Monetary Policy - Notes
Monetary Policy - Notes
1 Introduction
In general the setup is described somewhat like the following:
πt = mt + vt (1.1)
xt = θt + πt − πet − t (1.2)
∞
X
L= βt Lt (πt , xt ) (1.3)
t=1
1 2
Lt = (πt − π̄)2 + λ (xt − x̄) (1.4)
2
Equation (1.1) describes the demand side of the economy. For simplicity, we assume that inflation is
determined by the monetary policy and some stochastic demand shock vt . Equation (1.2) describes
a Phillips-curve relationship, describing that output/employment, xt , is determined by two types of
stochastic shocks as well as surprise inflation, πt − πet . Lastly, equation (1.3)-(1.4) describes how we can
measure social loss as fluctuations from a target level of inflation and employment.1
• Assume shocks are persistent, for instance that t follows an AR(1) process:
• Assume that inflation evolves according to the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) instead of
(1.2):
xt = θt + κ1 πt − κ2 E[πt+1 ] − t (1.6)
• Include foreign currency zone and allow for a pegged currency, for instance the euro zone. As-
suming they have commitment policy this would imply:
λEU
πEU
t = EU , Corr(t , EU
t )=α (1.8)
1 + λEU t
1
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
• Assume imperfect control over inflation, such that monetary policy affects output through a DIS
curve:
In the case of (1.5)-(1.6), see notes from assignment 4. In the case of the dynamic setup of (1.7) and
trigger-strategies, see PS15. For different political parties and cooperation see PS16, and for the pegged
currency case see PS17.2 In the following sections, we will go through some standard results/cookbook
approaches in the simple static cases and leave the more advanced dynamic problems for problem sets.
2 Forthe case of imperfect control over inflation, forward guidance and other extensions, one source is Henrik Jensen’s
Monetary Policy course site, http://www.econ.ku.dk/personal/Henrikj/monpol2016/slides.asp.
2
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
1. The monetary authority announces their policy rule (only commitment case)
4. t is realized
In the last section we will briefly show how a different assumption of timing can affect our solution
approach.
• Postulate a monetary policy rule: It can be shown that optimal monetary policy with a quadratic
loss function follows a linear rule. Thus in our case, we announce a rule of the type:
mt = a1 + a2 vt + a3 θt + a4 t (2.1)
• Impose credibility of the rule: If we are in an equlibrium, private agents trust that we will in
fact carry out monetary policy according to (2.1). With our assumed timing, this implies that
expected inflation follows:
• Minimize expected social loss: Use the result in (2.1), (2.2) and the Phillips-curve to describe the
expected loss
=xt
=πt
1 z }| { z }| {
E[Lt ] = E (mt + vt −π̄)2 + λ(θt + πt − πet − t −x̄)2
2
Using (2.1) Using (2.1) and (2.2)
1 z }| { z }| {
= E (a1 + vt (a2 + 1) + a3 θt + a4 t −π̄)2 + λ(θt + t (a4 − 1) −x̄)2 (2.3)
2
Next we need to square the terms in (2.3) and take expectations, before minimizing the expres-
sion. We will use that (almost) all cross-products in expectation are zero.3 We finally obtain the
expected loss
1 2
a1 + (a2 + 1)2 σ2v + a23 σ2θ + a24 σ2 + π̄2 − 2a1 π̄ + λ(σ2θ + (a4 − 1)2 σ2 + x̄2
E[Lt ] = (2.4)
2
3 See appendix for an elaboration on this part.
3
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
The expression in (2.4) is straightforwardly differentiable. Thus we will have the 4 first order
conditions
πt −πe
z }| {
t
C λ
xt = θt + t −t
1+λ
1
=θ− t (2.12)
1+λ
The key take-aways of commitment policy (with this particular timing at least) is:
• Inflation is stabilized around target level π̄ (often assumed zero) perfectly offsetting demand
shocks. Letting our policy parameter a2 = −1 the demand shock vt will not affect inflation or
output.
• We cannot stabilize output around the target level x̄, as this would be anticipated and only create
an inflation bias.
• We cannot stabilize θt shocks, as they are anticipated by private agents. This is due to our
assumption of timing however.
