Rubin, who then went on to Citigroup.
International capital flows increased, growth slowed, private and public debt rose, and financial crises occurred
more frequently. 101 The corporate world’s goal became maximizing shareholder value, mostly ignoring the welfare
of workers and communities. These may be connected to the corporation longer than shareholders.
The Soviet collapse in 1989 permitted an era of American triumphalism. Reagan, Bush and the Democrats
who followed them dismantled major regulations of the New Deal, weakened unions and welfare programs, and
negotiated trade agreements that encouraged outsourcing. 102 Neoliberals believed that their policies would ensure
stability and steady growth, and should be a model for all countries. Thatcher called it TINA--there is no
alternative. Lending institutions like the World Bank force it on debtor countries. 103
When the most dangerous crisis since the 1930’s came in 2008, it met a tepid fiscal response, accompanied
by a bailout of financial miscreants. Even that response was criticized by anti-Keynesians, including Nobel
Laureates. 104 In early 2010, despite an unemployment rate of 9.7%, President Obama created, over Senate
objection, the National Commission on Fiscal Responsibility and Reform with two deficit hawks as co-chairs. 105 It
was charged with creating a “grand bargain”—a compromise agreement to reduce the debt by cutting Social
Security, Medicare and military spending, and increasing taxes. 106 Fortunately, the compromise failed, succumbing
to Republican intransigence. [Slide13] Financial Times commentator Martin Wolf ridiculed the debt-mongers with
this graph, showing British debt at 250% of income during the industrial revolution. 107
The Administration went into the midterm election with unemployment higher than when it began, and a
stimulus far smaller than many experts thought sufficient. Larry Summers, who was responsible for keeping it
modest, now says, “I think in the end we would've been better served if there had been more push to the
economy.” 108 The current recovery is the slowest of the postwar era. It took eight years for unemployment to
recover its prerecession level. 109 [SLIDE14] Compare Reagan’s ample government spending [red line] with
Obama’s [blue line]. Private sector weakness was reinforced as federal jobs were cut every year from 2011 through
2013, and inflation-adjusted Federal spending on goods and services declined every year from 2011 through
2014. 110 Is it surprising that Democrats became the minority party around the country? 111 The Congressional
Budget Office estimates our potential output in 2017 at 10% below the level it had projected in 2008, before the
worst of the recession—a loss of roughly $2 trillion a year, or $6000 per person, imposed by the austerity agenda.
Economist Dean Baker points out that, for future generations, this is like a yearly tax increase. 112
What then about the debt created by anti-recessionary policy that is so worrisome to conservatives? 113
Keynes considered deficits acceptable as a means of offsetting deficiencies in private spending. However, unlike
his critics, he did not expect that his policies would generate massive, continuing deficits and inflation. His perhaps
too blithe comment was, “look after the unemployment, and the Budget will look after itself.” 114 [Slide15] Keynesian
Abba Lerner believed that, during major recessions, there is no inflationary pressure. Then, he recommended,
12
deficits should be financed not by debt, but by Federal Reserve credit creation, in the vernacular, printing
money. 115
Keynes thought Lerner’s policy impractical, 116 as he considered the investment problem to be long-term for
rich countries with high savings and limited investment opportunities. He therefore expected a permanent role for
public investment, up to 20% of output, referring to “the socialization of investment.” 117 Given the volatility of
private investment, this would have a major stabilizing role. 118 Further, government spending sufficient to ensure
full employment would eliminate large budget deficits. In Keynes’s view, deficits result from the failure to reach
full employment. Deficits would occur only during minor recessions. 119 While public investment should be at least
partly debt-financed, the ordinary budget would usually be in surplus.
Since the 1990’s, there has been a counterattack against austerity. [Slide16] Modern Monetary Theory
extends Lerner, and provides an alternative to private credit creation. This theory asserts that the only reason to tax
is to control the level of spending. Greenspan would agree. Asked about the solvency of Social Security, he
replied, "There's nothing to prevent the federal government from creating as much money as it wants and paying it
to someone." 120 He added that the real question is whether goods are there for beneficiaries to buy. This implies
that government can minimize deficits by creating money to pay for its programs. 121 This would let us avoid the
austerity imposed by those claiming “there is no money,” though money is there for tax cuts, bailouts, or military
adventures. Currently, the important question of how much money we need is mostly decided by private banks, not
public officials. It is little understood that bank profits come mostly from creating money.
The Bank of England explains: 122
One common misconception is that banks act simply as intermediaries, lending out the deposits that savers place with them. ....In
123
reality, commercial banks are the creators of deposit money …. the act of lending creates deposits.
In 2017, a large US bank could extend $9 in loans, that is, create money, for every dollar in deposits. 124
Pavlina Tcherneva and some others of this school argue that Keynesian theory is also misinterpreted as
proposing solely to increase aggregate demand generally, raising the likelihood of inflation. 125 Rather, Keynes
preferred directed spending, like public works, to create employment, both during recessions and for
unemployment that continues even when an economy is near full employment. Remember that his target for
unemployment was less than 1%. 126 Keynes thought it ‘‘easy to employ 80 to 90 percent of the national
resources...” but “To employ [the rest], including labor, we would be ‘more in need . . . of a rightly distributed
demand than of greater aggregate demand.’” 127 Because “full, or even approximately full, employment is a rare
and short-lived occurrence,” 128 policy should aim to stabilize investment, not consumption, by public works. If
true, this is of enormous importance, as it would avoid the inflation that occurs if the policy is limited to increasing
aggregate spending. 129 Public works can be directed to geographic areas of need and specifically to unused
resources.
13
How well have the promises of neoliberalism been kept? US median annual earnings during the Bretton
Woods era rose steadily until 1972. [Slide17] Then throughout the neoliberal era, real wages for men [blue line]
have stagnated. Now women’s [purple line] are stagnating, too. Catching up with productivity increases [green
dashes] is better for women than catching up with men. It would raise women’s wages by 70%. [Slide18] Global
growth rates have slowed as debt burdens soared, and the investment share declined. 130 [Slide19] Consumer debt
[red line], which rivals business and government debt, is worrisome, as households have neither the government’s
power to increase revenues nor to create money. [Slide-20] Student loan debt is over one-third of non-housing
debt. A German sociologist attributes to these failures the birth of “a new sort of political deceit...the expert lie. It
began with the Laffer Curve.” This predicted that lower tax rates would raise revenues, justifying the Reagan tax
cuts. 131
Then has neoliberalism failed? No. Its global reach continues, as corporations gain access to markets and
cheap labor through trade agreements that restrict government action. Governments continue to appoint Goldman
Sachs alumni to jobs, both here and abroad. Obama had several 132 and so does Trump, including Secretary of the
Treasury, chair of the SEC, and chief economic adviser. 133 Our rules continue to leave much of the social surplus
in the hands of a few. Globalizers tout the benefits without trying to offset their uneven distribution or even noting
them. [Slide21] Alan Greenspan, former Federal Reserve Chair, 134 acknowledged during hearings on the financial
crisis
“Those of us who have looked to the self-interest of lending institutions to protect shareholders’ equity... are in a state of shocked
disbelief.”.... [to the question] Do you feel that your ideology pushed you to make decisions that you wish you had not
made?” Greenspan answered: “Yes, I’ve found a flaw.” 135
A form of privatized Keynesianism helped create the bubble that burst in 2008: households with lagging income
were induced to use debt to buy houses and maintain spending. 136
Anatole Kaletsky, writing for the Financial Times, describes our current plight. Capitalism, when it is
successful, provides material progress that mutes political pressure. It ceases to be acceptable when, in Keynes’s
phrase, “it doesn’t deliver the goods.” 137 It didn’t during the Depression and it doesn’t now.
1
www.federalobserver.com/wp-content/uploads/2009/03/the-once-and-future-money-bob-landis.pdf and
http://www.goldensextant.com/LLCPostings4.html#anchor237271
2
Lynn Turgeon, Bastard Keynesianism, p.1. Our data from https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/M0892AUSM156SNBR
3
http://www.primeeconomics.org/articles/is-globalisation-dead
4
The Liberals created the beginnings of the British welfare state. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Liberal_Party_(UK)
5
“Keynes and Beatrice Webb now embarked on an improbable friendship based on mutual fascination, much incomprehension, but
a shared belief in social science and public service.” http://www.skidelskyr.com/site/article/doing-good-and-being-good/
6
http://www.nybooks.com.ezproxy.hofstra.edu/articles/1967/01/26/smoothing-out-keynes/
7
Robert Skidelsky, Keynes: The Return of the Master,75. From Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren
8
http://www.skidelskyr.com/site/article/keynes-in-the-long-run/
9
Keynes, General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, ch. 24, pp.378-9. He continued, “ I see no reason to suppose that the
existing system seriously misemploys the factors of production which are in use.”
10
He is said to have replied to a critic, “When I find new information I change my mind; What do you do?”
http://quoteinvestigator.com/2011/07/22/keynes-change-mind/
11
Tcherneva, Keynes’s Approach to Full Employment: Aggregate or Targeted Demand? Levy, Working Paper No. 542, 8/08, p.6.
14
12
Tcherneva, “Permanent On-The-Spot Job Creation—The Missing Keynes Plan for Full Employment and Economic Transformation,”
Review of Social Economy, 70 (1) 66 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00346764.2011.577348, 65-6. Keynes, Collected Wks, v.27, 303.
13
www.levy.org/pubs/wp_542.pdf
14
Keynes, General Theory, Concluding Notes, p. 379.
15
Keynes, General Theory, p. 378. By 1943, Keynes thought that eventually, reduced work time would be a better solution than private
investment. “...the full employment policy by means of investment is only one particular application of an intellectual theorem. You can
produce the result just as well by consuming more or working less. Personally I regard the investment policy as first aid. In U.S. it almost
certainly will not do the trick. Less work is the ultimate solution (a 35 hour week in U.S. would do the trick now).” Quote from a letter to
TS Eliot, and Keynes, 1943: “The Long-Term Problem of full employment,” https://ecologicalheadstand.blogspot.com/p/long-term-
problem-of-full-employment.html
16
Robert Skidelsky, Keynes: The Return of the Master, 80
17
“Rick Perry showed up at a coal plant this week and invoked a novel economic theory to explain his push to expand coal mining in an
age of declining coal use. ‘Here’s a little economics lesson: supply and demand. You put the supply out there and the demand will
follow.’” https://www.counterpunch.org/2017/07/07/93955/
18
Quoted by Arthur Schlesinger, Crisis of the Old Order, p. 61.
19
http://review.chicagobooth.edu/magazine/summer-2013/simon-kuznets
20
To that date. www.ebhsoc.org/journal/index.php/journal/article/download/205/207
21
https://www.nytimes.com/2017/04/13/technology/artificial-intelligence-automation-report.html
22
“They [Keynes and Roosevelt] met in 1934, but most observers believed that Keynes had little impact on the president’s thinking.
Although Keynes’s ideas were in circulation by 1933, the lag between academic advances and their use in policy tends to take decades.....
Several of Roosevelt’s advisers also argued for using government programs as a stimulus, but they followed a different logical path for
their arguments.” https://www.cfr.org/content/thinktank/Depression/Fishback_NewDeal_Chapter.pdf
23
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/John_Maynard_Keynes
24
Means to Prosperity http://crookedtimber.org/2013/06/17/the-queer-personality-and-floating-mind-what-did-keynes-say-to-and-about-
roosevelt-2/
25
NY Times, June 10, 1934.
26
http://crookedtimber.org/2013/06/17/the-queer-personality-and-floating-mind-what-did-keynes-say-to-and-about-roosevelt-2/
27
http://crookedtimber.org/2013/06/17/the-queer-personality-and-floating-mind-what-did-keynes-say-to-and-about-roosevelt-2/
28
Like Robert Lucas: “Rational-expectations economists supposed that fiscal policy would be undermined by forward-looking taxpayers.
They should understand that government borrowing would eventually need to be repaid, and that stimulus today would necessitate higher
taxes tomorrow. They should therefore save income earned as a result of stimulus in order to have it on hand for when the bill came due.
The multiplier on government spending might in fact be close to zero, as each extra dollar is almost entirely offset by increased private
saving.” http://www.economist.com/news/economics-brief/21704784-fiscal-stimulus-idea-championed-john-maynard-keynes-has-gone-
and-out
29
The CWA's workers laid 12 million feet of sewer pipe and built or improved 255,000 miles of roads, 40,000 schools,
3,700 playgrounds, and nearly 1,000 airports (not to mention building 250,000 outhouses still badly needed in rural America). The
program was praised by Alf Landon, who later ran against Roosevelt” in 1936. It was abandoned under criticism by conservatives, who
argued it produced little of value. WPA replaced it. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Civil_Works_Administration
30
https://www.bea.gov/scb/pdf/2011/08%20August/0811_gdp_nipas.pdf GDP=103.6B and I=16.5B in 1929; 56.4B and 1.7B resp,
in 1933.
31
Interest is 1.4%. http://www.cbpp.org/research/federal-budget/program-spending-as-a-percent-of-gdp-historically-low-outside-social
32
In 2016, F=3.85tr; S/L=3.5 [almost =]; 34% 2015 including trs. 2016: SS=5%; medicare=3+%; welfare & Medicaid-6%
http://www.usgovernmentspending.com/welfare_spending_analysis Total f/s/l: 36% GDP in 2017
33
See the Living New Deal: https://livingnewdeal.org/map/
34
1934. http://crookedtimber.org/2013/06/17/the-queer-personality-and-floating-mind-what-did-keynes-say-to-and-about-roosevelt-2/
35
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Florence_Ada_Keynes
36
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/A_Treatise_on_Probability
37
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/John_Maynard_Keynes
38
Robert Skidelsky, Keynes: Return of the Master, 76.
39
Skidelsky, ibid., 78.
40
https://www.theguardian.com/books/2015/mar/08/universal-man-seven-lives-john-maynard-keynes-review and
http://www.nytimes.com/books/98/12/06/specials/skidelsky-keynes.html
41
“... the point of the system that Keynes hoped to design was to prevent imbalances between nations — that is, one nation owing too much
to another, thus causing onerous debt repayments.... Keynes — along with the equally brilliant founder of Buddhist Economics..., EF
Schumacher — proposed something really radical, revolutionary, beautiful, transformative. History’s first ultranational currency, Bancor.
