2019 Subject Guide
2019 Subject Guide
D.E. Baines
EC3096
2019
Undergraduate study in
Economics, Management,
Finance and the Social Sciences
This subject guide is for a 300 course offered as part of the University of London
undergraduate study in Economics, Management, Finance and the Social
Sciences. This is equivalent to Level 6 within the Framework for Higher Education
Qualifications in England, Wales and Northern Ireland (FHEQ).
For more information see: london.ac.uk
This guide was prepared for the University of London by:
D.E. Baines, BSc (Econ), Reader in Economic History, Department of Economic History,
London School of Economics and Political Science.
This is one of a series of subject guides published by the University. We regret that due to
pressure of work the author is unable to enter into any correspondence relating to, or arising
from, the guide. If you have any comments on this subject guide, favourable or unfavourable,
please use the form at the back of this guide.
The course previously known as EC2096 Economic history in the 20th century has
now been renamed EC3096 Economic history since 1900. There is no change to the
assessment methods or course content.
University of London
Publications Office
Stewart House
32 Russell Square
London WC1B 5DN
United Kingdom
london.ac.uk
Contents
Chapter 1: Course introduction............................................................................... 1
1.1 What this course is about........................................................................................ 1
1.2 What is economic history?....................................................................................... 1
1.3 Learning outcomes.................................................................................................. 2
1.4 What you should be able to do after studying this course......................................... 2
1.5 Some important concepts........................................................................................ 2
1.6 The structure of the course....................................................................................... 8
1.7 A note on the names of countries.......................................................................... 10
1.8 The subject guide.................................................................................................. 10
1.9 Essential reading................................................................................................... 11
1.10 Further reading................................................................................................... 12
1.11 Online study resources......................................................................................... 13
1.12 The examination.................................................................................................. 14
1.13 Summing up........................................................................................................ 15
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth.......................................... 17
What this chapter is about............................................................................................ 17
Objectives.................................................................................................................... 17
Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 17
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 17
Further reading............................................................................................................. 17
Introduction................................................................................................................. 18
2.1 Factors that determine economic growth ............................................................... 18
2.2 ‘Modern economic growth’.................................................................................... 21
2.3 Industrialisation .................................................................................................... 23
2.4 The spread of modern economic growth................................................................. 24
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 27
Questions..................................................................................................................... 27
Chapter 3: The development of an international economy by 1900:
trade, capital and labour....................................................................................... 29
What this chapter is about............................................................................................ 29
Objectives.................................................................................................................... 29
Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 29
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 29
Further reading............................................................................................................. 30
Introduction................................................................................................................. 30
3.1 Characteristics of the international economy.......................................................... 30
3.2 Why did international trade grow so fast?.............................................................. 31
3.3 Overseas investment.............................................................................................. 35
3.4 International migration.......................................................................................... 37
Summary...................................................................................................................... 38
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 38
Questions..................................................................................................................... 38
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the
First World War...................................................................................................... 39
i
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
ii
Contents
Objectives.................................................................................................................... 73
Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 73
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 73
Further reading............................................................................................................. 73
Introduction................................................................................................................. 74
7.1 War economies and the direct effects of the First World War................................... 74
7.2 The long-run economic effects of the First World War.............................................. 77
7.3 Long-run trade problems....................................................................................... 78
7.4 Long-run capital flow problems............................................................................. 80
7.5 Inflation................................................................................................................ 81
7.6 The new gold standard.......................................................................................... 82
7.7 Political problems.................................................................................................. 82
Summary...................................................................................................................... 83
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 83
Questions..................................................................................................................... 83
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33.............................. 85
What this chapter is about............................................................................................ 85
Objectives.................................................................................................................... 85
Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 85
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 85
Further reading............................................................................................................. 86
Introduction................................................................................................................. 86
8.1 What was the long-run context of the crisis?.......................................................... 86
8.2 How serious was the Depression?.......................................................................... 87
8.3 What happened in the USA?.................................................................................. 87
8.4 What happened in Germany?................................................................................ 88
8.5 What happened in primary producing countries?.................................................... 88
8.6 What went wrong for Brazilian coffee producers?................................................... 89
8.7 How did the Depression spread through the world?............................................... 90
8.8 How did a banking crisis finish off the gold standard? ........................................... 92
8.9 Had the gold standard made the crisis worse?....................................................... 93
8.10 How could the crisis have been avoided before 1929?......................................... 94
8.11 Aftermath............................................................................................................ 95
8.12 Overview............................................................................................................. 95
Summary...................................................................................................................... 95
A reminder of your learning outcomes........................................................................... 96
Questions..................................................................................................................... 96
Chapter 9: Government intervention, recovery and the international economy
in the 1930s........................................................................................................... 97
What this chapter is about............................................................................................ 97
Objectives.................................................................................................................... 97
Learning outcomes....................................................................................................... 97
Essential reading.......................................................................................................... 97
Further reading............................................................................................................. 98
Introduction................................................................................................................. 98
9.1 Crisis and response in the USA.............................................................................. 98
9.2 The effect of American policy on the international economy.................................. 100
9.3 The UK and Germany........................................................................................... 101
9.4 Trading blocs....................................................................................................... 102
9.5 Germany again.................................................................................................... 102
Summary.................................................................................................................... 103
iii
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Objectives.................................................................................................................. 141
Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 141
Essential reading........................................................................................................ 141
Introduction............................................................................................................... 141
13.1 The dominance of the American economy.......................................................... 141
13.2 Supply-side economics in theory........................................................................ 146
13.3 Reaganomics in practice.................................................................................... 147
13.4 What does the Reagan experiment tell us about the relationship between
government intervention and the growth rate?...................................................149
Summary.................................................................................................................... 149
A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 149
Questions................................................................................................................... 150
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation................................................. 151
What this chapter is about.......................................................................................... 151
Objectives.................................................................................................................. 151
Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 151
Essential reading........................................................................................................ 151
Further reading........................................................................................................... 151
Introduction............................................................................................................... 152
14.1 Deindustrialisation............................................................................................. 152
14.2 The relationship between technology and the structure of industries................... 157
14.3 Japan and the third revolution........................................................................... 159
Summary ................................................................................................................... 162
A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 163
Questions................................................................................................................... 163
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late
twentieth century................................................................................................ 165
What this chapter is about.......................................................................................... 165
Objectives.................................................................................................................. 165
Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 165
Essential reading........................................................................................................ 165
Further reading........................................................................................................... 165
Introduction............................................................................................................... 166
15.1 World trade patterns.......................................................................................... 166
15.2 Developing economies....................................................................................... 170
15.3 Can trade be an engine of growth?................................................................... 174
15.4 Can growth be an engine for trade?.................................................................. 175
Summary.................................................................................................................... 176
A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 176
Questions................................................................................................................... 176
Chapter 16: Japan and China............................................................................... 177
What this chapter is about.......................................................................................... 177
Objectives.................................................................................................................. 177
Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 177
Reading..................................................................................................................... 177
Introduction............................................................................................................... 178
16.1 China................................................................................................................ 178
16.2 Japan................................................................................................................ 183
Summary.................................................................................................................... 187
A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 187
v
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Questions................................................................................................................... 187
Chapter 17: The financial crisis of 2008.............................................................. 189
What this chapter is about.......................................................................................... 189
Objectives.................................................................................................................. 189
Learning outcomes..................................................................................................... 189
Essential reading........................................................................................................ 189
Further reading........................................................................................................... 189
Introduction............................................................................................................... 189
17.1 Instability in the world economy........................................................................ 189
17.2 The housing market in the USA.......................................................................... 190
17.3 The response..................................................................................................... 191
17.4 The rest of the world.......................................................................................... 193
17.5 The Euro problem ............................................................................................. 193
17.6 Further considerations about the US economy.................................................... 195
17.7 Some serious problems in the USA..................................................................... 195
17.8 Relations with the rest of the world................................................................... 196
Summary.................................................................................................................... 196
A reminder of your learning outcomes......................................................................... 196
Questions................................................................................................................... 196
vi
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
1
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
2
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
universities), plus all exports. It also includes all the money returned to
the country from overseas investments. GNP is easier to measure now than
in the past. Nevertheless we have good estimates for most countries from
about 1870.
1.5.5.1 Tariffs
Tariffs prevent countries from following their comparative advantage
in trade. Why? Because tariffs change the price of goods A and B when
these goods are traded. An import tariff means that it may no longer be
worthwhile for a country to specialise in B and export B while importing A.
3
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
1.5.9 Entrepreneurs
These are people who take risks to make a profit. They are not the
same as inventors, although they may use inventions. But they have to
see a market, raise finance and organise production. Usually the main
incentive is profit, but governments have often engaged in entrepreneurial
behaviour. Obtaining and using capital is an important part of the risk an
entrepreneur takes.
4
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
5
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
1.5.18 Contagion
In a depression there is a fall in income, investment and growth. But the
most damaging effect would be a collapse of a major bank or banks. Since
all banks have large funds with other banks, the collapse of one bank
is likely to lead to the collapse of other banks. The collapse of Lehman
Brothers in 2008 was a major example of this. The US government
allowed Lehman Brothers to go bankrupt but compensated those banks
(or other institutions) who were owed money by Lehman. In other words,
nowadays, contagion makes it very close to essential that the government
will step in. (This usually means that the government will increase money
supply.) In some circumstances the government may nationalise, or partly
nationalise, the banks.
6
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
1.5.23 Elasticity
Elasticity shows the effect of a change in one variable on another variable.
It has many forms. For example, price elasticity shows how much more of
a commodity will be purchased if the price falls and how much less will
be purchased if the price rises. If, for example, a 10 per cent fall in the
price leads to more than a 10 per cent rise in purchases, demand is said to
be ‘price elastic’. An example would be the sales of textiles in a relatively
poor country. If, on the other hand, a 10 per cent fall in the price leads to
less than a 10 per cent rise in purchases, the demand is said to be ‘price
inelastic’. An example of this would be the demand for food in a relatively
rich country.
Note what happens to ‘total revenue’ (price X quantity). When price
increases, total revenue falls if demand is price elastic. In contrast, when
price increases total revenue rises if demand is price inelastic.
‘Elasticity’ may also relate to income. If a rise in income of 10 per cent
leads to an increase in sales of more than 10 per cent then demand for
that good is said to be income elastic. An example would be the demand
for health care in rich countries.
7
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Chapter 2
We examine what we call ‘modern economic growth’ – a relatively recent
phenomenon. We see why it started in Europe and how it has spread from
one country to another. This introduces the concept of economic ‘catch up’.
Chapter 3
We explain how movements of capital, labour and goods created the
international economy and how trade was related to the growth of world
output. We examine the development of modern industry, including
an explanation of why both assembly-line production and the business
corporation first developed in the USA.
Chapter 4
We look at the main economic institutions of the pre-First World War
period. These were:
• free trade
• fixed exchange rates
• multilateral payments.
We explain why these were characteristics of the period before the First
World War and not after. This introduces you to the idea of ‘contingency’
– why, for example, fixed exchange rates have often been thought to be
universally desirable, but the condition of the international economy has
not always made it possible to have fixed exchange rates.
Chapter 5
We consider why Britain remained the most important player in the
international economy even though it was no longer the largest economy.
Chapter 6
We examine the economic advantages of colonies to the colonial powers.
We also discuss colonial development and see how far being a colony
inhibited development.
Chapter 7
We examine the long and short-run effects of the First World War on trade
and international finance. This introduces the idea of a war economy and
how it differs from a peacetime economy. Then we look at the medium-
run consequences of the war, in particular the reasons for the poor
performance of the international economy after 1918.
8
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
Chapter 8
We look at the international economic crisis of 1929–33. We examine the
spread of the crisis through the world economy, its causes, and why it was
not possible to use (macro) economic policy to contain it. We explain why
the Depression was more serious in some countries than in others, why the
rate of recovery was also different and why national economies recovered
faster from the Depression than the international economy. We also discuss
the changes in economic theory and their influence on economic policy.
Chapter 9
We look at the economic history of the Second World War, particularly the
successes and failures of the main economies. We look once more at the
nature of war economies and the relationship between the economy and
strategy.
Chapter 10
We examine the development of the international monetary system and
of international economic cooperation in the post war years (1945–52).
We discuss the changes to the Bretton Woods agreements and why
the agreements took a long time to implement. Then we look at the
development of the international monetary system in the later twentieth
century, including the end of fixed exchange rates and the change to the
floating exchange rate system of the late twentieth century. We analyse the
causes and effects of the oil crises.
Chapter 11
We look at the reasons why economic growth was so fast in the major
European economies up to the early 1970s and why growth rates then
fell. We discuss why some economies have grown faster than others. Then
we look at the growth of the European Economic Community. We look at
changes in economic policy in the post-war period, particularly the end of
the Keynesian consensus and the fashion for ‘supply-side economics’ in the
United States and Britain.
Chapter 12
We consider Japanese industrial performance, particularly the position of
Japan in the world motor industry since the Second World War, showing
how Japanese innovations and industrial organisation contrasted with
American.
Chapter 13
We explain ‘deindustrialisation’ and why services have become more
important than manufacturing in national economies.
Chapter 14
We show the development of industrial technology from the early factory
system through mass production to the flexible production systems of
today.
Chapter 15
We try to answer the question: is economic growth easier or harder to
transfer to poorer countries in the twenty-first century compared with the
twentieth century? This returns us to the relationship between trade and
development with which we started the module.
9
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Chapter 16
We show how China developed into the most important manufacturing
country in the world and how Japan developed extremely fast but in
recent years development has stalled.
Chapter 17
We show the main causes of the recent financial crisis, and how it spread
from one country to another.
1.8.2 Try to link the subject guide chapters together as you study
The chapters are designed to introduce you to the most important and the
most interesting parts of the subject. If you follow the guide right through
you will have thought about most of the important parts of the syllabus
and the main features of the development of the international economy.
The chapters are not self-contained and it is a mistake to think of each
chapter as a discrete piece of material, or as an answer to a particular
question that might come up in an examination.
For example, to learn about the reasons why the international economy
deteriorated after the First World War (see Chapter 7), you need to have
read the material on international economic institutions in Chapter 4.
To learn about the causes of the world economic crisis of 1929–33 (see
Chapter 8), you need to read first Chapter 7. Pay particular attention
to the earlier chapters. They contain material that will help your
understanding of the later part of the subject guide.
11
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The VLE
The VLE, which complements this subject guide, has been designed to
enhance your learning experience, providing additional support and a
sense of community. It forms an important part of your study experience
with the University of London and you should access it regularly.
The VLE provides a range of resources for EMFSS courses:
• Course materials: Subject guides and other course materials
available for download. In some courses, the content of the subject
guide is transferred into the VLE and additional resources and
activities are integrated with the text.
• Readings: Direct links, wherever possible, to essential readings in the
Online Library, including journal articles and ebooks.
• Video content: Including introductions to courses and topics within
courses, interviews, lessons and debates.
• Screencasts: Videos of PowerPoint presentations, animated podcasts
and on-screen worked examples.
• External material: Links out to carefully selected third-party
resources.
• Self-test activities: Multiple-choice, numerical and algebraic
quizzes to check your understanding.
13
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
14
Chapter 1: Course Introduction
1.13 Summing up
You do not have to read every word of the textbooks or the additional
readings mentioned in the guide. You may do more work on some chapters
rather than others, as you choose. But it is important for you to remember
that the guide has been designed only to introduce you to a very big
subject.
Remember also that this subject guide is not a set of examination notes. It
does not, on its own, contain sufficient material to enable you
to pass the examination.
Before the examination you will be sent the Examiner’s commentaries and
past examination papers for this course. They are a valuable resource.
Make sure that you read them carefully.
15
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
16
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
Objectives
To:
• explain the factors that led to modern economic growth
• make clear the distinction between growth and industrialisation
• show what factors encouraged growth to transfer from the central
economy (Britain) to a peripheral economy, the USA.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading,
you should be able to:
• explain what is meant by modern economic growth and why it became
a feature of countries over the last 200 years
• discuss how this relates to the development of the international
economy
• outline the mechanism by which economic growth was ‘transferred’
from one economy to another
• demonstrate why some countries ‘caught up’ with more developed
countries earlier than others did
• use economic concepts like the ‘gains from trade’ and ‘comparative
advantage’ to analyse how the international economy developed.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.6–29.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] Chapter 1 The causes of the growth of the international
economy in the nineteenth century, pp.25–38 and Chapter 8 International
aspects of economic growth in the nineteenth century, pp.121–29.
Further reading
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990) [ISBN 0582494230
pbk] pp.1–8.
17
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
We look at several processes that were under way during the nineteenth
century. There was the establishment of what we call ‘modern economic
growth’, meaning a rapid and continuous process of growth per head
of the population. We see how this began in Britain and spread to other
European countries. Next we consider the reasons behind this growth and
see how industrialisation is part of the process.
Then we look at how growth spread to countries on the periphery of the
international economy. We see how the preconditions for modern growth
were present in nineteenth-century USA. As US growth accelerated, trade
expanded on the basis of specialisation and comparative advantage. This
led to gains from the trade in the USA and elsewhere (see 1.5.6).
Finally, we emphasise that growth and its preconditions form the basis for
rising prosperity, while trade expands as a result of growth. Trade, without
these preconditions, does not lead to modern economic growth. This is as
true today as it was in the nineteenth century.
18
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
The first cars came from within the engineering firms of Daimler (Germany)
and Renault (France).
• Companies who were already involved in other transport (carriages/
horses/buses) were soon involved.
• But the success of the motor car depended on many things. In the
first place, the internal combustion engine was soon copied. But the
development of the industry also depended, for example, on new ways
of refining oil to make petrol, on new metals and on the development of
rubber tyres.
