0% found this document useful (0 votes)
83 views28 pages

A445160 PDF

Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
83 views28 pages

A445160 PDF

Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 28

Helmut-Schmidt-Universitit

Universitat der Bundeswehr Hamburg


University of the Federal Armed Forces Hamburg

S-f•,
I•Department -" Fachergruppe Volkswirtschaftslehre
of Economics

Discussion Paper No.


August 2005 41

Mobile Number Portability in Europe

Stefan BOhler, Ralf Dewenter


& Justus Haucap

DISTRIBUTION STATEMENT A
Approved for Public Release
Distribution Unlimited

20060412075 1
REPORT DOCUMENTATION PAGE Form Approved OMB No. 0704-0188
Public reporting burden for this collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per response, including the time for reviewing instructions, searching existing data sources,
gathering and maintaining the data needed, and completing and reviewing the collection of information. Send comments regarding this burden estimate or any other aspect of this
collection of information, including suggestions for reducing this burden to Washington Headquarters Services, Directorate for Information Operations and Reports, 1215 Jefferson
Davis Highway, Suite 1204, Arlington, VA 22202-4302, and to the Office of Management and Bud et, Paperwork Reduction Project (0704-0188), Washington, DC 20503.
1. AGENCY USE ONLY (Leave blank) 2. REPORT DATE 3. REPORT TYPE AND DATES COVERED

July 2005 Discussion Paper

4. TITLE AND SUBTITLE 5. FUNDING NUMBERS

Mobile Number Portability in Europe

6. AUTHOR(S)

Stefan Buehler, Ralf Dewenter, Justus Flaucap

7. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION NAME(S) AND ADDRESS(ES) 8. PERFORMING ORGANIZATION


REPORT NUMBER
UNIBW
University of the Federal Armed Forces Hamburg

9. SPONSORING/MONITORING AGENCY NAME(S) AND ADDRESS(ES 10. SPONSORING/MONITORING


AGENCY REPORT NUMBER
UNIBW
Discussion Paper No. 41, August 2005
11. SUPPLEMENTARY NOTES

Text in English, 20 pages, 32 references, 8 tables, 2 figures.

12a. DISTRIBUTION/AVAILABILITY STATEMENT 12b. DISTRIBUTION CODE

Public Release. Copyrighted.

ABSTRACT (Maximum 200 words)

This paper examines the causes and effects of mobile number portability WMNP) and provides a survey of its implementation in Europe. We
first examine the competitive effects and the costs of introducing MNP. Next, we discuss how to clarge for MNP. We argue that a price cap
regime starting from the average cost of porting is likely to provide appropriate incentives. Finally, we review the recent experience with
implementing MNP in Europe. Differences in the speed of porting and porting charges appear to explain part of the differences in the use of
MNP across countries.

14. SUBJECT TERMS 15. NUMBER OF PAGES

ISL, German, Mobile number portability (MNP), Mobile communications, Switching costs
16. PRICE CODE

17. SECURITY CLASSIFICATION 18. SECURITY CLASSIFICATION 19, SECURITY CLASSIFICATION 20. LIMITATION OF ABSTRACT
OF REPORT OF THIS PAGE OF ABSTRACT

UNCLASSIFIED UNCLASSIFIED UNCLASSIFIED UL


NSN 7540-01-280-5500 Standard Form 298 (Rev. 2-89)
Prescribed by ANSI Std. 239-18
298-102
Mobile Number Portability in Europe

Stefan Buehler*, Ralf Dewenter** & Justus Haucap*

July 2005***

This paper examines the causes and effects of mobile number


portability (MNP) and provides a survey of its implementation in
Europe. We first examine the competitive effects and the costs of
introducing MNP. Next, we discuss how to charge for MNP. We
argue that a price cap regime starting from the average cost of porting
is likely to provide appropriate incentives. Finally, we review the
recent experience with implementing MNP in Europe. Differences in
the speed of porting and porting charges appear to explain part of the
differences in the use of MNP across countries.

University of Zurich and University of St. Gallen; Socioeconomic Institute, Bliimlisalpstr. 10, CH-8006
Zurich. Fax: +41-1-634 49 07, email: [email protected].
Helmut-Schmidt-University, Department of Economics, Holstenhofweg 85, D-22043 Hamburg. Fax:
+4940 6541 2042, email: [email protected].
Ruhr-University of Bochum, Department of Economics, Universitiitsstr. 150, GC3/62, D-44780 Bochum.
Fax: +49 234 32 14311, email: [email protected].
We thank two anonymous referees, Bernhard Albrecht, Oliver Kaliski, J6m Kruse, Scott Minehane;
Alexander Zuser and participants at the 15th Biennial Conference of the International Tele-
communications Society (ITS) at Berlin 2004 for most helpful comments and suggestions. We are also
grateful to the numerous individuals and regulatory authorities who have responded to our survey on
mobile number portability. Sandra Grunewald and Jutta Kehrer provided valuable research assistance.

44Q O5-33
1 Introduction
Traditionally, consumers of mobile telecommunications services were required to give up
their number when switching providers. Consumers were thus hesitant to switch from the
incumbent to competing operators, thereby inhibiting more effective competition in mobile
telecommunications. Lately, the picture has changed dramatically, as mobile number
portability (MNP) has been implemented in the European Union (EU) and many other
countries around the world.
According to the EU's Universal Service Directive of 7 March 2002, which became effective
on 25 July 2003, MNP means that customers are given the right to keep their mobile
telephone number when switching between service providers. Under Article 30 of this
Directive ,,Member States shall ensure that all subscribers of publicly available telephone
services, including mobile services, who so request can retain their number(s) independently
of the undertaking providing the service". 1 Similar approaches towards introducing MNP
have been adopted elsewhere.
From a property rights perspective, the introduction of MNP reallocates the property rights in
mobile telephone numbers from operators to consumers. The main rationale for this re-
allocation is the enhancement of competition in mobile telecommunications. As the EU
argues, "number portability is a key facilitator of consumer choice and effective competition
in a competitive telecommunications environment" (see EU, 2002, p. 57). Accordingly,
national regulatory authorities (NRAs) shall ensure that (a) charges for mobile number
portability are cost-oriented and "that direct charges to subscribers, if any, do not act as a
disincentive for the use of these facilities" (Art. 30 (2) Universal Service Directive), and (b)
retail charges for MNP do not distort competition (Art. 30 (3) Universal Service Directive).
In this paper, we present a non-technical analysis of the causes and effects of MNP, and we
review the recent experience gained with MNP in European countries. We start with a
discussion of the competitive effects and the costs of introducing MNP (sections 2 and 3).
Section 4 provides an analysis of appropriate charges for MNP, an aspect that has largely
been ignored in previous literature. We then proceed to evaluate the recent experience with
MNP in Europe (section 5). We offer concluding remarks in section 6.

2 On the Competitive Effects of MNP


2.1 The Case for MNP
The rationale of introducing mandatory MNP is simple: It is expected to bring about
considerable benefits to consumers of mobile services (see, e.g., Ovum 2000). Adopting the
classification originally proposed by NERA/Smith (1998), we briefly discuss five potential
benefits of introducing MNP to consumers of mobile services (see Table 1).
With switching costs, customers that actually switch (and thus give up their number) incur a
utility loss. Also, switching costs induce some consumers to stick to a provider which is not
their preferred choice. Introducing MNP benefits both types of consumers: Consumers who
switch even in the absence of MNP can retain their number (benefit IA), and consumers who
switch only with MNP are more likely to obtain services from their preferred operator (benefit

Directive 2002/22/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 7 March 2002 on universal
service and users' rights relating to electronic communications networks and services (Universal Service
Directive), Official Journal of the European Communities, 24 April 2002, L108/51-77.
I B). 2 WhileMNP thus benefits consumers that actually switch, there are also benefits to non-
switching consumers resulting from more intense competition among providers of mobile
telecommunications services (benefit 2).3 Furthermore, introducing MNP benefits consumers
who place calls to ported numbers (benefit 3). Without MNP, these consumers have to update
their address books, may be unable to call a particular user, etc. 4 Finally, introducing MNP
benefits mobile customers because of the reallocation of property rights (benefit 4). The fact
that MNP reallocates property rights in telephone number is especially important for so-called
vanity numbers. If customers advertise their telephone number, this increases the number's
value and may be seen as a specific investment into the number's value. Hence, a telephone
number's value is to some extent endogenous. 5 The incomplete contracts literature suggests
that underinvestment results if the customer making the investment does not hold the property
right in the number. 6 Hence, the reallocation of property rights strengthens the customers'
investment incentive. This thickening of consumers' property rights benefits all consumers -
whether they actually port their number or not. The option to port one's number is decisive
here, and this option is given to every telephone user with MNP.