Bancor wasn’t a currency that you or I could hold: only governments could hold it, only gold could be exchanged for it, only the IMF could
lend and settle it, and... if you held too much, you’d be charged interest....It was the single most brilliant institutional design probably in
human history.....Because America was the stronger party in the post-war negotiations, Bancor never came to be. Why did America object
15
to Bancor? Largely for selfish reasons: so the dollar could become the world’s reserve currency.” https://medium.com/bad-words/why-the-
world-is-better-off-without-american-leadership-40f774faf44a
42
Robert Lekachman, “The Radical Keynes,” in Harold Wattel, The Policy Consequences of John Maynard Keynes, 36-7.
43
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/John_Maynard_Keynes
44
The Keyneses later were backers of the Royal Ballet.
45
https://www.lrb.co.uk/v30/n24/alison-light/lady-talky
46
http://www.dailymail.co.uk/home/books/article-1017464/Beauty-Brain.html May 8, 2008.
47
https://www.lrb.co.uk/v30/n24/alison-light/lady-talky
48
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/John_Maynard_Keynes
49
The first government to adopt demand management policies was Sweden in the 1930s.
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Keynesian_Revolution
50
http://www.economist.com/news/briefing/21697845-gross-domestic-product-gdp-increasingly-poor-measure-prosperity-it-not-even
51
The data discussion is based on Marcuss & Kane, “U.S. National Income and Product Statistics Born of the Great Depression and
World War II,” SCB, https://www.bea.gov/scb/pdf/2007/02%20February/0207_history_article.pdf Output data were measured from
industries like services, finance, manufacturing, and govt; income by wages and salaries in selected industries, dividends, rents, interest,
etc.
52
“These days, “pre-crash (2006), over 30 percent of the profits of American corporations classified as “industrial” came from financial
transactions rather than the production of goods and provision of services.” https://www.brookings.edu/wp-
content/uploads/2016/06/Whose-Capital-What-Gains.pdf
53
This is the paradox of thrift.
54
Transistors needed for missile guidance. Defense agencies, such as the Office of Naval Research, Army Research Office, Air Force
Office of Scientific Research, and Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency, invested in computing research with long-term effects
on military capabilities (and, indirectly, civilian capabilities). 1945 The ENIAC built at the University of Pennsylvania and funded by the
Army Ballistic Research Laboratory, was America's first such machine.
55
Keynes, “It is certain that the world will not much longer tolerate the unemployment which, apart from brief intervals of excitement, is
associated and in my opinion, inevitably associated with present-day capitalistic individualism.” General Theory, 381. See also
Skidelsky, “Keynes believed that, under laissez-faire, full employment levels of investment were achieved only in moments of excitement
strong enough to overcome the uncertainty normally attaching to estimates of future returns. The normal tendency was for the propensity
to save to be stronger than the inducement to invest. Moreover, this problem would grow more acute the richer societies became, because
people tended to save a higher fraction of higher incomes even as perceived (and actual) opportunities for profitable investment declined.”
Keynes: The Return of the Master, 198.
56
Joan Robinson, “Smoothing Out Keynes,” NYRB 1/26/67.
57
“... Keynes argued in How to Pay for the War...[1940], that the war effort should be largely financed by higher taxation and especially
by compulsory saving (essentially workers lending money to the government), rather than deficit spending, in order to avoid inflation.
Compulsory saving would act to dampen domestic demand, assist in channelling additional output towards the war efforts, would be
fairer than punitive taxation and would have the advantage of helping to avoid a post war slump by boosting demand once workers were
allowed to withdraw their savings.” https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/John_Maynard_Keynes
58
began June, 1950
59
As Times columnist Thomas Friedman has told us, ‘The hidden hand of the market will never work without a hidden fist -- McDonald's
cannot flourish without McDonnell Douglas, the builder of the F-15. And the hidden fist that keeps the world safe for Silicon Valley's
technologies is called the United States Army, Air Force, Navy and Marine Corps.”
http://www.nytimes.com/books/99/04/25/reviews/friedman-mag.html
60
“Two pyramids, two masses for the dead, are twice as good as one; but not so two railways from London to York.” General Theory,
130-1.
61
James E. Cronin, The World the Cold War Made, p.22.
https://books.google.com/books/about/The_World_the_Cold_War_Made.html?id=YmhX0qYrA48C
62
http://www.pogo.org/straus/issues/defense-budget/2017/americas-1-1-trillion-national-security-budget.html GDP c $19tr 2017, ERP
63
https://www.nytimes.com/2017/09/22/business/economy/military-industrial-complex.html
64
Budgeted increase is about $80B. http://fair.org/home/outlets-that-scolded-sanders-over-deficits-uniformly-silent-on-700b-pentagon-
handout/
65
https://rwer.wordpress.com/2016/12/27/military-keynesianism-and-the-military-industrial-complex/
66
https://fas.org/irp/offdocs/nsc-hst/nsc-68-5.htm
67
“An extraordinary new Pentagon study [A t O u r O w n P e r i l : D o D R i s k A s s e s s m e n t i n a P o s t - P r i m a c y W o r l d ,
6/17, Nathan P. Freier, Col. (Ret.) Christopher M. Bado, Dr. Christopher J. Bolan, Col. (Ret.) Robert S. Hume, Col. J. Matthew Lissner.
https://ssi.armywarcollege.edu/pubs/display.cfm?pubID=1358 Statregic Studies Inst, US Army War College--my files]
has concluded that the US-backed framework of international order established after World War II is “fraying” and may even be
“collapsing,” leading the United States to lose its position of “primacy” in world affairs. The solution proposed to protect US power in
this new “post-primacy” environment is, however, more of the same: more surveillance, more propaganda (“strategic manipulation of
perceptions”) and more military expansionism.”
16
68“euthanasia of the rentier” General Theory, 376. “...the amount of capital needed to operate an economy at full
employment is limited, and once achieved, the marginal return to capital will drop to the point that it merely covers
depreciation, obsolescence, and a small return for risk and for managerial skill and judgment. ‘Now, though this state of affairs
would be quite compatible with some measure of individualism, yet it would mean the euthanasia of the rentier, and, consequently, the
euthanasia of the cumulative oppressive power of the capitalist to exploit the scarcity-value of capital.’”
https://shadowproof.com/2013/02/10/euthanasia-of-the-rentier/
69
General Theory, 373.
70
http://michael-hudson.com/2016/10/rentier-capitalism-veblen-in-the-21st-century/
71
Minerals, timber, oil and gas get a depletion allowance. Real estate gets depreciation, value appreciates.
72
Hudson interview, https://harpers.org/blog/2017/06/slow-crash/
73
https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2017-06-21/the-wrong-kind-of-entrepreneurs-flourish-in-america based on
https://hbr.org/2017/06/is-america-encouraging-the-wrong-kind-of-entrepreneurship
74
“Nobel economist takes aim at rent-seeking banking and healthcare industries,” http://www.marketwatch.com/story/nobel-economist-takes-aim-at-
rent-seeking-banking-and-healthcare-industries-2017-03-06
75
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Keynesian_Revolution
76
“To complete the reconciliation of Keynesian economics with general equilibrium theory, Paul Samuelson introduced the neoclassical
synthesis in 1955. According to this theory, if unemployment is too high, the money wage will fall as workers compete with each other
for existing jobs. Falling wages will be passed through to falling prices as firms compete with each other to sell the goods they produce. In
this view of the world, high unemployment is a temporary phenomenon caused by the slow adjustment of money wages and money
prices. In Samuelson’s vision, the economy is Keynesian in the short run, when some wages and prices are sticky. It is classical in the
long run when all wages and prices have had time to adjust.” http://evonomics.com/new-keynesian-economics-betrays-keynes/
77
Lynn Turgeon, Bastard Keynesianism, p. 113.
78
https://larspsyll.wordpress.com/2013/06/05/paul-krugman-a-bastard-keynesian/
79
Krugman, The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008, pp 182-3. Quoted in John Eatwell & Murray Milgate, The Fall
and Rise of Keynesian Economics, 13. In any case, wages did decline during the Depression.
80
Eatwell and Milgate, op. cit., p. 16. Eatwell is a noted British Keynesian.
81
https://monthlyreview.org/2010/04/01/listen-keynesians-its-the-system-response-to-palley/
82
http://delong.typepad.com/kalecki43.pdf
83
Kalecki, Political Aspects of Full Employment, https://mronline.org/2010/05/22/political-aspects-of-full-employment/
https://www.socialeurope.eu/a-macroneconomic-revolution
84
Max Planck, quoted by Keynes in Alfred Marshall’s obit: Economic Journal, V. 34, N. 135 (Sep., 1924), p. 333, fn 2. http://semillero-
hpe.wikispaces.com/file/view/Keynes24+-+Alfred+Marshall.pdf
85
https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2017/09/toys-r-us-another-private-equity-casualty.html
86
A banking crisis in the early 1980’s https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Early_1980s_recession#Financial_industry_crisis the dot.com in the
late 1990’s and the 2008 financial crisis.
87
https://www.bloomberg.com/view/articles/2017-08-10/there-s-still-too-much-risk-in-the-financial-system
andhttps://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2017/sep/14/the-financial-system-is-still-blinking-red
88
in 2004. https://monthlyreview.org/2010/04/01/the-limits-of-minskys-financial-instability-hypothesis-as-an-explanation-of-the-crisis/
and https://newleftreview.org/II/97/adam-tooze-just-another-panic
89
Minsky distinguished between three kinds of financing. ...“hedge financing”, is the safest: firms rely on their future cashflow to repay
all their borrowings. For this to work, they need to have very limited borrowings and healthy profits. The second, speculative financing, is
a bit riskier: firms rely on their cashflow to repay the interest on their borrowings but must roll over their debt to repay the principal. This
should be manageable as long as the economy functions smoothly, but a downturn could cause distress. The third, Ponzi financing, is the
most dangerous. Cashflow covers neither principal nor interest; firms are betting only that the underlying asset will appreciate by enough
to cover their liabilities. If that fails to happen, they will be left exposed..... When speculative and, especially, Ponzi financing come to the
fore, financial systems are more vulnerable. If asset values start to fall, either because of monetary tightening or some external shock, the
most overstretched firms will be forced to sell their positions. This further undermines asset values, causing pain for even more firms.
They could avoid this trouble by restricting themselves to hedge financing. But over time, particularly when the economy is in fine fettle,
the temptation to take on debt is irresistible. When growth looks assured, why not borrow more? Banks add to the dynamic, lowering their
credit standards the longer booms last. If defaults are minimal, why not lend more? Minsky’s conclusion was unsettling. Economic
stability breeds instability. Periods of prosperity give way to financial fragility.” http://www.economist.com/news/economics-
brief/21702740-second-article-our-series-seminal-economic-ideas-looks-hyman-minskys
90
Robert Lucas, “Macroeconomic Priorities,” AER 3/2003, cited by John Eatwell & Murray Milgate, The Fall and Rise of Keynesian
Economics, p.2.
91
“Just as there never really was a Keynesian revolution in economic theory, there also never really was one in policy. […] All that was
assimilated from Keynes by the policy establishment and its clients was the analysis of an economy in deep depression and a policy tool
of deficit financing. […]The institutional structure has not been adapted to reflect the knowledge that the collapse of aggregate demand
and profits, such as occasionally occurred and often threatened to occur in pre-1933 small government capitalism, is never a clear and
present danger in Big Government capitalism such as has ruled since World War II. (Minsky 1986: 291, 295)” Eric Tymoigne, Minsky
17
and Economic Policy: “Keynesianism” All Over Again? , Levy WP #547, p.22. Government should act as both employer and lender of
last resort. Minsky, “Financial Instability and the Decline (?) of Banking: Public Policy Implications,” Hyman P. Minsky Archive. Paper
88. http://digitalcommons.bard.edu/hm_archive/88 p. 9. Minsky also recommended eliminating corporate income taxes as they encourage
debt finance, which is destabilizing. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, 354.
92
https://monthlyreview.org/2017/04/01/who-is-behind-the-assault-on-public-schools/
93
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Neoliberalism
94
NLR104, March-April 2017
95
For instance, from about the 1930s to the 1980s, many countries had policies of financial regulation that included many of the
following: 1. Interest rate ceilings 2. Liquidity ratio requirements 3. Higher bank reserve requirements 4. Capital Controls (that is,
restrictions on capital account transactions) 5. Restrictions on market entry into the financial sector 6. Credit ceilings or restrictions on the
directions of credit allocation 7. Separation of commercial from investment (“speculative”) banks 8. Government ownership or
domination of the banks. (Ito 2009: 431–433). https://socialdemocracy21stcentury.blogspot.com/2009/11/financial-deregulation-and-
origin-of.html
96
http://billmoyers.com/content/the-powell-memo-a-call-to-arms-for-corporations/
97
Gowan, “Crisis in the Heartland, “ New Left Review 55 jan feb 2009. “...as recently as 1975 roughly 80% of foreign exchange
transactions involved the real trading of a product or a service. The remaining 20% were speculative.... By the late 90s that ratio had
changed dramatically. In 1997 the percentage of foreign exchange which involved transactions in the real economy was only 2.5%.
Today, the picture is even starker. According to the Global Policy Forum, in 2011 only 0.6% of foreign exchange could be traced to
genuine international trade in goods and services. Of the rest, a minimum of 80% was directly attributable to exchange rate speculation.....
An estimated $5.3tn changes hands every day in the foreign exchange markets. That is an entire year's worth of the European Union's
GDP, gambled every three days.” https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2013/nov/20/money-trading-economy-foreign-exchange-
markets-economy
98
http://bilbo.economicoutlook.net/blog/?p=37018 Alan Blinder commented ...that by: “… about 1980, it was hard to find an American
macroeconomist under the age of 40 who professed to be a Keynesian. That was an astonishing turnabout in less than a decade, an
intellectual revolution for sure.”