• We can stabilize t shocks partially (not fully as with demand shocks, vt ). The optimal trade-off
between inflation and output is given by the coefficients, λ/(1 + λ) and −1/(1 + λ).
other shocks.
4
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
• Compute rational expectations of inflation: Use that private agents know that inflation will
follow the rule (2.14), such that
π̄ + λ(πet + x̄ − θt )
e λ −1 e
πt = E (π̄λ + πt + x̄ + t − θt )|θt = (2.15)
1+λ 1+λ
using that E[t |θt ] = 0. Solving for πet in (2.15) we have the rational expectation of inflation given
by
• Combine results in equilibrium: Substitute (2.16) into (2.14) to obtain equilibrium inflation
λ
πD
t = π̄ + λ(x̄ − θt ) + t (2.17)
1+λ
To arrive at the equilibrium for xD
t , use (2.16)-(2.17) in the Phillips-curve to obtain
xD D e
t = θt + πt − πt − t
1
= θt − t (2.18)
1+λ
The main result compared to commitment policy is the inflation bias: Discretionary policy entails an
inflation bias compared to commitment policy: The monetary authority has an incentive to stabilize
output around the level x̄ − θt . As private agents anticipate this, only inflation will increase, without
having an effect on output.
• Assume pegged currency: In our setup, this translates to adopting a monetary policy. Per con-
struction the inflation level is thus given by foreign inflation rule:
πPt = πEU
t , (2.19)
which may be further specified as following some sort of policy rule as in equation (1.8).
• Impose credibility: Assuming that we are in an equilibrium, private agents expect the rule in
(2.19), thus we have
t |θt ]
πet = E πEU
(2.20)
• Combine results in equilibrium: Use (2.19) and (2.20) in the Phillips-curve to obtain the output
level
• The main upside of the pegged currency is that compared to discretionary policy, we eliminate
the inflation bias.
• The downside of the approach depends on how the adopted inflation policy correlates with
domestic shocks. If domestic and foreign shocks are uncorrelated, the pegged currency will not
be able to stabilize domestic shocks t .
5
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
λB
B
!
B
πt π̄ + λ (x̄ − θt ) + 1 + λB t
= (2.22)
B
xt 1
θt − t
1 + λB
where λB represents the relative preference for output-stabilization of our hired central banker. We
solve the problem as follows:
• When choosing the optimal CB, we assume that we have to hire him before knowing the shocks.
Thus we need to evaluate the expected loss of hiring λB :
1
E (πB 2
+ λE (xB 2
E[Lt ] = t − π̄) t − x̄)
2 " 2 # " 2 #!
1 B λB 1
= E λ (x̄ − θt ) + t + λE θt − t − x̄ (2.23)
2 1 + λB 1 + λB
Before differentiating we start squaring the terms and take expectations. As in the case of com-
mitment policy, we will use that all the cross-terms are zero in expectations.
B
2 !
1 λ 1
E[Lt ] = (λB )2 (x̄2 + σ2θ ) + σ2 + λ σ2θ + x̄2 + σ2 (2.24)
2 1 + λB (1 + λB )2
• Ideally we would minmize the expected loss in (2.24) by differentiating with respect to λB setting
it equal to zero and solving for λB . That is, solve the equation:
∂E[Lt ] λB λ
= λB (x̄2 + σ2θ ) + σ2 − σ2 = 0 (2.25)
∂λ B B
(1 + λ ) 3 (1 + λB )3
However, as we cannot solve this, we will instead charactize the optimal solution by evaluating
derivatives in certain values of λB .
• Is it optimal to choose λB = 0?
∂E[Lt ] B
(λ = 0) = −λσ2 < 0, λ>0 (2.26)
∂λB
The derivative in (2.26) states that if we consider choosing a central banker with λB = 0, marginally
increasing λB would lower the expected loss. Thus the optimal central banker is characterized by
(λB )∗ > 0.
• Is it optimal to choose λB = λ?
∂E[Lt ] B
(λ = λ) = λ(x̄2 + σ2θ ) > 0, λ>0 (2.27)
∂λB
The derivative in (2.27) states that if we consider hiring a central banker with the same preferences
for output-stabilization as our own, λB = λ, we could lower the expected loss by decreasing λB .
