Chapter 6 Solutions Solution Manual Introductory Econometrics For Finance
Chapter 6 Solutions Solution Manual Introductory Econometrics For Finance
2. ARMA models are of particular use for financial series due to their flexibility. They
are fairly simple to estimate, can often produce reasonable forecasts, and most
importantly, they require no knowledge of any structural variables that might be
required for more “traditional” econometric analysis. When the data are available at
high frequencies, we can still use ARMA models while exogenous “explanatory”
variables (e.g. macroeconomic variables, accounting ratios) may be unobservable at
any more than monthly intervals at best.
3. yt = yt-1 + ut (1)
yt = 0.5 yt-1 + ut (2)
yt = 0.8 ut-1 + ut (3)
(a) The first two models are roughly speaking AR(1) models, while the last is an
MA(1). Strictly, since the first model is a random walk, it should be called an
ARIMA(0,1,0) model, but it could still be viewed as a special case of an autoregressive
model.
(b) We know that the theoretical acf of an MA(q) process will be zero after q lags, so
the acf of the MA(1) will be zero at all lags after one. For an autoregressive process,
the acf dies away gradually. It will die away fairly quickly for case (2), with each
successive autocorrelation coefficient taking on a value equal to half that of the
previous lag. For the first case, however, the acf will never die away, and in theory
will always take on a value of one, whatever the lag.
Turning now to the pacf, the pacf for the first two models would have a large positive
spike at lag 1, and no statistically significant pacf’s at other lags. Again, the unit root
process of (1) would have a pacf the same as that of a stationary AR process. The
pacf for (3), the MA(1), will decline geometrically.
(c) Clearly the first equation (the random walk) is more likely to represent stock
prices in practice. The discounted dividend model of share prices states that the
current value of a share will be simply the discounted sum of all expected future
dividends. If we assume that investors form their expectations about dividend
payments rationally, then the current share price should embody all information that
is known about the future of dividend payments, and hence today’s price should only
1
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
differ from yesterday’s by the amount of unexpected news which influences dividend
payments.
Thus stock prices should follow a random walk. Note that we could apply a similar
rational expectations and random walk model to many other kinds of financial series.
If the stock market really followed the process described by equations (2) or (3), then
we could potentially make useful forecasts of the series using our model. In the latter
case of the MA(1), we could only make one-step ahead forecasts since the “memory”
of the model is only that length. In the case of equation (2), we could potentially
make a lot of money by forming multiple step ahead forecasts and trading on the
basis of these.
Hence after a period, it is likely that other investors would spot this potential
opportunity and hence the model would no longer be a useful description of the
data.
(d) See the book for the algebra. This part of the question is really an extension of the
others. Analysing the simplest case first, the MA(1), the “memory” of the process
will only be one period, and therefore a given shock or “innovation”, ut, will only
persist in the series (i.e. be reflected in yt) for one period. After that, the effect of a
given shock would have completely worked through.
For the case of the AR(1) given in equation (2), a given shock, ut, will persist
indefinitely and will therefore influence the properties of yt for ever, but its effect
upon yt will diminish exponentially as time goes on.
In the first case, the series yt could be written as an infinite sum of past shocks, and
therefore the effect of a given shock will persist indefinitely, and its effect will not
diminish over time.
4. (a) Box and Jenkins were the first to consider ARMA modelling in this logical
and coherent fashion. Their methodology consists of 3 steps:
Identification - determining the appropriate order of the model using
graphical procedures (e.g. plots of autocorrelation functions).
Estimation - of the parameters of the model of size given in the first stage.
This can be done using least squares or maximum likelihood, depending on
the model.
Diagnostic checking - this step is to ensure that the model actually estimated
is “adequate”. B & J suggest two methods for achieving this:
- Overfitting, which involves deliberately fitting a model larger than that
suggested in step 1 and testing the hypothesis that all the additional
coefficients can jointly be set to zero.
- Residual diagnostics. If the model estimated is a good description of the
data, there should be no further linear dependence in the residuals of the
estimated model. Therefore, we could calculate the residuals from the
estimated model, and use the Ljung-Box test on them, or calculate their acf. If
2
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
If the model appears to be adequate, then it can be used for policy analysis
and for constructing forecasts. If it is not adequate, then we must go back to
stage 1 and start again!
(b) The main problem with the B & J methodology is the inexactness of the
identification stage. Autocorrelation functions and partial autocorrelations for
actual data are very difficult to interpret accurately, rendering the whole
procedure often little more than educated guesswork. A further problem
concerns the diagnostic checking stage, which will only indicate when the
proposed model is “too small” and would not inform on when the model
proposed is “too large”.