99
“The standard of living of the average American has to decline." http://www.nytimes.com/1979/10/18/archives/volcker-asserts-us-
must-trim-living-standard-warns-of-inflation.html
100
David Harvey, A Brief History of Neoliberalism, op. cit., 1
101
“The average annual increase in world GDP...was higher in the period 1952-75 than in the period since 1975, although that expansion
in economic activity was somewhat faster in the advanced economies. ....Advocates of globalisation as well as their opponents continue to
draw attention to flows of trade and labour, thereby deflecting attention from that which is most causal of instability and insecurity:
financialisation of the global economy – when banks and the finance sector dominate and distort the real economy.... This is done by
withholding affordable finance from the real economy, engaging in speculation and risk, making money from money rather than from
investment in productive sustainable activity that creates jobs, wages and profits.” Pettifor https://urpe.wordpress.com/2017/05/26/the-
neoliberal-road-to-autocracy/ original http://www.ips-journal.eu/opinion/article/show/the-neoliberal-road-to-autocracy-2046/Germany’s
disastrous Eurozone policy illustrates “pre-Keynesian ideas that most macroeconomists rejected many years ago.”
https://www.socialeurope.eu/2017/05/rethinking-german-economic-policy/
102
The Liberal Order is Rigged: “The fall of the Soviet Union removed the main “other” from the American political imagination and
thereby reduced social cohesion in the United States. The end of the Cold War generated particular political difficulties for the Republican
Party, which had long been a bastion of anticommunism. With the Soviets gone, Washington elites gradually replaced Communists as the
Republicans’ bogeymen. Trumpism is the logical extension of that development. ....During the Cold War, leaders in Western Europe
constantly sought to stave off the domestic appeal of communism and socialism. After 1989, no longer facing that constraint, national
governments and officials in Brussels expanded the EU’s authority and scope, even in the face of a series of national referendums that
expressed opposition to that trend and should have served as warning signs of growing working-class discontent..... Without the specter of
communist-style authoritarianism haunting their societies, eastern Europeans have become more susceptible to populism and other forms
of illiberalism. In Europe, as in the United States, the disappearance of the Soviets undermined social cohesion and a common sense of
purpose.” https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/world/2017-04-17/liberal-order-rigged
103
https://www.lrb.co.uk/v31/n22/john-gray/we-simply-do-not-know
104
Some economists resisted even this. “There are a number of economists who strongly object to even the basic idea that government
spending is a useful tool during this crisis. For example, 1995 Nobel Laureate Robert Lucas called multiplier estimates from
Economy.com “schlock economics”; John Cochrane of the University of Chicago has called government spending stimulus “a fallacy”;
Robert Barro of Harvard called one version of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) “the worst bill that has been put
forward since the 1930s.”Other economists say stimulus proponents are basing their arguments on the economics of yesteryear. Thomas
Sargent of New York University and the Hoover Institution remarked that the support for the ARRA “ignore[s] what we have learned in
the last 60 years of macroeconomic research,” while 2004 Nobel Laureate Edward Prescott has said, “Stimulus is not part of the language
of economics. There is an old, discarded theory that’s been tried and failed spectacularly. The stimulus bill is likely to depress the
economy.” https://www.forbes.com/2009/06/16/stimulus-arra-government-spending-krugman-prescott-opinions-contributors-
ohanian.html
105
Erskine Bowles and Alan Simpson, https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/National_Commission_on_Fiscal_Responsibility_and_Reform
18
Thrones .... While these can produce pleasure, their contribution to long-term prosperity is hard to measure.
https://jacobinmag.com/2017/09/private-investment-profits-united-states
131
Wolfgang Streeck, a German economic sociologist, “The Return of the Repressed,” NLR104, March-April 2017
132
Larry Summers, Timothy Geithner, and Gary Gensler, among others. http://www.whiteoutpress.com/articles/q42012/list-of-goldman-
sachs-employees-in-the-white-house/
133
Steve Mnuchin,, Treasury, and Gary Cohn, Director, NEC. Strategist Steve Bannon is also from Goldman
.https://theintercept.com/2017/07/15/trumps-team-overseeing-wall-street-brings-in-more-goldman-sachs-alumni-docs-reveal/
134
Along with Rubin and Summers. http://content.time.com/time/covers/0,16641,19990215,00.html
135
https://blogs.crikey.com.au/us08/2008/10/24/the-end-has-begun-“i-was-shocked…i’ve-found-a-flaw/ from
https://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/CHRG-110hhrg55764/html/CHRG-110hhrg55764.htm Nomi Prins quote, It Takes a Pillage, 121. He
considered laws against financial fraud unnecessary—“the market would take care of itself “Well, you probably will always believe there
should be laws against fraud, and I don’t think there is any need for a law against fraud,” she recalls. Greenspan, Born says, believed the
market would take care of itself.” Born headed the Commodity Futures Trading Commission.
https://alumni.stanford.edu/get/page/magazine/article/?article_id=30885
136
https://www.socialeurope.eu/2017/05/needed-progressive-vision-national-sovereignty/ The Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission
concluded, http://www.nytimes.com/2011/01/26/business/economy/26inquiry.html “’The greatest tragedy would be to accept the refrain
that no one could have seen this coming and thus nothing could have been done.’ ...regulators ‘lacked the political will’ to scrutinize and
hold accountable the institutions they were supposed to oversee.”
137
Anatole Kaletsky, “The Crisis of Market Fundamentalism,” https://www.socialeurope.eu/2017/01/crisis-market-fundamentalism/
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2098569?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Wiley is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of
Industrial Economics
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 0022-1821 $2.00
Volume XXXIV March 1986 No. 3
ASHER WOLINSKY
I. INTRODUCTION
247
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
248 ASHER WOLINSKY
(1) cii (xi, yi) < ci2(xi, yi) for all xi, yi > 0
It is easy to verify that (1) implies that for any s > 0, ci(x, y) > ci(x + ?, y - ?)
and in particular c'(x +y, 0) < c'(x, y). To understand the meaning of the cost
assumptions consider briefly the particular example c y(xJ)- C(xi + y) +
V(yi) where C'( ) > 0, V'( ) > 0, C"( ) > 0, V"( ) > 0. This example is easy
to interpret: products i and j share the same facilities and incur the same basic
cost C( ), but the production of j with technology i requires some special
adjustment effort which is captured by V(yi).
Let pi( * ) denote the inverse demand for product i and assume that the
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 249
demands for the two products are independent. To avoid later on a technical
discussion which is not our main interest, it is assumed that pi() is concave
(or linear).
Finally, we assume complete symmetry: pl(.) = p2( ) = p(), F' = F2 = F
and c'(x, y) = c2(x, y) = c(x, y) where the latter means that the cost of
producing x' = x and y2 = y with technology 1 is equal to the cost of
producing x2= x and y' = y with technology 2. (Notice that our notational
convention is that the first coordinate of c(-, ) is the quantity of the product
at which the considered technology is more efficient.)
It should be emphasized that our purpose is to obtain a simple model that
will enable us to focus on the main point, without dealing with additional
complications which are not directly relevant for that point. For this reason
we invoked quite strong assumptions, such as the limitation to two products
and the independence of the demands. These assumptions are not essential
for the derivation of the qualitative results, but they simplify the exposition
substantially.
The purpose of this section is to examine how the nature of the competition
affects the scope of firms in the context of the model outlined above. To this
end we suppose that there are many potential firms that have access to the
same technologies (as captured by the function c(-, .)) and consider the
equilibrium outcomes under two alternative forms of competition. One form
is competition among price takers which will be referred to as perfect
competition. The other form is competition among Cournot-type quantity
setting firms that recognize the effect of their actions on the prices and we
shall refer to it as imperfect competition. In both cases we consider the free
entry equilibrium in which the number of firms is determined endogenously
by the zero-profit condition.
Perfect competition
Suppose that there are many potential entrants. Each has to decide whether
or not to enter the industry (an entrant incurs the set-up cost F) and then
which technology to employ and what quantities to produce. The behavioral
assumption is that the firms are price takers. That is, given the prices p' and
p2, the profit maximization problem of a firm that chose technology i is
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
250 ASHER WOLINSKY
These conditions together with the condition that each firm chooses its
technology optimally and the free entry (zero-profit) condition characterize
the competitive industry's equilibrium. It can be verified that if c1 1 > 0 and
the fixed cost F is not "too large", then there exists a unique industry
equilibrium (in our statements concerning the equilibrium we ignore integer
problems which may arise due to the fact that, with an integer number of
firms, the requirement of zero-profit may not be satisfied precisely). This
unique equilibrium is of the following form: the prices of both products are
the same, pi = p2 = p*; a firm with technology i produces quantity xi = x*
such that c (x*, 0) = p*, and quantity yi = 0 of the other product; by the
zero-profit condition p* is equal to the average cost [c(x*, 0) + F]/x*.
To verify the above statements note first that at equilibrium we cannot have
yi > 0. This is because with technologies of the type considered here (see (1)
above), for all yi > 0 the equality p* = c1 (xi, yi) implies p*< C2(Xi, yi). Thus,
since profit maximization of a price taking firm with technology i implies
p* = cI(x', yi), it also implies p*< C2(Xi, yi) and hence yi = 0. Next, note that
the requirement that c1I > 0 guarantees that when a firm with technology i
produces only product i, its marginal cost function is strictly increasing.
Therefore, the case of c1,1 > 0 is the standard textbook case of a competitive
industry equilibrium with U-shaped average cost curves. That is, when
integer problems are ignored, the unique equilibrium prices are equal to
minimum average cost and the number of firms is such that the demand is
satisfied when all active firms operate at minimum average cost. The
requirement that F is not "too large" is then needed to guarantee that at a
price equal to minimum average cost, the demanded quantity is sufficient to
sustain the industry.
Similarly, it is easy to verify that for the case of c11 = 0 and F = 0 there
also exists a unique competitive equilibrium. This is the standard case of
constant marginal cost: the unique equilibrium here is also such that each
firm produces a single product; the equilibrium prices are equal to the
constant marginal cost c1; but the number of firms is indeterminate.
The conclusion is that in the industry considered here competition among
price takers, or for that matter any form of competition that results in
marginal cost pricing (see the discussion of this point at the end of the
section), leads to complete specialization.
As before, the firms that enter the market choose simultaneously which
technology to employ and what quantities to produce of products 1, 2. But
here each firm is aware that its actions affect the prices. The equilibrium
concept is Nash equilibrium with quantities and the choice of technology as
the strategic variables, and with the additional requirement of zero profit,
which together with the assumption of free entry determines the equilibrium
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 251
Claim 1: Ignoring integer problems there exists a symmetric zero profit equi-
librium. (The proof is sketched in the appendix.)
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
252 ASHER WOLINSKY
ing two examples. First, consider the functional form c(x, y) = C(x +y) +y2.
It is easy to verify that in this case the firms will always produce both
products at equilibrium. The property of this cost function which gives rise
to the joint production is the fact that c1 (x, 0) = C2(X,O). To see this suppose
that the firms specialized at -equilibrium and let p* denote the symmetric
equilibrium price. Notice that equation (6) implies c1(x*,O) < p* which
together with the quality of the marginal costs means that c2(x*, 0) < p*
But the last inequality means that it pays the firm to produce some positive
quantity of the other good and hence specialization cannot be an equilibrium
result.
Next, consider a cost function, c(x, y), for which c2(x, 0) is bounded away
from c1(x, 0), as is the case for the functional form c(x, y) = C(x +y) + ry. In
this case, depending on the parameters of the model, the equilibrium may
involve either specialization or joint production. When the fixed cost F is
relatively large, the equilibrium number of firms is relatively small, and at
equilibrium firms will produce both products. This is because, with a
relatively small number of firms, specialization will result in relatively high
mark-ups of prices over marginal costs. If the mark-up is in excess of r, firms
will be induced to start producing the other good, since the marginal cost of
producing it is lower than the price it fetches. Hence, when the size of the fixed
cost dictates a relatively small number of competitors, specialization cannot
be an equilibrium result. By the same reasoning, when the fixed cost F is
small and hence the equilibrium number of firms is relatively large, the firms
will specialize.
These points concerning the relations between the intensity of competition
(as measured by the equilibrium number of firms) and the pattern of
specialization are easily demonstrated by the simple example where c(x, y) =
c (x +y) + ry and the demand functions are linear p' (z) = p2(Z) = a-bz.
Using the equilibrium conditions one can calculate the symmetric equilibrium
magnitudes of n (the number of firms of each type), x* and y*. When the
set-up cost F is sufficiently large and hence n is sufficiently small to satisfy
n < [(a - c)/r] -1, then at equilibrium each firm produces both products in
quantities x* = (a-c + nr)/b(2n + 1) and y* = (a-c-(n + 1)r)/b(2n + 1) re-
spectively. As n is made larger (that is, F is made smaller) the ratio y*/x*
approaches zero, and as n reaches the critical value [(a - c)/r] -1 complete
specialization is achieved. In this sense one can say that a more intense com-
petition results in a greater degree of specialization. Note that the equilibrium
number of firms does not depend only on the size of the set up cost F but
rather on the size of F relative to the extent of the market. Thus, for the class
of cases considered here, one may say that, given the size of F, the degree of
specialization is determined by the extent of the market. This observation
suggests another interpretation for the idea that "the division of labor is
limited by the extent of the market", which was discussed by Stigler [1951]
in the context of vertical disintegration.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 253
IV. DISCUSSION
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
254 ASHER WOLINSKY
the product at the production of which it is more efficient; and the prices are
p*-pl(nx*) = p2(nx*). Notice that if c2(x*, O) < p*, then it pays a producer
of product 1 to produce also a unit of product 2 despite the facts that the price
of this unit, p2, is not higher than p1 (since p' = p2 = p*), and its production
is more costly than the production of an additional unit of product 1. The
reason that the firm wants to produce this more costly unit of product 2, but
does not want to increase its production of product 1 is that the marginal
revenue that accrues to the firm in market 2 is the price p* which is greater
than the marginal revenue, p* + x*(dpl/dx), it obtains in market 1.
The above explanation suggests that the results of section III do not just
reflect some peculiar properties of the simple model employed there. Rather,
the driving forces such as the firms' tendency to restrict their output and the
existence of price mark-up over marginal cost are quite common character-
istics of imperfectly competitive markets.