• Within ten years of their first appearance, cars were being
manufactured in most industrial countries.
• Then mass production revolutionised the way that cars were made and
made them cheap enough so that large numbers of people were able to
buy them (see Chapter 6).
• In other words, the invention of the internal combustion engine was
only a part of the development of the industry.
19
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The first element that makes growth more likely is the presence of
favourable institutions, in particular, the rule of law. As we note above,
entrepreneurs will not ‘invest’ (that is reduce current consumption in the
expectation of more income in the future) if they think that their contracts
will not be honoured or if they think that the government is likely to
confiscate their property.
• As well as the rule of law, the economy needs reasonably stable
financial institutions. Deposits in banks have to be safe. There has to
be an easy way to make payments and, most important of all, an easy
way to borrow money. A good financial system transfers savings from
one part of the economy so that it can be invested in another. But it is
not easy to develop stable financial institutions, especially if there is no
rule of law.
• The level of education among the population is also an important
element. Remember, however, that practical knowledge gained from
experience was probably more important in the past than book
learning. Nowadays technology is so advanced that formal education
has become much more important.
• Finally, if an economy has access to a large market, entrepreneurs can
produce on a larger scale. This market could be an export market in
another country of course.
20
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
21
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
• Although they protected property rights with legal codes, these could
be changed according to the ruler’s pleasure.
• If an empire was multinational, some nationalities were often treated
better than others.
• As a result, property rights were less reliable and lending money (e.g.
putting it in the bank) was less attractive.
22
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
In contrast, in Britain and the USA the business community had, by 1820,
become an important part of government. This made it less likely that the
government would act in an arbitrary way.
2.3 Industrialisation
By 1820 modern economic growth in western Europe was established,
though in most countries it was still rather slow – say about 1 per cent per
head per year. By about 1900, it was faster, but still less than 2 per cent
per head per year. This acceleration came about through the spread of
industry – a process known as ‘industrialisation’.
The reason why industrialisation came late was that until the late
eighteenth century, economies could not produce large amounts of energy.
Most energy came from waterpower, animal or human power. The wind
provided a cheaper source of power for ocean transport.
2.3.1 Summing up
• Modern economic growth began in western European nation states
during the period 1780–1820.
23
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
24
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
• In the early nineteenth century Britain and the United States were
each other’s best customers.
• Britain exported industrial products to the USA in return for cotton
and timber (unfortunately, since cotton was produced by slaves, cotton
exports prolonged the life of slavery in the USA).
• But United States exports were not enough to pay for US imports. In
other words, the USA had a balance of payments deficit (we look at
the balance of payments in Chapter 4).
• Britain lent money to the USA which financed the deficit. Note that,
in order to encourage this flow of credit, US interest rates had to be
higher than British interest rates.
The relationship between, what we call, a ‘central’ country like Britain, and
a ‘peripheral’ country, which the USA was at the time, raises several points.
25
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Think about the long-run consequences. Is it probable that the goods could
eventually be produced more cheaply at home? And even if they were, is
there another product in which the country has a comparative advantage?
The reason why Britain and the USA were initially such important trading
partners is because the economies were complementary:
• The USA had very large resources of land and raw materials. What
it lacked was capital and labour. Because resources were abundant,
labour and capital were scarce, by definition, and therefore more
expensive.
• Britain had relatively abundant labour and because it industrialised
first, relatively abundant capital. This meant that the return to labour
(wages) was higher in the USA than in Britain, and the return to
26
Chapter 2: International trade and economic growth
capital (interest rates) was also higher in the USA. On the other hand,
land and new materials were relatively scarce in Britain, and relatively
expensive.
• Labour (emigrants) and capital (investment) moved from Britain to
the USA and those goods that used a lot of natural resources (i.e. were
resource-intensive), such as timber and cotton, were traded from the
USA to Britain. The two countries specialised in those areas where
they had a comparative advantage.
Questions
1. Why did Britain introduce free trade in the mid-nineteenth century?
2. How did energy production constrain the rate of economic growth
before industrialisation?
3. Were there any features of the nation state in western Europe that
made economic growth easier?
27
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
28
Chapter 3: The development of an international economy by 1900: trade, capital and labour
Objectives
To explain:
• why trade grew so rapidly
• what role labour migration played
• what stimulated capital flows.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain why international trade grew so rapidly
• analyse the reasons for the high levels of both international investment
and international migration in the period before 1914
• apply the idea of comparative advantage to these movements
• explain the effect of migration on different economies
• account for the relatively low barriers to the mobility of factors of
production in the international economy 1870–1914.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.13–7 and pp.65–71.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition [ISBN
9780415476102]. Chapters 1, 2 and 3 and in particular the following
pages which relate to the sections below: Technical progress: transport
and communications, pp.27–38, Determinants of capital flow, pp.45–52,
International migration 1820–1913, pp.53–65, and The economic
consequences of free trade, pp.71–78.
29
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Further reading
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.31–49, pp.54–64, pp.97–101, pp.120–26, pp.133–
6, pp.140–53.
Introduction
During the period from 1870 to 1914 world trade grew by about a third
per head per ten years. World output (GDP) grew by only seven per cent
per person per decade, slower than trade but still impressive. The world
did not see such rapid growth in trade again until 1945–73.
Growth of trade and output were already under way in the 1820s. In this
chapter we examine why the increase took place. The chapter has four
main sections:
• characteristics of the international economy
• international trade
• overseas investment
• international migration.
A problem for us is that we have the benefit of hindsight. It seems almost
inevitable today that the international economy would have grown in that
period. Population was growing, new production processes were coming on
stream and, in particular, there was great development of steam transport.
But it was not inevitable that the international economy would grow.
In this and subsequent chapters, we see how beneficial conditions
encouraged the international economy to grow. Several relate to one
country, the UK. The UK was the first industrial economy and it could have
turned inward towards domestic production. It did not do so.
Instead, the UK became the dominant trading nation, with a large empire
which lasted well into the twentieth century. The UK also played a major
part in running the world’s monetary payments and credit. At the same
time the UK put up no barriers to trade, or any hindrances to the outflow
of labour or capital. It is worth remembering that the international
economy could have stagnated if different policies had been adopted.
In the twentieth century, the UK’s share of world exports and its share
of world overseas investment declined. This meant that its influence in
the international economy also declined. Once that happened, it was
important for the smooth functioning of the international economy that
new institutions were created to take over the role which the UK had once
had. As we see in Chapters 8, 12 and 13, this proved difficult.
In this chapter we look at the period 1870–1914, when UK influence was
at its height.
• labour
• capital.
There were fewer restrictions than at any period in history except perhaps
in very recent years.
3.1.1 Goods
Countries did have tariffs, but they rarely discriminated – the level of tariffs
faced by one country’s exports was usually the same as the level faced by
other countries. If a ‘discriminatory tariff’ is used it means that imports
might not come from the cheapest overseas producer. This reduces income.
3.1.2 Labour
There were no restrictions on international migration by people of
European origins. On the other hand, there were serious restrictions on
non-white emigration, even within the British Empire.
3.1.3 Capital
There were no restrictions, such as exchange controls, on international
capital movements.
All the major world currencies were freely convertible into each other at
fixed rates. The reasons why there was monetary stability are discussed in
Chapter 4. In this chapter we concentrate on the three factors above.
3.2.1 Peace
Between the end of the Franco-Prussian War in 1871 and the outbreak of
the First World War in 1914 there were no wars between any of the great
powers (Britain, France, USA, Russia and Germany).
32
Chapter 3: The development of an international economy by 1900: trade, capital and labour
The combined effects of the fall in transport costs and the increase
in information was to create an international market in the basic
commodities. Take wheat as an example.
• Let us assume that there was a very good harvest in Argentina and a
poorer one in the USA.
• The price of wheat would be lower in Buenos Aires than the price in,
say, Chicago.
• At the same time, the information about the Argentine harvest would
be available in, say, London. Ships would go to Buenos Aires to buy
wheat at a low price.
• In this way, the harvest in Argentina affected the price in the USA.
• Ultimately, the price of wheat anywhere in the world was the same
except for transport costs, which for bulk commodities like wheat
were low. ‘Futures markets’ subsequently developed, allowing people
to trade in basic commodities worldwide before the crops were even
harvested.
Activity
Which of the following goods and commodities are commonly traded internationally
today and which are not? Can you think why?
•• cement
•• bricks
•• steel sheets
•• potatoes
•• tropical root crop foods like cassava.
Cement and bricks have a low value-to-weight ratio and are seldom worth
trading internationally. Steel sheets are traded as long as they are of high
quality (and value) to make it worthwhile. Potatoes are easily stored and
graded so do get traded. Cassava is heavier and more uneven, so it is more
difficult to trade. In short, it depends on the value, the weight, and the
ease with which the product may be bought and sold. Then, if one country
has an advantage in its production trade develops. Otherwise it doesn’t.
Note that a country only needs to have a comparative advantage to
make trade worthwhile (see 1.5.5).
3.2.5 Specialisation
One of the main ‘gains from trade’ is a consequence of specialisation.
Consider what happened in UK, in the period from 1870 to 1914.
• Food imports increased because of the development of ‘virgin lands’,
first in the western part of the USA and then in other countries, such
as Canada. Note that this would not have been possible without
transport development, particularly the railway.
• In turn, agriculture in the UK declined because it became cheaper for
basic food to be imported rather than produced at home.
Of course, if the British government had decided to protect British farmers,
there would have been fewer imports. But the UK did not protect food
imports (see Chapter 5).
Imports meant that basic food costs in the UK fell by half in thirty years
(1870–1900). Since, at the time, British people, on average, spent about
half of their income on food, this had a significant effect on the standard
33
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
If this question gives you difficulties, have a look at Graff, Kenwood and
Lougheed, The economic consequences of protection, p.76. They explain
how farmers in the UK and Denmark moved out of grain and cattle
farming for meat, into areas where they had a comparative advantage,
notably pig rearing and dairy farming. A century later Denmark is still well
known for bacon and cheese production.
Activity
Imagine three families each having farms of 25 hectares in nineteenth-century Kansas.
A government land grant enables them each to increase to 50 hectares (25+25). Each
family uses double the inputs (labour, cattle, machinery etc.) Each family obtains the
following results:
•• The first family gets 200 per cent of the previous output.
•• The second family gets 50 per cent more output.
•• The third family gets 100 per cent more output.
Now describe the ‘returns to scale’ of each farm. Try this before reading on.
The first family obtains increasing returns, the second decreasing returns
and the third constant returns to scale.
But what if there was no extra land available?
Then 50 per cent more output, or a worse result, is the only conceivable
outcome. In other words, where land is scarce there are diminishing
returns to land.
But in the regions of recent settlement, technology and transport liberated
agriculture from diminishing returns to land – that is where adding more
labour and capital could not lead to an equivalent increase in output
because the amount of land could not be increased.
In the regions of recent settlement, the amount of land could be increased
and any increase in labour and capital applied to the land would lead to a
large increase in the output of food.
34
Chapter 3: The development of an international economy by 1900: trade, capital and labour
This is why the massive rise of population in the industrial countries and
increased demand for commodities did not lead to rising food prices.
Activity
Draw a supply and demand diagram for the world supply of food. The diagram should
show:
•• a demand curve that shifts to the right as population increased
•• a supply curve that shifts to the right as new areas come into production in new areas
•• an equilibrium price for food.
Finally, comment on the diagram:
•• Is the price of food falling?
•• Under what conditions would it fall?
Think about the increase in supply compared with demand, and if you know a bit more
economics think about the elasticity of demand. We know that world food prices fell c.
1870–1900. What are the implications for the diagram?
Bear in mind that food prices did begin to rise after 1900, once the best
land in the regions of recent settlement was taken up and farmed.
35
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Think about the return to new investment (capital) in these countries and
in the UK. Because they were relatively underpopulated, countries such
as Canada, Argentina and Australia and, until about 1900, the USA had
little capital but a lot of resources. In fact, if they had a lot of resources,
they would have relatively little capital, by definition. This meant that the
productivity of capital was high and the return to capital was high.
Pause and think
What else was needed, besides a favourable ‘resources-to-capital’ ratio, to make
investment in the regions of recent settlement profitable?
Demand for the products that the resources helped to create was also
required. This is an important point. Investment in these countries was
only profitable as long as there was a demand for the products associated
with the investment, such as a railroad that carried the products.
An example may help. British investment in railways in Argentina:
• allowed Argentine beef to reach the coast, so exports of beef rose
• gave the Argentine borrower the money to repay the loan, from sales
of beef in the UK
• made it profitable for the UK lender to lend the money in the first
place, as this repayment with interest justified the investment.
36
Chapter 3: The development of an international economy by 1900: trade, capital and labour
Many of the international migrants had valuable skills but the great
majority were unskilled.
37
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
No. A high proportion were young adults. They entered the new countries
at the peak of their productive and consuming power. In other words, the
cost of their upbringing had been paid in the country from which they
came. They were a free gift of human capital from Europe.
Summary
In this chapter we cover a lot of ground. Even so, we do not have space
to expand and discuss some important and interesting issues. You should
make sure you complete the reading before moving on.
• We have argued that there is a two-way relationship between the
growth of individual countries and the growth of the international
economy.
• In some countries trade based on exporting raw material led to a lot of
economic growth. In other countries to much less.
• European countries, especially the UK, experienced growth at home
that led to an expansion of exports and created a demand for imports.
• Many of the capital flows in the period were reliant on the UK export
surplus. This ‘recycling’ of export earnings was a vital part of the
development of the international economy.
• Labour migration had costs and benefits in both the country the
emigrants left and the one in which they arrived. It was only an
unambiguous benefit to the latter.
Questions
1. Assess the relationship between the spread of agriculture into
previously uncultivated land and the growth of industry in the UK and
other European countries before 1914.
2. Examine the effect of transport development in the creation of an
international market in the basic commodities in the early twentieth
century.
3. Why was the level of international investment high in the early
twentieth century?
38
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
Objectives
To explain:
• the implications of fixed exchange rates in the historical context
• how the gold standard worked in practice.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain why businessmen and governments were determined to
maintain fixed exchange rates
• outline what it was that allowed fixed exchange rates (i.e. the gold
standard) to be maintained
• discuss whether the gold standard worked because central banks
followed a set of rules or for some other reason
• explain how the flow of capital made it easier for the gold standard to
work, and give examples.
Essential reading
Eichengreen, B. Globalizing capital. A history of the international monetary system.
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008) second edition [ISBN
9780691139371] pp.15–42.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international economy,
1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition [ISBN 9780415476102]
Chapter 6 The evolution of a multilateral payments network and Chapter 7 The
evolution of an international monetary system.
Further reading
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.161–74. (This section is rather more difficult than
that in Graff, Kenwood and Lougheed.) 39
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
The international economy in the period from 1870 to 1914 was
characterised by three institutions. (An institution is defined here as
‘something manmade for a purpose’.) Laws, rules and organisations are
all examples of institutions. As we see in this chapter, there are three
institutions which were closely linked together:
• free trade
• multilateral settlements
• fixed exchange rates.
Activity
•• What determines whether or not a country introduces tariffs on food imports?
•• How does this affect the standard of living?
•• Make a case using the concept of ‘comparative advantage’ (1.5.5). Do this before
reading on.
You could make the following points to answer the questions above:
• Imported cheap food would mean major changes in the countryside,
for example, a large number of farmers might have to give up farming
and move to the cities.
• This would be an advantage if the country had a ‘comparative
advantage’ in manufactured exports and disadvantage in farming.
• On the other hand, there might be political and military reasons to
protect agriculture.
• Cheap food imports hold down the cost of living for industrial workers.
This exerts downwards pressure on wage rates and costs. Other things
being equal, this makes manufacturing exports more competitive.
The free trade stance of the UK was very important because it gave other
countries free access to the UK market. The UK remained the world’s
largest importer until 1939.
40
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
In the main, UK exporters were able to maintain their sales in the face
of tariffs and foreign competition. This was, partly, because the world
market was growing fast, and partly because UK exporters were very good
at finding new products and new markets. (UK exports still continued to
grow, although the UK’s share of total world exports was falling as other
countries began to compete.)
Owes 50 Owes 70
C
Owes 20
41
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
All the countries must be willing to accept C’s currency. B would have to
accept C’s currency which was paying debts owed by A.
Fixed exchange rates were thought to be an essential component of the
international economy in the years before the First World War. It was
thought that multilateral trade depended on certainty about exchange rates.
42
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
SHORT-RUN PROBLEM
A B
r r
Gold IN Gold OUT
l I
Prices Prices
M X M X
BoP Equilibrium
“Rules of the game” “Rules of the game”
43
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
If you answered (a) the money supply and (b) interest rates, read on.
Otherwise look back over the last few paragraphs and in the readings to
see where you went wrong.
Activity
The ‘rules of the game’ gave national economies more pain than the price-specie-flow
mechanism. See if you can explain why. Take a few minutes over this, and then read on.
When answering the question above you might have said something like
this:
A rise in interest rates in the deficit country affects output and
employment but the effects might not be too great if the rise in interest
rates is temporary. Conversely, a fall in interest rates in the surplus country
may have an inflationary effect and this can be damaging.
So far we have only talked about the gold standard and the international
economy. But the gold standard had important advantages in domestic
economies as well. The main reason was the relation with government
finance.
44
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
GB Capital exports
CURRENT PAYMENTS
GB USA &
CURRENT OTHERS
A/C CURRENT A/C
DEFICIT
SURPLUS
K FLOW
46
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
The position of the UK economy was very important. The UK was the
largest exporter of both goods and services and the greatest provider of
overseas investment; 40 per cent of the total, as late as 1914. The UK had
a balance of payments surplus; exports of goods and services exceeded
imports, and earnings from foreign investment exceeded new investment.