We can calculate the value of Akaike’s (AIC) and Schwarz’s (SBIC) Bayesian
information criteria using the following respective formulae
AIC = ln ( 2 ) + 2k/T
SBIC = ln ( 2 ) + k ln(T)/T
The information criteria trade off an increase in the number of parameters
and therefore an increase in the penalty term against a fall in the RSS,
implying a closer fit of the model to the data.
5. The best way to check for stationarity is to express the model as a lag polynomial
in yt.
y t 0.803 y t 1 0.682 y t 2 ut
Rewrite this as
y t (1 0.803 L 0.682 L2 ) ut
We want to find the roots of the lag polynomial (1 0.803 L 0.682 L2 ) 0 and
determine whether they are greater than one in absolute value. It is easier (in my
opinion) to rewrite this formula (by multiplying through by -1/0.682, using z for the
characteristic equation and rearranging) as
z2 + 1.177 z - 1.466 = 0
Using the standard formula for obtaining the roots of a quadratic equation,
1177
. 1177
. 2
4 * 1 * 1.466
z = 0.758 or 1.934
2
Since ALL the roots must be greater than one for the model to be stationary, we
conclude that the estimated model is not stationary in this case.
3
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
6. Using the formulae above, we end up with the following values for each criterion
and for each model order (with an asterisk denoting the smallest value of the
information criterion in each case).
The result is pretty clear: both SBIC and AIC say that the appropriate model is an
ARMA(3,2).
7. We could still perform the Ljung-Box test on the residuals of the estimated models
to see if there was any linear dependence left unaccounted for by our postulated
models.
Another test of the models’ adequacy that we could use is to leave out some of the
observations at the identification and estimation stage, and attempt to construct out
of sample forecasts for these. For example, if we have 2000 observations, we may
use only 1800 of them to identify and estimate the models, and leave the remaining
200 for construction of forecasts. We would then prefer the model that gave the
most accurate forecasts.
8. This is not true in general. Yes, we do want to form a model which “fits” the data
as well as possible. But in most financial series, there is a substantial amount of
“noise”. This can be interpreted as a number of random events that are unlikely to be
repeated in any forecastable way. We want to fit a model to the data which will be
able to “generalise”. In other words, we want a model which fits to features of the
data which will be replicated in future; we do not want to fit to sample-specific noise.
This is why we need the concept of “parsimony” - fitting the smallest possible model
to the data. Otherwise we may get a great fit to the data in sample, but any use of
the model for forecasts could yield terrible results.
Another important point is that the larger the number of estimated parameters (i.e.
the more variables we have), then the smaller will be the number of degrees of
freedom, and this will imply that coefficient standard errors will be larger than they
would otherwise have been. This could lead to a loss of power in hypothesis tests,
and variables that would otherwise have been significant are now insignificant.
4
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
This clearly looks like the data are consistent with a first order moving
average process since all but the first acfs are not significant (the significant
lag 4 acf is a typical wrinkle that one might expect with real data and should
probably be ignored), and the pacf has a slowly declining structure.
In this case, T=100, and m=3. The null hypothesis is H0: 1 = 0 and 2 = 0 and
3 = 0. The test statistic is calculated as
0.420 2 0.104 2 0.032 2
Q* 100 102 19.41.
100 1 100 2 100 3
The 5% and 1% critical values for a 2 distribution with 3 degrees of freedom
are 7.81 and 11.3 respectively. Clearly, then, we would reject the null
hypothesis that the first three autocorrelation coefficients are jointly not
significantly different from zero.
5
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
f t 1,3 a 0 a1 f t 1,2
So ft-1,1 = b1u t 1
But
E ( yt 1 yt 1 , yt 2 ,...) = E (u t 1 b1u t )
= 0
Suppose that we know t-1, t-2,... and we are trying to forecast yt.
Our forecast for t is given by
E ( yt yt 1 , yt 2 ,... ) = f t 1,1 0.036 0.69 y t 1 0.42u t 1 u t
= 0.036 +0.693.4+0.42(-1.3)
= 1.836
ft-1,2 =
E ( y t 1 y t 1 , y t 2 ,...) 0.036 0.69 y t 0.42u t u t 1
But we do not know yt or ut at time t-1.
(b) Given the forecasts and the actual value, it is very easy to calculate the
MSE by plugging the numbers in to the relevant formula, which in this case is
1 N
MSE ( x t 1 n f t 1, n ) 2
N n 1
if we are making N forecasts which are numbered 1,2,3.