Table 1: Benefits of Introducing MNP


Type of Benefit Applies to Benefit
IA Users who switch even Avoided Costs of Number Change (e.g.,
without MNP informing users, missed calls)
lB Users who only switch with Benefits of moving to a more preferred operator
MNP
2 All Users Intensified Competition
3 Caller Avoided costs of finding changed numbers
4 All Users Increased investment in number value due to re-
allocation of property rights

We now proceed to a more detailed analysis of the competitive effects of MVNP, focusing on
the elimination of switching costs associated with MNP.

2 In a model with differentiated products, this means that consumers can switch more easily to their pre-
ferred provider, so that an increase in allocative efficiency results (see, e.g., Buehler and Haucap, 2004).
3 See, e.g., Aoki and Small (1999); Galbi (2001), and Gans and King, (2001).
4 However, most cost benefit analyses have estimated this effect to be relatively small or almost negligible
(see, e.g. Oftel, 1997, Schwarz-Schilling and Stumpf, 1999).
5 Some numbers that are easy to remember already have a high exogenous value. This is illustrated by the
fact that in the Chinese province of Sichuan the telephone number 8888 8888 obtained a price of 2.33m
yuan ($282,000) in an auction in August 2003. The reason is that many Chinese people consider the
number eight to be lucky because it sounds similar to the Mandarin and Cantonese word for getting rich.
So an eight-digit number containing only the number eight is considered especially auspicious (see BBC,
2003).
6 The classic reference is Grossman and Hart (1986). Haucap (2003) provides an application to telephone
numbers.

2
2.2 The Effects of Eliminating Switching Costs
Consumers of mobile telecommunications services typically face switching costs which
derive from the real and psychological costs that consumers confront when changing suppliers
(see, e.g., Klemperer 1987a, 1987b, 1988, 1995). These switching costs are endogenous if
they emanate from customer loyalty programs (such as Deutsche Telekom's so-called Happy
Digits program) or contractual clauses that make the change of suppliers more costly (such as
contract termination penalties). There are also exogenous switching costs resulting from the
transaction costs associated with switching providers (e.g. for changing the network assign-
ment of a given number). Introducing MNP eliminates at least part of these switching costs. In
the following, we describe some important static and dynamic effects of introducing MNP.

2.2.1 Static Effects


Previous literature has mainly focused on the static effects of introducing MNP, largely
abstracting from market entry and investment. In this section, we briefly survey some of the
literature's key findings.

Retail Prices
It is well known that, in the presence of switching costs, firms may exploit their market power
over captured customers. For instance, with linear retail prices, an incumbent firm benefits
from a wedge driven between its price and the prices of new entrants, allowing the incumbent
to charge a higher price than would otherwise be possible. To see this, suppose that the
customers of an established provider A face switching costs S > 0. Firm A is thus able to
charge a higher retail price than its competitor B without inducing its customers to switch.
That is, the customers of provider A will switch only if PA > PB + S. Introducing MNP
should thus be expected to reduce retail prices, benefiting mobile customers.
With nonlinear retail prices, introducing MNP is still likely to benefit mobile customers
(provided they do not suffer from the so-called "customer ignorance problem" 7 ). However,
the argument is slightly more complex. Using a simple model with differentiated networks,
Buehler and Haucap (2004) show that the incumbent's customers benefit from lower fixed
fees with MNP, whereas competitors' customers suffer from higher fixed fees. Since the
beneficial effects on the incumbent's customers dominate the adverse effects on the
8
competitors' customers, the overall effect of MNP on mobile customers is positive.

PriceElasticities
The above arguments suggest that it is more difficult to gain market share in the presence of
switching costs, as undercutting needs to be more severe. Technically speaking, the firms'
perceived price elasticity of demand is smaller, and equilibrium prices should thus be
expected to be higher than with MINP. Moreover, the smaller price elasticity of demand helps
to stabilize collusive arrangements (see Schwarz-Schilling and Stumpf, 1999), as the extra
profits from deviating from collusive behavior will be relatively small.

7 We discuss the customer ignorance problem in more detail below (see section 3.2).

8 A referee correctly pointed out, though, that the overall effects on prices in a more general model are less
clear, as MNP reduces the firms' possibilities to discriminate between on-net and off-net tariffs.

3
Termination Charges
The effects of introducing MNP on termination charges crucially depend on the occurrence of
the "customer ignorance problem" (Gans and King, 2000). If customers can identify the
network assignment of each individual number even after introducing MNP, termination
charges should remain unaffected. However, if customers are no longer able to determine
which mobile network they are calling when placing a call, termination charges are likely to
increase. Intuitively, this follows from the firms' incentives to increase their charges when
customers only take notice of average charges (see Buehler and Haucap, 2004).

Market Shares
In the presence of switching costs, the market shares of the incumbent and its competitor will
typically be asymmetric. More specifically, the incumbent will have a large market share,
whereas its competitor will have a smaller market share. In standard network competition
models, introducing MNP will eliminate this asymmetry, as the competitor is no longer forced
to offer a discount relative to the incumbent to attract customers, and market shares will thus
be aligned. If the providers' profits are convex in own market share (as, e.g., in Buehler and
Haucap 2004), introducing MNP will reduce aggregate profits. That is, the incumbent's loss is
larger than the extra profit awarded to the competitor.

2.2.2 Dynamic Effects


In addition to static effects, introducing MINP will generate dynamic effects. In particular,
MNP might affect entry and investment decisions, as we now briefly discuss.

Entry
We have noted above that, with switching costs, entrants have to price aggressively to steal
business from the incumbent. Introducing MNP will alleviate the need to price aggressively,
thereby facilitating entry. However, there may be countervailing effects. For instance, if
incumbent mobile operators have a large captured customer base thanks to switching costs,
they are less likely to fight entry by aggressively cutting prices due to the so-called fat-cat
effect (see Fudenberg and Tirole, 1984). The net effect of introducing MNP on entry is thus
ambiguous.

Investment
Introducing MNP is likely to affect the investment incentives of both incumbents and
potential competitors. However, to the best of our knowledge, there is no systematic analysis
of the effects of MNP on the service providers' investment incentives. Standard arguments
suggest that introducing MNP will reduce the incumbent's incentive to make cost-reducing
investment, as the cost-reduction applies to a reduced customer base. Conversely, the
competitor's incentives to make cost-reducing investment should be expected to increase,
with ambiguous net effect. The aggregate effects on demand-enhancing investment, such as
infrastructure quality or product innovation, are even less clear.

4
2.2.3 Summary
Overall, the competitive effects of introducing MNP are fairly complex. MNP is likely to
affect retail prices, termination charges, price elasticities, market shares, as well as entry and
investment decisions. So far, it is fair to say that most analyses on MNP have supported the
notion that, on the whole, MNP intensifies competition in mobile telecommunications.
Available empirical evidence on the portability of premium rate numbers appears to support
this conclusion (Viard, 2004). Yet, it is unlikely that introducing MNP reduces all prices. In
fact, standard models suggest that handset prices will increase as the value of a captured
customer decreases, whereas prices for mobile services will decrease as competition
intensifies (Buehler and Haucap, 2004). Furthermore, the pro-competitive effects of MNP are
likely to vary across countries, depending on the degree of competition achieved before
introducing MNP. 9

3 The Costs of MNP


Obviously, the introduction of MNP generates costs (otherwise, the decision whether or not to
introduce MNP would be trivial). Generally speaking, we can distinguish between direct and
indirect costs of introducing MNP.

3.1 Direct Costs


The direct costs of implementing and running an MNP system consist of
Costs of developing and implementing a MNP system (set-up costs),
Costs per actual porting process,
Additional conveyance costs.
As we will further discuss below, the magnitude and structure of these costs depend heavily
on the technical solution used to implement MNP. The set-up costs are the non-recurring costs
of developing and implementing a particular MNP system. These costs include changeover
costs which arise when changing from an existing to a new system (e.g. when changing from
an on-switch to an off-switch solution, see Smith/Arcome/NERA, 1997, p. 62 f.). More
specifically, set-up costs include costs for developing software, upgrading switch software,
installing company procedural and operational methods, and developing an operational
support system. These costs are fixed, that is, they do not depend on the number of actual
portings or the traffic routed over a network. In general, these fixed costs are relatively high
for so-called IN solutions (off-switch), while they are relatively low for on-switch solutions.
In addition to fixed set-up costs, there are variable costs associated with the porting process.
These are mainly the costs of carrying out the porting, e.g. advising the customer,
communications between the donor and the receiver network, administrative work related to

9 For example, a NERA/Smith study of the costs and benefits of introducing MNP in Hong Kong estimated
the additional benefit from increase competition to amount to I Euro per customer over a period of 10
years, as competition was already quite intense even before MNP was introduced (see NERA/Smith,
1998). In contrast, Oftel (1997) estimated the additional benefits of increased competition resulting from
MNP to lie around 69 Euros per customer over a 10 year period - quite a significant difference which is
due to Oftel's assumption that competition would be significantly more intense with MNP than without
M7NP (see Oftel, 1997).