The point was the British surplus was continuously recycled. Look at
Figure 4.3 again. The UK had a permanent balance of payments surplus.
Therefore other countries, such as, in the late nineteenth century, the USA,
must have had permanent deficits.
• Under the gold standard, a deficit country had to choose between
leaving the gold standard, as mentioned above, or accepting higher
interest rates and lower output.
• The US growth rate would have had to be lower. But in reality, the
USA could always finance its deficit (i.e. pay for its excess of imports)
because it was always possible to borrow from the UK.
The UK was a free-trade country. The UK imported the bulk of its food and
raw materials. This meant that if a country borrowed from the UK, it was
relatively easy to obtain sterling to pay the interest by exporting to the UK.
In other words, in effect, the world was using a sterling standard, rather
than a gold standard.
47
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
It is not surprising that most countries held their foreign exchange reserves
in sterling rather than gold.
Summary
As we said at the beginning of this chapter, the gold standard worked
because:
• There was strong trade growth which made it easier for countries to
fix their exchange rates. Trade growth made it easier to earn foreign
currency.
• One country, the UK, had a persistent trade surplus. But this was not a
problem for other countries because the UK recycled the surplus.
• There was a strong central currency, which was universally expected to
remain strong.
• The gold standard could have been threatened if governments had
borrowed substantially, since this would have led to inflation. But
governments did not wish to borrow heavily.
48
Chapter 4: Institutions that underpinned the international economy before the First World War
Questions
1. Why were exchange rates fixed before the First World War?
2. Explain the reasons for the stability of the international monetary
system before the First World War.
49
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
50
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
Objectives
To:
• show the nature of the modern business corporation and how it
developed in the twentieth century
• explain how and why American industrial development took a
different character to either the UK or continental European models.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activity, you should be able to:
• explain how far UK manufacturing became a model for other countries
• explain why mass production first started in the USA
• suggest and evaluate reasons why the US industrial structure changed
• show how US industry differed from UK industry before the First
World War.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.69–74.
Eichengreen, B. Globalizing capital. A history of the international monetary
system. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008) second edition
[ISBN 9780691139371] pp.15–42.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] Chapter 5 Foreign trade in the nineteenth century and
Chapter 8 International aspects of economic growth in the nineteenth century.
Further reading
Blackford, M.G. The rise of modern business in Great Britain, the United States
and Japan. (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North California Press, 1988)
[ISBN 0807842028 pbk] pp.51–63, pp.72–4, pp.95–8.
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990)
[ISBN 0582494230 pbk] pp.12–19, pp.25–30, pp.38–41.
51
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
In this chapter we see why the manufacturing sector expanded in the
late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. We explain why American
manufacturing was not a copy of UK manufacturing, and why the
development of assembly-line production occurred first in the USA and
not in the UK or continental Europe. In the chapter, we also discuss
the development of new organisational structures in industry, another
American phenomenon of the period.
52
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
There are problems in using this sort of evidence, but although the UK
had a much higher per capita income than either the USA or Germany in
1870, its HDI index, although higher, was not proportionally as high as
the difference in income. The disappointing social development (HDI) in
Britain partly explains the US, and later German, ‘catch up’.
• Workers whose literacy and numeracy skills are weak are likely to be
less flexible and slower to learn new skills.
• The type of education might have been important. In Britain there
was less secondary and tertiary (university) education in science and
technology than in Germany and the USA. Secondary and tertiary
education in the UK was more likely to be in the humanities and aimed
at an elite who took jobs in the colonial service or the professions.
• The main route to industrial training in the UK was by apprenticeship.
This was fine as long as UK industry was changing relatively slowly (as
in the nineteenth century). But in the twentieth century, it made the
acquisition of new skills more difficult since the younger workers were
taught by older workers with older skills.
Note that these reasons became more applicable in the twentieth century.
This is because industry became much more technically and scientifically
based.
53
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
54
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
Lower food prices helped offset lower money wages. Food was an
important part of consumption. Hence, real wages (money wages divided
by prices) could still rise even if money wages stayed constant.
55
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
• Because they had only one task, each worker could become very
proficient at it. Nor did the workers have to spend time looking for
parts, tools etc. Hence there was an increase in output per worker
(labour productivity rose). Moreover, because each worker only had to
learn one task, it was easy to train them, which reduced the demand
for highly skilled labour, which was very expensive in the USA.
Mass production first started in industries where there was already a
continuous process, for example: paint making, sugar and food processing.
A famous early example was meat packing (canned food), which started in
Chicago.
This demonstrates that mass production was used long before its most
famous example: the Ford Car plant, which was built to manufacture
the Model T Ford in the early twentieth century. It was the most famous
example of the work of Frederick Taylor who was the key figure in the
development of mass production. (See below.)
Figure 5.1 Model T production, before and after the assembly line, 1914
The introduction of the assembly line to the Ford plant in Detroit increased
labour productivity by about twelve times. But it was not easy to get the
assembly line to work. It took Henry Ford three years after he started
to produce the Model T to perfect his assembly lines. There were three
variables which had to be optimised:
• the layout of the plant
• the speed at which the line moved
• the speed at which the workers worked.
The subdivision of production required a very high degree of management
control. Tasks had to be identified, incentives paid and quality maintained.
Time and motion studies, called ‘scientific management’, were common
56
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
in Ford plants. This was partly the work of Frederick Taylor and his
assistants. Taylor had been instrumental in optimising the layout of
mass production plants for many years. There was also another result
of his work. Before the onset of mass production, it had been difficult to
show those workers who worked hard and those who did not. But mass
production made it easy to see who was a good worker and who was not.
The less good workers were dismissed immediately.
57
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
58
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
59
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
5.4 UK industry
We have seen that the UK economy was different. One consequence was
that firms in the UK operated on a much smaller scale than American
firms. Most British industries had far more firms than the same industries
in the USA.
Summary
Mass production began in the USA. It was associated with changes in
finance, management and in the organisation of the firm. It was aided
by tariff protection. British industry did not have the same structure, had
no import protection, and in some respects the UK had an inappropriate
educational system.
Germany had a strong industrial structure and appropriate education, yet
still it did not match levels of productivity in the USA. This was because
the US resource environment and the size of the market were much more
favourable to large-scale production. Consequently, Germany found it
impossible to catch up in this period.
60
Chapter 5: The development of modern industry
Questions
1. How far was the development of the UK economy in the nineteenth
century unique? Was the UK economy well placed to achieve high
productivity growth in the twentieth century?
2. Does an increase in bureaucracy in giant non-competitive companies
lead to more or less efficiency?
3. What happened to American industry when it was faced with new
technology in the late twentieth century? Were American companies
flexible enough to cope, for example, with Japanese competition?
61
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
62
Chapter 6: Britain – trade and empire
Objectives
To:
• round off our discussion of the pre-1914 international economy
• explain the continuing importance of British trade
• consider the effects of imperialism and Empire on the international
economy.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain how the UK remained the most important country in the
international economy
• discuss why economic imperialism was more characteristic of the other
industrial countries than it was of the UK
• discuss whether the colonies were disadvantaged compared with
independent countries
• outline why the UK remained a free-trading economy rather than
a tariff-protected one, and say why this was beneficial to the
international economy.
Essential reading
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] pp.131–42.
Further reading
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.13–17 and pp.90–113.
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990)
[ISBN 0582494230 pbk] pp.199–202.
63
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
This chapter examines gains from trade in the years before the First World
War, using mainly the example of the UK. We saw in Chapter 5 that the UK
economy was overtaken by the USA and Germany during the period from
1870 to 1914. Nevertheless, the UK remained the most important trading
country.
If the UK had imposed tariffs on German imports into the UK the Germans
would have bought less from India, in turn this would have given India
less foreign exchange and UK exports to India would have fallen.
Either the country has to lend abroad or offer greater access to its local
market. Otherwise there will be a shortage of liquidity (foreign currency)
in the world economy and a shortage of development funds. In the early
twentieth century period the UK export surplus was recycled – that is
‘exported’ overseas.
Pause and think
How could the UK import more goods than it exported yet still have a balance of
payments surplus on current account?
The current account is made up of trade and payments from services and
from profits from previous investments (‘invisibles’). Britain had a surplus
of exports over imports of invisibles and this surplus was larger than the
deficit of imports over exports of visible trade.
As we have seen, the UK was investing abroad during the whole period
from 1820 to 1914. The inflow of profits (plus services) kept the current
account in surplus.
Activity
What do you think happened later, after 1918, when the UK surplus fell? Try to trace
through the logic following the end of the British surplus.
66
Chapter 6: Britain – trade and empire
To change the economy so that the UK produced more high-tech goods would
have required tariffs. Britain would then have looked more like the German
economy, which, as we have seen, did develop sophisticated industries
behind tariffs. The key question is which path would have maximised GNP?
As you decide on your position, keep the following points in mind.
• Did the concentration on traditional trade and services make the
UK population richer or poorer than would have a different sort of
economy?
• Remember, free trade allowed the UK to purchase everything it wanted
in the cheapest markets.
• If there were benefits of tariffs, they would come in the long run. The
benefits of free trade came in the short run.
The simple answer is that it was difficult for people at the time to see that
there was something wrong with the UK economy. A free-enterprise
economy changes through price and profit signals. If the economy is
concentrating on the ‘wrong’ industries, they will be unprofitable. Profits
are the ‘signals’ that tell the entrepreneurs that they need to invest in new
industries. But the UK export industries were doing quite well before the
First World War. They were not unprofitable. Hence, there was no political
demand for tariffs to help create new industries.
The big problem for the UK economy came only after the war. So for an
entrepreneur to know that he was investing in the ‘wrong’ industry, he
would have to know what the effect of the First World War was going to be.
68
Chapter 6: Britain – trade and empire
a large export sector, but they also had more industry. There is some
evidence, therefore, that being a colony may have held back development.
Now try the next activity.
Activity
See if you can write answers to these two questions.
•• Was the fact that they were colonies the main reason for the slow development of
these countries?
•• Would India have been much richer in, say 1914, if it had been independent, for
example?
Think about the conditions that led to economic growth in Europe (see
Chapter 2). Do you think that many of these countries had the ‘social
capability’ to develop, whether they were independent or not? In other
words, colonialism held back these colonies only if it retarded their social
capability.
The second question is much more difficult. Interestingly, many Indian
historians, in the main, no longer think that India’s colonial status to 1947
was the cause of its problems. This may be because the Indian economy
since 1947 has been very successful, with high growth rates. A large
proportion of the Indian population are still poor but India was very poor
in, say, 1900. It was also much poorer than Britain was in, say, 1820.
Development can be a long, slow process.
The short answer is no. British colonies were free to purchase goods from
any country, unlike the colonies of other countries.
The first answer to the question above is because the UK was the world’s
cheapest producer of the main goods that primary producing countries,
including the colonies, wanted to import. Given a choice, the colonies
would still buy mainly UK goods.
Second, part of the UK success in the primary producing countries was
because of the UK’s early start in industrialisation. For example, both the
Indian and the Argentine railways were British designed and equipped
and employed British technicians. Hence, they were likely to continue to
reorder British equipment. This is an example of ‘path dependency’.
69
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The answer to the first question is probably yes. New industries were
unable to get started against the unhindered competition of well-
established UK imports. The second answer is that during the First World
War British shipping had to be concentrated in the North Atlantic so that
UK textile exports to India could not be transported. In effect, the shipping
shortage had the same effect as a tariff, which the Indian textile industry
had wanted for some time, but had not been able to obtain.
In this chapter we have suggested that the answer to the question about
the economic importance of empires is rather complicated. There is
another point to remember, however. Most less developed countries
could not have been independent countries at that period of history.
Other European countries, for instance France, Germany, the Netherlands
and Portugal, as well as the USA, did restrict trade. Imports into their
territories were reserved for the ‘mother country’, which meant that the
UK could not export to them.
This is what happened in the 1930s. The British government response was
to negotiate trade agreements leading to ‘Imperial Preference’ within the
British Empire. The 1930s was a period when world trade was seriously
depressed, reducing British markets in other countries.
70
Chapter 6: Britain – trade and empire
Summary
In this chapter we have suggested that the pattern of British trade
maximised income in the short run. Changing the British economy to
include more ‘high-tech’ industry, would have involved short-term welfare
losses. We have also suggested that the UK did not exploit its colonies,
in the sense that they forced them to purchase British products. This
was not because of ideology, but because, given the choice, the colonies
would have purchased British manufactures anyway. They did not need to
be compelled to do so. Colonies of other countries could not buy British
manufactures. Hence, British colonies had an advantage and it was
important that they were in the British Empire and not another empire.
Questions
1. How was it possible for the UK to remain the most important country
in the international economy before the First World War? How
important was the British Empire to Britain’s pre-eminence in trade?
2. Assess the benefits to (a) the UK and (b) the international economy of
the UK’s policy of free trade before the First World War.
3. What were the main economic advantages and disadvantages of
colonial status in the early twentieth century?
71
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
72
Chapter 7: The First World War and the international economy
Objectives
To:
• demonstrate how the war affected economic and financial systems
• analyse the effects of war on different types of country
• evaluate the long-term economic problems caused by the war.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain how the war was financed and the long-run economic
problems this led to
• make an argument about why there was a high level of international
debt and why it proved so difficult to eradicate
• give reasons why fixed exchange rates were difficult to establish.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.134–9 and pp.143–56.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition [ISBN
9780415476102] Manufacturing production to the end of Chapter 11, pp.164–
72.
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.8–30 and pp.46–54.
Feinstein, C.H., P. Temin and G. Toniolo The world economy between the world wars.
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008) second edition [ISBN 9780195307559
hbk] pp.24–38.
73
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
The First World War began in August 1914 between France, the UK,
Russia, Belgium and Serbia (the ‘allies’) and Germany and Austria-
Hungary (the ‘central powers’). Other countries became involved – Italy,
Romania and Portugal joined the allies and Bulgaria and Turkey joined
the central powers. In 1917 the USA finally joined the Allies, and Russia
collapsed into revolution.
It was called a ‘world war’ because fighting had spread to the colonies;
countries such as India, Australia, New Zealand, Canada and the French
colonies contributed large numbers of troops. Japan was also involved,
although only to a limited extent.
The war was the first ‘total’ war. It involved, in some way, most of the
population of the main protagonists. Technical change (e.g. the invention
of the machine gun, the submarine and heavy artillery) meant that it was
difficult to achieve a quick result. There were also very heavy casualties –
about 10 million military deaths and possibly another 10 million from the
diseases and hunger that accompanied the war. At the end of the war there
was also a worldwide influenza pandemic which probably killed 50 million
people.
The war had a number of economic effects. The scale and duration of the
war meant that governments had to learn how to shift resources from
peacetime to wartime use, how to manage the finance and pay for the war.
Governments had to take control of some parts of the economy. The first
part of the chapter looks at these challenges.
7.1.1 Inflation
In wartime an economy creates more purchasing power than goods.
Pause and think
What does the increase in purchasing power, but not in goods, lead to?
74
Chapter 7: The First World War and the international economy
Activity
Why did many governments print money even though it created inflation? Why didn’t
they increase taxes instead? See if you can evaluate the two options before you read on.
The economic needs of a short war can be met using temporary measures.
Supplies can be switched from current production or from stocks. A long
war needs new investment in factories to maintain output and to replace
those called into the armed forces. Hence a long war needs planning.
There are major structural changes that must be met in wartime due to
huge increases in the demand for certain products. Supply cannot adjust
quickly so leaving it to market forces would mean that prices would
fluctuate wildly, causing problems.
75
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
At the end of the war the USA and the western allies relinquished control
of their economies as quickly as they could. The defeated central powers
were in a chaotic state of revolution and disintegration; government
intervention simply fell apart.
Activity
How was Latin America affected by the First World War?
Think about this for a few minutes. Remember, before 1914 Latin America was an
important market for UK exports. Once you have formed an opinion, read on.
• During the war the UK was unable to export to Latin America because
British resources were needed for the war effort and shipping was not
available for exporting.
• Some countries were able to replace UK imports with domestic
production – ‘import substitution’.
• The United States was not a belligerent nation until 1917 and was able
to take over many of Britain’s Latin American markets.
• Similarly Japan, whose economy was not fully committed to war, was
able to increase its exports to south-east Asia at the expense of Britain.
• Unless Britain could regain these markets after the war, the UK
economy would face serious problems.
German trade was also seriously disrupted during the war. Germany was
the second most important producer of ‘high-tech’ goods after the USA,
but it could not sell outside Europe because of a UK blockade and could
not sell to France, Italy or Russia because they were enemies. In contrast,
the USA was the biggest beneficiary of the war.
• The USA entered the war late. Her economy could continue to produce
peacetime goods, which were in demand.
• The USA was well-placed to produce and sell wartime goods on a large
scale because it had developed mass production before other countries
(see Chapter 6). France and the UK, for example, placed huge orders
for armaments in the USA.
• The supply of food and raw materials in the USA was very elastic so it
was easy to increase output.
A major development during the war was the growth of import
substitution in many countries. Some countries, which had imported
manufactures before the war, were cut off from their European suppliers.
They began to make them for themselves. India is a good example. India
was a major importer of UK textiles, but turned to domestic production.
UK exports to India were permanently reduced.
7.1.5 Borrowing
As we note above, borrowing was the most important way that
governments financed the war. Governments borrowed from abroad and at
home. Let’s look at each source separately.
76
Chapter 7: The First World War and the international economy
To repay debts to the USA, the UK and France would need to earn export
surpluses after the war. Since it was difficult to do this (we come to that
later) this presented a critical problem after 1918.
They lost markets and their exports declined. In order to avoid balance of
payments crises, they also restricted imports.
