0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views

ECO 317 - Economics of Uncertainty - Fall Term 2009 Slides To Accompany

This document summarizes issues related to adverse selection in insurance markets. It discusses how asymmetric information, where one party has private information about risk, can lead either to a separating equilibrium where high- and low-risk individuals purchase different policies, or potentially to a pooling equilibrium. In a separating equilibrium, low-risk individuals cannot obtain full coverage due to high-risk individuals posing as low-risk. Pooling may be preferable if there are few high-risk individuals, but is unstable due to cream-skimming competition between insurers.

Uploaded by

Laurence Go
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
86 views

ECO 317 - Economics of Uncertainty - Fall Term 2009 Slides To Accompany

This document summarizes issues related to adverse selection in insurance markets. It discusses how asymmetric information, where one party has private information about risk, can lead either to a separating equilibrium where high- and low-risk individuals purchase different policies, or potentially to a pooling equilibrium. In a separating equilibrium, low-risk individuals cannot obtain full coverage due to high-risk individuals posing as low-risk. Pooling may be preferable if there are few high-risk individuals, but is unstable due to cream-skimming competition between insurers.

Uploaded by

Laurence Go
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 7

ECO 317 – Economics of Uncertainty – Fall Term 2009

Slides to accompany
15. Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets

ADVERSE SELECTION – GENERAL ISSUES


One party in a trade or contract has advance private information
that it can use for its own benefit / the other’s detriment
The other side knows the situation, so wary to trade
Akerlof’s example of market collapse: Private used car market
In population of used cars, qualities (measured in dollars)
uniformly distributed over [a, b]. Distribution is common knowledge,
but the actual realization for any single car is private info of owner
So price of individual car cannot be contingent on quality
If common price is p, only those in [a, p] will sell
Potential buyers will recognize this, and condition on it:
Average quality in the market will be 12 (a + p)
For equilibrium, p = 12 (a + p).
So p = a, and only the worst cars will trade.

1
Solution requires conveying credible information about
qualities of individual cars. Works in two ways:
Signaling – action taken by informed party (owner)
Screening – action required / initiated by uninformed (prospective buyer)
(i) direct inspection at a cost
(ii) mechanism using informed player’s self-selecting (info. revealing) action
Direct inspection (get car checked by professional,
give test to job applicant or check-up to health/life insurance applicant)
Possible but costly, imperfect; ignore these here and focus on other actions.
General idea – action should be optimal if information is “good”
but not if it is “bad”, so wrong type won’t imitate, pretend to be good.
Signaling example – seller offers warranty on car, but is this credible?
Screening by self-selection example – restricted fares on airlines
We will develop three examples (models) in detail:
[1] Rothschild-Stiglitz (QJE 1976): competitive screening in insurance (today)
[2] Spence (QJE 1973): job market signaling (later)
[3] Pricing policy of monopolist facing unknown demand (later)
(version of Baron-Myerson Econometrica 82,Mussa-Rosen JET 1978)

2
PERFECT INSURANCE – Reminder From Handout 9, pp. 1-4
Initial wealth W0 , loss L in state 2; probability of loss π
Can choose level of insurance; p = premium per dollar of coverage (indemnity)
Budget line in state-contingent wealth space (W1 , W2 ):
(1 − p) W1 + p W2 = (1 − p) W0 + p (W0 − L)

Slope of budget line = (1 − p)/p

EU = (1 − π) u(W1) + π u(W2)

Slope of indiff. curve on 45-degree line


= (1 − π)/π.
If statistically fair insurance is available
in competitive market, then p = π;
tangency on 45-degree line,
customer buys full coverage.
Fair budget line is also insurance company’s zero-profit line.
Contract below it gives positive profit; above, makes a loss.

3
TWO RISK TYPES, SYMMETRIC INFORMATION
Loss probabilities πL < πH
MRS for type i in (W1 , W2 ) space is


dW2  ∂EU/∂W1
− 

=
dW1 EU =const ∂EU/∂W2
1 − πi u(W1 )
=
πi u(W2 )

At any (W1, W2 ), indifference curve of


L-type is steeper than that of H-type
Similar conditions appear in
all signaling/screening models.
Crucial for separation of types. Called
Mirrlees-Spence single-crossing property.
So without information asymmetry, in competitive market, each type
can get separate contract with fair premium, and chooses full coverage.

4
ASYMMETRIC INFO – SEPARATING EQUILIBRIUM
Each firm offers one contract
Free entry; firms compete in contracts
In equilibrium, each has zero expected profit
Ignore other costs, so a contract with
only type-L customers must be on
fair premium line of slope (1 − πL )/πL ;
if only H-types,line of slope (1 − πH )/πH .
Full fair coverage contracts CH , CL are
not incentive-compatible: H will take up CL
Must restrict coverage available to L-types
Can at best offer SL , so H-types
only just prefer CH to SL .
Then single-crossing property ensures
that L-types definitely prefer SL to CH

So separation by self-selection (screening). But at a cost: L-types can’t get full coverage.
H-types’ existence exerts a kind of negative externality on L-types.

5
ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION – POOLING?
Separation may be Pareto inferior if
there are very few H-types in population
Population proportions θH , θL
population average loss probability is
πM = θH πH + θL πL
Contract with randomly drawn customers
from whole population has zero profit line
of slope = (1 − πM )/πM
On it, any point between P1 and P2
is Pareto-better than the contracts
CH , SL of separating “equilibrium”
Segment P1 P2 exists when πM is
close to πL, i.e. θH is small
Then new firm can offer contract just below segment P1 P2 .
This will attract full sample of pop’n and make profit.
Then the original separating contracts CH , SL cannot be an equilibrium.

6
But can pooling itself be a
(Nash) equilibrium? No.
Consider any point PM on
population-average zero-profit line
By single-crossing property
can find S that appeals only to L-types
and is below zero-profit line for
contracts with only L-type customers
So company offering S makes positive profit
Entry of such insurers will destroy pooling
Then equilibrium may not exist at all –
competition can generate cycles
between separation and pooling.

More complex notions of equilibrium (where entrants anticipate effects of


incumbents’ responses to entry) can allow pooling to be sustained in equilibrium.
Also government can play a role: can make joining pool compulsory,
thereby preventing the harmful “cream-skimming” competition.
Of course a government-run pool can have its own problems.

You might also like