5
the number switch, and so on. These costs are essentially personnel costs, and they depend on
the specific administrative and technical procedures put in place.
Finally, there may be conveyance costs, which also depend on the technical solution chosen to
implement MNP. Since simple technical solutions (on switch) lead to an inefficient use of
network resources, these costs are much lower with more advanced IN solutions (off-switch).
With simple solutions, it becomes difficult to determine the exact costs of a connection, and
the problem is exacerbated when the number of portings and networks involved is high. As a
result, simple solutions for the implementation of MNP are usually regarded as inefficient
temporary solutions at best (see Smith/Arcome/NERA, 1997, p. 67).
Comparing the direct costs of the various technical solutions, we note that on-switch solutions
are characterized by comparatively low fixed set-up costs and high variable costs. In contrast,
IN solutions have relatively high fixed set-up costs, whereas their variable costs are low.
Hence, IN solutions are cost-efficient if the expected number of portings is relatively high,
whereas less advanced solutions (such as call forwarding) are efficient as long as the number
of portings is low. The stylized average cost function for these two technologies, on-switch
(ONS) and off-switch (IN), are depicted below, as is the threshold number of portings after
which an IN solution becomes more efficient than an on-switch solution.

Figure 1: Direct Costs of MNP using ONS or IN Technology

SA ACONs

ACIN

•Number of
Portings X

3.2 Indirect Costs of MNP


There are also indirect costs of introducing MNP, resulting from the potential loss in tariff
transparency-an effect that has largely been ignored in the debate on MINP. The loss of tariff
transparency results from the fact that MNP can make it more difficult for consumers to
distinguish between different networks when placing a call. In the absence of MNP,
consumers can usually distinguish between different mobile networks through the number
prefix. When MNP is introduced, however, the number prefix no longer indicates the network
assignment of a given number. Thus, if calling prices differ across networks, customers will
be unaware of the exact charges for placing calls to mobile networks. As Ovum (2000,
p.14/15) acknowledges in its cost-benefit-analysis of MNP in Ireland, "the first three digits of
the called number no longer indicate the network operator of the called subscriber reliably.

6
Full tariff transparency is therefore lost and, unless prices change, callers end up paying a lot
more than expected for certain calls. [...But] it is difficult to quantify these effects and we
have excluded them from our cost benefit analysis."
In the academic literature, the "customer ignorance problem" has been explored by Gans and
King (2000) and Wright (2002). These authors show that mobile operators may have
incentives to increase their termination charges if consumers only take notice of average
prices. Dewenter and Haucap (2005) provide empirical support for this finding, and Buehler
and Haucap (2004) analyze the tradeoffs related to the introduction of MNP.
However, the loss of tariff transparency may be overcome. In Finland and Germany, for
example, consumers can call a toll-free number to identify a particular number's network
assignment. In Portugal, an acoustic signal alerts consumers when placing off-net calls. Yet,
such mechanisms generate costs on their own, and they are often considered a nuisance by
many consumers.
An alternative method to avoid the customer ignorance problem would be the introduction of
the so called receiving partypays regime (RPP), as in the United States, in Canada and some
Asian countries. Since under RPP the calling party is charged for the origination but not for
the termination of off-net calls, tariff transparency becomes irrelevant. That is, under RPP, the
customer ignorance problem vanishes.

4 Charges for MNP


We have argued that there are various costs and benefits of introducing MNP. However,
virtually all cost-benefit analyses have concluded that the overall effect of MNP on welfare is
likely to be positive. Since MNP is not costless, at least two questions remain: Who should
pay for MNP? And what is the efficient charge for porting a number? In the following
subsections, we discuss potential answers to these questions.

4.1 Inefficiency of Free Porting


Economic efficiency typically requires that users of a given resource or service pay for their
usage if the resource under consideration is scarce (i.e. carries an opportunity cost). If users
are not made to pay even though their usage causes costs, an inefficient over-use of the
resource will result. This problem is also known as the "tragedy of the commons". More
generally, a below-cost usage fee leads to inefficiencies. Making a resource available free of
charge is thus only efficient if it is either not scarce or a public good, where the latter is
characterized by two distinctive features:
(a) It is economically not feasible to exclude people from using a good or service (non-
excludability); and
(b) Additional users do not cause additional costs (non-rivalry in use).
It should be clear that MNP is not a (pure) public good, as (a) people unwilling to pay for
MNP can be excluded and (b) additional portings cause additional costs, i.e. the incremental
cost of an additional porting is positive.
However, as we have seen, there are various benefits associated with MNP, some of which
are private and some of which are public. While type IA and lB benefits are private, type 2
and 4 benefits resulting from the strengthening of competition and increased investment
incentives are public, as they do not only accrue to those users who actually port their

7
number. In particular, it is not possible to exclude any user from the competitive benefits that
arise from the introduction of MNP. Moreover, type 2 and 4 benefits do not actually arise
from porting a number, but from the option to do so. The possibility to port one's number
strengthens users' positions vis-At-vis their provider, and this possibility is decisive for
competition.10
Existing cost-benefit-analyses suggest that type IA and lB benefits are at least as large as
type 2 benefits. Furthermore, type 2 benefits are expected to be the smaller the more
competitive a particular market was before introducing MNP. Hence, at least in highly
competitive markets the benefits of MNP will be largely private, while in less competitive
markets the benefits are more likely to be contain public benefits.
While private benefits and positive incremental costs per porting call for positive charges,
there are also positive externalities to be considered. These are the benefits to potential
callers, i.e. type 3 benefits. On the other hand, there are negative externalities, as MNP can
reduce tariff transparency. We think that neither the positive nor the negative externalities
should be overemphasized, as their magnitude has not been estimated to be significant. From
this, we conclude that making MNP available free of charge will be inefficient: Free porting
will induce users to port their number even if their number's valuation is smaller than the
incremental cost of porting. Therefore, an avoidable deadweight loss will result.
Furthermore, MNP can be viewed as a new service offered to consumers. In a perfectly
competitive market, new services will be offered if providers expect the total revenues from
these services to cover the costs. Hence, even in a perfectly competitive environment, MNP
would not be offered free of charge, but at a positive price. Accordingly, donor and/or
recipient networks should be allowed to charge for porting.

4.2 Regulating Charges for MNP


The next step is to look for an efficient charge for porting a number. Economic intuition
suggests that market forces are unlikely to lead to efficient charges for captured customers, as
the respective operators are the only providers of MNP for their customers and thus enjoy
monopoly power. Note that most customers have received their mobile telephone number well
before MNP has been introduced.
The picture is less somber for new customers, where the porting charge is just one element of
the service packages offered by the different providers. Here, it is conceivable that providers
voluntarily offer MNP at efficient prices so as to convince consumers to sign a contract." In
particular, with nonlinear tariffs, service providers have an incentive to charge efficient
variable charges and extract the costumer surplus using the fixed fee. In this case, the outcome
may be efficient, even though the consumer surplus is redistributed to the providers. Overall,
it seems nevertheless likely that, at least in the short run, market prices for MNP are at
inefficiently high levels, as mobile operators have monopoly power in setting MNP charges
for the majority of their customers since MNP was not available when most customers'

I0 Also note that users can not be excluded from the option to port their number, even if users who do not
wish to pay can be excluded from actually porting the number.
l This argument is related to Farrell and Gallini (1988) who show that producers may voluntarily commit to
keep markets competitive (by opening up second sources) in order to convince consumers that they will
not be exploited at a later stage.