7.3.3 Problems
The USA was not only the world’s largest industrial country but also
the world’s largest primary producer. As we have seen, US total factor
productivity (TFP) was higher than European TFP. Most US industrial and
primary products were now the cheapest in the world.
The USA needed few imports and was a large exporter (it had a trade
surplus). In addition, US economic policy favoured the domestic economy.
Exports only represented six per cent of GDP, the domestic economy the
other 94 per cent. This meant that the USA could have high tariffs with
little impact on the domestic economy from higher prices.
The USA could have reduced tariffs, which would have increased imports.
It could also have ‘recycled’ the trade surplus by lending. Lending dollars
abroad (as the UK had done in the period 1870–1914) would have
allowed the other countries to buy more imports. The USA did lend
abroad, but (unlike the UK, 1870–1914) its lending formed only half the
US trade surplus. The UK did manage to earn a small trade surplus after
1918 but not enough to make up for the lack of US recycling. Therefore
half the US surplus accumulated as gold in Fort Knox and foreign
exchange reserves.
79
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
To close the dollar gap US exports would have had to fall compared with
European exports. To do this the USA would have to remove all tariffs.
But, in the 1920s, US productivity was growing faster than that of Europe,
hence the dollar would have to appreciate relative to the European
currencies. If this did not reduce the trade imbalance between Europe and
the USA, American companies would have to invest in Europe to replace
imports from the USA.
Stated like this, it is obvious that the American people (and electorate)
would have rejected such measures.
• The only way to repay debt in the long run was with a trade surplus.
• The position of the USA in the international economy made a trade
surplus very difficult to achieve.
• Countries could borrow to repay earlier loans of course (remember
that the USA was lending some of its trade surplus). But this simply
postponed the final payment.
Defeated countries such as Germany did not have foreign debt because
they had been unable to borrow from the USA or Britain during the war.
This was regarded as unfair by the victors, especially France. They made
it a condition of the 1918 Armistice that the defeated countries had to
pay ‘reparations’. These were payments to compensate the victorious
countries for the damage done to them. Germany had occupied Belgium
and a large part of the French industrial areas during the four years of war.
Reparations were seen by France and the UK as a way of repaying their
war debts, primarily to the USA.
80
Chapter 7: The First World War and the international economy
• Because the German economy was run down by the war, its ability to
export was limited.
• Insufficient exports made it difficult for Germany to pay the reparations.
• Germany had lost a large part of its economy, including 38 per cent of
its steel capacity and 26 per cent of its coal output to other countries in
the post-war settlement.
• The government proved unable to control spending, and inflation
began.
At the same time, Germany needed imports to enable reconstruction to
occur. Germany had to borrow heavily. Part of the short term ‘solution’ was
for the US banks to make short-term loans to Germany which were used
to pay reparations (e.g. to the UK) which were then used to repay some of
the war loans from the USA. With the reparations, this made Germany the
world’s largest debtor. The USA was the largest creditor of course.
In this way, the trade problem made it impossible to solve the debt problem.
In the next chapter, we will see that there was in fact no solution to this.
What happened instead was a major financial crisis. This led to changes
in the international economy. One result was that Germany refused to pay
reparations and a large part of the other war debts were never repaid.
The danger became apparent in the 1920s. The new American loans were
deposited in European, especially German, banks. When the loans were
recalled by the USA, from 1928 onwards, the German banks collapsed.
7.5 Inflation
As we have discovered, most governments used inflationary finance during
the war. This inflation carried over into the post-war period because of the
need for economic reconstruction and the war pensions that had to be paid
to widows and disabled soldiers. Political changes in many countries meant
that welfare had become a more pressing issue than it had been before the
war.
As we have seen, governments abandoned the gold standard during the war.
But after the war it was generally agreed that countries should go back to
the gold standard as soon as they were able. This was partly because they
found it difficult to visualise a world with floating exchange rates (which
was the alternative) and partly because they wanted the ‘good housekeeping
seal of approval’ which we talked about in Chapter 4.
But in the short run it was impossible for most countries to fix their
exchange rates. As we saw above, many countries had serious balance
of payments problems after the war. And most countries, other than the
USA, had various rates of inflation. If they fixed their currency in gold,
they would lose all their reserves. It was impossible to go back to the gold
standard immediately.
81
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Because the rates of inflation during and after the war had differed, the
price levels in different countries were no longer in line. The new fixed
exchange rates were not always the appropriate ones. For example the
pound was overvalued from 1925 and the French franc was undervalued
from 1926.
82
Chapter 7: The First World War and the international economy
Summary
The international economy worked poorly after 1918 because:
• The war changed trade patterns and reduced the earnings of the
European exporters.
• Political problems associated with the rise of nationalism reduced
European export earnings further.
• Many countries incurred large international debts.
• These international debts were difficult to repay because the USA had
a large trade surplus but was not recycling all of the surplus, as the UK
had done before 1914.
• In turn, this affected exchange rates and made it difficult for the
reimposed gold standard to work properly.
• The USA had become the dominant economy but was unwilling to act
as the leader of the international economy.
• The USA was not willing to negotiate to solve these problems.
• The inability to solve the trade problem, and hence the debt problem,
made it inevitable that there would be a major international crisis.
This occurred in 1931.
Questions
1. How far was the First World War a turning point in the international
economy?
2. Why did the international economy work less well after the First World
War than it had before?
3. Compare the position of the UK in the international economy before
the First World War with that of the USA after the First World War.
83
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
84
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33
Objectives
To:
• interpret the events of the 1930s in an international context
• explain how the Depression had both national and international
aspects
• see what lessons were learned as a result of countries’ failures in the
1930s.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• describe the nature of the 1931 financial crisis
• give reasons why the United States’ economy caused such problems for
the post-1918 international economy
• explain why the world economic crisis was unavoidable, given the
post-war settlement
• explain why the world crisis was a turning point in the development of
the international economy.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.215–8.
Eichengreen, B. Globalizing capital. A history of the international monetary
system. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008) second edition
[ISBN 9780691139371] pp.70–83.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] Chapter 13 The collapse of the gold standard and the
disintegration of the international economy, and Chapter 14 International trade
during the interwar period (pp.196–98).
85
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.66–67.
Feinstein, C.H., P. Temin and G. Toniolo The world economy between the
world wars. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008) second edition
[ISBN 9780195307559 hbk] pp.93–104.
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition [ISBN
0745009352 pbk] pp.98–201, pp.204–6, pp.215–28 and pp.232–4.
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990)
[ISBN 0582494230 pbk] pp.64–73.
Introduction
In Chapter 7 we saw how the First World War permanently altered
the system of trade and payments that had fuelled the growth of the
international economy since 1870. In particular, the UK could no longer
play a key role in providing stability and aiding growth in the rest of the
world. The USA, which was now the dominant economy, was unwilling to
take up this role.
Between 1918 and 1926, a major breakdown in the financial system was
narrowly avoided. German reparations were rescheduled, the inflations
were contained and most countries had returned to gold by 1926. But the
system was weak and some exchange rates were unsustainable.
Moreover, nationalism was much more important than it had been in
1914. When the crisis spread round the world from Germany, the USA
and the primary producing countries in 1929, there was no international
mechanism to contain it. Recovery, when it came in the 1930s, was based
on national economies, not international trade. The Second World War
came at the end of this period. When peace returned, governments turned
to international institutions again, as they had before 1914.
In this course, there are many questions. The topic is complicated so do
not go through the chapter too quickly. Don’t forget the readings. You
will also find that there are close links between Chapters 7, 8 and 9, so
remember to look backwards and forwards.
86
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33
Trade, debt and exchange rates were the main problems in the 1920s.
Inflation was also a problem, but it was important for the international
economy insofar as it affected exchange rates.
In contrast, in the 1930s, virtually no government was trying to recreate
the pre-1914 situation. Recovery from the Depression came, not via
trade but via the national economies of countries, often through active
government intervention in the economy. World output recovered strongly.
But in 1939 world trade was still below its 1929 level. (This situation was
unique in recorded history, except in time of war.)
87
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Since the rest of the world had falling incomes, the chances of increasing
exports were slim. The only realistic outcome was that Germany would
be so impoverished that imports would decline enough to leave an export
surplus to make reparation payments.
But there was a serious political risk. The more serious the depression,
the more likely it was that the Nazis would be elected. And the Nazis had
promised to cancel reparations, which put them at an electoral advantage.
The German economy had become dependent on short-term loans from
the USA. The loans began to be recalled in 1928 (so that they could be
spent on the Wall Street boom). When the US economy fell into depression
in 1929, more loans were recalled, causing the German banking system to
collapse and making the Depression far more serious.
88
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33
In the 1920s, this was reversed. Demand increased slowly while supply
increased very fast. As a result prices fell.
The ratio of the price of primary products to the price of industrial
products is called the ‘terms of trade’ (see 1.5.20). We can say that the
terms of trade moved against primary producers after 1921.
• All the main producers must join in the scheme and new producers
must also join.
• Demand must be inelastic, so that restricting production would lead to
an increase in total revenue.
• Stocks must be under the control of the scheme.
• There must be no artificial products or other substitutes for customers
to turn to.
As you can see, this makes it difficult for a commodity scheme to last very
long!
8.7.2.1 Tariffs
In 1930 the USA increased its tariffs substantially. (The famous Smoot–
Hawley tariff.) This lead to almost immediate retaliation. When faced with
falling export earnings, countries raised their tariffs on imports. Naturally
this reduced another country’s exports and so spread the Depression.
The point was that the tariffs were often much higher than necessary;
governments overreacted.
Activity
Imagine it is 1931, the Depression is serious and you are a government economic advisor.
1. You are in an industrial country. The government asks you two questions.
a. Can you think of any policies that we should follow?
b. Do you think our country alone can get itself out of the Depression or is
international cooperation essential? What do you say?
2. Imagine you are advisor to a primary producing country. Explain to them why the fall
in world prices in recent months has been much greater in food and raw materials
than in industrial products.
91
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
3. You are advisor in an industrial country. The Minister of Agriculture wants to introduce
tariffs on imported food so that local farmers can be protected. He asks you if it will
that have any negative effects on the country’s recovery from the Depression.
Answer these questions using the readings as well as this subject guide
for help. Once you have completed your answers, compare them to the
possible responses below:
1. a. You can recommend an expansionary monetary policy which will
lower interest rates. But this cannot be introduced with fixed
exchange rates. You can also recommend a deficit budget, unless
the country relies on exports. It would probably have worked in the
USA, but not as well in the UK.
b. If there is no international agreement (and in 1931 there isn’t)
national policies without international cooperation will only work
if the country is largely isolated from the (depressed) international
economy. If this country expands demand alone, it will suffer a
balance of payments deficit followed by a currency crisis.
2. When the demand for industrial goods goes down, supply can be
reduced by closing factories and reducing employment. Therefore
supply contracts as well as demand and prices do not fall too much.
On the other hand, when demand for agricultural products goes down,
supply does not fall so quickly or easily – land continues to be farmed.
This means prices must fall a lot further.
3. Tariffs will raise the cost of food and therefore lower the real wages
of workers. This will have a deflationary effect. If there are no tariffs
and food is freely imported, food prices will be lower, real wages will
be higher and workers will have more money to spend on industrial
goods.
8.8 How did a banking crisis finish off the gold standard?
Pause and think
What is a banking crisis?
Think for a moment before reading on.
92
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33
If a country traded a lot with the UK and the pound was devalued, the
cost of its exports to the UK would rise, so that it would sell less, possibly
leading to a balance of payments crisis. Similarly if the central bank of
the country held its reserves in sterling, the value of its reserves would be
devalued. Note that the possibility of either of these occurring would lead
people to sell the currency, thus making its devaluation inevitable.
Once countries were off gold:
• Their currencies were no longer valued at a fixed rate of exchange
with gold.
• Currency could not be exchanged for gold at a central bank.
• There was no longer a link between the country’s gold reserves and its
money supply.
93
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Activity
1. Imagine it is 1931 and you are again an economic advisor in an industrial country.
Your central bank chairman has decided to stay on the gold standard. Explain to him
why you must therefore advise the government to pursue a deflationary policy, which
will reduce output.
2. Now the contrary position. This time your central bank chairman says the country is
leaving the gold standard. What, he asks you, does that mean for economic policy?
1. With a deflationary policy the country will have less output and
employment and there will be downward pressure on wages. This
economic pain is expected to reduce prices and costs. In turn, this
should increase exports and reduce imports, thus eliminating a balance
of payments deficit.
2. Here the government has more room to manoeuvre in monetary and
fiscal policies. An expansion of domestic demand is possible, increasing
output and employment. When this leads to a balance of payments
deficit, the exchange rate can be allowed to fall.
It is important to remember that the crisis had several causes. This meant
that there was no simple way of avoiding it. But it is likely that, to avoid
the crisis, the following were required:
• The world’s currencies needed to be realigned. Most important, the
dollar had to be revalued upwards. Remember the fact that the US
trade surplus was not fully recycled led to the dollar gap.
• The dollar gap problem meant that the USA had to remove its tariffs.
• Europe needed American investment and technology. Otherwise
European goods would continue to be more expensive than US
goods. This meant that the USA would not increase its imports of
manufactured goods from Europe. The result of new investment
and technology in Europe from the USA would have been to raise
European productivity to US levels.
• Finally, all war debts and reparations had to be cancelled.
In the real world of the 1920s none of these solutions were politically
possible. Therefore, there was no way that the world economic crisis could
have been avoided.
Interestingly, all the things mentioned above did happen after the Second
World War.
94
Chapter 8: The world economic and financial crisis, 1929–33
8.11 Aftermath
The world depression led to serious problems for ordinary people,
for example mass unemployment. In turn, this led to the election of
governments that were committed to intervene in the economy to improve
conditions. We look at this in Chapter 9.
Some countries were less depressed or were recovering faster. The UK
economy reached its 1929 output in 1934, Germany in 1936, the USA only
in 1939 and France not until after 1945. Those countries that recovered
fast, the UK and Germany, needed to insulate themselves from other, still-
depressed countries. Consequently they avoided links through trade and
exchange rates with countries that were still depressed.
It meant that output (GDP) rose faster than international trade. Note this
was the opposite of the situation before 1914. In that period, as we saw,
trade increased faster than GDP.
8.12 Overview
To complete the chapter, here is a synopsis of the changes that occurred
in the international economy. We put them in the context of change
throughout the period we have dealt with so far in the course.
A synopsis of the development of the international economy,
1820–1945
c.1820–70: There was a great deal of variety, including changing
exchange rates. There were examples of both bilateral
and multilateral trade.
c.1870–1914: Fixed exchange rates. Multilateral settlements.
1914–c.1919: Crisis 1 – the First World War.
c.1919–31: Return to fixed exchange rates but serious problems.
c.1931: Crisis 2 – serious banking crisis.
c.1931–39: Interventionist governments. End of fixed exchange rates.
Bilateral trade.
1939–45: Crisis 3 – the Second World War.
Summary
The world economic crisis of the early 1930s was caused by the structural
problems of the international economy of the 1920s. These problems were
caused by the changes initiated by the First World War. Governments in
the 1920s failed to understand that the world economy was in serious
crisis, or if they did, they were unwilling to change their policies. Hence,
the world economic crisis was inevitable. In the later 1930s, countries did
recover from the crisis but recovery was based on domestic recovery, not
on international trade and finance.
95
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Questions
1. Explain the main causes of the Depression in the international
economy in the early 1930s.
2. How far was the world economic crisis of the early 1930s ‘inevitable’?
3. How far did the existence of the gold standard make the world
economic crisis worse?
96
Chapter 9: Government intervention, recovery and the international economy in the 1930s
Objectives
To:
• explain the course of the Depression in selected countries
• show the links between national events and policies and the
international economy
• evaluate the extent to which Keynesian economics could have improved
the situation and how far it was tried by governments.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activity, you should be able to:
• outline why international trade in the 1930s failed to recover from the
Depression although world output did recover
• explain why multilateral trade ceased in the 1930s and trade became
bilateral
• discuss why government intervention in national economies in the 1930s
reduced the level of international trade in the short run.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.219–24.
Eichengreen, B. Globalizing capital. A history of the international monetary
system. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008) second edition
[ISBN 9780691139371] pp.83–90.
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990) [ISBN 0582494230 pbk]
pp.75–9 and pp.89–92.
97
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.80–93.
Feinstein, C.H., P. Temin and G. Toniolo The world economy between the world wars.
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008) second edition [ISBN 9780195307559
hbk] pp.135–59.
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.201–4 and 228–32.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] The end of the gold standard to the end of Chapter 13,
pp.185–95.
Introduction
In Chapter 7 we looked at how the countries affected by the First World
War recovered, but how the recovery was beset with problems. In Chapter
8 we continued the historical analysis and examined the breakdown of the
financial system and the onset of the Depression. In this chapter we look at
the 1930s from the different perspectives of the USA, the UK and Germany.
The Depression was much more serious than we would expect from the
problems of the American economy in 1929. In other words, something
made the Depression more serious after it had started. The most likely
explanation is government policy.
Economists in the 1930s and since have argued about the causes of the
Depression and also whether US policy could have prevented it, or, once it
began, reversed the decline. Two of the most popular approaches are:
• a monetary explanation
• a Keynesian explanation.
98
Chapter 9: Government intervention, recovery and the international economy in the 1930s
Evidence for the monetarist explanation can be found in the three bank
crises between 1929 and 1933. This was largely the policy of the Federal
Reserve Bank (the FED) in 1931. The FED allowed real interest rates to
rise; the monetarists say they should have fallen.
Keynesian explanations, named after the UK economist John Maynard
Keynes, depend on the strength of demand; consumer incomes, investment
etc.