In the light of this it is quite obvious that some of our assumptions are not
crucial for the derivation of the qualitative results but rather serve to simplify
the analysis. For example, consider the possibility to relax the assumption
that the demands for the two products are independent. If the price of each
product is assumed to depend on the total quantities of both products, then
the qualitative results concerning the scope of firms under the two forms of
competition do not change. The only difference is that whether or not
imperfectly competitive conduct results in the emergence of two-product
firms in any particular case will now also depend on the cross demand
effects in that case. Note that the above remains true when the two products
are complementary. This is because the argument given in section III for why
price takers specialize is not affected (it depends only on the cost advantages
to specialization), while the possibility that imperfect competitors will pro-
duce both products is just enhanced by the complementarity.
Next, let us consider the issue of efficiency. Provided that the rest of the
economy (that is, all markets other than the markets for goods 1 and 2) is
competitive, the imperfectly competitive conduct in the markets for goods 1
and 2 results in an inefficient allocation. Two of the distortions which exist in
this case are not special to the present model. These are the allocative
inefficiency which is due to the fact that the imperfectly competitive sector
produces too little and the productive inefficiency which has to do with the
fact that, given the industry's output, the industry's cost is not necessarily
minimized with respect to the number of firms. An additional aspect of
inefficient production, which is special to the present model, has to do with
the existence of multi-product firms despite the cost advantages to specializa-
tion. That is, given the equilibrium number of active firms and the total
industry output, the industry cost is not minimized with respect to specializa-
tion. A reorganization of production whereby each firm produces the same
volume but specializes in a single product will facilitate the production of the
same outputs at lower industry costs. Since the latter distortion is added to
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 255
the distortions that would have existed anyway, one cannot say in general
whether or not the possibility of joint production improves the allocation.
That is, letting welfare be measured by total surplus (the sum of consumers'
surplus and profits), it can be shown that if the firms are forced to specialize
the total surplus can be either lower or higher (depending on the various
parameters) than it is when joint production is allowed. This is because the
existence of multi-product firms might lead to higher output and hence
higher consumers' surplus, but it involves higher costs of production which
may or may not outweigh the added consumers' surplus.
The above-described inefficiency which may arise in competition among
multi-product firms is, of course, due to the nature of the costs of production
assumed throughout (see (1)). For a complementary discussion concerning
the efficiency aspects of competition among multi-product firms the reader is
referred to Waterson [1983], who considers industries in which the cost
conditions are favorable to multi-product production and analyzes the
efficiency tradeoff between economies of scope and the effects of market
power.
V. ECONOMIES OF SCOPE
The modern literature on multi-product firms has dealt mainly with the
technological (cost side) determinants of the structure of such firms. The
present paper has exposed another determinant of the scope of firms-the
nature of the competition in the industry. The purpose of this section is to
consider the connection between the results of the present paper and the
technological property of economies of scope which is a central concept in the
literature referred to above.
Let us start by describing the concept of economies of scope in the context
of the two-product industry considered here (Panzar and Willig who coined
this term discuss it for arbitrary number of products). It is said that there are
economies of scope at the output combination xi, yi if the cost of producing
this combination by one firm is lower than the cost of producing it by two
single-product firms. That is,
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
256 ASHER WOLINSKY
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 257
VI. CONCLUSION
This paper has examined how the scope of firms is affected by the nature of
the competition in the industry. In the context of the model studied here it
was shown that imperfectly competitive conduct may lead to the formation
of multi-product firms in an industry in which perfect competition results in
specialization. The qualitative conclusion is that imperfectly competitive
behavior creates additional incentives (as compared with perfectly competi-
tive behavior) for firms to expand their scopes. These incentives supplement
cost considerations which are the only relevant data for understanding the
scope of firms under perfect competition. The implications of this paper are
potentially testable in the sense that one can use a measure of the degree of
competition as one of the explanatory variables for the differences in the
scope of firms across industries.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
258 ASHER WOLINSKY
APPENDIX
Proof of Claim 1
Consider first a configuration of 2n firms such that n employ technology 1 and the
other n technology 2. With n and the technologies fixed, the convexity of c(, ), the
concavity of p( * ) and the complete symmetry imply that there exists a symmetric equi-
librium with respect to the choice of quantities (this follows from standard arguments
which are brought, for example, in Friedman [1977]). Further, since c1l > c12 and
C22 > c12 it can be shown that, for a given n, there is only one such symmetric
equilibrium (upon differentiating the first order conditions for a symmetric equi-
librium, one can observe that these properties of cost together with the aforementioned
properties imply a unique solution).
To see that this configuration is at equilibrium with respect to the choice of
technology as well, it has to be shown that, given the quantities produced by all other
firms, no firm can profit from changing both its technology and quantities. Suppose
that at the quantity equilibrium with fixed n and fixed technologies, a firm with
technology i produces x* of product i and y* of product j. It follows from the first
order conditions (6) and (7) that x* > y*. Consider now a firm with technology 1. The
total quantities produced by all other firms Q', Q2 are Q1 = (n - 1)x* + ny* < nx* +
(n- 1)y* = Q2. Suppose that the firm switches to technology 2 and produces
quantities z, w of products 1,2 respectively. If z > w then c1(z, w) < c2(w,5z) imp
that r2(w, z) < 7r' (x* y*
Ifz < w,then
x2(W, Z)_- x'(W, Z) = p(Q2 + W)W + P(Ql + Z)Z-p(Ql + W)W _p(Q2 + Z)z
= [p(Q1 +z)_p(Q2 +z)] _ [p(Q1 +W)_p(Q2 +W)] < 0
where the last inequality follows from w > z, Q2 > Q' and the concavity of p( ).
Therefore, 7r2(w,z) < x'(w,z) < xl(x*, y*) and the switch of technology is unprofit-
able. So far we have shown that, for any given n, there exists a symmetric configuration
satisfying conditions (3) and (4). Now, ignoring integer problems, n can be raised
(lowered) until the per-firm profit sufficiently falls (rises) so as to satisfy the zero-profit
condition (5).
Q.E.D.
REFERENCES
BAUMOL, W., PANZAR, J. and WILLIG, R., 1981, Contestable Markets and the Theory of
Industry Structure (Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, San Diego).
CLARK, J., 1923, Studies in the Economics of Overhead Costs (Chicago University
Press).
CLEMENS, E., 1958, 'Price Discrimination and the Multiproduct Firm', reprinted in
R. Heflebower and G. Stocking (eds.), AEA Readings in Industrial Organization
and Public Policy, pp. 262-276 (Homewood, Illinois).
DIXIT, A., 1980, 'The Role of Investment in Entry Deterrence', Economic Journal, 90,
pp. 95-106.
FRIEDMAN, J., 1977, Oligopoly and the Theory of Games (North-Holland, Amsterdam).
GROSSMAN, S., 1981, 'Nash Equilibrium and the Industrial Organization of Markets
with Large Fixed Costs', Econometrica, 49, 5, pp. 1149-1172.
PANZAR, J. and WILLIG, R., 1979, 'Economies of Scope, Product Specific Economies of
Scale and the Multi-Product Competitive Firm', Bell Labs Economic Discussion
Paper No. 152.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
COMPETITION AND THE SCOPE OF FIRMS 259
PANZAR, J. and WILLIG, R., 1981, 'Economies of Scope', American Economic Review,
71, 2, pp. 268-272.
SCHERER, F., 1980, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (Second
Edition, Rand McNally, Chicago).
SCHMALENSEE, R., 1978, 'Entry Deterrence in the Ready-to-Eat Breakfast Cereal
Industry', Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 2 (Autumn), pp. 305-327.
STIGLER, J., 1951, 'The Division of Labor is Limited by the Extent of the Market',
Journal of Political Economy, 59, pp. 185-193.
WATERSON, M., 1983, 'Economies of Scope within Market Frameworks', International
Journal of Industrial Organization', 1, pp. 223-237.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Wed, 22 Jan 2020 10:00:06 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
BACK TO BASICS
What Is Keynesian
Economics?
The central tenet of this school of thought is that
government intervention can stabilize the economy
D
URING the Great Depression of the 1930s, exist- • Aggregate demand is influenced by many economic deci-
ing economic theory was unable either to explain sions—public and private. Private sector decisions can some-
the causes of the severe worldwide economic col- times lead to adverse macroeconomic outcomes, such as
lapse or to provide an adequate public policy so- reduction in consumer spending during a recession. These
lution to jump-start production and employment. market failures sometimes call for active policies by the gov-
British economist John Maynard Keynes spearheaded a ernment, such as a fiscal stimulus package (explained below).
revolution in economic thinking that overturned the then- Therefore, Keynesian economics supports a mixed economy
prevailing idea that free markets would automatically provide guided mainly by the private sector but partly operated by
full employment—that is, that everyone who wanted a job the government.
would have one as long as workers were flexible in their wage • Prices, and especially wages, respond slowly to changes
demands (see box). The main plank of Keynes’s theory, which in supply and demand, resulting in periodic shortages and
has come to bear his name, is the assertion that aggregate surpluses, especially of labor.
demand—measured as the sum of spending by households,
businesses, and the government—is the most important Keynes the master
driving force in an economy. Keynes further asserted that
Keynesian economics gets its name, theories, and prin-
free markets have no self-balancing mechanisms that lead to
ciples from British economist John Maynard Keynes
full employment. Keynesian economists justify government
(1883–1946), who is regarded as the founder of modern
intervention through public policies that aim to achieve full
macroeconomics. His most famous work, The General
employment and price stability.
Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, was pub-
The revolutionary idea lished in 1936. But its 1930 precursor, A Treatise on
Money, is often regarded as more important to econom-
Keynes argued that inadequate overall demand could lead
ic thought. Until then economics analyzed only static
to prolonged periods of high unemployment. An economy’s
conditions—essentially doing detailed examination of a
output of goods and services is the sum of four components:
snapshot of a rapidly moving process. Keynes, in Trea-
consumption, investment, government purchases, and net
tise, created a dynamic approach that converted eco-
exports (the difference between what a country sells to and
nomics into a study of the flow of incomes and expen-
buys from foreign countries). Any increase in demand has to
ditures. He opened up new vistas for economic analysis.
come from one of these four components. But during a reces-
In The Economic Consequences of the Peace in 1919,
sion, strong forces often dampen demand as spending goes
Keynes predicted that the crushing conditions the
down. For example, during economic downturns uncertainty
Versailles peace treaty placed on Germany to end World
often erodes consumer confidence, causing them to reduce
War I would lead to another European war.
their spending, especially on discretionary purchases like He remembered the lessons from Versailles and from
a house or a car. This reduction in spending by consumers the Great Depression, when he led the British delegation
can result in less investment spending by businesses, as firms at the 1944 Bretton Woods conference—which set down
respond to weakened demand for their products. This puts rules to ensure the stability of the international financial
the task of increasing output on the shoulders of the govern- system and facilitated the rebuilding of nations devastated
ment. According to Keynesian economics, state intervention by World War II. Along with U.S. Treasury official Harry
is necessary to moderate the booms and busts in economic Dexter White, Keynes is considered the intellectual found-
activity, otherwise known as the business cycle. ing father of the International Monetary Fund and the
There are three principal tenets in the Keynesian descrip- World Bank, which were created at Bretton Woods.
tion of how the economy works:
The total developmental assistance to the six countries in the four years
amounted to Rs 21,101.52 crore.
• STORES
• MACHINES
Production • WORKERS
• FINISHED GOODS STORES
• DESPATCH [Inventory]
Demand and Supply
Demand
• Total quality customers are willing and able to
buy/Purchase the goods.
• Demand function is a behavior function for
consumers.
Types of Demand
• Direct demand
Consumers goods [FMCG]
• Derived demand
Demand for steel is derived from the
demand for final goods [ Automobiles field]
• Types:
1. Simple average method
2. Increase or Decrease method
3. Weighted average method
4. Exponential smoothing method
Simple average method
• Example:
Year Tea sales/Ton
2004 25
2005 32
2006 24
2007 28
2008 26
2009 27
2010 ?
Simple average= 25+32+24+28+26+27/6 (no.of
data's)
F= 27
F= Forecasting
2. Increase/ Decrease Method
• Data level/Trend
Year Tea sales/Ton
2004 25 Decrease
2005 32 Increase
2006 24 Decrease
2007 28 Increase
2008 26 Decrease
2009 27 Increase
2010 ? ???
F= 26+27/2 = 26.5
3. Weighted average method
• Taking a recent years data's
• Gives a weighted values
Example:
Taking last 3 years data's
Year Tea sales/Ton
2007 28
2008 26
2009 27
2010 ?
• 2007 gives weighted for 1
• 2008 gives weighted for 2
• 2009 gives weighted for 3
F= (1X28)+(2X26)+(3X27)/ 6 (Total allotted
weights)
= (28+52+81)/6
= 26.833
4. Exponential smoothing
• Like Reverse engineering process
• Ft+1= ɸ Dt + (1-ɸ)Ft
F= Forecast
D= Demand
ɸ= Smoothing constant (0 to 1)
t= Time period
Dt= Demand of period ‘t’
• F7= ɸD6 + (1-ɸ)F6
• F6= ɸD5 + (1-ɸ)F5 …..Proceeding further
……. …….
……. …….
Over heads
Fixed cost
The cost tends to be unaffected with the volume
of output.
Fixed cost depends upon the passage of time and
does not vary directly with the volume of output.
Example:
Rent of factory
Insurance of factory
Variable cost
Variable cost tends to vary directly with the
volume of output.
It varies almost in direct proportion to the
volume of production.
If prodcution increases, variable cost will be
increases.
Example:
Direct material cost
Direct labour cost
Marginal cost
Marginal cost= Total cost – Fixed cost
Revenues:
The sales of goods/ Services.
Break-Even Analysis
• Break-Even analysis implies that the total revenue equals
the total cost at some point in the operations.
• Break-Even analysis is concerned with finding the point at
which revenues and cost agree exactly. It can be carried
out algebraically or graphically.
Break-Even Point
• Break-Even point is, therefore, the volume of output at
which neither a profit is made nor a loss is incurred.
• Break-Even point is a point where the total sales are equal
to total cost.
Break-Even Chart
• Break-Even chart is a graphical representation of the
relationship between costs and revenue at a given time.