Then the MSE is given by
MSE
1
3
(1.836 0.032) 2 (1.302 0.961) 2 (0.935 0.203) 2
1
(3.489 0.116 0.536) 1.380
3
6
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
Notice also that 84% of the total MSE is coming from the error in the first
forecast. Thus error measures can be driven by one or two times when the
model fits very badly. For example, if the forecast period includes a stock
market crash, this can lead the mean squared error to be 100 times bigger
than it would have been if the crash observations were not included. This
point needs to be considered whenever forecasting models are evaluated. An
idea of whether this is a problem in a given situation can be gained by plotting
the forecast errors over time.
(c) This question is much simpler to answer than it looks! In fact, the inclusion
of the smoothing coefficient is a “red herring” - i.e. a piece of misleading and
useless information. The correct approach is to say that if we believe that the
exponential smoothing model is appropriate, then all useful information will
have already been used in the calculation of the current smoothed value
(which will of course have used the smoothing coefficient in its calculation).
Thus the three forecasts are all 0.0305.
(d) The solution is to work out the mean squared error for the exponential
smoothing model. The calculation is
MSE
1
3
(0.0305 0.032) 2 (0.0305 0.961) 2 (0.0305 0.203) 2
1
0.0039 0.8658 0.0298 0.2998
3
Therefore, we conclude that since the mean squared error is smaller for the
exponential smoothing model than the Box Jenkins model, the former
produces the more accurate forecasts. We should, however, bear in mind that
the question of accuracy was determined using only 3 forecasts, which would
be insufficient in a real application.
11. (a) The shapes of the acf and pacf are perhaps best summarised in a table:
Process acf pacf
White noise No significant coefficients No significant coefficients
AR(2) Geometrically declining or damped First 2 pacf coefficients significant,
sinusoid acf all others insignificant
MA(1) First acf coefficient significant, all Geometrically declining or damped
others insignificant sinusoid pacf
ARMA(2,1) Geometrically declining or damped Geometrically declining or damped
sinusoid acf sinusoid pacf
A couple of further points are worth noting. First, it is not possible to tell what the
signs of the coefficients for the acf or pacf would be for the last three processes,
since that would depend on the signs of the coefficients of the processes. Second, for
mixed processes, the AR part dominates from the point of view of acf calculation,
while the MA part dominates for pacf calculation.
7
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
(b) The important point here is to focus on the MA part of the model and to
ignore the AR dynamics. The characteristic equation would be
(1+0.42z) = 0
The root of this equation is -1/0.42 = -2.38, which lies outside the unit circle,
and therefore the MA part of the model is invertible.
(c) Since no values for the series y or the lagged residuals are given, the
answers should be stated in terms of y and of u. Assuming that information is
available up to and including time t, the 1-step ahead forecast would be for
time t+1, the 2-step ahead for time t+2 and so on. A useful first step would be
to write the model out for y at times t+1, t+2, t+3, t+4:
y t 1 0.036 0.69 y t 0.42u t u t 1
y t 2 0.036 0.69 y t 1 0.42u t 1 u t 2
y t 3 0.036 0.69 y t 2 0.42u t 2 u t 3
y t 4 0.036 0.69 y t 3 0.42u t 3 u t 4
The 1-step ahead forecast would simply be the conditional expectation of y
for time t+1 made at time t. Denoting the 1-step ahead forecast made at time
t as ft,1, the 2-step ahead forecast made at time t as ft,2 and so on:
E ( y t 1 y t , y t 1 ,...) f t ,1 E t [ y t 1 ] E t [0.036 0.69 y t 0.42u t u t 1 ] 0.036 0.69 y t 0.42
since Et[ut+1]=0. The 2-step ahead forecast would be given by
E ( yt 2 yt , yt 1 ,...) f t , 2 Et [ yt 2 ] Et [0.036 0.69 yt 1 0.42ut 1 ut 2 ] 0.036 0.69 f t ,1
since Et[ut+1]=0 and Et[ut+2]=0. Thus, beyond 1-step ahead, the MA(1) part of
the model disappears from the forecast and only the autoregressive part
remains. Although we do not know yt+1, its expected value is the 1-step ahead
forecast that was made at the first stage, ft,1.
The 3-step ahead forecast would be given by
E ( yt 3 yt , yt 1 ,...) f t , 3 Et [ yt 3 ] Et [0.036 0.69 yt 2 0.42ut 2 ut 3 ] 0.036 0.69 f t ,2
(e) Moving average and ARMA models cannot be estimated using OLS – they
are usually estimated by maximum likelihood. Autoregressive models can be
estimated using OLS or maximum likelihood. Pure autoregressive models
contain only lagged values of observed quantities on the RHS, and therefore,
the lags of the dependent variable can be used just like any other regressors.