According to this view, the reason for the Depression was that there
was a fall in investment, which was caused by an autonomous fall in
consumption. An implication of the Keynesian view is that there is no
automatic reason for demand to rise. For example, falling prices and
falling interest rates would not necessarily increase investment, as the
monetarists believe. Remember, however, that both explanations could be
true, they are not substitutes for each other.
9.1.3 How far was the New Deal based on new economic theory?
J.M. Keynes changed the way that governments looked at intervention.
Before Keynes people believed that markets always cleared and that
the economy was in equilibrium at full employment. For example, they
believed that unemployment was caused because wages were too high
for everyone to be employed. If wages fell, unemployment would fall.
According to this view government intervention would make the market
work badly. Hence intervention was difficult to justify.
Keynes showed that the economy could be in equilibrium at less than full
employment.
This meant that employment could never recover through the market
mechanism (see above). This is a prima facie argument that government
intervention was necessary for recovery from the Depression. The correct
policy in a depression was for the government to increase expenditure (e.g.
on unemployment benefits or public works) so that demand increased.
The whole idea of economic management came from these insights.
Keynesian ideas were very important in many countries after the Second
World War.
There was one major problem with the ‘New Deal’ of 1933. There was no
worked out policy of fiscal deficits. This was not surprising since Keynes
himself did not fully work out this part of his economic model until 1936!
99
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
9.1.5 How successful was the New Deal in getting the USA out of
the Depression?
In the main, the New Deal was not successful. It did not lead to rapid
recovery. Income per capita was no higher in 1939 than in 1929. Recovery
and growth in the US economy came later through rearmament.
The New Deal government in the USA believed that the fall in prices
caused the fall in output. Hence their policy was to increase output by
increasing prices. In fact, it was the other way round; the fall in prices was
caused by the fall in output. Therefore a fall in prices would not increase
output (see Figure 9.1).
They thought:
⇓ prices caused ⇓ output
so, ⇑ prices would lead to ⇑ output
But, in reality:
⇓ output caused ⇓ prices
so, ⇑ prices would not lead to ⇑ output
Figure 9.1. New Deal economic policy
100
Chapter 9: Government intervention, recovery and the international economy in the 1930s
Activity
Follow through the sequence below and think about what might have happened if the
USA or the UK had run a fiscal deficit during the 1930s instead of covering expenditure
by raising taxes, as they both did.
Think about three hypothetical countries, all equally depressed.
•• The government of one country opens up a fiscal deficit. In other words, government
spending is higher than taxation.
•• That country begins to grow fast. That would mean that its demand for imports
would rise but not its demand for exports. (Because the other two countries were still
depressed.)
•• If there were no remedial action, that country would suffer a balance of payments crisis.
•• This would mean that the government would have to reduce expenditure (i.e. it would
have to deflate the economy and the recovery would stop).
•• Or it could isolate the country from the rest of the world, by even more tariffs and/or
exchange control. This would mean that both exports and import would be seriously
affected.
A government’s ability to create growth is constrained by its connection
with the rest of the world economy. It is not surprising that the
interventionist governments of the 1930s used various means to insulate
their economies. As we would expect, the degree of insulation depended
on the extent that the government was creating growth.
101
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
exchange was used up, the government used strict exchange control to
avoid the increase in demand leading to a balance of payments crisis.
The German government also started a massive ‘work creation’ scheme,
designed to eradicate unemployment. By 1936 rearmament had started in
earnest. Government deficits paid for armaments. Since Germany, by then,
had full employment, inflation was a danger. This was suppressed through
restrictions on consumption and trade.
German GNP in 1939 was 50 per cent higher than in 1929. ‘Recovery’ in
statistical terms had occurred. But the main products of the economy were
armaments and capital goods. ‘Guns before butter’, as it was put at the
time. Consumption was less than in 1929. This leads to the question of
whether the German recovery could be considered to be economic growth.
We continue the discussion of ‘guns before butter’ in Chapter 10 where we
look at wartime economies.
Summary
The economic depression of the 1930s led to major changes in the role of
government in the economy, changes which still affect economies today.
The effect of national recovery policies in the 1930s was to reduce the
importance of trade and to change the international economy, from which
it only recovered after the Second World War.
Questions
1. Explain why international trade grew slowly in the 1930s.
2. How far was it necessary for countries to turn away from international
trade in the 1930s in order to recover from the Depression?
3. How successful was government intervention to the recovery of
economies from the Depression of the early 1930s? You may confine
your answer to one country if you wish.
103
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
104
Chapter 10: The war economies, 1939–45
Objectives
To show:
• explain the market does not work in wartime
• how the market in wartime is always controlled by government policy
• that a government may have different objectives in wartime than in
peacetime
• the importance of output (i.e. GDP) in war as well as in peace
• the problems associated with the transition from a wartime to a
peacetime economy.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activity, you should be able to:
• explain why planning was necessary to maximise output in wartime
• explain why strategic objectives may affect the efficiency of the
economy in wartime
• suggest possible reasons why some countries were able to devote
proportionally more resources to the war effort than others
• discuss what the main constraints on output in a war economy can be.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.134–55.
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.97–114.
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990)
[ISBN 0582494230 pbk] pp.93–103 and pp.106–8. 105
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
In this chapter we examine the relative scarcity of capital and labour
in wartime. We discuss the successes and failures of war economies,
particularly governments’ management of war economies.
Next, we show the important choices that governments had to make
and how these were related to the military strategy that the country was
pursuing.
We examine how much trade is possible and desirable in wartime.
Examples are taken from the experience of the USA, the UK, Germany and
the USSR, during the Second World War.
Activity
•• Write down the goods produced during a modern war and compare the list with the
products made in peacetime.
•• The same goods are made during peace and war but think about the quantities that
are required. What are the differences therefore between a wartime and a peacetime
economy?
•• Are the objectives of a government the same in peace and war?
•• Finally, why do governments intervene in the economy more in wartime? In particular,
why doesn’t a government in a capitalist economy simply allow the market to allocate
labour and capital?
The market will not sort this out, or at least not in any reasonable period
of time. So, if the government needs to increase armaments production, it
has to restrict consumption.
106
Chapter 10: The war economies, 1939–45
Summing up
In wartime a government intervenes in the economy because if it did not:
• Non-essential goods would continue to be manufactured, wasting
scarce resources.
• All prices would rise, but not equally.
In other words, in wartime the price system will not allocate resources
efficiently.
We know that looking for a market price will not help, because the market
will not work in wartime. A government could offer to purchase, say
aircraft, from the private sector. This would presumably mean that the
government would have to offer a higher price than previously. But it has
no way of knowing if that is an ‘efficient price’.
The aircraft manufacturer may be paying too much or too little for his
inputs. The government has, in effect, to decide how many resources,
labour and capital investment to allocate to aircraft production.
• Capital was not the scarcest factor in the Second World War – as it
usually is in peacetime. This was because large economies of scale
were possible for most wartime goods. Economies of scale mean that
as output rises the cost per unit of output falls. For example, if there
was a large amount of underused capital, as on a railway, more trains
could be run without much more investment in equipment. Moreover,
machine tools and other capital goods could themselves be mass
produced.
• The scarcest resource must have been labour. The industrial labour
force could not easily be increased, particularly when, as in the 1939–
45 period, the armed forces took a large proportion of the pre-war
labour force (20 per cent in the UK). Once full employment had been
achieved, the only source of additional labour in most countries was
married women. There was also a major redeployment of women from
consumer industry and services to war factories in most countries.
107
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
It was possible, therefore, in the short run, to have both ‘guns’ and ‘butter’
but only in the short run. For example, although Hitler was elected in
Germany in 1933, the Nazi economy did not introduce maximum controls
until 1937. This was when the economy reached full employment.
The position of the United States was quite different. The American
economy was still very depressed in 1939. Output per person was no
higher in 1939 than in 1929. It was, therefore, initially very easy to
increase output. Rearmament started after the fall of France in 1940 and
the USA fully entered the war in late 1941.
In other words, initially, supply constraints were less in the USA than in
other countries.
Now consider another aspect of the wartime economy.
108
Chapter 10: The war economies, 1939–45
Consumption fell most in the USSR, then Japan and then Germany. It did
not fall in the USA. It fell in the UK, but thanks to strict rationing and price
controls, not for the poorest people.
109
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
110
Chapter 10: The war economies, 1939–45
111
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
10.6.3 Reconstruction
The war caused massive destruction in Europe and the Far East. In
particular, capital equipment had to be replaced. Japan and Germany
had been heavily bombed for example, and even countries less heavily
bombed, like the UK, ended the war with worn out factories and transport
systems.
The only undamaged economy of any size was the USA. The USA made 50
per cent of world manufactures in 1945. Clearly the majority of the capital
needed for reconstruction could only come from the USA. However, the
damaged economies did not have the capacity to export to pay for imports
from the USA.
There were two possible solutions:
• War-damaged economies could recover by devoting the few resources
they had to investment. This would mean that consumption would
have to remain low. In other words, it would take many years of
privation before countries could recover from the war.
• The only alternative was that these countries were given loans to help
recovery. The loans would have to come from the USA.
112
Chapter 10: The war economies, 1939–45
We explore these problem and the decisions taken in 1944 and after in
Chapter 11.
Summary
The Second World War required that governments intervene in the
economy to an unprecedented extent. Depending on circumstances, some
economies were able to devote proportionally more resources to the war
effort than others.
After the war, there was a serious reconstruction problem and only
international loans from the USA could save governments from continuing
to impose severe restrictions on consumption.
Questions
1. How does a wartime economy differ from a peacetime economy? You
may restrict your answer to any one country during the Second World
War if you wish.
2. Account for the successes of economic management during the Second
World War in any country that you choose.
113
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
114
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
Objectives
To:
• explain that international institutions are contingent on the
circumstances of the time
• make clear why the post-war international monetary arrangements
could not be implemented at the time
• show why the fixed rate regime (Bretton Woods system) collapsed and
was replaced by flexible exchange rates
• discuss how the move to flexible exchange rates affected national
economies
• explain the methods used to contain major economic crises, such as
the oil crises of 1973 and 1979.
The effect of the recent crisis (from 2007) will be discussed in Chapter 17.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• discuss whether it was the Bretton Woods ‘rules’ or something else that
made the international economy work so much better after 1945 than
before 1939
• explain the importance of political considerations in the development
of international economic structures
• explain how a country (and its currency) may remain dominant in the
international economy without being economically the most efficient
• explain how an important ‘shock’ to the international economy, such as
an oil crisis, can be contained.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of modern
Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.361–7.
Eichengreen, B. Globalizing capital. A history of the international monetary system.
(Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008) second edition [ISBN
9780691139371] pp.126–33, pp.157–64, pp.219–25 and pp.228–32.
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition [ISBN
115
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.114–21, 204–8.
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition [ISBN
0745009352 pbk] pp.239–57, pp.305–11 and pp.335–8.
Introduction
In this chapter we investigate international monetary arrangements and
the changes that occurred before and after 1973. We discuss the reasons
why the Bretton Woods agreements took the shape that they did. Then we
explain why the Bretton Woods agreements were unsuitable for the post-
war recovery and why different monetary arrangements had to be made
which were not envisaged at the end of the war. We also look at the effects
of Marshall Aid on the recovery of Europe.
Next we explain why the dollar declined in the 1960s and why this led to
the end of fixed exchange rates and the introduction of floating currencies.
Finally, we look at the oil crises of 1973 and 1979 and how the effects of
the crises were controlled.
• The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (the GATT), whose role
was to ensure that barriers to trade were as low as possible, so that the
amount of international trade was as great as possible.
• The International Bank for reconstruction and development (the
World Bank), whose role was to give aid to help, first, in the
reconstruction of Europe and secondly, in the long-term financial
support of developing economies.
Make sure you can see that these objectives were almost the exact opposite
of what countries were doing during the 1930s.
117
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The IMF was a fund and the amount a country could draw on was related to
the amount it had put in. With the exception of the USA, this was not much.
The Europeans wanted an institution that would allow them to draw funds
from the IMF without being limited by the original contributions. In other
words, they wanted to obtain ‘overdraft facilities’, to use the British term
for borrowing from banks.
The problem for the European countries, for example, was that if they
could not obtain credit, it would be necessary to deflate their economies.
Both imports and consumption would have to be seriously limited. This
was politically very difficult, particularly in countries such as the UK,
which had won the war and had a new government which was committed
to social expenditure programmes.
Activity
Imagine that you are the finance minister of a war-damaged west European country
between 1945 and 1950 such as Belgium. Explain why your country would have to
deflate unless it could obtain foreign credit.
In your answer, remember the following:
•• Your country can produce few saleable exports.
•• Imports are required to rebuild the economy and meet consumer demand.
•• Without credit, investment can only be at the expense of other expenditure.
Most countries were also unwilling to accept that there would be no trade
discrimination in the post-war international economy. The reasons were
similar to the reasons that they wanted access to international loans.
• The USA was the most powerful economy, with a dominant trade
position.
• This meant that a so-called ‘dollar gap’ was inevitable.
• People would always want dollars in order to buy US goods so there
would be a shortage of dollars.
• It would be necessary to buy as much as possible from non-dollar
sources. So, those holding dollars could not use them without
permission from the central bank.
• This meant that it would be necessary to discriminate against the
dollar. Technically, under IMF rules, to declare the dollar a ‘scarce
currency’. This would allow the government to take dollars owned by
exporters, and use them only for essential imports. So the purpose of
the trade was to obtain dollars.
• Trade with other (European) countries would be on a barter basis, that
is it would be bilateral. (The value of exported goods would equal the
value of the imported goods.)
118
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
119
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Activity
•• Say it is now 1947. What factors do you consider when choosing to hold pounds or
dollars?
•• Why would a country discriminate if it could not obtain large loans?
•• If it were not allowed to discriminate (because of ‘rules’ being enforced) what other
methods could it use to reduce a large balance of payments deficit?
120
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
• This would mean that the governments would have to deflate the
economies to correct the deficit – that is increase taxes and lower
expenditure.
• But that would make it harder to meet the Communist threat. The only
alternative was loans to allow imports to grow so that the balance of
payments constraint was reduced.
• But, as we have seen, the Bretton Woods agreements had no provision
for large loans.
The solution was the European Recovery Programme or Marshall Aid
as it was called after its Director, the American General Marshall, which
started in 1949. Under Marshall Aid, the USA gave large grants in dollars
(plus a few loans on extremely generous terms) to European countries.
Marshall Aid lasted for four years, and allowed the European economies
to import more than they exported, increasing the growth rate. Moreover,
European governments could still control imports, so Marshall Aid dollars
were used to pay for capital not consumption goods.
121
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The answer is quotas. Think about a tariff. Both the exporter and the importer
could absorb some of the price increase from a tariff to hold prices down.
Marshall Aid finished in 1952, but the flow of American funds to other
countries continued. For example the Cold War between the West and
the Soviet Union meant that the USA kept military forces overseas and
spent abroad large sums on the military. In turn this meant that dollars
were spent in foreign countries. The key event was the Korean War which
both increased American spending overseas and American imports and
effectively ended the dollar shortage.
There was also an increase in direct investment by Americans overseas.
The reason was that the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
had not worked. Free trade had not come about and all the major
economies still had tariffs. This meant, for example, that large American
corporations were unable to export cars to Europe. Hence they used
factories in European countries and manufactured the cars within the tariff
barriers – that is in Europe.
The Cold War and American overseas investment both helped to maintain
the flow of dollars to other countries. As a result, European countries
quickly recovered and the dollar gap closed in the 1950s. This was quite
different to the situation in the 1920s (see Chapter 7).
Activity
Work through these hypothetical figures to help you understand the changing position of
the USA in the international economy during the period.
1. Say in the 1950s that US exports were 10 and imports were six. What was the deficit
on capital account required to balance these net exports?
2. Say in the 1960s, US exports expanded to 12 and imports to nine. What happened if
net capital flow abroad rose to eight?
3. How could balance be obtained? Six theoretical possibilities are listed below, though
the Bretton Woods agreements ruled out several. We look into these more closely
later in this chapter.
4. Say in the late 1960s, US exports stay at 12 and imports rise to 17. The net capital
outflow is still 8 but what is the excess of dollars?
122
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
1. Four.
2. An excess of dollars flowing out of the USA of eight minus three equals
five.
3. a. The exchange rate of the dollar is lowered, US exports increase and
imports fall by a net of five. However, this would have meant ending
the fixed exchange rate for the dollar that underpinned Bretton
Woods. The same applies to the other option, a rise in the exchange
rates of the yen and the mark.
c. Other countries increase their dollar reserves by five.
d. People and companies in other countries build up dollar holdings by
five.
e. The USA introduces import controls to reduce imports by five.
f. The USA introduces capital controls to reduce the capital outflow by
five.
g. The USA deflates the economy and as a result net exports increase
by five.
4. The excess of dollars rises to five plus eight equals thirteen.
The possibility that the USA might have a deficit had not been anticipated
in the post-war settlement. But American foreign policy made it likely that
a deficit would eventually appear.
The increase in direct investment overseas by American companies made
a deficit even more likely. The appearance of the American capital deficit
meant that bonds, denominated in dollars were taken up by the overseas
central banks. This increased the central bank reserves. In theory the
central banks could have used the increase to finance more spending.
But they would not do this, largely because of a fear of inflation. This
meant that by holding US bonds the European central banks were in effect
lending money to the Americans. This was bound to weaken the dollar in
the long run (see below).
Fixed exchange rates had been established by the early 1950s. But this was
a bit of an illusion. Convertibility was the most difficult aspect of the post-
war settlement to establish. Many European currencies were not 100 per
cent convertible until the 1960s, for example. And countries still had some
controls on currency used for capital movements (but not on currency
used for trade).