Total Sales (S)
B
Break-even sales
Variable cost (VC)
Sales
Loss
Fixed cost (FC)
Quantity of Production
It is a graphic device to determine the break-even
point and profit potential under varying conditions of
output and costs.
Total cost= Fixed cost + Variable cost
Variable cost (VC) = v*Q
Where, v=Variable cost/unit
Q= Volume of production
Total sales (S)= s*Q
Where, s= Selling price/unit
• The intersection point of the total sales line and the total
cost line is called as the break-even point.
• At the intersection point (B), the total cost is equal to the
total revenue.
• For any production quantity which is less than the break-
even quantity, the total cost is more than the total
revenue. Hence, the firm will be making loss.
• Oil.
• Precious stones.
• Electronics.
• Heavy machinery.
• Organic chemicals.
• Plastics.
• Animal and vegetable oil.
• Iron and Steel.
Largest trading Imports partners
1 China 68.06
Definition:
• The World Trade Organization (WTO) is the only global
international organization dealing with the rules of trade
between nations.
• Its main function is to ensure that trade flows as
smoothly, predictably and freely as possible.
• Location: Geneva, Switzerland
• Head: Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala (Director-General)
• Established: 1 January 1995
• The WTO officially commenced on 1 January
1995 under the Marrakesh Agreement, signed
by 123 nations on 15 April 1994, replacing the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), which commenced in 1948. It is the
largest international economic organization in
the world.
• Total Members: 164
Functions/Key objectives of WTO:
• Administering WTO trade agreements
• Forum for trade negotiations
• Handling trade disputes
• Monitoring national trade policies
• Technical assistance and training for developing
countries
• Cooperation with other international
organizations
Indian EXIM Policy
• Definition:
EXIM Policy is the export import policy of the
government that is announced every five years. This policy
consists of general provisions regarding exports and
imports, promotional measures, duty exemption schemes,
export promotion schemes, special economic zone
programs and other details for different sectors.
• Trade Policy is prepared and announced by the Central
Government (Ministry of Commerce).
• Export Import Policy also known as Exim Policy.
• Also known as Foreign Trade Policy
Indian EXIM current Policy
• Trade Policy is prepared and announced by the Central
Government (Ministry of Commerce). India's Export
Import Policy also know as Foreign Trade Policy, in
general, aims at developing export potential, improving
export performance, encouraging foreign trade and
creating favourable balance of payments position.
• The Government of India advices the EXIM Policy of India
for a phase of 5 years under section 5 of the Foreign
Trade Development and Regulation Act, 1992.
• The EXIM Policy is renewed every year on the 31st of
March and the revisions, improvements and new
proposals become effective from 1 st April of every year.
Objectives of EXIM Policy
• To establish the framework for globalization
• To promote the productivity, competitiveness of
Indian industry
• To generate new employment
• To provide quality consumer products at
reasonable prices
• The policy aims at developing export potential,
improving export performance, boosting foreign
trade and earning valuable foreign exchange.
EXIM
• Export-Import (EXIM) Bank of India is the principal financial
institution set up in 1982 under the Export-Import Bank of India
Act 1981 for coordinating the working of institutions engaged in
financing export and import trade in India.
• Exim Policy, also known as the Foreign Trade Policy is announced
every 5 years by Ministry of Commerce and Industry, Government
of India. It is updated every year on the 31st of March and all the
amendments and improvements in the scheme are effective from
the 1st of April.
An international exchange rate, also known as
a foreign exchange rate, is the price of one country's
currency in terms of another country's currency. Exchange
rates play a vital role in a country's level of trade, which is
critical to most every free market economy in the world.
• Definition:
The foreign exchange market (Forex, FX, or
currency market) is a global decentralized or over-the-
counter market for the trading of currencies.
This market determines foreign exchange rates for
every currency. It includes all aspects of buying, selling
and exchanging currencies at current or determined
prices.
Exchange rate:
An exchange rate is the value of one
nation's currency versus the currency of another
nation or economic zone. For example, how many INR
does it take to buy one USD? As of 31-08-2021, the
exchange rate is 73.26, meaning it takes INR 73.26 to
buy $ 1
A currency is classified as strong when it is
worth more than another country's currency.
The dollar gets stronger when its exchange rate
rises relative to other currencies like the Chinese
yuan and the European Union’s euro. Thus,
exchange rates can affect foreign trade via
depreciation of currency, economic impact on
importers, impact on profit margins or price,
appreciation of local currency and the state of
the economy.
• Depreciation of Currency
When there is a depreciation of a local
currency relative to another, the country’s
exports become cheaper for foreign traders, and
thus improve the export competitiveness of that
nation.
A weaker domestic currency stimulates
exports and makes imports more expensive. On
the other hand, a strong domestic currency can
hamper exports and make imports cheaper.
• Appreciation/Strengthening of Currency
A strengthening dollar can create
trouble for U.S. companies that export a lot of
goods to other countries. As products are priced
in dollars, those exports become more
expensive for the foreign consumers and
businesses that have to pay for them in other
currencies. The value of the profits they make
on export sales falls when they convert overseas
profits back to dollars.
The spot price is the current price in the
marketplace at which a given asset—such as a
security, commodity, or currency—can be bought or
sold for immediate delivery. In contrast to the spot
price, a futures price is an agreed upon price for
future delivery of the asset.
Forward pricing is a convention used by
mutual funds to price fund shares based on the end
of each day's net asset value (NAV). NAV computes
the total market value of the investments held by
the fund less fund liabilities and expenses
• Forward price is the price at which a seller
delivers an underlying asset, financial
derivative, or currency to the buyer of
a forward contract at a predetermined date.
Abstract:
In recent years, there has been spontaneous and unpredictable fluctuation in the value of Indian
rupee. The paper looks at the necessity of managing foreign exchange rate exposure, and ways by
which it can be accomplished. This paper discusses exchange rate exposure in terms of transaction
risk (sensitivity of firm's future cash flows from contracts denominated in foreign currency to changes
in exchange rate), translation risk (sensitivity of firm's foreign denominated financial statements to
changes in exchange rate) and economic risk (sensitivity of firm's competitive position in the market
to changes in exchange rate). It identifies various steps involved in foreign exchange risk
management process. This paper seeks to analysis the various options available to the Indian
corporates for hedging exchange rate exposure.
1. Introduction
With the fall of fixed exchange regime in 1973, exchange rates between currencies were determined
by market forces of demand and supply leading to the advent of fluctuating exchange rate regime.
This brought with it randomness and unpredictability in exchange rates. Exchange rates have become
more volatile than they were expected. This random fluctuation in exchange rate has made cash flows
and asset value of companies dealing in different currencies unpredictable, that is to say, cash flows
and asset value of MNCs in their respective domestic currency are at stake of exchange rate between
its domestic currency and foreign currency. Thus, Foreign Exchange Exposure is risk associated with
unanticipated changes in exchange rate.
With globalization and liberalization of Indian economy in nineties, scope of business for Indian
companies with the rest of world has broadened and foreign corporations too have become much
interested in India. In India, exchange rates were deregulated and were allowed to be determined by
markets in 1993. This volatility in exchange rates can have detrimental effect on the firm’s financial
position and negative effect on its competitive position in the market and value of firm, if ignored it
can paralyze the company.
2. Significance of Study
In 1992-93 Budget provided for partial convertibility of Indian Rupee in current accounts and, in
March 1993, the Rupee was made fully convertible in current Account. Since then, there has been
continuous increase in foreign investment in India. Multi-national corporations are entering the Indian
market with their products and services either through subsidiaries or joint venture. Indian corporate
houses are also involved in cross border transactions with different countries and in different
products. Indian firms have also started raising funds from international financial sources. Rupee
depreciated against dollar by about 24% between March 2008 and March 2009 from Rs. 39.80 to Rs.
52.20. And it depreciated against dollar by about 6.23% between June 2014 and June 2014. This
48 Online & Print International, Refereed, Impact factor & Indexed Monthly Journal www.raijmr.com
RET Academy for International Journals of Multidisciplinary Research (RAIJMR)
Abhay Kumar Gupta [Subject: Management/Commerce] International Vol. 4, Issue: 5, July: 2016
Journal of Research in Humanities & Soc. Sciences [I.F. = 0.564] ISSN:(P) 2347-5404 ISSN:(O)2320 771X
impulsive and volatile change in exchange rate makes the environment unpredictable making the
business decisions complicated and this volatility can negatively affect the firm's cash flows and
value. The paper looks at the necessity of managing foreign exchange rate exposure, and discusses the
measures that can be taken to mitigate foreign exchange risk. It identifies various steps involved in
foreign exchange risk management process. This paper attempts to evaluate the various alternatives
available to the Indian corporates and foreign business houses operating in India for hedging
exchange rate exposure. The financial stability report published by RBI in Dec 2012 mentions
“excessive volatility in exchange rate makes it difficult for economic agents to make optimal
intertemporal decisions. The economic agents, therefore, need to properly understand and measure the
nature of currency risk embedded in their business and use appropriate derivative instruments to
hedge their currency risk..."
3. Objectives of Study
This paper identifies various types of foreign exchange exposures in MNCs operating in India. The
focal point of this paper is identification of various tools and techniques to mitigate foreign exchange
exposure of companies operating in India. Objectives of the study have been to discuss foreign
exchange risk management process and the steps involved in it and to examine the facilities available
for managing foreign exchange exposure in India.
4. Literature Review
Bradford Cornell and Alan C. Shapiro (1983) described how foreign exchange risk can be managed.
Ian H. Giddy and Gunter Dufey, in their article “The Management of Foreign Exchange risk”,
identified that in many realistic situations, the economic effects of randomness of exchange rate are
different from those predicted by the various measures of translation exposure. It emphasizes the
distinctions between the currency of location, the currency of denomination and the currency of
determination of a business. They argued that a market based approach be followed in international
financial planning.
Fok et al. (1997) have found that hedging not only reduces variability in earnings but it also increases
firm value. They found that hedging not only decreases the chances of financial distress but also the
agency costs of debt and the costs of equity.
Chowdhry and Howe (1999) argue that firms use financial instruments to hedge short term exposure
and for managing long-run operating exposure, they use long-term strategy adjustments (i.e.,
operational hedges).
Niclas hagelin and bengt pramborg (2002) investigated the effectiveness of currency derivatives and
foreign denominated debt in reducing foreign exchange exposure. The results were positive.
Sathya Swaroop Debasish (2008) studied the foreign exchange risk management practices of 501 non-
banking Indian firms to identify the techniques which they use to hedge their foreign exchange risk. It
was revealed that volatility and reduction in cash flows was the rationale behind hedging. The
techniques used by Indian firms are forward contracts, swaps and cross-currency options. Confused
perception about derivative use, technical and administrative constraints and fear of high cost were
found to the main reasons of not pursuing any foreign exchange risk management technique. The
paper discusses the various foreign exchange risk management techniques.
Jain, Yadav, and Rastogi (2009) discusses and compares the foreign exchange risk management
strategies and interest rate risk management strategies followed by public companies, private business
houses and foreign companies operating in India. All the risks are not managed. Management of these
companies operating in India are of opinion that amount of exposer accruing to these do not require to
be specially managed.
49 Online & Print International, Refereed, Impact factor & Indexed Monthly Journal www.raijmr.com
RET Academy for International Journals of Multidisciplinary Research (RAIJMR)
Abhay Kumar Gupta [Subject: Management/Commerce] International Vol. 4, Issue: 5, July: 2016
Journal of Research in Humanities & Soc. Sciences [I.F. = 0.564] ISSN:(P) 2347-5404 ISSN:(O)2320 771X
Peter mbabazi mbabazize, twesige daniel and issac emukule ekise(2014) found that exporting firms in
Uganda had a significant relationship between currency risk transfer strategies and gross profit
margin, net profit margin and sales growth.
5. Research Methodology
Extensive literature review of books, journals, articles and other published data related to the focus of
the study, and also concerned websites, was done to gather background information about the general
nature of the research problem.
9. Internal Techniques
A. Netting
Netting implies offsetting exposures in one currency with exposure in the same or another currency,
where exchange rates are expected to move high in such a way that losses or gains on the first
exposed position should be offset by gains or losses on the second currency exposure. It is of two
types of bilateral netting & multilateral netting. In bilateral netting, each pair of subsidiaries nets out
their own positions with each other. Flows are reduced by the lower of each company’s purchases
from or sales to its netting partner.
B. Matching
Matching refers to the process in which a company matches its currency inflows with its currency
outflows with respect to amount and timing. When a company has receipts and payments in same
foreign currency due at same time, it can simply match them against each other. Hedging is required
for unmatched portion of foreign currency cash flows. This kind of operation is referred to as natural
matching. Parallel matching is another possibility. When gains in one foreign currency are expected to
be offset by losses in another, if the movements in two currencies are parallel is called parallel
matching.
C. Leading and Lagging
These involve adjusting the timing of the payment or receivables. Leading is accelerating payment of
strengthening currencies and speeding up the receipt of weakening currencies. Lagging is delaying
payment of weakening currencies and postponing receipt of strengthening currencies. In these the
payable or receivable of the foreign currency is postponed in order to benefit from the movements in
exchange rates.
D. Pricing Policy
There can be two types of pricing tactics: price variation and currency of invoicing policy. Price
variation can be done as increasing selling prices to offset the adverse effects of exchange rate
fluctuations. However, it may affect the sales volume. So proper analysis should be done regarding
customer loyalty, market position, competitive position before increasing price. Secondly, foreign
customers can be insisted to pay in home currency and paying all imports in home currency.
52 Online & Print International, Refereed, Impact factor & Indexed Monthly Journal www.raijmr.com
RET Academy for International Journals of Multidisciplinary Research (RAIJMR)
Abhay Kumar Gupta [Subject: Management/Commerce] International Vol. 4, Issue: 5, July: 2016
Journal of Research in Humanities & Soc. Sciences [I.F. = 0.564] ISSN:(P) 2347-5404 ISSN:(O)2320 771X
E. Government Exchange Risk Guarantee
Government agencies in many countries provide insurance against export credit risk and introduce
special export financing schemes for exporters in order to promote exports. In recent years a few of
these agencies have begun to provide exchange risk insurance to their exporters and the usual export
credit guarantees. The exporter pays a small premium on his export sales and for this premium the
government agency absorbs all exchange losses and gains beyond a certain level.