8
received their current mobile telephone number.12 This suggests that regulating the charges
for MNP is desirable (at least for a transition period after introducing MNP).
For determining the efficient charge for porting a number, it is important to note that MNP
has both fixed and variable costs. In particular, IN solutions are characterized by decreasing
average costs. This means that determining efficient charges for MNP gives rise to similar
problems as the determination of efficient charges in natural monopoly settings. It is well
known from standard economic theory that the efficient price for natural monopoly services is
at the marginal or incremental cost level (see, e.g. Viscusi, Vernon, Harrington, 2000). The
resulting deficit should ideally be compensated through government subsidies. Hence, one
could argue that porting charges should be set at incremental or variable cost and the
government should cover the fixed cost associated with the development and implementation
3
of mandatory MNP.1
One might be tempted to argue that the operators should bear the fixed cost and set prices at
incremental costs in order to guarantee allocative efficiency if the government is not willing
to cover the fixed cost. However, this solution distorts the operators' choice of technology: If
operators are forced to cover the fixed cost and the technology is not predetermined, operators
are likely to choose a technology with relatively low fixed and high variable costs (such as an
on-switch solution), which may lead to productive inefficiencies. That is, providers may
deliberately install an inefficient technology with relatively high variable costs, attempting to
recover a larger part of the total cost from MNP. In addition, higher MNP charges imply
higher consumer switching costs. This again allows incumbent providers to charge less
aggressively without losing their current customers. Hence, incumbent providers are likely to
set rather high MNP charges in order to avoid losing customers.
To avoid this problem, regulatory authorities could prescribe the technology to be used.
However, this approach is unlikely to give rise to an efficient outcome, as operators typically
have better information about the efficient use of technologies than regulators. It is well
known from principal-agent analysis that the regulator (the principal) has to reward the
operators (the agents) to induce an efficient technology choice in the presence of asymmetric
information. If operators anticipate that they will have to lower their porting charges if they
use an efficient instead of an inefficient technology, an inefficient technology will result. An
obvious way to provide incentives is a price cap regulation for porting charges. As a starting
point, one may use current average cost, but also some other figure exceeding incremental
cost (to avoid the over-use problem). To avoid potential "gold plating" by operators, one may
use a ceiling for the average cost, based on the most efficient technology in use today.
There are essentially two arguments in favor of a price cap regime starting from current
average costs. First, such a regime leads to efficient "make or buy" decisions: If operators are
allowed to recover variable costs only, they may strategically outsource parts of their business
in order to substitute variable for fixed costs. Since an external provider of MNP-related
services will charge a price for its services that at least covers average cost, mobile operators

12 It should thus not come as a surprise that the German regulatory authority (RegTP) felt it had to step in
and to regulate charges for MNP ex post after two small service providers decided to charge their
customers a price of 116.00 E for porting their number (see
http://www.rectp.de/aktuelles/pin/03140/index.htinl). Most other European countries have regulated MNP
charges ex ante.
13 Introducing two-part tariffs for MNP is not very useful, as most consumers have only one mobile number
to port (i.e., one unit of consumption). Alternatively, one might consider a tariff involving a (fixed) fee
for buying an option to port one's number and another charge when exercising this option (the
incremental cost of porting). Note, however, that it is virtually impossible to install different technologies
for different customers on the same network. Hence, in practice, the MNP option can only be installed
jointly for all customers and it is not possible to exclude consumers from this option.

9
will outsource excessively in order to reduce their fixed cost (if they cannot recover them
through MNP fees). In contrast, under a price cap regime starting from current average costs,
operators will only outsource if an external provider of MNP services can offer these services
at lower prices than the corresponding costs of in-house production. Second, starting from
current average costs allows operators to implement MNP without incurring losses. If,
instead, operators are forced to offer MNP at prices below average cost, this will be regarded
as a government hold-up or expropriation. Since license fees, network investments and
customer acquisition costs are all specific investments, operators are vulnerable to
expropriation through renegotiation of the regulatory contract (see Goldberg, 1976; Sidak and
Spulber, 1997). In dynamic and innovative industries such as mobile communications,
dynamic efficiency aspects are highly relevant. Therefore, regulators should be hesitant to
introduce regulations adversely affecting investment and innovation incentives.
Summing up, we argue that the market is unlikely to generate efficient charges for MNP, as
service providers have monopoly power over their captured customers, as MNP became
available after most consumers had been allocated a mobile number. Regulating the charges
for MNP thus seems desirable (at least in a transition period after introducing MNP), provided
that the regulated charges cover not only the variable costs, but also parts of the fixed costs (a)
in order to avoid an ex post hold-up which adversely affects investment incentives and (b) to
provide incentives to implement an efficient MNP technology. We argue that a price cap
regime starting from the current average cost of the most efficient technology in use should be
expected to provide appropriate incentives.

5 The European Experience


As noted at the outset, the EU's Universal Service Directive requires member states to
implement number portability for publicly available telephone services (including mobile
services). The provision of number portability should be cost oriented and charges should not
prevent subscribers from porting their numbers. The implementation of MNP may be
abandoned if it either leads to negligible positive effects for end-users and competition or is
technically non-feasible. The directive furthermore stresses the importance of transparent
tariff information and instructs NRA's to facilitate tariff transparency when implementing
number portability.
We now review the introduction of MNP and its success in European countries and abroad. In
particular, we focus on the actual use of MNP, porting charges, porting speeds and regulatory
4
interventions to foster price transparency for off-net-calls.'

5.1 Introduction of MNP


In 1997, Singapore was the world's first country to implement (limited)15 MNP. The United
Kingdom and the Netherlands first implemented MNP in Europe in 1999. Countries such as
Spain (2000), Sweden and Denmark (all 2001), Belgium, Italy, Germany and Portugal (all
2002) followed suit. Most recently, Estonia implemented MNP due to regulatory intervention.
Only few EU member states have not yet introduced MNP (see Table 2).

14 We have surveyed European regulatory authorities in fall 2003 with respect to regulatory frameworks and
their first experiences with MNP. In the following, we present some of this survey's results.
15 Even though implemented in 1997, MNP has been limited to voice telephony without the ability to
support data services such as SMS and MMS.

10
Table 2: Introduction of MNP in Europe
Year Countries
1997
1999 UK, Netherlands,
2000 Spain, Switzerland
2001 Sweden, Denmark, Norway,
2002 Belgium, Italy, Germany, Portugal
2003 Finland, Luxembourg, Ireland, France
2004 Greece, Austria, Slovenia, Cyprus, Lithuania, Poland, Hungary,

2005 Estonia, Latvia (planned) , Malta (31 July 2005)


Not clear Czech Republic, Slovakia,

Sources: Own inquiries, EEC (2004).

Table 3: Delays in Implementing MNP


Country Original Date Time lag Reason
plan started (months)
Austria Aug-2003 Oct-2004 15 Opposition of large MNOs
Czech Republic 2004 Not Not Not known
known known
France Jan-2001 Jun-2003 30 Not known
Germany 1997 Nov-02 60 Awaiting international standards
Public consultations
Time needed to design solution
Ireland Nov-02 Jul-03 9 Lack of co-operation due to
resources being deployed in the
transition to the Euro
Emphasis on full automation and
very fast porting times leading to
complex specifications.
The Netherlands Dec-98 Apr-99 4 Technical issues
UK Jul-98 Jan-99 6 Technical issues
Source: Ovum (2005), own inquiries.

The widespread implementation of MNP in Europe thus took about six years. A number of
countries postponed the implementation of MNP for various reasons. For instance, Germany
delayed the introduction of MNP due to the lack of an adequate technical solution. Also,
Austria postponed the introduction of MNP several times (see Table 3): While smaller
Austrian operators such as tele.ring and Tele2 supported MNP, the larger operators mobilkom
and T-Mobile had reservations about MNP.16 Similar delays occurred in Non-European

16 See http:/iwww.heise.de/newsticker/meldunez/45307 (18 June 2004).

12
countries such as Australia, where MNP started with a delay of no less than 50 months (see
Ovum, 2005).

5.2 The Use of MNP


It should be clear that the actual use of MNP is crucial for its impact. Since MNP lowers
switching costs, chum rates should be expected to increase, thereby intensifying competition.
Unfortunately, there are no statistics on chum rates available for most European countries. We
therefore focus on the number of portings as a proxy for the success of MNP.1 7 Table 4
illustrates that the use of MNP differs widely across countries. In the UK, in Spain and in
Italy, more than two million numbers were ported during the last few years. In countries such
as Germany and France, however, relatively few subscribers ported their numbers. In terms of
percentages of subscribers, Finland, Denmark, and the Netherlands show the highest numbers.