Thus the optimal central banker must have preferences such that (λB )∗ < λ. Thus we know that
0 < (λB )∗ < λ.
The intuition behind choosing a central banker where λB < λ comes from balancing the two effects:
• Choosing λB < λ means that the loss from the inflation bias is lowered: λ(x̄2 + σ2θ ).
6
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
• Choosing λB < λ means that the stabilization of the t shocks is not optimal anymore, as a
suboptimal large part of the shock affects output.
• The optimal monetary policy weighs the two effects in optimum, thus 0 < (λB )∗ < λ. Lastly,
note that choosing λB = λ is equivalent to choosing our own discretionary policy, while λB = 0 is
equivalent to choosing a pegged currency where foreign inflation is always zero. Thus the central
banker solution is preferred to discretionary policy and pegged currency.
7
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
• Assume pegged currency: The same first step as in the equilibrium approach. Thus we adopt
the foreign inflation level:
πt = πEU
t (3.1)
• Impose no credibility: Assuming that we are not in equilibrium implies that private agents
expect the outcome of second step in discretionary policy, equation (2.16):
xt = θt + πEU
t − (π̄ + λ(x̄ − θt )) − t
= (1 + λ)θt + πEU
t − π̄ − t − λx̄ (3.3)
In order to create credibility we have to live with a relatively large shock to output/employment,
as we play πEU
t , but agents expect the inflation bias.
λ
πt = π̄ + t (3.4)
1+λ
λ
xt = θt + π̄ + t − (π̄ + λ(x̄ − θt )) − t
1+λ
1
= (1 + λ)θt − t − λx̄ (3.6)
1+λ
In order to obtain credibility of the policy rule, we have to live with a relatively large shock to
employment. The intuition is that we will not have any inflation bias, but agents will expect it.
8
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
However, other changes such as those explained in equation (1.5)-(1.8) in the introduction does not
change the fundamental steps of our solution approach, but alters how we perform each step. For
instance, changing our model setup as in assignment 4 such that
t = ρt−1 + ut
xt = θt + πt − Et [πt+1 ] − t ,
we would still perform discretionary policy by the steps 1) Minimize actual social loss, 2) compute
rational expectations and 3) combine results in equilibrium. However, the way we have changed
our model implies that the second step, computing rational expectations, is a lot more involved than
outlined in section 2.2. The same general comment can be tied to the assumption of timing: The general
steps for solving the problem will often be the same, but often change how we carry out the specific
steps.
5 For the interested, this involves solving a system of expectational difference equations. This can be done by using a Bellman
equation/value-function approach. Once again, you could check out the course site for Monetary Policy for inspiration. (or ask
me)
9
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
π t = mt (5.1)
xt = θt + πt − πet − t (5.2)
∞
X
L= βt Lt (πt , xt ) (5.3)
t=1
1 2
πt + λ(xt − x̄)2 ,
Lt = (5.4)
2
where we assume that both θt and t are IID errors with zero mean and constant standard deviations
σθ , σ . Furthermore, we assume that the timing of the model follows from:
πt = a1 + a2 θt + a3 t (5.5)
• Impose credibility of the rule: Assuming that we are in an equilibrium, private agents expect
monetary policy to follow the rule (5.5). Using the timing stated above, they form expectations
not knowing t and θt is, as they are realized after expectations are formed:
• Minimize expected social loss: Use the results in (5.5) and (5.6) and the Phillips-curve in our
expected loss function:
=πt =xt
1 z }| { z }| {
E[Lt ] = E (a1 + a2 θt + a3 t )2 + λ(θt + πt − πet − t −x̄)2
2
1
E (a1 + a2 θt + a3 t )2 + λ(θt (1 + a2 ) + t (a3 − 1) − x̄)2
= (5.7)
2
In order for us to minimize this expression, we need to start by evaluate expectations first. Once
again using that all cross-terms in expectations are zero, we only have squared terms left after
squaring and taking expectations:
1 2
a + a22 σ2θ + a23 σ2 + λ(σ2θ (1 + a2 )2 + σ2 (a3 − 1)2 + x̄2 )
E[Lt ] = (5.8)
2 1
10
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
Mimizing this expression we differentiate with respect to our 3 policy parameters, a1 , a2 , a3 and
solves:
∂E[Lt ]
=a1 = 0 (5.9)
∂a1
∂E[Lt ]
=a2 σ2θ + λ(1 + a2 )σ2θ = 0 (5.10)
∂a2
∂E[Lt ]
=a3 σ2 + λ(a3 − 1)σ2θ = 0 (5.11)
∂a3
Solving this we get the inflation policy with commitment
λ λ
πC
t = |{z}
0 − θt + t . (5.12)
1 + λ
| {z } | {z λ}
1 +
=a1
=−a2 =a3
In general, the solution approach is not changed with the new timing. However, performing the steps
of imposing credibility of rule, and minimizing expected loss involves some new information as we
no longer condition inflation expectations on θt .
