Homogeneous and Homothetic Function PDF
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function PDF
DC-1
Semester-II
Paper-IV: Mathematical methods for Economics-II
Lesson: Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Lesson Developer: Sarabjeet Kaur
College/Department: P.G.D.A.V College, University of Delhi
1
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Contents
1. Learning Outcomes
2. Tools of Comparative Static Analysis
2.1 Chain Rule
3. Exercise
4. References
1. Learning Outcomes
2
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
In economic analysis, the theory represents certain association between the independent variables
and the dependent variables. It is harder to solve clearly by transmuting the equations to ones
that reveal the dependent/endogenous variables as functions of the independent/exogenous
variable of the given data. When there is change in exogenous variable then endogenous variable
also change, to determine this change; the method of implicit differentiation is applied. This
technique of finding rates of change of endogenous variables, as exogenous variables change, is
known in economic as comparative statistics.
2.1Chain Rule:
One of the most important techniques of differentiation is chain rule. The chain rule is a rule of
differentiating compositions of functions. Composition of function signifies the function of
another variable. These are functions of one or several variables in which the variables
themselves functions of the another basic variables.
If a function consists of two variables and both are function of common variable ‘t’, e.g.
= + .
=2t; =12t2
3
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
=3 and =5
= +
=6t + 60t2
If x and y are both multivariable functions; i.e. x = x(u,v) and y=y(u,v); have first order partial
derivatives at the point (u,v) and suppose z = f (x, y) is differential at point (x(u,v); y(u,v)) then
f(x(u,v); y (u,v)) has first order partial derivatives at (u,v) given by:
= +
and
= +
Example:
;
Let z= where x(u,v) =
= 2xy and = x2
= +
.
= (2xy) ( ) + x2.0
4
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
= . 2xy. .
=
. xy. .
= (uv)1/2. . ..
= eu.
= . + .
=(2xy ). . + x2 .
( )
= (xy. - )
= ( – )
= ( –
= (0)
=0
The chain rule can also be extended to a number of variables, which is a function of other
variables:
X1= x1 (t1……..tm)
X2= x2(t1……….tm)
5
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
= . + . +…….+ .
For a function z=f(x,y), the partial derivative with respect to x gives the rate of change of f in the
x0 direction and the partial derivative with respect to y gives the rate of change of f in the y0
direction. How do we compute the rate of change of f in an arbitrary direction? The rate of
change of a function of several variables in the direction u is called the directional derivative in
the direction u. Here u is assumed to be a unit vector.
If z=f (x,y), the partial derivatives f'1 (x,y) and f'2 (x,y) Choose a particular point (xo,yo) in the
domain. Any nonzero vector (h,k) is then a direction in which we can move away from (xo, yo)
in a straight line to points of the form.
Given the point (xo, yo) and the direction (h, k) ≠ (o,o), define the directional function g by
By using the chain rule, the derivative of this directional function can be calculated as
If t=0 then
For the case when the vector (h,k) has length 1, the derivative of f in the direction (h,k) is called
the directional derivative of f in the direction (h,k) at (xo,yo). It is denoted by Dh,k f(x0,y0). Hence,
the directional derivative of f(x,y) at (x0,y0) in the direction of unit vector (h,k) (where h2+k2=1)
is
6
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Any move from (x0,y0) to (h,k) changes the value of f by approximately Dh,k f(x0,y0). The vector
(f1(x0,y0), f2(x0,y0)) is called as gradient of the function f (x,y) at (x 0,y0). Therefore, it is the
scalar product of gradient with vector (h,k).
Now, differentiating (2) with respect to t, we get second derivative of the directional function g.
i.e,
where x= x0 +th, and y= y0 +tk. Again, applying the chain rule, the above equation becomes:
again x= x+ t.h and y= y+t.k. Assuming t=0 and (h,k) has length 1, then above equation
becomes:
Compute the first and second directional derivatives of f at (xo yo) in the directions:
Solution: We have
7
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
and
If (h,k) = ( , - ); then
and
f(xo.yo)= = -1
Suppose that x and y are related to each other with the relation; F(x,y)=0 where y = f(x) is a
differentiable function of x. Find by using chain rule method.
Consider a function:
then
Example:
8
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
y3 + y2-5y-x2+4=0.
Solution:
Define a function
F(x,y)=y3+y2-5y-x2+4.
Fx (x,y)= =-2x.
Fy(x,y)=(∂Fy(x,y))/∂y=3y2+2y-5
Let’s assume that there is an implicit function consists of three variables; i.e, F (x,y,v) = 0.