Table 4: Ported Numbers in European Countries


Country Period Ported Avg. Percentage of
Numbers ported all
numbers subscribers
(monthly)
UK 1/1999 - 8/2004 3036863 44659.75 5.6
Italy 5/2002 - 8/2004 2500000 89285.71 4.5
Spain 12/2002 - 8/2004 2091515 99595.95 5.5
Finland 7/2003* - 8/2004 993578 76429.07 20.8
Netherlands 4/1999 - 8/2004 925343 17459.30 6.9
Denmark 7/2001 - 8/2004 918000 35307.69 17.8
Belgium 10/2002 - 8/2004 500408 21756.86 6.2
Sweden 9/2001 - 8/2004 486936 13526.00 5.6
Germany 11/2002 - 8/2004 349000 15863.63 0.6
Ireland 7/2003* - 8/2004 142414 10954.92 4.1
Lithuania 1/2004 - 8/2004 130000 16250.00 n.a.
France 7/2003 - 8/2004 100000 7142.85 0.2
Portugal 1/2002 - 8/2004 35032 1094.75 0.4
Hungary 5/2004 - 8/2004 13875 3468.75 n.a.
Cyprus 7/2004** - 8/2004 98 65.33 <0.1
Source: EEC (2004), own inquiries. *25 July 2003, *'12 July 2004

Since many European countries have introduced MNP only recently, it is difficult to predict
future adoption processes.. Furthermore, because of different introductory dates and
considerable heterogeneity among the countries, it is no trivial task to compare the number of
portings. Many variables such as contract periods, competitive environments, and switching
costs affect the decision to use MNP services. A crucial factor, however, should be the price

17 Note, however, that there may also be an overuse of MNP if porting charges are too low as argued above.

13
for porting numbers. As charges for porting mobile numbers strongly vary across countries,
price differentials might be an adequate explanation.

5.3 Charges for Porting: Regulatory Frameworks and Empirical Evidence


The EU's Universal Service Directive requires that charges for porting mobile numbers are
cost oriented, and most member states have thus implemented regulations that should prevent
porting charges to exceed costs. Nevertheless, the extent to which these 'charges are cost
oriented is difficult to assess, since the evaluation of costs is a daunting task. If mobile
operators use IN-solutions with high set-up costs, for example, uncertainty about the future
number of portings could lead to a serious misinterpretation of costs. In particular,
underestimating the number of future portings would lead to charges above costs.
Our survey indicates that in many countries, either the donor network (as, e.g., in Sweden) or
the recipient network (as in Finland, Italy, and Norway) is allowed to charge fees for this
service. A typical situation is that the recipient network charges a fee to the customer's
account and, simultaneously, the donor network charges a fee to the recipient network's
account. In Finland, for example, operators are allowed to charge fees to the switching
customers, and maximum fees are not regulated. However, number porting is typically free in
practice, due to the competitive situation in Finland. Irish and Spanish operators, in contrast,
are not allowed to set charges that can be a disincentive to porting numbers. Table 5
summarizes the various regulatory frameworks in European countries.

Table 5: Regulation of One-time Charges for Porting Mobile Numbers


Country Permission of charging Regulation of maximum Basis
fees? fee?
Austria YES Max. E19
Belgium YES - Only recipient Max. £15 Cost oriented
network is allowed to
charge fees.
Denmark YES - Customers pay NO Cost oriented
typically the fee that
operators charge to their
competitors.
Germany YES A unique fee based on the Cost oriented
costs caused by porting
numbers.
Finland YES - Only recipient NO Cost oriented
network is allowed to
charge fees.
Greece YES
Ireland YES - Charges shall not Charges shall not be an Cost oriented
;be an disincentive for disincentive for users to
users to port their number port their number
Italy YES - Only recipient Max. £10.02
network is allowed to
charge fees.
Netherlands YES - Only recipient Max. C9
network is allowed to
charge fees. Charge shall

14
not exceed administrative
costs.
Norway YES - Only recipient NO Charge between networks
network is allowed to should cover costs of donor
charge fees. network.
Portugal YES NO
Sweden YES - Only donor NO (to customer) Cost oriented
network is allowed to YES (donor to recipient) (administrative and porting
charge fees. costs)
Switzerland YES NO
Spain YES Charges shall not be an
disincentive for users to
port their number.
UK YES "adequate fees" Marginal costs
Source: Own inquiries.

As can be seen from Table 6, there are a number of countries where networks do not charge
customers for porting numbers. For instance, in addition to Finland, MNP is typically free in
the UK and in Ireland. In Belgium, only pre-paid subscribers pay for porting their mobile
number. German operators charge between C22.50 and C29.95, whereas networks charge
between C9 and €24 in other countries.
Table 6: Charges for Porting Mobile Numbers
Country Fee
Austria Recipient network charges E4-15.
Belgium Only pre-paid but not post-paid customers are charged for porting mobile
numbers.
Denmark Operators committed to charge C9.60 per ported number to customers.
The donor operator charges the same amount to the' new operator.
Germany 02 charges C22.50 and T-Mobile, Vodafone and E-Plus charge C24.95 to
their customers. Some small service providers charge C29.95.
Finland The donor network charges about C5-10 to the recipient operator. No fees
for customers.
Ireland No fees for Customers.
Italy The donor operator charges £10.02 to the recipient operator.
No fees for Customers.
Netherlands The recipient operator is allowed to charge the customer E9. Charges
consist of administrative fees.
Sweden Only donor operators charge E4-24 fees to the recipient operator.
Spain No fees.
UK Typically no fees. Some operators charge £25.
Source: Own inquiries.
Relating the actual use of MNP (measured by the percentage of ported numbers) to the
relevant charges yields ambiguous results: In some countries with free porting (Ireland, Spain
and UK) only a moderate number of portings occurs, whereas Finland shows a high number
(see Figure 2). Moreover, German operators seem to have set nearly prohibitively high
charges. Overall, there appears to be a negative relation between porting fees and the number

15
of portings (in percent of all numbers). Higher charges tend to lead to higher consumer
switching costs and therefore to a lower use of MNP.

Figure 2: Comparison of Charges and Portings

30-

25- A Germany

20

015-
L.

10 A Italy A Netherlands A Denmark

5
Ireand Spain
Ireland UK Finland
0 A 'A A
0 5 10 15 20 25
Percentage of Ported Numbers

5.4 Speed of Porting


During the porting process, the ported number cannot handle incoming or outgoing calls.
Therefore, increasing the speed of porting is crucial for fostering the use of MNP. Porting
time depends both on the technical porting systems and on the willingness of networks to
speed up the porting process. Typically, neither the donor nor the recipient network have
strong incentives to quickly resolve technical problems in porting, as it is less costly to let the
other networks look for a solution.18 A further obstacle to rapid porting is the notice period.
Subscribers must wait until the notice period in their contract expires before the donor
network releases the number.19
Table 7 illustrates that the speed of porting is heterogeneous across countries. While in some
countries porting time is extremely short-porting takes only two and a half hours in the
US--operators from other countries may need days, weeks or even months to port a number
(see Ovum, 2005). Porting time has also varied considerably over time. While many countries
have partly used manually operated porting processes in the beginning of MNP, nowadays
most countries have installed automated porting systems. Although, porting time has been
reduced considerably, there are still obstacles to rapid porting. In the UK, for instance, porting
processes are donor led. Since the donor network has little incentive to speed up porting, this
is likely to delay porting. In Germany, subscribers are not allowed to terminate contracts and

18 In particular, the donor network has little to gain from speeding up the process.
19 In Germany, for example, subscribers have to inform the donor network about their intention to port a
mobile number about 2 weeks before the contract expires.

16
port their numbers when the contract has not yet expired. In the Netherlands, roughly 60% of
porting requests are not successful because of invalid customer information (see Ovum,
2005).
Table 7: Speed of Porting
Country Speed of porting Porting process

Austria 3 days Via recipient


Germany 6 days, 2005 Via recipient

Italy 15 days, 2003 -

Ireland 2 hours, 2005 Via recipient


Netherlands 4 days, 2005 Via recipient
3-12 weeks, 2004
2 month, 1999
UK 5-7 days, 2005 Via donor
1 month, 1999

Sources: Ovum, 2005; Syniverse Technologies, 2004 and Wind, 2003.

5.5 Tariff Transparency


As we noted above, once MNP is implemented, the prefix of a mobile number no longer
indicates the network of a subscriber, and consumers may thus be unaware of exact charges
for calls. 20 As a consequence, introducing MNP reduces tariff transparency. For this reason,
the EU's Universal Service Directive stresses the importance of transparent tariff information
and instructs NRA's to facilitate tariff transparency when implementing number portability.
There are different options to increase tariff transparency in the presence of MNP. Customers
may be informed by enquiry numbers or SMS services to learn about the network of a given
number. Acoustic signals may alert subscribers when placing off-net calls, or verbal
announcements could inform about tariffs when calling to different networks. Table 8
summarizes the methods used in European countries. In Finland, consumers can call a toll-
free number to learn about subscribers' network association. In Germany, toll-free numbers
and a toll-free SMS service is available. In Portugal, Ireland and Belgium, consumers are
informed by an acoustic signal when placing off-net calls. Consequently, users are informed
that they are placing an off-net call, but they do not learn the price of the call. Obviously, a
better system would inform subscribers about prices when placing their calls.