• Minimize actual social loss: As monetary policy is carried out after observing all shocks and
we do not need to announce a policy rule, as we do not have commitment, the objective of the
monetary authority is to solve the problem:
1 2
πt + λ(θt + πt − πet − t − x̄)2 .
min Lt = (5.14)
πt 2
This yields the first order condition and solution that
∂Lt λ
= πt + λ(θt + πt − πet − t − x̄) = 0 ⇒ πt = (x̄ − θt + t + πet ) (5.15)
∂πt 1+λ
• Combine results in equilibrium: Lastly, we combine the result in (5.15) − (5.16) as well as the
Phillips-curve to obtain equilibrium outcome:
λ
πD
t =λx̄ + (t − θt ) (5.17)
1+λ
1
xD
t =(θt − t ) (5.18)
1+λ
Thus once again our solution approach is the same, but the derivations, in particular how to compute
rational expectations of inflation change slightly.
11
Macro III, E2016 Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen
Appendices
A Expectations, squared terms and derivatives
When we solve for the optimal policy under commitment or central banker, we have to take into
account that we are using expected losses. In section 2.1 we encountered the expected loss function:
K1 K2
z }| { z }| {
1
E[Lt ] = E (a1 + vt (a2 + 1) + a3 θt + a4 t − π̄)2 +λ (θt + t (a4 − 1) − x̄)2 (A.1)
2
In general, it turns out that it matters whether we start by taking derivatives or expectations.6 Thus
we would prefer to write out (A.1) before differentiating. In this case, we have assumed that vt , θt , t
are all mean zero stochastic shocks with zero covariance. If we were to write out the K1 part we would
obtain:
K1 =a21 + (a2 + 1)2 v2t + a23 θ2t + a24 2t + (−π̄)2 (A.2)
+2a1 ((1 + a2 )vt + a3 θt + a4 t − π̄)
+2(1 + a2 )vt (a3 θt + a4 t − π̄)
+2a3 θt (a4 t − π̄)
+2a4 t (−π̄),
where the first line contains all the squared terms, and the last 4 contains all the cross-products. Taking
expectations now, we use that we assume that all shocks are mean zero and have zero covariance:
Note that assumptions (A.3) − (A.4) imply that almost all the cross-products in (A.2) will be zero in
expectation:
E[K1 ] =a21 + (a2 + 1)2 E v2t + a23 E θ2t + a24 E 2t + π̄2
(A.5)
−2a1 π̄
Lastly, note that with the assumption that the 3 shocks are mean zero variables implies that
2
σ2x ≡ E x2 − = E x2 .
E [x] (A.6)
| {z }
=0, when mean zero
E[K1 ] = a21 + (a2 + 1)2 σ2v + a23 σ2θ + a24 σ + π̄2 − 2a1 π̄. (A.7)
You can verify by arguments (A.3) − (A.4) and (A.6) that the last part of (A.1) is given by
6 In our simple monetary policy setup, we generally do not need to take expectations first, as the Lebesgue Dominated
Convergence Theorem holds. However, taking expectations first does not make our problem harder to solve, but it makes our
approach more robust towards more ’funky’ setups. Thus we prefer this approach.
12