10. Conclusion
Foreign exchange exposure management is too important to be ignored by businesses across the
world, including emerging world like India. Businesses which did not give due care to it have paid the
penalty. Business firms need to be proactive in foreign exchange risk management. Firms need to
look at instituting a sound risk management system and also need to formulate their hedging strategy
that suits their specific firm characteristics and exposures. In India, regulation has been steadily eased
and turnover and liquidity in the foreign currency derivative markets have increased, although the use
is mainly in shorter maturity contracts of one year or less. Forward and option contracts are the more
popular instruments. Initially only certain banks were allowed to deal in this market however now
corporate can also write option contracts. Indian companies are actively hedging their foreign
exchanges risks with forwards and currency swaps and different types of options. Introduction of
Cross-Currency Futures and Exchange Traded Option Contracts by the RBI will further enhance the
companies’ ability to effectively manage foreign exchange exposure. A larger interactive model
capable of culminating all facets of enterprise-wide risk management needs to be developed. It is
concluded that business and industry should invariably hedge their actual risk exposures without
exception as a base case strategy as it is most conservative and prudent strategy. Government should
make appropriate policy and took measures that can accelerate the process of further development of
foreign exchange market. Companies should upgrade their foreign exchange risk management
(FERM) process and employ innovative tools to mitigate foreign exchange exposure.
References
1. Anuradha Sivakumar and Runa Sarkar, ''Corporate Hedging for Foreign Exchange Risk in India''
2. Björn Döhring, "Hedging and invoicing strategies to reduce exchange rate exposure: a euro-area
perspective"
3. Bradford Cornell and Alan C. Shapiro (1983). “Managing Foreign Exchange Risks”
4. Brown, G. (2001), "Managing foreign exchange risk with derivatives"
5. Chowdhry and Howe (1999). ''Corporate risk management for multinational corporations;
financial and operational hedging policies''
6. David A. Carter, Christos Pantzalis, and Betty J. Simkins, (2001). "Firmwide Risk Management
of Foreign Exchange Exposure by U.S. Multinational Corporations"
7. Stephen, D. Maker and Stephen P. Huffman, "Foreign currency risk management practices in
U.S. multinationals"
8. Financial Markets Regulation Department, RBI, A.P. (DIR Series) Circular No. 35 RBI/2015
9. Florentina-Olivia Bãlu and Daniel Armeanu, “Foreign Exchange Risk in International
Transactions”, Theoretical and Applied Economics, 65
10. Ian H. Giddy and Gunter Dufey, “The Management of Foreign Exchange risk”
11. Michael Papaioannou, (2006). “Exchange Rate Risk Measurement and Management: Issues and
Approaches for Firms”, IMF Working Paper, Monetary and Capital Markets, WP/06/255
12. Niclas hagelin and bengt pramborg (2002). ''hedging foreign exchange exposure: risk reduction
from transaction and translation hedging",
13. Varma, Jayanth R. "Indian Financial Sector after a Decade of Reforms"
14. Sagi rajkumar varma, "Foreign exchange risk management in India: issues and challenges"
15. Sathya Swaroop Debasish (2008). “Foreign Exchange Risk Management Practices – A Study in
Indian Scenario”
16. Sharma, V.K." The Risk management imperative"
53 Online & Print International, Refereed, Impact factor & Indexed Monthly Journal www.raijmr.com
RET Academy for International Journals of Multidisciplinary Research (RAIJMR)
IEOR E4706: Foundations of Financial Engineering
c 2016 by Martin Haugh
1 Forwards
Definition 1 A forward contract on a security (or commodity) is a contract agreed upon at date t = 0 to
purchase or sell the security at date T for a price, F , that is specified at t = 0.
When the forward contract is established at date t = 0, the forward price, F , is set in such a way that the initial
value of the forward contract, f0 , satisfies f0 = 0. At the maturity date, T , the value of the contract is given2
by fT = ±(ST − F ) where ST is the time T value of the underlying security (or commodity). It is very
important to realize that there are two “prices” or “values” associated with a forward contract at time t: ft
and F . When we use the term “contract value” or “forward value” we will always be referring to ft , whereas
when we use the term “contract price” or “forward price” we will always be referring to F . That said, there
should never be any ambiguity since ft is fixed (equal to zero) at t = 0, and F is fixed for all t > 0 so the
particular quantity in question should be clear from the context. Note that ft need not be (and generally is not)
equal to zero for t > 0.
Examples of forward contracts include:
• A forward contract for delivery (i.e. purchase) of a non-dividend paying stock with maturity 6 months.
• A forward contract for delivery of a 9-month T-Bill with maturity 3 months. (This means that upon
delivery, the T-Bill has 9 months to maturity.)
F = S/d(0, T ) (1)
where S is the current spot price of the security and d(0, T ) is the discount factor applying to the interval [0, T ].
Proof: The proof works by constructing an arbitrage portfolio if F 6= S/d(0, T ).
Case (i): F < S/d(0, T ): Consider the portfolio that at date t = 0 is short one unit of the security, lends S
until date T , and is long one forward contract. The initial cost of this portfolio is 0 and it has a positive payoff,
S/d(0, T ) − F , at date T . Hence it is an arbitrage.
Case (ii): F > S/d(0, T ): In this case, construct the reverse portfolio and again obtain an arbitrage
opportunity.
Forward Price for a Security with Non-Zero Storage Costs: Suppose a security can be stored for
period j at a cost of c(j), payable at the beginning of the period. Assuming that the security may also be sold
short, then the forward price, F , for delivery of that security at date T (assumed to be M periods away) is given
by
M −1
S X c(j)
F = + (2)
d(0, M ) j=0
d(j, M)
where S is the current spot price of the security and d(j, M ) is the discount factor between dates j and M .
Proof: As before, we could prove (2) using an arbitrage argument. An alternative proof is to consider the
strategy of buying one unit of the security on the spot market at t = 0, and simultaneously entering a forward
contract to deliver it at time T . The cash-flow associated with this strategy is
market. Eventually the security is repurchased and returned to the original lender. Note that a profit (loss) is made if the
security price fell (rose) in value between the times it was sold and purchased in the market.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 3
and its present value must (why?) be equal to zero. Since the cash-flow is deterministic we know how to
compute its present value and we easily obtain (2).
Exercise 1 Convince4 yourself that we can indeed only conclude that (4) is true if short-selling is not
permitted.
4 See Luenberger, Chapter 10, for a discussion of tight markets.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 4
In such circumstances, we say that the market is tight. An artifice that is often used to restore equality in (4) is
that of the convenience yield. The convenience yield, y, is defined in such a way that the following equation is
satisfied.
M −1
S X c(j) − y
F = + . (5)
d(0, M ) j=0
d(j, M )
The convenience yield may be thought of as a negative holding cost that measures the convenience per period
of having the commodity on hand.
2 Swaps
Another important class of derivative security are swaps, perhaps the most common of which are interest rate
swaps and currency swaps. Other types of swaps include equity and commodity swaps. A plain vanilla swap
usually involves one party swapping a series of fixed level payments for a series of variable payments.
Swaps were introduced primarily for their use in risk-management. For example, it is often the case that a party
faces a stream of obligations that are floating or stochastic, but that it will have to meet these obligations with
a stream of fixed payments. Because of this mismatch between floating and fixed, there is no guarantee that the
party will be able to meet its obligations. However, if the present value of the fixed stream is greater than or
equal to the present value of the floating stream, then it could purchase an appropriate swap and thereby ensure
than it can meet its obligations.
C = P × (0, r0 − rf , ... , rM −1 − rf )
| {z } | {z }
st th
At end of 1 period At end of M period
where rf is the constant fixed rate and ri is the floating rate that prevailed at the beginning of period i. In
general, ri will be stochastic and so the swap’s cash-flow, C, will also be stochastic. As is the case with forward
contracts, the value X (equivalently rf ) is usually chosen in such a way that the initial value of the swap is zero.
Even though the initial value of the swap is zero, we say that party A is “long” the swap and party B is “short”
the swap.
Exercise 2 Make sure you understand how to use the terms “long” and “short” when referring to a swap.
the swap while a German company might receive the dollar payments. Note that the value of the swap to each
party will vary as the USD/Euro exchange rate varies. As a result, the companies are exposed to foreign
exchange risk but if necessary this risk can be hedged by trading in the forward foreign exchange market.
Why might the US and German companies enter such a transaction? A possible explanation might be that the
US company wishes to invest in the Eurozone while the German country wishes to invest in the U.S. Each
company therefore needs foreign currency. However, they may have a comparative advantage borrowing in their
domestic currency at home as opposed to borrowing in a foreign currency abroad. If this is the case, it makes
sense to borrow domestic currency at home and use a swap to convert it into the foreign currency.
C = N × (0, S1 − X, S2 − X, . . . , SM − X) .
Note that this cash-flow is stochastic and so we cannot compute its present value directly by discounting.
However, we can decompose C into a stream of fixed payments (of −N X) that we can easily price, and a
stochastic stream, N (0, S1 , S2 , . . . , SM ). The stochastic stream is easily seen to be equivalent to a stream
of forward contacts on N units of the commodity. We then see that receiving N Si at period i has the same
value of receiving N Fi at period i where Fi is the date 0 forward price for delivery of one unit of the commodity
at date i. As the forward prices, Fi , are deterministic and known at date 0, we can see that the value of the
commodity swap is given by
XM
V = N d(0, i)(Fi − X).
i=1
C = P (0, r0 − rf , r1 − rf , . . . , rM −1 − rf ).
where ri is the short rate for the period beginning at date i. Again this cash flow can be decomposed into a
series of fixed payments that can be easily priced, and a stochastic stream, P (0, r0 , r1 , . . . , rM −1 ). We can
6 As mentioned above, the fixed payment stream of a swap is usually chosen so that the initial swap value is zero. However,
once the swap is established its value will then vary stochastically and will not in general be zero.
7 Later in the course we will develop the theory of martingale pricing. Then we will be able to price swaps directly, without
value the stochastic stream either using an arbitrage argument or by recalling that the price of a floating rate
bond is always par at any reset point. Note that the stochastic stream is exactly the stream of coupon payments
corresponding to a floating rate bond with face value P . Hence the value of the stochastic stream must be
(why?) P (1 − d(0, M )) and so the value of the swap is given by
" M
#
X
V = P 1 − d(0, M ) − rf d(0, i) . (6)
i=1
As before, rf is usually chosen so that the initial value of the swap is zero.
3 Futures
While forwards markets have proved very useful for both hedging and investment purposes, they have a number
of weaknesses. First, forward markets are not organized through an exchange. This means that in order to take
a position in a forward contract, you must first find someone willing to take the opposite position. This is the
double-coincidence-of-wants problem. Second, because forward contracts are not exchange-traded, there can
sometimes be problems with price transparency and liquidity. Finally, in addition to the financial risk of a
forward contract, there is also counter-party risk. This is the risk that one party to the forward contract will
default on it’s obligations. These problems have been eliminated to a large extent through the introduction of
futures markets. That is not to say that forward markets are now redundant; they are not, and they are used, for
example, in the many circumstances when suitable futures markets are not available.
Perhaps the best way to understand the mechanics of a futures market is by example.
Remark 1 You should make sure that you fully understand the mechanics of this futures market as these are
the same mechanics used by other futures markets.
In Example 5 we did not discuss the details of margin requirements which are intended to protect against the
risk of default. A typical margin requirement would be that the futures trader maintain a minimum balance in
her trading account. This minimum balance will often be a function of the contract value (perhaps 5% to 10%)
multiplied by the position, i.e., the number of contracts that the trader is long or short. When the balance drops
below this minimum level a margin call is made after which the trader must deposit enough funds so as to meet
the balance requirement. Failure to satisfy this margin call will result in the futures position being closed out.
• It is easy to take a position using futures markets without having to purchase the underlying asset. Indeed,
it is not even possible to buy the underlying asset in some cases, e.g., interest rates, cricket matches and
presidential elections.
• Futures markets allow you to leverage your position. That is, you can dramatically increase your exposure
to the underlying security by using the futures market instead of the spot market.
• They are well organized and designed to eliminate counter-party risk as well as the
“double-coincidence-of-wants” problem.
• The mechanics of a futures market are generally independent of the underlying ‘security’ so they are easy
to “operate” and easily understood by investors.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 8
• The fact that they are so useful for leveraging a position also makes them dangerous for unsophisticated
and/or rogue investors.
• Futures prices are (more or less) linear in the price of the underlying security. This limits the types of risks
that can be perfectly hedged using futures markets. Nonetheless, non-linear risks can still be partially
hedged using futures. See, for instance, Example 7 below.
When perfect hedges are not available, we often use the minimum-variance hedge to identify a good hedging
position in the futures markets. To derive the minimum-variance hedge, we let ZT be the cash flow that occurs
at date T that we wish to hedge, and we let Ft be the time t price of the futures contract. At date t = 0 we
adopt a position9 of h in the futures contract and hold this position until time T . Since the initial cost of a
futures position is zero, we can (if we ignore issues related to interest on the margin account) write the terminal
cash-flow, YT , as
YT = ZT + h(FT − F0 ).
Our objective then is to minimize
Var(YT ) = Var(ZT ) + h2 Var(FT ) + 2hCov(ZT , FT )
and we find that the minimizing h and minimum variance are given by
Cov(ZT , FT )
h∗ = −
Var(FT )
Cov(ZT , FT )2
Var(YT∗ ) = Var(ZT ) − .
Var(FT )
Such static hedging strategies are often used in practice, even when dynamic hedging strategies are capable of
achieving a smaller variance. Note also, that unless E[FT ] = F0 , it will not be the case that E[ZT ] = E[YT∗ ]. It
is also worth noting that the mean-variance hedge is not in general the same as the equal-and-opposite hedge.