20 Recall that this problem arises only when the so called calling-party-pays regime applies as in most
European countries.

17
Table 8: Methods of Carrier Identification
Country Method
Austria Verbal announcement
Belgium Acoustic signal when placing off-net calls
Finland Toll-free enquiry numbers
Germany Toll-free enquiry numbers and toll-free SMS Service
Ireland Acoustic signal when placing off-net calls
Portugal Acoustic signal when placing off-net calls
Sources: Own inquiries

6 Summary and Conclusions


We have argued that the rationale of introducing MNP is simple: It is expected to eliminate or
at least reduce the costs of switching providers, making mobile telecommunications more
competitive and thus bringing about considerable gains to consumers of mobile services. Even
though there are both direct and indirect costs of introducing MNP (including reduced tariff
transparency), virtually all cost-benefit-studies have concluded that the overall effect of MNP
is positive. Interestingly, none of these studies has focused on the question of how to best
charge for porting a mobile number. We have argued that a price cap regime starting from the
current average cost of porting a number provides appropriate incentives for operators.
Our review of the experience with MNP in Europe indicates that the regulatory frameworks
for MNP and its actual use vary considerably across Europe. In countries such as Finland or
Denmark, a large number of subscribers have already ported their mobile number, whereas in
other countries, including Germany, France and Italy, relatively few subscribers have ported
their number. To some extent, this may be explained by the differences in (i) charges for
porting numbers, and (ii) the speed of porting.

References
Aoki, R., Small, J. (1999), The Economics of Number Portability: Switching Costs and Two-
Part Tariffs, Working Paper, University of Auckland, November 1999.
BBC (2003), China's Lucky Phone Number, online at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/l/hi/world//asia-
pacific/3163951 .stm
Buehler, S., Haucap, J. (2004), Mobile Number Portability, Journal of Industry, Competition
and Trade 4, 223-228.
Dewenter, R., Haucap, J. (2005), The Effects of Regulating Mobile Termination Rates for
Asymmetric Networks, forthcoming in: EuropeanJournal ofLaw andEconomics 20.
EEC (2004), European Electronic Communications Regulations and Markets 2004, 1 0 th
Report Annex 3, Commission Staff Working Paper, Brussels 2.12.2004.
European Parliament (2002), Directive 2002/22/EC of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 7 March 2002 on universal service and users' rights to electronic
communications networks and services.
Farrell, J., Gallini, N. (1988,), Second-sourcing as Commitment: Monopoly Incentives to
Attract Competition, QuarterlyJournalof Economics 103, 673-694.

18
Farrell, J., Shapiro, C. (1988,), Dynamic Competition with Switching Costs, RAND Journalof
Economics 19, 123-137.
Fudenberg, D., Tirole, J. (1984), The Fat-Cat Effect, the Puppy-Dog Ploy and the Lean and
Hungry Look, American Economic Review 74, 361-368.
Galbi, D.A. (2001), Regulating Prices for Shifting Between Service Providers, Information
Economics andPolicy 13, 181-198.
Gans, J.S., King, S.P. (2000), Mobile Network Competition, Customer Ignorance and Fixed-
to-Mobile Call Prices, Information Economics and Policy 12, 301-328.
Gans, J.S., King, S.P. (2001), Regulating Endogenous Customer Switching Costs,
Contributions to Theoretical Economics 1, No. 1, Article 1.
http ://www.bepress.com/bejte/contributions/vol 1/iss 1/artl
Gans, J.S., King, S.P., Woodbrige, G. (2001), Numbers to the People: Regulation, Ownership,
and Local Number Portability, InformationEconomics and Policy 12, 301-327.
Goldberg, V.P. (1976), Regulation and Administered Contracts, Bell Journal of Economics 7,
426-448.
Grossman, S.J., Hart, 0. (1986), The Cost and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical
and Lateral Integration, Journalof PoliticalEconomy 94, 691-719.
Haucap, J. (2003), Telephone Number Allocation: A Property Rights Approach, European
Journalof Law and Economics 15, 91-109.
Klemperer, P. (1987a), Markets with Consumer Switching Costs, Quarterly Journal of
Economics 102, 375-394.
Klemperer, P. (1987b), The Competitiveness of Markets with Switching Costs, RAND
Journalof Economics 18, 139-150.
Klemperer, P. (1988), Welfare Effects of Entry into Markets with Switching Costs, Journal of
IndustrialEconomics 37, 159-165.
Klemperer, P. (1995), Competition When Consumers Have Switching Costs: An Overview
with Applications to Industrial organization, Macroeconomics, and International Trade,
Review of Economic Studies 62, 515-539.
NERA/Smith (1998), Feasibility Study and Cost Benefit Analysis of Number Portability for
Mobile Services in Hong Kong, Final Report OFTA, NERA/Smith, London.
Oftel (1997), Economic Evaluation of Number Portability in the UK Mobile Telephoney
Market, Oftel: London.
Ovum (2000), Mobile Numbering and Number Portability in Ireland, A Report to the ODTR,
Ovum: London.
Ovum (2005), Mobile Number Portability - An International Benchmark, A Report to MTN,
Ovum Project CLM42, Ovum: London.
Schwarz-Schilling, C., Stumpf, U. (1999), Netzbetreiberportabilitdit im Mobilfunk: Auswir-
kungen auf Wettbewerb und Verbraucherinteressen, Discussion Paper No. 199, WIK:
Bad Honnef.
Sidak, J.G., Spulber, D.F. (1999), Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory Contract: The
Competitive Transformationof Network Industries in the United States. MIT Press.
Smith/Arcome/NERA (1997), Technical Options and Costs for Achieving Number
Portability, Final report for the European Commission, Brussels.

19
Syniverse Technologies (2004), A Global Perspective on Number Portability, Syniverse
Technologies Inc.
Viard, V.B. (2004), Do Switching Costs Make Markets More or Less Competitive?: The Case
of 800-Number Portability, Stanford Graduate School of Business Research Paper
Series Paper No. 1773(R 1). http://ssrn.com/abstract=371921
Viscusi, K., Vernon, J., Harrington, J.E. (2000): Economics of Regulation and Antitrust. 3rd
edition, MIT-Press, Cambridge, MA.
Wind (2003), Mobile Number Portability, WIND Telecommunications - Media Relations.
Wright, J. (2002), Access Pricing under Competition: An Application to Cellular Networks,
Journalof IndustrialEconomics 50, 289-315.

20
Bisher ersehienen:

Diskussionspapiere der Faichergruppe Volkswirtschaftslehre

"* Bifihler, Stefan, Ralf Dewenter & Justus Haucap, Mobile Number Portability in Europe, No. 41
(August 2005).
"* Meyer, Dirk, Manuskriptstaus behindern den Wissenschaftsbetrieb: Zur M6glichkeit von
Einreichungsgeb-ihren, Autorenhonoraren und Gutachterentgelten, Nr. 40 (Juni 2005).
"* Carlberg, Michael, International Monetary Policy Coordination, No. 39 (March 2005).
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Reto Schemm-Gregory, Eine Welt voller Clubs, Nr. 38 (Mdirz 2005),
erscheint in: Zeitschriftfiir Wirtschafispolitik.
"* Hackmann, Johannes, Die Bestimmung der optimalen Bev6lkernngsgr6Be als (wirtschafts-)
ethisches Problem, Nr. 37 (M~irz 2005).

"* Josten, Stefan Dietrich, Middle-Class Consensus, Social Capital and the Mechanics of Economic
Development, No. 36 (January 2005).

"* Dewenter, Ralf & Ulrich Kaiser, Anmerkungen zur bkonomischen Bewertung von Fusionen auf
dem Printmedienmarkt, Nr. 35 (Januar 2005).

"* G6bel, Markus & Tobias Thomas, Informal Institutions and the "Weaknesses" of Human Behavior,
No. 34 (January 2005).
"* Dewenter, Ralf & Justus Haucap, Estimating Demand Elasticities for Mobile Telecommunications
in Austria, No. 33 (Dezember 2004).

"* Meyer, Dirk, Die Entmachtung der Politik: Zur Frage der Oberlebensfdhigkeit demokratischer
Nationalstaaten in einer globalisierten Weltwirtschaft, Nr. 32 (Dezember 2004).
"* Josten, Stefan Dietrich & Klaus W. Zimmermann, Unanimous Constitutional Consent and the
Immigration Problem, No. 31 (Dezember 2004), erscheint in: Public Choice.
"* Bleich, Torsten, Importzoll, Beschiftigung und Leistungsbilanz: ein mikrofundierter Ansatz,
Nr. 30 (September 2004).