However, in the context of MA and mixed models, the lagged values of the
error term that occur on the RHS are not known a priori. Hence, these
8
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
quantities are replaced by the residuals, which are not available until after the
model has been estimated. But equally, these residuals are required in order
to be able to estimate the model parameters. Maximum likelihood essentially
works around this by calculating the values of the coefficients and the
residuals at the same time. Maximum likelihood involves selecting the most
likely values of the parameters given the actual data sample, and given an
assumed statistical distribution for the errors. This technique will be discussed
in greater detail in the section on volatility modelling in Chapter 9.
12. (a) Some of the stylised differences between the typical characteristics of
macroeconomic and financial data were presented in Chapter 1. In particular,
one important difference is the frequency with which financial asset return
time series and other quantities in finance can be recorded. This is of
particular relevance for the models discussed in Chapter 6, since it is usually a
requirement that all of the time-series data series used in estimating a given
model must be of the same frequency. Thus, if, for example, we wanted to
build a model for forecasting hourly changes in exchange rates, it would be
difficult to set up a structural model containing macroeconomic explanatory
variables since the macroeconomic variables are likely to be measured on a
quarterly or at best monthly basis. This gives a motivation for using pure time-
series approaches (e.g. ARMA models), rather than structural formulations
with separate explanatory variables.
9
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
(c) Setting aside the lag 5 autocorrelation coefficient, the pattern in the table
is for the autocorrelation coefficient to only be significant at lag 1 and then to
fall rapidly to values close to zero, while the partial autocorrelation
coefficients appear to fall much more slowly as the lag length increases. These
characteristics would lead us to think that an appropriate model for this series
is an MA(1). Of course, the autocorrelation coefficient at lag 5 is an anomaly
that does not fit in with the pattern of the rest of the coefficients. But such a
result would be typical of a real data series (as opposed to a simulated data
series that would have a much cleaner structure). This serves to illustrate that
when econometrics is used for the analysis of real data, the data generating
process was almost certainly not any of the models in the ARMA family. So all
we are trying to do is to find a model that best describes the features of the
data to hand. As one econometrician put it, all models are wrong, but some
are useful!
(d) Forecasts from this ARMA model would be produced in the usual way.
Using the same notation as above, and letting fz,1 denote the forecast for time
z+1 made for x at time z, etc:
Model A: MA(1)
f z ,1 0.38 0.10u t 1
f z , 2 0.38 0.10 0.02 0.378
f z , 2 f z , 3 0.38
Note that the MA(1) model only has a memory of one period, so all forecasts
further than one step ahead will be equal to the intercept.
Model B: AR(2)
xˆ t 0.63 0.17 xt 1 0.09 xt 2
f z ,1 0.63 0.17 0.31 0.09 0.02 0.681
f z , 2 0.63 0.17 0.681 0.09 0.31 0.718
f z ,3 0.63 0.17 0.718 0.09 0.681 0.690
f z , 4 0.63 0.17 0.690 0.09 0.716 0.683
(e) The methods are overfitting and residual diagnostics. Overfitting involves
selecting a deliberately larger model than the proposed one, and examining
the statistical significances of the additional parameters. If the additional
parameters are statistically insignificant, then the originally postulated model
is deemed acceptable. The larger model would usually involve the addition of
10
Introductory Econometrics for Finance by Chris Brooks
one extra MA term and one extra AR term. Thus it would be sensible to try an
ARMA(1,2) in the context of Model A, and an ARMA(3,1) in the context of
Model B. Residual diagnostics would involve examining the acf and pacf of the
residuals from the estimated model. If the residuals showed any “action”,
that is, if any of the acf or pacf coefficients showed statistical significance, this
would suggest that the original model was inadequate. “Residual diagnostics”
in the Box-Jenkins sense of the term involved only examining the acf and pacf,
rather than the array of diagnostics considered in Chapter 5.
It is worth noting that these two model evaluation procedures would only
indicate a model that was too small. If the model were too large, i.e. it had
superfluous terms, these procedures would deem the model adequate.
(f) There are obviously several forecast accuracy measures that could be
employed, including MSE, MAE, and the percentage of correct sign
predictions. Assuming that MSE is used, the MSE for each model is
MSE ( Model A)
1
4
(0.378 0.62) 2 (0.38 0.19) 2 (0.38 0.32) 2 (0.38 0.72) 2 0.17
MSE( Model B )
1
4
(0.681 0.62) 2 (0.718 0.19) 2 (0.690 0.32) 2 (0.683 0.72) 2 0
Therefore, since the mean squared error for Model A is smaller, it would be
concluded that the moving average model is the more accurate of the two in
this case.
11