When the controls were lifted, it was not possible to avoid devaluations.
This was contrary to the original Bretton Woods agreements, under which
fixed exchange rates were taken for granted and IMF loans would only be
made to cover ‘temporary’ balance of payments deficits.
But if a country’s export performance was weak it might be necessary to
devalue. Not devaluing would be more damaging than doing so.
The final way out was, rather than devaluing the dollar, to persuade the
surplus countries to revalue. But this was easier said than done since
it would mean that the exports of the surplus countries, such as Germany
and Japan would fall.
In other words it was easier for the surplus countries to adjust their
economies if there was an exchange rate problem. However the fact that
exchange rates were fixed meant that it was the deficit countries that had
to adjust and not the surplus countries. This was because, under fixed
exchange rates, a deficit country that did not adjust would eventually run
out of reserves.
This problem had been anticipated, but when the USA had designed the
system in 1944, it was not anticipated that the USA would itself be a
deficit country one day.
The IMF system was making it difficult for the USA to solve the weakness
of the dollar.
124
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
$
USA/UK assets (35%)
Figure 11.1
The increase in the price of oil meant large flows of dollars into the OPEC
countries because oil was priced in dollars. (OPEC is the Organisation of
125
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Petroleum Exporting Countries). But the OPEC countries were not able
to absorb all the dollars that they were earning. Hence they lent them to
other countries or international institutions.
About 35 per cent of OPEC earnings went into assets in the UK and USA
(property, shares and bonds), about 42 per cent went to the Eurodollar
market (which was located in London) and about 10 per cent went into
IMF funds. In this way the dollars that had been paid to OPEC were
recycled.
11.2.7.3 ‘Stagflation’
The oil crisis was partly responsible for a major change in the internal
economies of developed countries. The increase in the oil price fed
through into the price of most products, causing inflation. At the same
time rising energy costs led to reduced output and more unemployment.
This considerably worsened a problem which had first appeared in the
1960s – the coexistence of both unemployment and inflation, ‘stagflation’,
as this phenomenon was called. This was made more serious by incorrect
policy responses to the oil crisis. These issues are dealt with in Chapter 13.
126
Chapter 11: International monetary relations since 1944
127
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Summary
In 1944, attempts were made to create a set of institutions to ensure that
the problems of the 1930s would not reccur in the post-war international
economy. These institutions did not work well and had to be modified
in the light of circumstances, particularly the problems of reconstruction
from the effects of the Second World War in Europe.
But the international economy did recover and in the 1950s and 1960s
there was unprecedented economic growth, as we will see in Chapter 12.
Then a new and unforseen problem appeared.
This was the relative weakness of the American economy and of the dollar.
Changes in the structure of the international economy were inevitable as a
result and particularly after the oil crisis of 1973. By then, fixed exchange
rates had gone and the international economy entered a new phase.
Questions
1. How far were the Bretton Woods agreements the reason for the
recovery of the international economy after the Second World War?
2. What were the effects of the change from a dollar shortage to a dollar
glut on the international economy in the second half of the twentieth
century?
3. What was the effect of the 1973 oil crisis on the less developed
countries?
128
Chapter 12: Economic growth in western Europe since 1950
Objectives
To:
• explain why rapid growth occurred in the 1950s and 1960s
• explain why growth slowed down in the 1970s
• outline what this growth and slowdown meant for the international
economy.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activity, you should be able to:
• explain why growth rates in western Europe after the Second World
War were relatively high
• discuss the importance of labour market behaviour in growth rates
• give reasons why technology favoured the shift to very large integrated
markets in the late twentieth century
• show how changes in the relative growth rates may be explained by
the idea of convergence.
Essential reading
Broadberry, B.N. and K. O’Rourke (eds) The Cambridge economic history of
modern Europe. Volume 2: 1870 to the present. (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2010) [ISBN 9780521708395] pp.334–49.
Further reading
Aldcroft, D.H. The European economy, 1914–2000. (London: Routledge, 2001)
[ISBN 0415250633 pbk] pp.128–62, pp.168–72 and pp.180–6.
Blackford, M.G. The rise of modern business in Great Britain, the United States
and Japan. (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North California Press, 1988)
[ISBN 0807842028 pbk] pp.141–7.
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.258–62 and pp.289–91.
129
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
We start with a discussion of the changes in the share of American,
Japanese and western European manufactures in the international
economy since the Second World War. We then concentrate on explaining
two features of the growth of the western European economies in the
period:
• why post-war growth in western Europe was exceptionally fast
compared with all other periods
• why growth rates fell in the 1970s.
Remember an important lesson from Chapter 11. It wasn’t the rules of the
Bretton Woods agreements that led to a flourishing international economy.
Rather, success came for other reasons. In economic history we must be
careful to find the real causes of events.
Activity
Look back at Chapters 2 and 3.
•• What were typical growth rates for those countries, which had achieved ‘modern
economic growth’ in the nineteenth century?
•• How do the nineteenth-century rates compare with those shown in Table 12.1?
•• What other economic information would you want before assessing how far living
standards were raised in the countries shown in Table 12.1?
After 1950 per capita growth rates were high. The growth rates are much
higher than any previous period, so much so in fact that the 1950s and
1960s have been called a ‘golden age’.
Table 12.1 also shows that the growth rates of the continental European
countries were faster in the 1950s and 1960s than in the 1970s and
1980s. The reasons for the high growth rates must also have been truly
exceptional and would not be repeated.
Some of the main reasons for the rapid growth are discussed below.
130
Chapter 12: Economic growth in western Europe since 1950
We can look at this question historically. There was a large and relatively
poor agricultural population in all European countries long before the late
1940s and 1950s. So if the driving force was labour supply, why did it
not happen before? Obviously this suggests that something must have
been special about the period after 1950.
Now think about this. In the period that labour supply to industry was
growing very fast, so was investment in labour-saving technology. Why
would companies have bothered to do this? If factories were taking on
labour for no other reason than that wages were very low, would they also
have invested in machinery that saved labour? Wouldn’t they have had
more workers and fewer machines?
We may conclude that the movement out of agriculture was not supply
driven, but was because the demand for industrial goods was
rising fast, which, in turn increased the demand for labour.
We know that the international economy was working better than it had
before. Trade was increasing. We saw in Chapter 11 how the ‘dollar gap’
was closed. Specifically, Germany had not been able fully to participate in
the international economy in the inter-war period. In the 1920s, German
growth had been held back by the debt problem and by the failure to
achieve a post-war economic settlement. And in the 1930s, German trade
had been held back by the development of a war economy.
After the war Marshall Aid and the European Payments Union made
it possible, in fact essential, for trade barriers to be reduced to allow
rapid trade growth within Europe. This led first to the European
Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), which was set up in 1950. The ECSC
ensured free trade in coal, iron ore and steel between West Germany, Italy,
132
Chapter 12: Economic growth in western Europe since 1950
Once the move to political unity was made, this made the expansion of
trade easier.
Activity
You are a trade union negotiator in 1950s Germany. What strategy would you use to gain
higher wages? Would you
•• try to get higher wages at the expense of profits
or
•• cooperate with the employers and allow profits to rise in the hope that they will
reward the workers with higher wages at a later date?
A major reason why there was full employment was that the reduction
in trade barriers within the EEC expanded demand which, in turn, led
to more output. This was because trade creation was more important
than trade diversion. Think about the effect of a common market with
a common external tariff. One effect would be to divert imports which
had previously come from a lower cost producer outside the common
market to a higher cost producer within it. This would reduce income. The
other effect is that the larger ‘common market’ increases demand within
it so that trade specialisation increases. This would increase income. In
the 1958 common market, trade creation was more important than trade
diversion, so incomes rose.
135
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
136
Chapter 12: Economic growth in western Europe since 1950
12.7.5.1 The UK
The share of Britain in trade in manufactures fell to 4 per cent by 2010.
This sounds small. However, the share is virtually the same as in France
and Italy, both economies of a similar size. Moreover, Britain has a much
larger share of world trade in services than any European country.
137
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
138
Chapter 12: Economic growth in western Europe since 1950
• The need for young workers to receive virtually the same conditions
as adults had the effect of protecting adult jobs since it prevented
adult wages from being undercut. But, at the same time, it made it less
attractive to employ young workers. Their wages were high relative to
their productivity. Hence youth unemployment increased.
• The increase in job security in European countries for the existing
full-time adult workers and young workers led to the growth of
secondary labour markets. Fewer full-time workers and young
workers were recruited. Far more part-time workers, who were
mainly women and immigrants, were recruited. Such workers were
rarely unionised, were paid lower wages and fewer benefits than the
established workers. This phenomenon occurred in every European
country in the 1960s but particularly in the UK.
12.9 Convergence
In 1957 there were considerable differences in per capita income between
the original six countries of the EEC, notably between Italy and Germany.
By the 1990s these differences were quite small.
139
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
We must remember, however, that two factors were behind the better
economic performance of the UK:
• changes in government policy
• convergence within the more integrated west European economy.
Summary
Economic growth in western Europe in the 1950s and 1960s was
unprecedented. The growth was caused by ‘catch up’ and the improvement
in the performance of the international economy. In turn, this led to
further integration of the economies and to further growth. In the 1970s
growth slowed, partly due to changes in the labour market. But the
convergence of the European economies continued.
Questions
1. Why were growth rates in western European economies relatively high
in the 1950s and 1960s?
2. Why did growth rates in the western European economies fall in the
1970s?
3. Explain the economic benefits of the creation of a ‘common market’ in
western Europe. Were the expected benefits achieved?
140
Chapter 13: The American economy since 1960: supply-side economics
Objectives
To:
• explain why economic management in the USA became more difficult
in the 1960s
• explain supply-side economics and show the reasons why it did not
work as expected
• argue that the poor performance of the dominant world economy
leads to problems for other countries.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• list and explain the objectives of economic policy
• give reasons why economic management became more difficult in the
1970s
• analyse why supply-side economics in the USA did not work
• list and explain the international implications of the poor performance
of the largest economy.
Essential reading
Kemp, T. The climax of capitalism. (London: Longman, 1990) [ISBN 0582494230
pbk] pp.127–34, pp.143–7, pp.177–88 and pp.204–11.
Introduction
We have seen how the US economy dominated the post-war international
economy during the 1940s and 1950s. This dominance started to change
in the 1960s.
13.1.2 Unemployment
A new problem in the 1960s was the rise in unemployment to what in
the USA was considered to be a high level (6 per cent). At this time,
unemployment was considered to be a ‘structural’ problem and nothing to
do with the overall demand for labour in the economy.
For example surveys showed that unemployment rates among young
black men and women were several times as high as the national average.
Black men and women were less well educated than whites. Hence,
unemployment policy was aimed at increasing their skill levels. This meant
that unemployment policicy was aimed at individuals, as opposed to
demand management.
13.1.3 Growth
A second problem was that since the 1940s, the growth rate of the
American economy had been very low. The 1960s decade had higher
growth but it was against a trend of falling growth rates and the 1960s
were seen as an aberration. In other words, the US economy seemed to
have peaked in the 1940s.
Moreover, budget deficits were increasing and inflation was increasing in
the USA. In other words, economic management did not seem to
be working. However, the failure of economic management was passed
off, not as a problem of government policy, but as a problem of industry.
Firms were individually blamed by the US government for increasing their
prices.
13.1.4 ‘Stagflation’
We noted briefly in Chapter 11 that the problems of the 1960s were
followed by a new combination of problems in the 1970s and 1980s.
• Prices were rising.
• Output was falling.
• Unemployment was rising.
This was a new combination of problems and the economic models
available could not explain it.
In the standard Keynesian model, which was developed in the 1930s
and was in the ‘toolbox’ of all government economists in the 1960s,
unemployment and inflation were substitutes. This meant that, in theory,
142
Chapter 13: The American economy since 1960: supply-side economics
Activity
Look at the objectives and instruments below. Go through how you think a 1960s
government would have reacted to:
a. a depression
b. a period of ‘normal’ inflation.
Then imagine that the problem was ‘stagflation’. Can you see how the policy responses to
(a) and (b) made the situation worse?
Year 2
Year 1
X Z % UNEMPLOYMENT
143
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Figure 13.1 is a schematic way of showing the reasons why the trade off
between unemployment and inflation had gone and, hence, the dilemma
faced by government policy under ‘stagflation’:
• In the first year, the economy has Y per cent inflation and X per cent
unemployment.
• In the second year, the workers expect that prices will continue to rise
by Y per cent.
• Workers are able to demand wages to compensate them for the
expected inflation (see below).
• Any government policy to reduce inflation will lead not to X per cent
unemployment but to even more unemployment (Z per cent).
144
Chapter 13: The American economy since 1960: supply-side economics
The oil crisis was a supply problem. This is shown in Figure 13.2
where the supply curve moves from S1 to S2 while the demand curve D1
remains fixed. The supply curve was also affected by more than the oil
price (e.g. COLAs).
The American government was faced with two choices. The ‘correct’
policy would have been to reduce expenditure and demand. This would
have reduced inflation, but the problem was that it would have further
increased unemployment. This is shown in Figure 13.3 Option A. If the
supply curve had moved from S1 to S2, the most effective policy would
have been for the American government to reduce demand – that is to
move D1 to D2.
The American government chose to try and reduce inflation without
reducing demand. But they failed to control inflation. This meant that
the high price of fuel was causing shortages, which was reducing output.
To deal with this the government then increased demand from D1 to D2.
The effect of this was to cause much more inflation, but not much more
output. This is shown in Figure 13.3 Option B.
The key point to understand is this: stagflation meant that conventional
economic management would not work.
Option A Option B
S2
S2
S1 P2 S1
P2
P1 P1
D1 D2
D1
D2
O2 O1 O1 O2
Activity
Look at the diagrams above and imagine the effect of restricting the money supply during
stagflation – when there was rising prices, falling output and rising unemployment.
Consider how monetarist ‘medicine’ would affect each of the characteristics of
stagflation.
In other words monetarism was not painless. It was not possible to reduce
inflation without increasing unemployment.
146
Chapter 13: The American economy since 1960: supply-side economics
147
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Activity
Consider some of the assumptions of Reaganomics. For example:
•• Would a super-rich person work harder if marginal tax rates fell?
•• Do successful rich people, like business managers, only work for money?
•• Is it possible for such people to work harder than they do?
Predictions Outcomes
Productivity increases Productivity falls
Savings increase Savings fall
Investment increases Investment falls
Prices fall Prices fall (*)
Unemployment falls Unemployment falls (**)
(*) from tight monetary policy
(**) thanks to a rise in defence expenditure
Figure 13.5 Expectations and outcomes of Reaganomics in the 1980s
If you work through Figure 13.5 you can see that the objectives were
achieved, but not because of supply-side economics.
There were also some undesirable side effects:
• The balance of payments deficit rose.
• The budget deficit rose (because taxes fell).
• The growth rate was low (because savings and investment were low).
And, (as Reaganomics intended) there was more income inequality.
Poverty increased. Welfare declined.
148
Chapter 13: The American economy since 1960: supply-side economics
There was a major crisis in 2007. The causes and consequences are
discussed in Chapter 17.
Summary
In the 1950s and 1960s it was believed that government intervention in
the economy could guarantee full employment and economic growth.
This was not the case in the 1970s, which lead to the implementation of
different economic policies – monetarism and Reaganomics.
Economic performance improved in the 1980s, but not necessarily because
economic policies were the correct ones.
149
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Questions
1. Why did Keynesian demand management become difficult in many
countries in the 1970s?
2. For what reasons were supply-side policies introduced in the USA in
the 1980s? Were the policies successful?
3. How did the poor performance of the American economy after the
1960s affect the international economy?
150
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
Objectives
To:
• explain why the share of industry in developed countries has declined
• show the main long-run changes in manufacturing technology
• explain the main contribution of Japanese industry to world
technology.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• explain why the relative share of services in the output of the major
economies increased
• discuss whether the increase in the share of services was a source of
problems in economies
• describe the major differences between ‘flexible production’ methods
and ‘mass production’ methods in industry
• explain why it was possible in the late twentieth century to have
products that were both cheap and of high quality, and why it was not
in any other period.
Essential reading
Kemp, T. Industrialisation in the non-Western world. (London: Longman, 1989)
[ISBN 0582021820 pbk] pp.200–203 and pp.212–18.
Further reading
Blackford, M.G. The rise of modern business in Great Britain, the United States
and Japan. (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North California Press, 1988)
[ISBN 0807842028 pbk] pp.127–38 and pp.148–68.
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.262–7.
151
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
In this chapter we will show the changes in the demand for industrial
goods and services in the second half of the twentieth century. We look
closely at the concept of ‘deindustrialisation’ – why the share of industry in
the output of the major industrial economies fell compared with the share
of services.
We will also discuss a related issue – long-run changes in technology:
• from craft production to the early factory system
• from early factory system to mass production
• from mass production to flexible production.
And we will use the automobile industry, in particular, the rise of the
Japanese automobile industry as our example.
14.1 Deindustrialisation
We begin with the evidence for deindustrialisation. (Table 14.1)
Shares in total employment by sector (%)
UK USA Japan
1870
Agriculture 21 50 85
Manufacturing 34 17 4
Services 26 25 10
1913
Agriculture 12 32 61
Manufacturing 32 22 20
Services 42 37 20
1955
Agriculture 5 10 39
Manufacturing 36 29 18
Services 47 53 37
1980
Agriculture 3 3 10
Manufacturing 26 22 25
Services 62 66 55
1997
Agriculture 1 3 5
Manufacturing 24 23 32
Services 64 70 59
2010 (Japan 2009)
Agriculture 1 2 4
Manufacture 19 15 26
Services 79 83 69
(Excludes employment in mining, construction and utilities.)