"* Dewenter, Ralf, Justus Haucap, Ricardo Luther & Peter R6tzel, Hedonic Prices in the German
Market for Mobile Phones, No. 29 (August 2004).

"* Carlberg, Michael, Monetary and Fiscal Policy Interactions in the Euro Area, No. 28 (Mdrz 2004).
"* Dewenter, Ralf & Justus Haucap, Die Liberalisierung der Telekommunikationsbranche in Deutsch-
land, Nr. 27 (Mdirz 2004), erschienen in: Zeitschrififlir Wirtschaftspolitik 53, 2004, 374-393.
"* Kruse, J6m, Okonomische Konsequenzen des Spitzensports im 6ffentlich-rechtlichen und im
privaten Fernsehen, Nr. 26 (Januar 2004).

"* Haucap, Justus & J6rn Kruse, Ex-Ante-Regulierung oder Ex-Post-Aufsicht fuir netzgebundene
Industrien?, Nr. 25 (November 2003), erschienen in Wirtschaft und Wettbewerb 54, 2004, 266-275.
"* Haucap, Justus & Tobias Just, Der Preis ist heiB. Aber warum? Zum Einfluss des Okonomie-
studiums auf die Einschdtzung der Fairness des Preissystems, Nr. 24 (November 2003), erschienen
in WirtschaftswissenschafilichesStudium (WiSt) 33 (9), 2004, 520-524.
"* Dewenter, Ralf & Justus Haucap, Mobile Termination with Asymmetric Networks, No. 23
(October 2003), erscheint in: EuropeanJournalof Law and Economics 20, 2005.
"* Dewenter, Ralf, Raising the Scores? Empirical Evidence on the Introduction of the Three-Point
Rule in Portugese Football, No. 22 (September 2003).
"* Haucap, Justus & Christian Wey, Unionisation Structures and Innovation Incentives, No. 21
(September 2003), erschienen in: The Economic Journal 114, 2004, C 145-C 165.
"* Quitzau, J6nm, Erfolgsfaktor Zufall im Profiful3ball: Quantifizierung mit Hilfe informations-
effizienter Wettmarkte, Nr. 20 (September 2003).
"* Reither, Franco, Grundztige der Neuen Keynesianischen Makro6konomik, Nr. 19 (August 2003),
erschienen in: JahrbuchfiirWirtschaftswissenschaften 54, 2003, 131-143.
"• Kruse, J6rm & J6rn Quitzau, FuBball-Fernsehrechte: Aspekte der Zentralvermarktung, Nr. 18
(August 2003).
"• Bfihler, Stefan & Justus Haucap, Mobile Number Portability, No. 17 (August 2003), erschienen in:
Journalof Industry, Competition and Trade 4, 2004, 223-238.
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Just, On the Relative Efficiency of Democratic Institutions,
No. 16 (July 2003).
"* Biihler, Stefan & Justus Haucap, Strategic Outsourcing Revisited, No. 15 (July 2003), erscheint in
Journalof Economic Behavior and Organization,2005.
"* Meyer, Dirk, Die Energieeinsparverordnung (EnEV) - eine ordnungspolitische Analyse, Nr. 14
(Juli 2003).
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Thomas, Patek Philippe, or the Art to Tax Luxuries, No. 13
(June 2003).
"* Dewenter, Ralf, Estimating the Valuation of Advertising, No. 12 (June 2003).
"* Otto, Alkis, Foreign Direct Investment, Production, and Welfare, No. 11 (June 2003).
* Dewenter, Ralf, The Economics of Media Markets, No. 10 (June 2003).
* Josten, Stefan Dietrich, Dynamic Fiscal Policies, Unemployment, and Economic Growth, No. 9
(June 2003).
"* Haucap, Justus & Tobias Just, Not Guilty? Another Look at the Nature and Nurture of Economics
Students, No. 8 (June 2003).
"* Dewenter, Ralf, Quality Provision in Interrelated Markets, No. 7 (June 2003).
"* Brauninger, Michael, A Note on Health Insurance and Growth, No. 6 (June 2003).
"* Dewenter, Ralf, Media Markets with Habit Formation, No. 5 (June 2003).
"* Haucap, Justus, The Economics of Mobile Telephone Regulation, No. 4 (June 2003).
* Josten, Stefan Dietrich & Achim Truger, Inequality, Politics, and Economic Growth. Three Critical
Questions on Politico-Economic Models of Growth and Distribution, No. 3 (June 2003).
* Dewenter, Ralf, Rational Addiction to News?, No. 2 (June 2003).
* Kruse, J6rn, Regulierung der Terminierungsentgelte der deutschen Mobilfunknetze?, Nr. 1 (Juni
2003).

Frfihere Diskussionsbeitraige zur Wirtschaftspolitik


"* Brduninger, Michael & Justus Haucap, Das Preis-Leistungs-Verhdiltnis 6konomischer Fachzeit-
schriften, Nr. 120 (2002), erschienen in: Schmollers Jahrbuch 123, 2003, S. 285-305.
"* Kruse, Jbrn, Competition in Mobile Communications and the Allocation of Scarce Resources: The
Case of UMTS, Nr. 119 (2002), erschienen in: Pierrre Buigues & Patrick Rey (Hg.), The
Economics ofAntitrust and Regulation in Telecommunications, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham 2004.
"* Haucap, Justus & J6rn Kruse, Predatory Pricing in Liberalised Telecommunications Markets,
Nr. 118 (2002), ersehienen in: Christian von Hirschhausen, Thorsten Beckers & Kay Mitusch
(Hrsg.), Trends in Infrastructure Regulation and Financing, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham 2004,
S. 43-68.
"* Kruse, J6rn, Pay-TV versus Free-TV: Ein Regulierungsproblem?, Nr. 117 (2002), erscheint in:
Mike Friedrichsen (Hg.), Kommerz - Kommunikation - Konsum. Zur Zukunfi des Fernsehens in
konvergierenden Mdrkten, 2003.
"* Kruse, J6m, Regulierung der Verbindungsnetzbetreiberauswahl im Mobilfunk, Nr. 116 (2002), als
Kurzform erschienen in: Multimedia undRecht, Januar 2003, S. 29-35.
"* Haucap, Justus & J6rn Kruse, Verdr~ingungspreise auf liberalisierten Telekommunikations-
markten, Nr. 115 (2002), erschienen in: Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 5, 2004, 337-361.
"* Haucap, Justus & Helmmar Schmidt, Kennzeichnungspflicht ftir genetisch verainderte Lebens-
mittel: Eine 6konomische Analyse, Nr. 114 (2002), erschienen in: Zeitschrifit flir Wirtschafts-
politik 53, 2002, S. 287-316.
"* Kruse, J6rn & Join Quitzau, Zentralvermarktung der Fernsehrechte an der FuBball-Bundesliga,
Nr. 113 (2002), erschienen in: Zeitschrift ffir Betriebswirtschaft, Erginzungsheft zur Sport-
6konomie, 2002, S. 63-82.
"* Kruse, J6rn & Justus Haucap, Zuviel Wettbewerb in der Telekommunikation? Anmerkungen zum
zweiten Sondergutachten der Monopolkommission, Nr. 112 (2002), erschienen in: Wirtschafis-
dienst 82, 2002, S. 92-98.
"* Brduninger, Michael & Justus Haucap, What Economists Think of Their Journals and How They
Use Them: Reputation and Relevance of Economics Journals, Nr. 111 (2002), erschienen in
Kyklos 56, 2003, S. 175-197.
"* Haucap, Justus, Telephone Number Allocation: A Property Rights Approach, Nr 110 (2001),
erschienen in: EuropeanJournalof Law and Economics 15, 2003, S. 91-109.
"* Haucap, Justus & Roland Kirstein, Government Incentives when Pollution Permits are Durable
Goods, Nr. 109 (2001), erschienen in: Public Choice 115, 2003, S. 163-183.
"* Haucap, Justus, Konsum und soziale Beziehungen, Nr. 108 (2001), erschienen in: Jahrbuchfiir
Wirtschafiswissenschaften 52, 2001, S. 243-263.
"* Brauninger, Michael & Justus Haucap, Was Okonomen lesen und schitzen: Ergebnisse einer
Umfrage, Nr. 107 (2000), erschienen in: Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 2, 2001, S.185-210.
"* Haucap, Justus, Uwe Pauly & Christian Wey, Collective Wage Setting When Wages Are Generally
Binding: An Antitrust Perspective, Nr. 106 (2000), erschienen in: InternationalReview of Law and
Economics 21, 2001, S. 287-307.
"* Haucap, Justus, Selective Price Cuts and Uniform Pricing Rules in Network Industries, Nr. 105
(2000), erschienen in: JournalofIndustry, Competition and Trade 3, 2003, 269-291.
"* Brduninger, Michael, Unemployment Insurance, Wage Differentials and Unemployment, Nr. 104
(2000) erschienen in: Finanzarchiv75, 2000, S. 485-501.
"* Kruse, J6rn, Universaldienstlast etablierter Postunternehmen, Nr. 103 (2000) erschienen in:
ZeitschrifiirBetriebswirtschaft,Erganzungsheft 3, 2002, S. 99-117.
"* Kruse, J6m, Sportveranstaltungen als Fernsehware, Nr. 102 (2000) erschienen in: SchellhaaB,
Horst-Manfred (Hg.), Sportveranstaltungen zwischen Liga- und Medien-Interessen, Hofmann:
Schomdorf 2000, S. 15-39.