9 A positive value of h implies that we are long the futures contract while a negative value implies that we are short. More
generally, we could allow h to vary stochastically as a function of time. We might want to do this, for example, if ZT is path
dependent or if it is a non-linear function of the security price underlying the futures contract. When we allow h to vary
stochastically, we say that we are using a dynamic hedging strategy. Such strategies are often used for hedging options and
other derivative securities with non-linear payoffs.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 10
R = D1 P1 + D2 P2
where Pi represents the price per widget at time ti . We assume that Pi is stochastic and that it will depend in
part on the general state of the economy at date ti . In particular, we assume
Pi = aSi ei + c
where a and c are constants, Si is the time ti value of the market index, and 1 and 2 are independent random
variables that are also independent of Si . Furthermore, they satisfy E[ei ] = 1 for each i. The firm wishes to
hedge the revenue, R, by taking a position h at t = 0 in a futures contract that expires at date t2 and where the
market index is the underlying security. The date t2 payoff, Y , is then given by
Remark 2 A more sophisticated hedge would be to choose a position of size h1 at date t = 0 and then to
update this position to h2 at date t1 where h1 and h2 are constants that are chosen at date t = 0. In this case
the resulting hedging strategy is still a static hedging strategy.
Note, however, that since h2 need not be chosen until date t1 , it makes sense to allow h2 to be a function of
available information at date t1 . In particular, we could allow h2 to depend on P1 and S1 , thereby obtaining a
dynamic hedging strategy, (h1 , h2 (P1 , S1 )). Such a strategy should be able to eliminate most of the uncertainty
in R.
Exercise 4 How would you go about solving for the optimal (h∗1 , h∗2 (P1 , S1 ))? Would you need to make an
assumption regarding F1 ?
Note that the most general class of dynamic hedging strategy would allow you to adjust h stochastically at
every date in [0, t2 ) and not just at dates t0 and t1 .
Exercise 5 What types of risk do you encounter when you roll the hedge forward?
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 11
In order to answer Exercise 5, assume you will have a particular asset available to sell at time T2 . Today, at time
t = 0, you would like to hedge your time T2 cash-flow by selling a single futures contract that expires at time T2
with the given asset as the underlying security. Such a futures contract, however, is not yet available though
there is a futures contract available at t = 0 that expires at time T1 < T2 . Moreover, upon expiration of this
contract the futures contract with expiration T2 will become available. You therefore decide to adopt the
following strategy: at t = 0 you sell one unit of the futures contract that expires at time T1 . At T1 you close out
this contract and then sell one unit of the newly available futures contract that expires at time T2 . What is your
net cash-flow, i.e. after selling the asset and closing out the futures contract, at time T2 ?
Note that we have only discussed the mechanics of futures markets and how they can be used to hedge linear
and non-linear risks. We have not seen how to compute the futures price, Ft , but instead will return to this after
we have studied martingale pricing.
Definition 3 An American call (put) option gives the right, but not the obligation, to buy (sell) 1 unit of the
underlying security at a pre-specified price, K, at any time up to an including a pre-specified time, T .
K and T are called the strike and maturity / expiration of the option, respectively. Let St denote the price of
the underlying security at time t. Then, for example, if ST < K a European call option will expire worthless and
the option will not be exercised. A European put option, however, would be exercised and the payoff would be
K − ST . More generally, the payoff at maturity of a European call option is max{ST − K, 0} and its intrinsic
value at any time t < T is given by max{St − K, 0}. The payoff of a European put option at maturity is
max{K − ST , 0} and its intrinsic value at any time t < T is given by max{K − St , 0}.
Put-Call Parity
A very important result for European options is put-call parity. Suppose the underlying security does not pay
dividends. We then have
pE (t; K, T ) + St = cE (t; K, T ) + Kd(t, T ) (7)
where d(t, T ) is the discount factor used to discount cash-flows from time T back to time t. We can prove (7)
by considering the following trading strategy:
• At time t buy one European call with strike K and expiration T
• At time t sell one European put with strike K and expiration T
• At time t sell short 1 unit of the underlying security and buy it back at time T
• At time t lend K d(t, T ) dollars up to time T
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 12
Regardless of the underlying security price, it is easy to see that the cash-flow at time T corresponding to this
strategy will be zero. No-arbitrage then implies that the value of this strategy at time t must therefore also be
zero. We therefore obtain −cE (t; K, T ) + pE (t; K, T ) + St − Kd(t, T ) = 0 which is (7).
When the underlying security does pay dividends then a similar argument can be used to obtain
Therefore the price of an American call on a non-dividend-paying stock is always strictly greater than the
intrinsic value of the call option when the events {ST > K} and {ST < K} have strictly positive probability.
We have thus shown that it is never optimal to early-exercise an American call on a non-dividend paying stock
and so cA (t; K, T ) = cE (t, K, T ). Unfortunately there is no such result relating American put options to
European put options. Indeed it is sometimes optimal to early exercise an American put option even when the
underlying security does not pay a dividend.
Suppose now that S0 = 100, R = 1.01, u = 1.07 and d = 1/u = .9346. Some interesting questions now arise:
Definition 4 A type A arbitrage is a security or portfolio that produces immediate positive reward at t = 0
and has non-negative value at t = 1. i.e. a security with initial cost, V0 < 0, and time t = 1 value V1 ≥ 0.
Definition 5 A type B arbitrage is a security or portfolio that has a non-positive initial cost, has positive
probability of yielding a positive payoff at t = 1 and zero probability of producing a negative payoff then. i.e. a
security with initial cost, V0 ≤ 0, and V1 ≥ 0 but V1 6= 0.
Theorem 1 There is no arbitrage in the 1-period binomial model if and only if d < R < u.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 13
Proof: (i) Suppose R < d < u. Then at t = 0 we should borrow S0 and purchase one unit of the stock.
(ii) Suppose d < u < R. Then short-sell one unit of the stock at t = 0 and invest the proceeds in cash-account.
In both cases we have a type B arbitrage and so the result follows.
We will soon see the other direction, i.e. if d < R < u, then there can be no-arbitrage. Let’s return to our
earlier numerical example and consider the following questions:
1. How much is a call option that pays max(S1 − 102, 0) at t = 1 worth?
2. How will the price vary as p varies?
To answer these questions, we will construct a replicating portfolio. Let us buy x shares and invest y in the cash
account at t = 0. At t = 1 this portfolio is worth:
Can we choose x and y so that portfolio equals the option payoff at t = 1? We can indeed by solving
107x + 1.01y = 5
93.46x + 1.01y = 0
and the solution is x = 0.3693 and y = −34.1708. Note that the cost of this portfolio at t = 0 is
The arbitrage-free time t = 0 price of the derivative must (Why?) then be C0 := xS0 + y. Solving (10) and
(11) then yields
1 R−d u−R
C0 = Cu + Cd
R u−d u−d
1
= [qCu + (1 − q)Cd ]
R
1 Q
= E [C1 ] (12)
R 0
where q := (R − d)/(u − d) so that 1 − q = (u − R)/(u − d). Note that if d < R < u then q > 0 and 1 − q > 0
and so by (12) there can be (why?) no-arbitrage. We refer to (12) as risk-neutral pricing and (q, 1 − q) are the
risk-neutral probabilities. So we now know how to price any derivative security in this 1-period binomial model
via a replication argument. Moreover this replication argument is equivalent to pricing using risk-neutral
probabilities.
We also note that the price of the derivative does not depend on p! This at first appears very surprising. To
understand this result further consider the following two stocks, ABC and XYZ:
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 14
Note that the probability of an up-move for ABC is p = .99 whereas the probability of an up-move for XYZ is
p = .01. Consider now the following two questions:
Question: What is the price of a call option on ABC with strike K = $100?
Question: What is the price of a call option on XYZ with strike K = $100?
You should be surprised by your answers. But then if you think a little more carefully you’ll realize that the
answers are actually not surprising given the premise that two stocks like ABC and XYZ actually exist
side-by-side in the market.
and we note the risk-neutral probabilities for ST are displayed at the far right in the binomial lattice above.
Risk-neutral pricing pricing via (13) has the advantage of not needing to calculate the option price at every
intermediate node.
Question: How would you find a replicating strategy for the option?
For example, the value of the option at the lower node at time t = 2 is given by
1
12.66 = max 12.66, (q × 6.54 + (1 − q) × 18.37)
R
where 12.66 = 100 − 87.34 is the intrinsic value of the option at that node. More generally, the value, Vt (S), of
the American put option at any time t node when the underlying price is S can be computed according to
1
Vt (S) = max K − S, [q × Vt+1 (uS) + (1 − q) × Vt+1 (dS)]
R
1 Q
= max K − S, Et [Vt+1 (St+1 )] .
R
We will return to option pricing in much greater generality when we study martingale pricing.
Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options 16
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/3866575?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
International Monetary Fund, Palgrave Macmillan Journals are collaborating with JSTOR
to digitize, preserve and extend access to Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund)
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Effect of Exchange Rate
Changes on the Prices and Volume
of Foreign Trade
MORDECHAI E. KREININ *
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
298 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
2 See, for example, the following studies: Morris Goldstein and Mohsin S.
Khan, "Large Versus Small Price Changes and the Demand for Imports," Staff
Papers, Vol. 23 (March 1976), pp. 200-25; Hendrik S. Houthakker and Stephen
P. Magee, "Income and Price Elasticities in World Trade," Review of Economics
and Statistics, Vol. 51 (May 1969), pp. 111-25; Mordechai E. Kreinin, "Disag-
gregated Import Demand Functions-Further Results," Southern Economic Jour-
nal, Vol. 40 (July 1973), pp. 19-25, and "Price Elasticities in International Trade,"
Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 49 (November 1967), pp. 510-16; and
James E. Price and James B. Thornblade, "U. S. Import Demand Functions
Disaggregated by Country and Commodity," Southern Economic Journal. Vol. 39
(July 1972), pp. 46-57.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 299
curves. In other words, such a country can, by its own actions, affect its
terms of trade. The reverse may be the case with respect to the supply
of exports. Here, a large country is likely to have a more elastic export
supply than a small one '(because exports constitute a smaller proportion
of output in most industries in large countries) and is, therefore, less
likely to change export prices denominated in its own currency following
an exchange adjustment. Consequently, exporters in a large country are
likely to pass through a greater proportion of a devaluation or revalua-
tion than exporters in a small country.3
But this argument assumes that the small country specializes in the
export of a few commodities and that it exports a substantial portion of
domestic output of each commodity-an assumption that may be incor-
rect. Viewed from the demand side, the foregoing observations reflect
the fact that a small country is a price taker on the international market,
unable to influence its terms of trade. But this statement leaves open the
question of how large a country has to be before it acquires some control
over its terms of trade, as well as the different degrees of market power
associated with varying economic size. Consequently, the above a priori
statement must be regarded as tentative. In essence, the pass-through
question is an empirical one; it can be handled either through precise
knowledge of the elasticities involved, or by a method specifically
designed to measure the pass-through.
In many empirical studies of the domestic impact of commercial policy
conducted in the 1950s and early 1960s, there was a tendency on the
part of researchers to assume (implicitly or explicitly) a 100 per cent
pass-through. More specifically, it was commonly assumed that changes
in, say, tariffs were fully reflected in changes in import and/or export
prices. In recent years, the pendulum has swung almost completely in
the opposite direction (especially in some theoretical discussions). For
example, in the view of some economists the law of one price ensures
the same price on the world market for each internationally traded good
(including "differentiated" products). Consequently, given sufficient time,
exchange rate adjustments would be fully compensated for by changes in
domestic prices.
Furthermore, during the recent period of fluctuating exchange rates,
the issue has become a key factor in a certain theory that purports to
explain world-wide inflation. While the basic hypothesis involved, the
3 Note, however, that even if domestic export prices rise in full proportion to
the devaluation, there is an inducement to expand exports, since domestic output
expands and consumption contracts with the increase in local currency prices.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
300 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 301
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
302 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 303
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
304 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 305
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
306 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
revalued by 8 per cent relative to the dollar between 1970 and 1972,
while Finland did not change its dollar exchange rate. If the U.S.
(dollar-denominated) import price index from Norway increased 16 per
cent, while that from Finland increased 14 per cent, the effect of Nor-
way's revaluation on its dollar export prices to the United States is taken
to be (16 per cent - 14 per cent =) 2 per cent, and its pass-through effect
on U. S. imports is then (2 - 8 =) 25 per cent. It other words, the export
price change of Finland (the control, or c, country) is used as a proxy for
the hypothetical price change of Norway (the i country in which follows)
in the absence of revaluation. Schematically (with all figures representing
percentages):
Estimated
Norway Finland Differential Pass-Through
ERJ +8 0 8
p-.s. +16 +14 2
where EsR is the percentage chan
1970 and 1972, and pv..' is the pe
from each country over the sam
follow, the country under investig
will be referred to as the K countr
such countries. In the study of eac
tries (the criteria used for their se
to 11 i countries (defined as all cou
that trade with the K country),
estimated pass-through of the K
tions, with the averaging procedur
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 307
For any country K whose currency was devalued with respect to coun-
try i:
iPM (1)
That is,
country
relative
P/I as a
rate adju
estimated as:
pK _ pK
a= 100 (2)
In all calculatio
average 1970 t
price levels in
cluded in each
i countries ar
matching don
But this proce
are unaffected
rise in p/ Kwo
from country
Although this
short time spa
lation must, th
through effec
trol country,
Equation (2) i
pass-through.
9 to 11 i coun
The import p
will be discuss
dwell on vario
well as alternative formulas.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
308 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
is 12 per ce
cent. This is t
ber subtracted
mate should
change adjustm
bound estimate is to the true estimate. As a second alternative, assume
15 None of the three countries is "ideal." Thus, Finland's exports are highly
specialized, while the United Kingdom suffers from perennial domestic problems.
Therefore, only average results are presented. These were later verified using Italy
as a control country.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 309
that the control country (the United Kingdom) experienced a 100 per cent
pass-through. Then only 8 (12 - 4) per cent of the U. K. price rise would
have occurred in the absence of a sterling revaluation. The German pass-
P = f (ERK, Pd)
Since our interest centers on the effect of the exchange rate, we wish to
hold constant the impact of domestic inflation. But Pd may be different in
the control and the i country. To account for the difference, the price index
of K country imports from the control country was adjusted in each com-
parison (with an i country) by the difference between the two countries'
1972 domestic prive indices (1970= 100).