Table 14.1 Evidence of deindustrialisation
152
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
Activity
Table 14.1 presents a number of intriguing features. Look through the table and find
answers to the following questions:
•• Did the agricultural labour force fall in all countries?
•• Was employment in services generally high or low, and was this rising or falling over
time?
•• Did manufacturing employment rise or fall relative to services?
•• By the late twentieth century which sector was the greatest employer in all
economies?
•• Was the shift to services greater in the USA and UK than in Japan?
•• How far are the data in Table 14.1 affected by differences in productivity in the
different sectors of the economy?
153
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
You can see that these criticisms are similar to those which led to
‘Reaganomics’ in the USA and ‘Thatcherism’ in the UK in the 1980s (see
Chapter 13).
One problem was that the solution to industrial inefficiency led to a
further relative decline of the industrial sector. In the UK, for example, the
competitiveness of industry was far higher in 1990 than it was in 1979.
But industry was also relatively smaller. Competitiveness had risen because
the less efficient firms had disappeared, leaving only the most efficient
firms, which were ‘leaner’ and ‘fitter’.
Activity
•• Estimate how much it would cost you to buy a television, video recorder, stereo,
refrigerator, cooking stove and small second-hand car in your country.
•• Assuming that the products last approximately seven years, what does your total for
the point above represent as a percentage of annual average income in your country?
•• How much does a university place cost in your country? (How much does the
government pay and how much the individual?)
•• What proportion of average income is this?
•• Comparing your answers, what does this say about the relationship between the cost
of manufacturing and service products?
155
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Activity
•• Think about any country. Do you think that manufacturing gives this economy a
dynamism that services cannot? Does it matter if labour moves from manufacturing
to financial services and retailing?
•• Most services are part private, part public. For example, think of health, education,
transport and security. Is there a difference between the productivity of public and
private services? Could productivity be raised by privatising services?
•• Do you think that manufacturing is technologically more dynamic than services? Put
another way, is the potential for increasing value added greater in manufacturing
than in services? (‘Value added’ is the improvement in the quality of products and
in their value.) If this were true, those countries where services have become more
important would have become, on average, less competitive.
The answer to the last question depends on which services are included
and what we consider to be technology. Obviously baggage handling and
waiting at tables have low productivity (although they are still important
jobs) but computer consultants have high productivity. A study in the USA
showed that some people working in services, like baggage handling,
produced only a half as much as the average worker in manufacturing. On
the other hand, workers in services like computer consultancy produced
three times as much. In other words, highly productive services are more
important than manufacturing.
156
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
The question of whether public services are less productive than private
ones is not easy to answer. Crudely, the argument is that because
government output is not traded (sold) there is no criterion against which
to judge efficiency. Government services are therefore often considered to
be ‘over-staffed’ and ‘inefficient’.
The problem is that we observe only the inputs that go into government
services (e.g. the cost of the labour working in a hospital) not the output
(e.g. a higher standard of health for the population as a whole).
But the output of a public service could be very large. For example, the
additional output created by a university degree may not be easy to
measure, but all countries think that a highly educated labour force is
essential for economic growth. (Although the private return is higher, of
course, which is why the British and other governments expect individuals
to pay.)
Nor is it true that all government services are not traded. (A government-
owned airline sells its output, for example.) Much of the output of
government is sold in competitive markets.
We conclude that there is no evidence that economies which have a
high proportion of their output in services were (or are) necessarily less
efficient than economies with a smaller proportion in services.
Pause and think
Could a country export only services and import all its manufactured goods?
Currently the market for traded services in the world is limited. Services
are only one third of world exports of goods and services combined. In
fact, it is probably more difficult for countries to increase their exports of
services than of manufactures. This means that an economy that is highly
dependent on exporting services has to be very productive in order to
compete. It is probably easier to compete in the export of manufactures.
157
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
158
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
LABOUR
PRODUCTIVITY
J
US JUS
NIC
QUALITY
Figure 14.1 Quality and productivity in world car production in the 1980s
Activity
Study Figure 14.1 which shows the relationship between labour productivity and quality.
It includes car plants in Japan, the USA, Europe and the NICs (newly industrialised countries)
and also Japanese-owned plants in the USA (JUS in the diagram). The further out on the Y
axis, the higher is productivity. The further on the X axis, the higher is the quality.
Write down the main points that the diagram illustrates (seven are listed below). Try this
before reading on.
159
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Make sure that you can see that the diagram shows the following:
• Japanese plants at that time had the highest productivity and were
high quality.
• US plants had high productivity (but less than Japan) but lower
quality.
• European plants had high quality (the same as Japan) but lower
productivity.
• Plants in the NICs (the ‘New Industrial Countries’ in south and east
Asia) have lower quality and lower productivity.
• The US plants achieved high productivity at the expense of quality.
• The European plants achieved high quality at the expense of
productivity.
• Japanese plants achieved high quality and productivity.
The productivity differences were not because the Japanese workers were
‘different’ to non-Japanese workers. We may see this from the performance
of Japanese-owned and American-owned plants in USA, both of which had
American workers. The Japanese-owned plants had higher quality than the
American-owned plants but the same productivity as the American-owned
plants.
The conclusion of the Toyota study was that Japanese plants had achieved
high productivity and high quality because their production methods were
more ‘flexible’ than American ones.
This was a consequence of the particular problems of the Japanese motor
industry in its early years. Japan did not have a mass-produced consumer
car industry until the 1950s. The market was too small and the economy
had been destroyed in the Second World War. In other words there was a
desperate shortage of capital.
Not long after the war, Toyota engineers returned from the USA with
some second-hand American machinery. But because Toyota had very
little capital it could not use the inflexible high volume machines, made
for American mass-production methods. It took the company ten years to
work out how to use the machines flexibly. This led to what is called ‘total
quality control’. (In total quality control the workers are individually
responsible for the quality of the product.) The companies introduced ‘just
in time production’ because they did not have the capital to hold large
stocks of materials (see below).
160
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
By the early 1970s Japanese imports were making inroads into the US
domestic market.
• The American car producers knew that by the 1970s the large
Japanese car plants had higher productivity than American car plants.
• American car producers misread the signals and thought that the
reason for Japanese success was automation.
• This led American companies to introduce robots in car assembly. So
they built highly automated plants just to make a single model.
• Even with robotic car assembly labour productivity was still lower than
in Japan.
• Another problem was that the new integrated plants were very
inflexible. If the model they were building turned out to sell badly, it
was very expensive to change the plant and produce a different one.
LABOUR
PRODUCTIVITY
JAPAN
USA
NIC EUROPE
AUTOMATION
Figure 14.2 Automation and productivity in world car production in the 1980s
Study the diagram. (NIC stands for newly industrialising countries.) The
further along the X axis a country is, the greater the degree of automation;
the further along the Y axis, the greater the productivity. The diagram
shows that the Americans had less automation and less productivity
than Japan. European producers had high automation but not very high
productivity. The point was that there was no direct relationship between
automation and labour productivity.
14.3.2 ‘Manufacturability’
The Toyota study of the 1980s discovered another difference between
Japanese and other cars. They asked all the car companies which car was
the easiest to manufacture. Nearly all producers in the world said that
Japanese car design made it easier to assemble the cars. It was
thought that half of the Japanese cost advantage was because of better
design and about a half was because of better factory organisation.
161
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Summary
• Massive changes in the productivity of industry and the quality of
products reduced the inputs needed to produce high quality products.
• There is now much less of a trade off between quality and cost.
• Consumers in developed countries have a whole range of good quality
products at low prices and still have money left over.
• Transport costs are now much lower than previously.
• Since the consumer in the developed country is not going to spend
more on food (as opposed to on restaurants) they spend it on services.
• Hence additional resources have been used in services, many of which
(like restaurants) have lower productivity than industry.
162
Chapter 14: Technology and deindustrialisation
Questions
1. Why was ‘deindustrialisation’ a major concern of the large industrial
economies in the late twentieth century? Was the alarm justified?
2. Account for the success of the Japanese motor industry and the
relative failure of the American motor industry in the later twentieth
century.
3. Examine the main differences between ‘best practice’ mass-production
methods of the mid-twentieth century and flexible manufacturing
methods of the late twentieth century.
163
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
164
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late twentieth century
Objectives
To:
• identify those developing economies which have been successful
• examine the relation between developed and developing countries
• look at some simple models of economic development
• understand those factors which make development more likely.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading and
activities, you should be able to:
• give the main reasons why first one country, then another dominated
the international economy
• explain why it took less time for Japan to ‘catch up’ the USA’s position
in the international economy than it had for the USA to ‘catch up’ the
UK’s position
• account for the rise of the Chinese economy (see Chapter 16)
• explain whether the circumstances of the international economy were
more favourable to the poorest countries in the past than they are today
• describe and analyse some of the main ways that poor countries have
developed in the past.
Essential reading
Graff, M., Kenwood, A.G. and A.L. Lougheed The growth of the international
economy, 1820–2015. (London: Routledge, 2013) fifth edition
[ISBN 9780415476102] Chapter 17 The international economy, 1950–2000,
section on International capital flows: private investment to the end of the
chapter, pp.237–47, and Chapter 21 Trade and growth in the international
economy, section on The developing economies, pp.289–95.
Further reading
Foreman-Peck, J. A history of the world economy: international economic relations
since 1850. (New York: Harvester/Wheatsheaf, 1995) second edition
[ISBN 0745009352 pbk] pp.270–4, pp.315–19, pp.324–9, pp.332–3 and
pp.344–6.
Jones, E., L. Frost and C. White Coming full circle. An economic history of the Pacific
Rim. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1993) [ISBN 0813312418 pbk] pp.112–15
and pp.156–63.
165
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
In this chapter we consider whether or not economic conditions were more
conducive to the economic development of the poorer countries in the late
twentieth century than in the early twentieth century.
We discuss the effects on the less developed countries of changes in
international economic relations and in the economies of the richer
countries.
There is also an appraisal of the relationship between trade and growth
in historical perspective which will include a brief description of the
contrasting growth paths followed by developing countries.
UK
= services
= primary producers
c. 1890
= manufacturers
PP USA
USA
c. 1950
PP UK
c. 1990
PP USA
c. 2010
PP USA
Activity
As we said, Table 15.1 is very crude and very simplified. Try adding industries and reasons
for their success to the table.
Next we consider in more detail the cases of Britain, the USA and Japan.
15.1.1 Britain
Pause and think
What was Britain’s success in the pre-1914 period based upon? Use Figure 15.1 and
Table 15.1 to answer the question.
167
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The cost of producing, transporting and handling raw materials has fallen
dramatically in the late twentieth century. World commodity markets have
become globalised. And now most of the world has very low tariffs on raw
materials. In other words the USA is not the only large free-trade area.
Other very large free-trade areas exist. This means that the possession of
very cheap resources no longer confers an advantage as it did for the USA
in the early twentieth century. Remember, when we consider Japan, that
Japan has no natural resources to speak of. It simply imports them.
15.1.3 Japan
The reasons for the increasing importance of the Japanese economy are
different to the reasons for the USA when it was the dominant economy.
Japanese industry is highly technological and produces very high quality
products. Therefore its success depends on a high level of skills plus
research and development programmes.
Research in Japan occurs within large business corporations, unlike in
the UK and the USA where it is more likely to come from universities
and research units. It was Japanese not American industry that created
reprogrammable machines which were different to the American mass-
production machines of an earlier period.
168
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late twentieth century
The reason for the ‘catch-up’ period reducing is, of course, that the world
economy has become much more integrated. Direct foreign investment is
much commoner than in the past. (In a recent publication, the World Bank
estimated that, on average, 56 per cent of each country’s share capital and
government stock was held overseas.)
‘Globalisation’ has had an important effect for developing countries. It
is now possible, for example, to purchase ‘turnkey’ plants – which come
complete and ready to operate (the Brazilian steel industry has done this).
In the nineteenth century technical transfer depended on the transfer
of skills, which were difficult to acquire outside the already developed
economies. Hence it was difficult for other countries to ‘catch-up’ with the
UK because they did not have the UK’s stock of human capital.
169
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
15.1.4 China
Although China is technically a socialist country, a series of reforms from
about 1995 onwards made it capitalist. It has now become the dominant
producer of industrial goods. Because the country is still quite poor, GNP
per capita is about $4700 a year. Import demand does not equal the
demand for exports. There is a large luxury trade in China – high quality
motor cars, fashion items, etc. But the majority of the population does not
buy them. On the other hand, demand for raw materials is very large,
because the country is still at the stage of developing major industries.
(For example, the Australian economy is becoming increasingly dependent
on Chinese demand for iron ore and coal.)
Hence, because on average China is poor and because savings are very
high, it has a balance of trade surplus. This is partly invested abroad,
in, for example, African raw materials and partly it helps pay for other
countries’ trade deficits. So, for example, about 15 per cent of the USA
trade deficit is financed by China. One effect of this is to stop the Renminbi
rising, which is good for China’s exports.
Both Japan and China will be discussed in greater detail in Chapter 16.
As we know, before the First World War, exporting primary products was
very profitable and this was the way the economies of many countries
started to grow. But, it may not be easy for present day developing
economies to grow in the same way. Consider this and form your own
opinion before reading on.
170
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late twentieth century
One piece of evidence to think about it this – over recent decades, primary
products has been a decreasing proportion of international trade.
1951 16%
1953 11%
1980s 2%
2010 4%
Table 15.2 UK net imports, food and raw materials (as a percentage of GNP)
Since the Second World War UK raw material imports have declined
relatively and absolutely. The UK can import all the primary products
it needs at very low cost – only 4 per cent of GDP in 2010. Obviously,
this does not provide a large market for primary products from the less
developed countries. (This is much lower proportionately than UK imports
in 1914.)
Activity
You should try to work out why this happened yourself before reading further. The things
to think about are deindustrialisation, changing demand, price levels and agricultural
protection. Another factor special to Britain was the exploitation of oil from the North Sea
during the 1980s; this affects Table 15.2.
With the exception of oil, the price of food and raw materials has
been low since the Korean war, when prices were high. This is because of
technology and competition between producers.
171
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
• North Sea oil: This was the reason why UK imports were so low in
the 1980s. A fraction of it provided most of the country’s energy needs.
The rest was exported. At its peak, North Sea oil comprised five per
cent of UK GDP.
• Agricultural protection. All industrial countries support
agriculture and protect their farmers against imports. The USA is
currently the worst offender. The UK as part of the EU follows the
Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). Under the CAP, European farmers
are partly protected. European consumers pay more for European
products than they would if they imported them from outside the
EU. For a long time, UK farmers were investing heavily in protected
agricultural products leading to amazing increases in productivity.
land output
wheat +64% +350%
barley +166% +442%
Table 15.3 UK agriculture, 1945–82
172
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late twentieth century
First, the social cost was very high. Many peasants died in the 1930s, when
their food was taken away to feed the cities. Subsequently, no LDCs, except
China, seem to be willing to pay the price paid by the USSR population.
Second, in more recent years the USSR economy has fallen apart, and
as a result, not surprisingly, the USSR model has lost its appeal. Growth
without consumer incentives, without an increase in the standard of
living of ordinary people, is an unattractive choice. (Now Russia is
fundamentally capitalist.)
Let us return to the linkages between trade and growth. In recent years,
development economists have changed their thinking. They now think of
trade not as the driving force of development but as a ‘vent for surplus’.
What happened was that before 1914 export enclaves became established
using surplus or near-surplus land and labour in tropical colonies.
However, the lack of social and political structure outside the enclave
prevented the export industry from helping the rest of the economy. This
explains why, for example, Jamaica is still a poor country despite 300
years of exporting sugar.
The ‘vent for surplus’ approach makes us aware that changes in the social
and political structure of the country are necessary before the benefits
of export trade will spill over into the whole country. When it does, for
instance, a peasant society can change into an exporter of manufactures,
as happened in Japan in the nineteenth century.
173
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Activity
What evidence is there that trade led to economic growth in various countries? Make
notes and write down your opinion before reading further.
Once you think you have decided what the answer is, read on.
We have seen, of course, that exports of primary products were the key
reason for the initial development of countries like the USA, Canada and
Australia. But there may have been a special reason for their success which
we will discuss later in the chapter.
Remember that the demand for primary products was high in the
nineteenth century. Since the late twentieth century, prices of primary
products have been low compared with industrial prices. We say the terms
of trade are against countries exporting primary goods and importing
industrial goods. Such countries now receive fewer industrial goods for
each unit of primary exports compared with what they got in the recent
past. This makes development and growth more difficult to finance.
Activity
The ‘terms of trade’ argument downgrades the value of aid to LDCs. What is the point of
aid if it increases the supply of primary exports from LDCs? Try to make the case against
aid that increases the supply of primaries. Then read on.
• The late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries were not uniquely
favourable to international trade in primary products.
174
Chapter 15: International trade and developing countries in the late twentieth century
If the prices of primary products are high, industrial countries will develop
substitutes such as plastics to replace metal, and synthetics to replace
rubber and cotton. In any case it is not the price alone that matters to
LDCs but the total revenue from exports (price times quantity). In the
nineteenth century, countries bought large quantities of primary products
because they were cheap.
Therefore low prices on their own are not a reason to avoid exporting
primary products. But that leaves the basic question unanswered – can
trade be an engine of growth? To answer this let us look at the other
possibility: can growth be an engine for trade?
makes the per capita growth rate less. It is simply that the big LDCs
were very poor in 1945. So it will take them a long time for their
income to catch up with the rich countries.
• As we saw in Chapter 11, the oil crises were a particular problem for
the LDCs, most of which are oil importers. The crises left many LDCs
with huge debts.
Summary
Conditions affecting LDCs, with the significant exception of the oil crises,
are not very different than they were in the early twentieth century. The
key to their development is not, in the main, exporting primary products.