Fruhere Diskussionsbeitraige aus dem Institut ffir Theoretische Volkswirtschaftslehre


"* Brauninger, Michael, Social Capital and Regional Mobility, Nr. 4/2002.
"* Schifer, Wolf, EU-Erweiterung: Anmerkungen zum Balassa-Samuelson-Effekt, Nr. 3/2002,
erschienen in: Stefan Reitz (Hg.): Theoretische und wirtschaftspolitischeAspekte der internatio-
nalen Integration, Duncker & Humblot: Berlin 2003, S. 89-98.
"* Brduninger, Michael, The Budget Deficit, Public Debt and Endogenous Growth, Nr. 2/2002.
"* R6sl, Gerhard, Die Umverteilung der Geldsch6pfungsgewinne im Eurosystem: Das Earmarking-
Verfahren seit dem 1.1.2002, Nr. 1/2002, als Kurzform erschienen in: Wirtschaftsdienst 82, 2002,
S.352-356.
"* Schniewindt, Sarah, Two-Way Competition in Local Telecommunication Networks, Nr. 2/2001.
"* Reither, Franco, Optimal Monetary Policy when Output Persists: On the Equivalence of Optimal
Control and Dynamic Programming, Nr. 1/2001.
"* Schafer, Wolf, MOEL-Wechselkursarrangements, Nr. 1/2000, erschienen in: GUnther Engel &
Peter Rifihmann (Hg.): Geldpolitik und Europdische Wdhrungsunion, G6ttingen 2000, S. 217-228.
"* Heppke, Kirsten, On the Existence of the Credit Channel in Poland, Nr. 8/1999.
"* Brduninger, Michael, Unemployment and International Lending and Borrowing in an Overlapping
Generations Model, Nr. 8/1999.
"* Henning, Andreas & Wolfgang Greiner, Organknappheit im Transplantationswesen - L6sungs-
ansditze aus 6konomischer Sicht, Nr. 7/1999.
"* Chung, Un-Chan, East Asian Economic Crisis - What is and What Ought to be Done: The Case of
Korea, Nr. 6/1999, erschienen in: Research in Asian Economic Studies 10, 2002, S. 93-121.
"* Carlberg, Michael, Europdiische Wdhrungsunion: Der neue Policy Mix, Nr. 5/1999, erschienen in
WirtschaftswissenschaftlichesStudium (WiSt) 29(1), 2000, S. 8-13.
"* Carlberg, Michael, European Monetary Union: The New Macroeconomics, Nr. 4/1999, erschienen
in: Gerhard Rfibel (Hg.), Real and Monetary Issues of International Economic Integration,
Duncker & Humblot: Berlin 2000, S. 155-175.
"* Briuninger, Michael & J.-P. Vidal, Private versus Financing of Education and Endogenous
Growth, Nr. 3/1999, erschienen in: Journalof PopulationEconomics 13, 2000, S. 387-401.
"* Reither, Franco, A Monetary Policy Strategy for the European Central Bank, Nr. 2/1999 erschienen
in: Rolf Caesar & Hans-Eckart Scharrer (Hg.), European Economic and Monetary Union: Regional
and Global Challenges,Nomos Verlag: Baden-Baden 2001, S. 213-226.
"* Brauninger, Michael, Wage Bargaining, Unemployment and Growth, Nr. 1/1999 erschienen in:
Journalof Institutionaland TheoreticalEconomics 156, 2000, S. 646-660.

Fruihere Diskussionsbeitraige zur Finanzwissenschaft


"* Josten, Stefan, Crime, Inequality, and Economic Growth. A Classical Argument for Distributional
Equality, 2002, erschienen in: InternationalTax andPublicFinance 10, 2003, S. 435-452.
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Thomas, Offentliche Giter, natfirliche Monopole und die
Grenze marktlicher Versorgung, 2002, erschienen in: WirtschaftswissenschafilichesStudium (WiSt)
32, 2003, S. 340-344.
"* Holm-Mtiller, Karin & Klaus W. Zimmermann, Einige Anmerkungen zur Internalisierungsstrategie
mit dem produktorientierten Konzept der Pigousteuer, 2002, erschienen in: Zeitschrifit ffir
Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 25, 2002, S. 415-420.
"* Josten, Stefan, Nationale Schuldenpolitik in der EWU, 2002, erschienen in: Wirtschaftsdienst 82,
2002, S. 219-225.
"* Hackmann, Johannes, Der Sonderabgabenbezug nach dem Lebenspartnerschaftsergdinzungsgesetz,
2002, erschienen in: Wirtschaftsdienst,82, 2002, S. 241-248.
"* Josten, Stefan, Das Theorem der Staatsschuldneutralitit. Eine kritisch-systematische Rekonstruk-
tion, 2001, erschienen in: JahrbuchjfirWirtschaftswissenschaften53, 2002, S. 180-209.
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W., Komplikationen und Fallstricke in der Pigou-Analyse von Externalititen,
2001, erschienen in: JahrbuchfiirWirtschaftswissenschaften 53, 2002, S. 245-267
"* Josten, Stefan, National Debt in an Endogenous Growth Model, 2001, erschienen in: Jahrbuchfiir
Wirtschaftswissenschaften53, 2002, S. 107-123.
* Hackmann, Johannes, Vom Ehegattensplitting zum Partnerschaftssplitting?, 2001, erschienen in:
Volker Arnold (Hg.), Wirtschaftsethische Perspektiven VI, Schrifien des Vereins ftir Social-
politik 228/VI, Ducker & Humblot: Berlin 2002, S. 189-222.
* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Just, Politische Glaubwfirdigkeit und der Euro: Eine ver-
fassungs6konomische Perspektive, 2000, erschienen in: Fritz S611ner & Arno Wilfert (Hg.), Die
Zukunfi des Steuer- undSozialstaates,Physica Verlag 2001, S. 373-397.
* Josten, Stefan, National Debt, Borrowing Constraints, and Human Capital Accumulation in an
Endogenous Growth Model, 2000, erschienen in: FinanzArchiv 58, 2001, S. 317-338.
* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Just, The Euro and Political Credibility in Germany, 2000,
erschienen in: Challenge 44, 2001, S. 102-120
* Josten, Stefan, Public Debt Policy in an Endogenous Growth Model of Perpetual Youth, 1999,
erschienen in FinanzArchiv 57, 2000, S. 197-215.
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W., Internalisierung als Nirwana-Kriterium der Umweltpolitik, 1999,
erschienen in: Kilian Bizer, Bodo Linscheidt & Achim Truger (Hg.), Staatshandeln im Umwelt-
schutz. Perspektiven einer institutionellen Umwelt6konomik, Duncker & Humblot: Berlin 2000.
"* Hackmann, Johannes, Die unterlassene Besteuerung der Nutzungswerte selbstgenutzten
Wohnungseigentums: Vergebene Reformpotentiale, 1999, erschienen in: R. Lideke, W. Scherf &
W. Steden (Hg.), Wirtschaftswissenschaft im Dienste der Verteilungs-, Geld- und Finanzpolitik,
Festschrift for A. Oberhauser, Berlin 2000, S. 387-412.
"* Zimmermann, Klaus W. & Tobias Just, Interest Groups, Referenda, and the Political Process: On
the Efficiency of Direct Democracy, 1999, erschienen in: Constitutional PoliticalEconomy 11,
2000, S. 147-163.
"* Josten, Stefan, Staatsverschuldung und Wirtschaftswachstum in einem Diamond-OLG-Modell mit
AK-Technologie, 1999, erschienen in: Jahrbuchfir Wirtschaftswissenschafien 51, 2000, S. 237-
254.

You might also like