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
310 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 311
ai iMM70+72
a = M for imports (MK represents imports of K)
E M70+72
E ai ? iX70+72
a = X fK for exports (XK represents exports of K)
70+72
P = a + b ER
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
312 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
P = -2.17 + 0.92 ER
'K *K
M cM 5?
/ REGRESS
0 /
EFFECTIVE EXCHANGE ERK
RATE CHANGE
Figure 1
18A shortcoming of this method in the present context is that the effective
exchange rate index is computed for country K relative to all currencies-the
control currencies as well as the i currencies-while the regression line is esti-
mated on the basis of the relation of country K's currency to the (adjusted)
i country currencies only.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 313
Q - Q and (7)
QK- K (8)
These would t
average as ind
substitution bet
tions of its exp
mates must be
Implied in the
demand elastic
demand for eac
Finally, the d
substitution b
market. In mo
observations
between 1970
pertains to a co
pair. A regres
19 On the expor
tion) absorbed b
pass-through.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
314 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
In Qt/Qj = a + b In (Pg/Pj)
for each pair of suppliers i and j (covering matched products), wher
is the estimated elasticity.
1. PERIOD COVERED
2. DATA SOURCES
Because the study focuses on the behavior of unit value and quantity
(or volume 21), it requires the use of a set of commodity trade statistics
20 Consumer price indices are available in the OECD, Main Economic Indi-
cators (various issues). For some countries, the wholesale price index and the
index of producers' prices of manufactured goods are given in the same publica-
tion. Indices of unit labor costs in manufacturing for ten countries were compiled
and supplied privately by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U. S. Department
of Labor.
21 The words quantity and volume are used interchangeably in this study. Unit
value is value divided by volume; it is used as the only available (albeit imper-
fect) proxy for price.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 315
3. COMPUTATIONAL PROCEDURES
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
316 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
E (%AUVGer X ValueGe6+1972)
all
IV. Results
1. PASS-THROUGH EFFECT
24 Negative changes in either quantity or unit value were taken into account.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 317
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
TABLE 2. Six INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES: ESTIMATED EFFECTS OF EXCHANGE RATE ADJUSTMENT ON TR
Value of
Trade With Percentage
Industrial Change in
Direction Countries Estimated Effective C
K Control of (average for Pass- Exchange Terms of
Country Countries Trade 1970-72) Through 1 Rate Tr
Billion U. S.
dollars X Per cent
United States Canada Imports 32 50 -1
United Kingdom Exports 28
Finland
1 A pass-through on the import side is defined as the percentage of the devaluation (revaluation) translated
in domestic prices. On the export side, it is defined as the percentage of the devaluation (revaluation) translate
in foreign import prices from the country under study, or 100 per cent minus the percentage change in that country's
2 Figure appears to be unduly high.
3 Volume and estimated elasticity of import demand are biased downward.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 319
Imports
Exports
27 The results for the United States were checked by rerunning the estimates
using Italy as a control country. The estimates so generated closely approximate
the results shown in Table 2.
Also, the U. S. estimates conform to the results obtained for the floating
exchange rate period, using a distributed lag model, in Clark, "Effect of Exchange
Rate Changes" (cited in footnote 9), and to the estimates derived by Jacques
R. Artus in his paper, "The Behavior of Export Prices for Manufactures," Staff
Papers, Vol. 21 (November 1974), pp. 583-604.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
320 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
and 80 per cent for Germany and Japan, respectively.2' For the remai
three countries in Table 2, the import pass-through rises to betwee
and 100 per cent. Not reported in the table are estimates for Austria a
Switzerland, each of which show 100 per cent import pass-through. Th
results conform to theoretical expectations in terms of their absolute
they conform especially well in terms of the country ranking.
On the export side, the estimated pass-through ranges from 60-
per cent. The export pass-through appears to be invariably on the
side, meaning that export prices expressed in domestic currencies did
change much. For the Federal Republic of Germany and Italy, the resu
appear to be unduly high, and to contain a possible upward bias. T
estimates for Canada undoubtedly reflect the importance of the U
States as a trading partner of Canada, for they are nearly a mirror im
of the U. S. results.
By applying the pass-through estimates in Table 2 to the respec
changes in the effective exchange rates, we obtain the changes in the te
of trade of each country owing to the exchange adjustment. The la
positive impact occurred in Japan, while the largest negative effect to
place in the United States. In sum, within the three-year time span un
consideration, the estimates support the traditional view that (whe
product of the supply elasticities exceeds the product of the dem
elasticities) devaluation worsens a country's terms of trade, while reva
ation improves them.
These results cast doubt on the strength of the so-called ratchet eff
Foreign exporters to the United States met the revaluation of their cu
rencies by lowering their export prices by more than half the revalua
more than matching the increase in import prices in the devaluing coun
Conversely, exporters to the Federal Republic of Germany (and,
lesser extent, to Japan) raised their prices by only 40 per cent of
German revaluation.
Similarly, U. S. export prices, expressed in foreign currencies, declin
roughly in proportion to the U. S. devaluation,29 while Japanes
Canadian export prices rose proportionately less than their revalua
Nor is there support for the M-L argument that domestic price incre
would fully erode any competitive gain from devaluation, or that cur
devaluations constitute the main force propelling the worldwide infla
28 Highly tentative estimates for the United Kingdom yield results simil
those obtained for Japan.
29 For evidence that such declines can also lower domestic prices in the im
ing countries, consult Goldstein, op. cit.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 321
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
322 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
V. Direction of Causality
Throughout this study, it has been assumed that exchange rate changes
affect the prices of traded goods, and not the converse; this is a fairly
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 323
Finland -0.8
France -1.0 -0.4
Netherlands -0.4
Norway -0.8
Sweden " -0.6
United States " -1.8 -0.8
SITC 5 -1.2
SITC 6 -0.5 ...
SITC 7 -1.5 ...
SITC 8 -1.8
safe assumption for the period under review. While only a properly speci-
fied distributed lag model can provide a conclusive test of this proposition,
it was suggested long ago by Gustav Cassel that the causation runs from
exchange rates to prices in a period of fixed exchange rates, and from
prices to exchange rates in a period of freely fluctuating rates.32 The
evidence presented in this study, based on the Smithsonian Agreement,
was obtained in the context of discrete exchange adjustments in a regime
of fixed rates. Moreover, the price comparisons between the 1970 average
and the 1972 average, with most exchange variations occurring in August-
December 1971, introduce two sequential time lags, of roughly 13 and 11
months, respectively, between the exchange rate changes and the two price
bases being compared. These features strongly suggest (although they do
not guarantee) that the causal effect is from exchange rate changes to
price changes.
This conjecture is supported by the results pertaining to the United
States, a country which was at one extreme on the spectrum of exchange
variations (i.e., it experienced the largest effective devaluation). It is well
known that the U. S. competitive position on world markets deteriorated
greatly in the 1960s, especially in the second half of the decade, and it
32 See Harry G. Johnson and Jacob A. Frenkel, "Essential Concepts and His-
torical Origins," in The Monetary Approach (cited in footnote 7), p. 29.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
324 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
was this deterioration that led to the dollar devaluations in the early
If causation ran from prices to exchange rate adjustments, then
prices denominated in dollars (a proxy for domestic prices) wou
been expected to move up (in a relative sense), leading to the dev
of the dollar. Instead, no export price movement accompanied the
exchange adjustment-that is, a 100 per cent pass-through effect was
observed on the export side. This is consistent with an exchange adjust-
ment to price change causality, when the export supply elasticities are
infinite or nearly so. A similar point can be made concerning the terms
of trade. The terms of trade of the United States deteriorated, and those
of the Federal Republic of Germany and Japan improved following the
exchange adjustments. Again, this suggests that it was exchange rates
that influenced price movements.
By March of 1973, the fixed exchange rate regime gave way to fluctu-
ating rates. The purchasing-power-parity theory of exchange rate determ-
ination postulates that variations in (some index of) domestic prices
determine exchange rate fluctuations. Since exchange rate changes also
affect the prices of traded goods, the direction of causality can run both
ways. Consequently, in a 1970-73 comparison of exchange rate variations
with price changes, the causal relation is probably mixed. Indeed, in
studies correlatinig price and exchange rate movements in the recent period
of floating exchange rates, no causal relation can be postulated. Certainly,
a strong departure from, or a complete reversal of, the results mentioned
in the previous paragraph would suggest a causal relation from prices to
exchange rates, at least in part. And a mixed causality is what the results
for 1970-73 strongly suggest.
Using the same technique, this paper investigates the pass-through
effect occurring between (average) 1970 and (average) 1973 in some of
the major industrial countries. It will be recalled that the fixed exchange
rate system broke down, and floating rates were introduced, in March
1973. But, in most cases, the float was managed-sometimes heavily-
by government intervention. For Japan, it is widely assumed that govern-
ment intervention was so intense as to practically preserve the fixed
exchange rate regime. Indeed, the Japanese pass-through results for
1970-73 confirm this, for they were similar to those for 1970-72: 60 per
cent on the import side and 75 per cent on the export side. With a 22
per cent effective revaluation of the yen, this implies a terms-of-trade
improvement of 8 per cent.33 While there was no discernible effect on
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 325
Japan's import volume, its exports are estimated (by the control country
method) to have declined by 23 per cent as a result of the revaluation,
yielding a demand elasticity for Japan's exports of -1.4.
In contrast, the 1970-73 results for the United States reflect a "prices
to exchange rate," or a mixed, causality. The effective dollar exchange
rate fell 15 per cent, with an estimated pass-through of 40 per cent on both
the import and the export sides. This implies a 3 per cent improvement34
in the U. S. terms of trade. The association of depreciation with improved
terms of trade (precisely the reverse of the 1970-72 condition) suggests
a "prices to exchange rate" causality. Mixed causality is suggested by the
results pertaining to other industrial countries.
APPENDIX
34A (0.40 x 15 per cent =) 6 per cent rise in dollar import prices and a
(0.60 x 60 per cent =) 9 per cent rise in dollar export prices.
35 These are available upon request from the author, whose address is Depart-
ment of Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan 48823.
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
TABLE 5. FRANCE: EXPORTS TO 15 INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES, 1970-
.0
0
Cd
S S z
-
Canada 84% 76 82 80 83 64 71 65 6
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
TABLE 6. FRANCE: IMPORTS FROM 15 INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES, 1970-7
o
.0
*a a a ?* a S
Canada 65% 42 53 67 85 42 57 48 4
24 1
Japan 56 19 63 77 26 61 75 75 5
39 6 156
Austria 48 23 57 65 56 56 65 67 5
29 4 131 221
Denmark 51 36 61 65 31 41 60 52 5
277 132 213 164
Finland 23 50 21 24 43 28 29 24 3
116 72 78 78 72
Belgium-Luxembourg l 93 94 92 90 95 91 98 98 9
707 244 405 306 293 117
Germany, Fed. Rep. 95 92 99 97 96 96 99 99 99
783 249 445 329 300 125 917
Italy 83 47 95 94 90 64 93 95 92
695 226 432 314 289 108 796 872
Netherlands 90 77 85 94 93 88 97 96 95
675 229 388 292 210 114 769 815 719
Sweden 62 54 68 71 86 90 68 77 65 63
370 169 253 230 221 108 396 411 382 310
Switzerland 81 61 86 89 89 85 81 87 86 7
568 207 364 278 269 105 626 690 629 58
United Kingdom 88 82 92 92 92 61 91 94 90 8
682 237 402 300 284 112 731 803 720 67
Norway 40 55 37 58 64 90 37 47 36 3
167 101 116 100 106 78 177 182 162 16
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
328 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND STAFF PAPERS
Exports Imports
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
EFFECT OF EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON TRADE 329
This content downloaded from 203.129.195.130 on Tue, 03 Mar 2020 03:32:14 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
Marketing
Marketing
Definition:
The business of promoting and selling
products or services, including market research
and advertising is called as marketing.
Primary and essential skill of economist
Attitude based
Marketing steps
• Understand Customers
• Define brand person
• Crystalize the brand promise
• Perfect visual assets
• Refine customer experience
• Remember to give back
• The process involved in creating a unique name
and image for a product in the consumers' mind,
mainly through advertising campaigns with a
consistent theme.
• Branding aims to establish a significant and
differentiated presence in the market that attracts
and retains loyal customers. Branding is almost
intangible.
• The purpose of branding is knowing and consistently
living from a true identity, from a real story, so that
executive leadership, sales, marketing, product, support,
operations, and corporate culture all align and mature in
a compelling manner of the product.
• Good branding elevates a business and builds
recognition and loyalty. Customers are attracted to
brands that share similar values with them. When you
showcase what you value through branding, customers
will develop an emotional connection to you.
Types of Brands
• Individual Brands.
• Service Brands.
• Organization Brands.
• Personal Brands.
• Group Brands.
• Event Brands.
• Geographic Place Brands.
• Private-Label Brands.
Examples
Personality
• Five major traits
underlie personality,
according to psychologists.
They are
introversion/extroversion,
openness, conscientiousness,
extraversion, agreeableness
and neuroticism.
• The combination of characteristics or qualities that form
an individual's distinctive character.
• Personality, a characteristic way of thinking, feeling, and
behaving. Personality embraces moods, attitudes, and
opinions and is most clearly expressed in interactions
with other people. It includes behavioural characteristics,
both inherent and acquired, that distinguish one person
from another and that can be observed in people’s
relations to the environment and to the social group.
Motivation
• Motivation is the word derived from the word
'motive' which means needs, desires, wants or drives
within the individuals. It is the process of stimulating
people to actions to accomplish the goals. In the
work goal context the psychological factors
stimulating the people's behaviour can be - desire for
money. success.
• Extrinsic Motivation----Extrinsic motivation
comes from outside us.
• Intrinsic Motivation----Intrinsic motivation is
done for internal reasons, for example to align
with values or simply for the hedonistic
pleasure of doing something.
• Introjected Motivation.
• Identified Motivation.
Fishers man son---- President of India
Tourist Guide------- Alibaba owner
School teacher son---- King of Software
Petrol station worker----Reliance
Hotel supplier boy----IAS officer (Veerapandian, Madurai)
House wife---IPS officer, Mumbai (M.Ambika)
School teacher--- SRM university
A drop out degree holder--- CavinKare
Leadership