Rather it is establishing the right social and political conditions to allow
growth to begin. Trade will then follow.
Questions
1. Was the international economy of the early twentieth century more
favourable to trade in primary products than the late twentieth
century?
2. Why did manufactures become the most important components of
international trade in the later twentieth century?
176
Chapter 16: Japan and China
Objectives
To:
• show how first Japan and then China industrialised very fast and how
they became important players in the international economy
• show how the communist regime in China was unable to deliver
economic growth and was replaced by a system which was largely
capitalist in nature including (in effect) private ownership of land and
industry.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading,
you should be able to:
• explain the main features of growth in these countries
• discover why countries that were very poor, for example, China, grew
very fast in the last 60 years
• explain the significance of the relative fall of the Japanese economy in
recent years
• show how socialism was replaced by capitalism
• explain why growth was different in some periods than in others.
Reading
China
Jones, E., L. Frost and C. White Coming full circle. An economic history of the Pacific
Rim. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1993) [ISBN 0813312418 pbk] pp.122–30.
Naughton, B. The Chinese economy: transitions and growth. (Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 2006) [ISBN 9780262640640 pbk]pp.2–10, pp.33–8, pp.69–82, pp.87–
101, pp.114–34, pp.140–50, pp.156–7, pp.164–72, pp.210–4, pp.275–82,
pp.378–86 and pp.391–8.
Japan
Jones, E., L. Frost and C. White Coming full circle. An economic history of the Pacific
Rim. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1993) [ISBN 0813312418 pbk] pp.107–21.
Mosk, C. Japanese economic development: markets, norms, structures. (Abingdon:
Routledge, 2008) [ISBN 9780415771580] pp.231–8, pp.263–59, pp.264–72,
pp.278–282, pp.305–8, pp.312–6, pp.321–31 and pp.337–52.
177
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Introduction
Both Japan and China were devastated by the effects of the Second World
War. Japan was richer and continued its development of capitalism. But
there were several features that were unique to Japanese society.
China initially pursued a policy of strict socialism, which only had a
modest growth rate. Hence the strict socialism had to be replaced by
largely free markets and private ownership of industry. This has led to very
high rates of economic growth.
16.1 China
China has achieved an average growth rate of 10 per cent from 1978 (per
capita, 8.5 per cent). Because of the world depression the average growth
rate is now a bit lower but still 8 per cent or so. At these rates China
will overtake US GDP, per capita, round about 2050. Of course, we don’t
know whether this will actually occur. For example, it was predicted that,
per capita, Japanese growth would exceed US GDP by 2005, but, in fact
Japanese GDP was only 80 per cent of US GDP in 2005.
The important features of the Chinese economy are:
• Initially, China was very poor.
• China is moving away from a socialist economy and moving towards
many features of a market economy.
• China is in the middle of an industrial revolution, with profound
changes to its economy and society.
178
Chapter 16: Japan and China
11.8 million and Beijing only rose 6.7 million to 9.1 million in this period.)
In roughly the same period (1950–82), the urban growth in most of the
less developed countries grew about 200 per cent. Most significantly, the
government controlled the export of food (that is, from the countryside)
to the cities. This was at low prices, which obviously befitted the cities, but
meant that the farmers could not benefit directly from industrialisation.
In other words, the farmers did not receive high prices from the urban
population.
179
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
180
Chapter 16: Japan and China
GDP per year Population per year GDP per capita per year
1952–1978 6.0 1.9 4.1
1978–2005 9.6 1.1 8.5
181
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
The benefits to urban workers include job security, health care and
education for their children. Urban workers also gained access to low cost
housing from their employers on favourable terms. Rural workers, on the
other hand, pay more for health services – about 90 per cent of health care
expenses, even though their income is lower than urban workers. This
means that there are large differences between urban and rural workers –
about three times, in effect.
And it is difficult for rural residents to change their place of work
permanently, even if the rural resident was married to an urban resident.
Only those with permanent residence permits have the right to live in
the city. This has been liberalised since 1980, but not completely. It is still
virtually impossible for a rural worker to live in Shanghai or Beijing, for
instance. But movement to the cities was commonplace in virtually all the
countries at a similar level of development. So a basic problem emerges.
How is China going to cater for large numbers of rural workers who want
jobs in the city? Will they be able to forbid it?
16.1.9 Trade
In 2005, exports were around 34 per cent of GDP. Membership of the
World Trade Organisation (WTO), from 1991, has had a major effect on
trade. In the early 1990s, Chinese trade was about 15 per cent of GDP.
By 2004–5 it had grown to nearly 30 per cent and then to 34 per cent
in 2005. Most major trading countries blame the Renminbi, which is
normally assumed to be an undervalued currency. But, say, a devaluation
of the Renminbi by some 10 per cent would have an effect on trade, but
Chinese trade would still be very important. The Chinese were able to join
the World Trade Organisation in 2001. This was because of a further set of
market reforms, which in turn led to a further acceleration in the growth
rate.
182
Chapter 16: Japan and China
16.2 Japan
There is some more material about Japanese industry in Chapter 14 and
foreign trade in Chapter 15.
16.2.3 Tenancy
Most farmers were tenants before the Second World War owing rent to
landlords. But, after the war, the USA (who was the occupying power) had
legislated against tenancy. So landlordism was destroyed. By 1950, only 12
per cent of peasant workers were tenants. As the economy was developing
very rapidly, the ‘surplus labour’ could leave the farm. Hence, a large
number of farmers moved into (small scale) industry. The better educated
urban workers moved into modern industry.
183
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
184
Chapter 16: Japan and China
for most of their life – or working for an associate company – earning so-
called ‘seniority wages’, with the oldest person having the highest income
in the company. But this has declined in recent years. Moreover, seniority
wages were very useful when the labour force was so young in the 1950s
and 1960s. But in the present day, the Japanese have an extremely old
population – with the increasing problems of an older labour force.
But there are problems with a view that the Japanese are culturally
different. Confucianism (the majority Japanese belief) has not been a
very good predictor of economic growth. For example, the Japanese
performance has been rather poor in more recent years, and does not look
likely to overtake the USA in income per capita. Of course, Japan started
out with the labour costs of a developing country. Now it has the labour
costs of a higher productivity country.
185
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
186
Chapter 16: Japan and China
Summary
China was a desperately poor country at the end of the Second World
War. The government tried to produce a socialist state but this failed.
From about 1976, agricultural productivity grew faster. Industry became
capitalist, and this led to enormous growth in construction and overseas
trade.
Japan was the first Asian country to industrialise, particularly after the
Second World War. Progress was so fast that some people thought that
Japan would exceed US GDP per capita by about 2010. However, in early
1992, Japan suffered a collapse from which it has not fully recovered.
Questions
1. Why has China become more capitalist and less socialist?
2. Account for the success of foreign trade in China.
3. Why has the Japanese growth rate been no more than 2 per cent in the
last 15 years compared with 4 per cent in the period after 1973?
187
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
188
Notes
Notes
189
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Objectives
To:
• understand how the US economy affected the rest of the world
• understand how incorrect polices made the situation more serious.
Learning outcomes
By the end of this chapter, and having completed the Essential reading,
you should be able to:
• explain how the problem of the US economy spread so quickly around
the world
• discuss the main problem of the securitisation of assets
• describe how far the main policies were appropriate
• identify the problems of the US housing market.
Essential reading
Stiglitz, J. Freefall: free markets and the sinking of the global economy. (London:
Penguin Books, 2010) [ISBN 9780141045122 pbk] pp.50–66, pp.77–86,
pp.109–20, pp.136–46, pp.169–72, pp.186–92, pp.198–200, pp.309–15,
pp.325–8 and pp.335–9.
Further reading
Krugman, P. The return of depression economics and the crisis of 2008. (London:
Penguin Books, 2008) [ISBN 9781846142390 pbk] pp.9–28, pp.56–76, pp.96–
100, pp.120–5, pp.165–80, pp.185–6 and p.189.
Introduction
The financial crisis came as a shock to many people. But it needn’t have.
In the first place, much of the world had had similar experiences – Japan,
Indonesia, Malaysia, South Korea and Argentina, for example. However, it
was thought that the countries of the west would be immune to a slump
and a serious fall in their GNP. The prevailing theory was the ‘Washington
consensus’, which held that a slump was impossible.
190
Chapter 17: The financial crisis of 2008
central bank tried to inject some stimulus into the economy from the
1990s onwards but it didn’t work. Interest rates fell to zero. Japanese
growth was less than 2 per cent compared with more than 4 per cent in
the 1980s and 8 per cent in the 1960s.
In Thailand, there was a big boom in the early 1990s. Growth was
impressive. The baht/dollar exchange was stable leading to a big
increase in foreign investment, but increasingly in dubious projects. But
in 1997, the baht sank 50 per cent, far more than was needed to restore
equilibrium. In other words there was a loss of confidence in the Thai
economy. This was partly caused by hedge funds, who were betting that
the baht would fall. The markets were also worried about contagion –
that is, the effect on other projects, some in other countries. So it was
not surprising that there were big falls in the Korean and Malaysian
exchange rate in 1997. Of course, all these economies had problems, such
as excessive building of private hotels, but as Krugman (2008) explains, it
was really a financial panic and not very well handled.
There was a different problem in Argentina. The government decided that
the value of an Argentine peso would be one dollar. This was an anti-
inflation device. But in 2002, the value of an Argentine peso fell from $1
dollar to 30 cents. Real GDP fell 11 per cent in one year. The total fall was
18 per cent from 1998 to 2002 – a huge contraction. The problem was that
many Argentine businesses had debts in dollars. Argentina recovered, but
only paid 30 cents on the dollar for foreign investment. And there were
other examples of weaknesses in the international economy.
The Washington consensus was particularly powerful in the USA and, to a
lesser extent, in Britain. According to this view, the money market worked
almost perfectly in the long run. A bank should always be able to borrow
as much as it needed to. Of course, the interest rate mattered but there
was always was an appropriate rate of interest which compensated the
bank for the possibility of default.
the USA were already 1.3 million in 2007. In 2008 they were 2.3 million.
Moody’s thought that 3.6 homes million would default and 2.6 million
households would lose their homes in 2009.
The problem is that the big banks became too big to fail. The banks knew
that the effects of bank failures would lead to devastating losses in the
real economy. Projects could not be completed, leading to unemployment,
ordinary citizens would lose their savings, pensioners’ income would be
lost etc. Hence, many of the banks assumed that the government would
step in to save them.
One problem was securitisation. These were a collection of mortgage
obligations (collateralised mortgage obligations) which were sold on to
other banks. In the second quarter of 2008, there were $10.24 trillion
outstanding. That is almost ten months’ of the annual US income. But it
was very difficult to apportion the risks that the banks were running. This
is a classic problem of imperfect information. The market did a very bad
job of being risk averse – that is, they did not know how to apportion risk.
The bank itself always knows more than its customers – big or small. This
would include the government. Hence, the government had little option
but to aid the banks.
In addition, a lot of the banks had been working ‘off balance sheet’, so
that shareholders could not tell what they were doing. The staff of the
banks were paid with stock options. This was one of the easiest ways to
move potential losses off balance sheet while recording profitable fees.
What should have happened is that the banks should have moved to real
incentive pay – in other words, pay should reflect the actual performance
of the bank. For example, Lehman Brothers had a net worth of $26 billion
shortly before its collapse. But the hole in its balance sheet was getting
close to $200 billion.
because each bank did not know the value of assets held by the other
banks. Remember, this was a characteristic of the previous period when
banks were working ‘off the book’. And Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (the
intuitions whose job it was to underwrite mortgages) were also bankrupt.
They were nationalised; this means that the taxpayer was, in effect, paying
the cost of their bankruptcy. But, in 2008, Lehman Brothers were allowed
to fail. And we saw their workers lose their jobs instantly.
Was it because Lehman Brothers was ‘beyond hope’? Most of the banks
would have to be bailed out. Was it connected to the fact that stock was all
uninsured? Many banks thought that they had bought insurance, so their
behaviour tended to be more risky. Unfortunately, this type of insurance
was unregulated.
To summarise, the banks’ behaviour was very dubious. For example:
• Securitisation was not necessarily bad, but it has to be carefully
managed. Securitisation means that the bankers shared the risk with
others. The banks seemed to do this in a very cavalier way. Some
assets (for example, mortgages or pension funds) were virtually
worthless, but were still sold on. As we said, the big banks had
privileged information – commonly known as insider information.
• The US bankruptcy code could aid the banks. Chapter 1 of the code
allowed businesses to continue to operate while bankrupt. So the
big losers were the shareholders. Some lost everything. This was
connected with the idea that the major banks were ‘too big to fail’.
Hence, the only source of money was the taxpayer.
• Initially, the government thought that a loan to the financial sector
would be sufficient. However, almost immediately there was a large
increase in unemployment, a huge fall in automobile sales. There was
a 20 per cent fall in business, 2005–8, and a 4 per cent fall in GDP in
2008.
Nor has government policy been consistent. Fannie Mae shareholders lost
everything but the bondholders were fully protected. Washington Mutual
(a large insurance company) shareholders and bondholders lost almost
everything. Then the government safety net extended to investment
banks, and then to AIG, an insurance firm. Stiglitz says that the AIG
bailout (which was an 80 per cent share going to the government) came
about without going to Congress. There was no congressional oversight
or judicial review. In retrospect, the bailout cost $180 billion. The FED
had tried to keep the whole thing secret. The biggest beneficiary, other
than AIG itself, was Goldman Sachs. The Goldman Sachs risky derivative
positions were paid at 100 cents on the dollar.
Pause and think
Why was Goldman Sachs privileged in this way? Was Goldman Sachs ‘too big to fail’?
The problem was that very few people were able to contemplate a
systematic crash – where all the assets lost money simultaneously. By
2002, the big investment banks operated a leverage of 97 per cent. (That
is, they only held 3 per cent in cash or government securities.) Yet in 2004
the SEC (Securities and Exchange Commission) suggested that the banks
operated a leverage of 40 per cent. This was ignored.
193
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
was concealed, even from the European Central Bank. The fundamental
problem is that rich Greeks pay hardly any tax. Hence, the government
has to borrow to meets its obligations. When the Greeks approached the
market for additional loans in 2008, the banks sold the existing bonds
‘short’, betting that the bonds would fall in price. They could do this
because they were able to negotiate ‘credit default swaps’, which made it
even more difficult for the Greeks to approach the market.
We have now reached the stage that when Greece cannot repay the
current loans they can only be repaid though a Greek austerity package.
But, at the time of writing, it is not clear that the Greek government is able
to deliver an austerity package. The general population has said no.
This places the Germans (and the French) in a difficult position. They
don’t want to extend another loan unless they will get it back in the future,
but, at the time of writing, it looks as if the Greeks will not repay it. Hence
Germany, the biggest economy in the EU, has a problem. It will have to
extend another loan to Greece because the Greek state is bankrupt. If
it does not, Greece might default and go back to using drachmas. The
problem is that other countries would probably leave the Euro too (Italy,
Spain). And the Euro would break up.
The European Central Bank thinks that the cost of defaults is six times
the cost of extending the loan to the Greeks. But, fundamentally, most of
the German population does not care about the Euro as long as Germany
itself remains prosperous, which is very likely. No-one knows what will
happen, of course, but it is likely that in the long run the Euro experiment
will break up. It is possibly that Spain, Portugal, Italy and Greece will have
separate (and lower value currencies) compared with Germany, France
and the Netherlands.
Britain suffered a fall of 6 per cent in its GNP, from 2007–8. However, the
British government achieved a better deal than the US government. One
bank in Britain was 100 per cent nationalised in 2007. And some banks
were forced to amalgamate with weaker banks. But the real problem
came in 13 October 2008. The banks were losing money so fast that many
of them were very close to closing. The government had no choice but
to announce a £500 billion loan ($800 billion) to the banks, including
£50 billion in cash. This was the equivalent of £20,000, per tax payer.
Not surprisingly, this calmed the markets. (In fact, the government is not
expected to lose any money on the loan in the long run.)
Not very long ago, the Royal Bank of Scotland was a relatively modest
bank in Edinburgh. By 2007, it was trying to become the largest bank
in the world – and may well have succeeded. It was aggressively buying
a series of banks in Britain, the USA and on the continent of Europe. A
large Dutch bank with undisclosed liabilities was their undoing. By 2009,
the government owned 68 per cent of RBS. British banks are still in the
doldrums. They won’t be as affected as the French and German banks by
the problems of the Euro – because Britain is not in the eurozone. But
the banks are still not lending to small businesses and the rate of new
house building is at its lowest peacetime rate since the 1920s. In 2010,
the Labour government was replaced by a coalition of Conservatives and
Liberal-Democrats. They immediately embarked on a policy of cutting
government spending and raising taxes. This policy is more restrictive than
any policy of all the major countries – and the IMF. It is designed to reduce
the government deficit from 11.2 per cent of GDP to 4 per cent, which was
the pre-2007 rate, in four years. Many, included the IMF, think that it is too
harsh. Only time will tell.
195
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
196
Chapter 17: The financial crisis of 2008
Summary
The world depression started in the US housing market, quickly spreading
to US banks, other financial institutions and overseas. In many countries,
some banks collapsed and others were taken over by government.
The main cause was the profligate lending policy of banks, leading to
enormous debts on government account. At the time of writing, for
example, the USA is still experiencing the effects of the depression and the
Euro is still suffering problems. But in Asia, for example, there is a much
higher growth rate.
Questions
1. Why was the housing market in the USA at the forefront of the
depression of 2008?
2. What has been the effect on the Euro on the international depression
starting in 2008?
197
EC3096 Economic history since 1900
Notes
198
Notes
Notes
199