In order to get derivative hold one of the variable constant. Suppose v is constant then dv=0 and
0= ∂z/∂x.dx+ .dy., rearrange the equation we get as in two
variable case, because one variable was constant, so this difference is partial. So notations have
to change. Therefore,
∂y/∂x=(-∂z/∂x)/(∂z/∂y)
∂y/∂x=(-fx)/fy.
Example:
Fx= ∂v/∂x=1, Fz = 2z -3
Fy= -2.
= = .
Where Y= 10,000, P2= 200 and P1= 100. Find the income elasticity of demand and cross
elasticity of demand for first commodity.
Solution:
ey= /
= ( )
= 0.1 ……..(1)
10
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
ec = ( )
= 1.5
2.3.b Implicit functional theorem (for 2 variables): Let F(x,y)=0 be an implicit function with
continuous first derivatives, which is satisfied at some point, (x0, y0) and is defined in some
neighborhood of this point. If Fy≠0 at this point, then there is a function y=f(x) defined in some
neighborhood of x=xo corresponding to the relationship defined by F(x,y)=0 such that:
Statement: Let F (x1, x2……xn,y)=0 be an implicit function with continuous first derivatives
which is satisfied at some point, (x1, x2…….xn, y) is defined at some neighborhood of this point.
If Fy≠0 at this point, then there is a function y=f(x1, x2…..xn) defined in some neighborhood of
x=xo=(x1, x2…..xn) such that
(i) yo=f(xo)
(ii) fi(xo)=-Fxi/Fy.
Example: The Cobb-Douglas production function: 50 K0.3 L0.7 = Q, where Q is a given level of
output, K is the amount of capital and L is the amount of labor. The isoquant associated with the
function reflects the levels of capital and labor that yield a constant level of output.
a. Use the Implicit Function Theorem to derive an equation for the slope of an isoquant
associated with the production function.
b. When K = 6 and L = 2, what is the slope of a line tangent to this isoquant? What is the
slope of the line when K = 3 and L = 14?
c. Find the MRTS for both examples in part (b).
11
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
a. Slope of Isoquant = =- =-
=-
Slope of Isoquant= - = . = -7
Slope = - = .
c.i) MRTS= =7
ii) MRTS=
Note: The marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS) is the rate at which the two production
inputs can be substituted if output is held constant. It is the absolute value of the slope of the
isoquant.
σk,L = = =
12
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Example: The implicit function U AB shows what combinations of apples (A) and bananas
(B) provide the levels of utility U. Find the derivative of the implicit function to determine the
MRS of apples for bananas (MRSAB).
Solution: Given the utility function:
U=
Slope of IC = =-
MRS A,B=
Note: The absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution
(MRS), which measures the rate at which one good can be substituted for another, while
maintaining the same level of utility.
13
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
If utility function is
u(x; y) = xy,
is a homogenous function of degree 2. Then the monotonic transformations
g1(z) = z + 1;
g2(z) = z2 + z;
g3(z) = log z
generate the following homothetic (but not homogenous) functions
v1(x; y) = xy + 1;
v2(x; y) = x2y2 + xy;
v3(x; y) = log x + log y:
Example
For the function f (x1, x2) = Ax1ax2b, test the homogeneity of function.
Solution:
= Ata+bx1ax2b
14
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Example: Given the function, check whether function is homogeneous functions or not
= α10 x5 y2 z3
Now differentiate both sides of this equation with respect to xi, to get
t f 'i(tx1, ..., txn) = tk f 'i(x1, ..., xn),
If the function z = f(x,y) is a homogeneous of degree ‘n’ then according to Euler’s theorem:
x. + y. = n.f(x,y)
15
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Example:
Use Euler’s theorem to determine the degree of homogeneity of the following functions
=fx(x,y)= 4x+y
=fy(x,y)= x-2y
x +y = nf(x,y)
= x(4x+y)+y(x-2y)
=4x2+xy+xy-2y2
=4x2+2xy-2y2
=2(2x2+xy-y2 )
Example:
Use Euler’s theorem to determine the degree of homogeneity of the following function
f(L,K)=ALαKβ
= αALα-1 β
= βALα β-1
By Euler’s theorem
L +K = nf(L,K)
16
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
=(α+β) (ALαK β)
=(α+β) f(L,K)
Example: Suppose that f (x1, ..., xn) is homogeneous of degree r. Show that each of the
following functions h(x1, ..., xn) is homogeneous, and find the degree of homogeneity.
Solution:
a. Is the function (x3 − y3)/(x1/2 + y1/2) homogeneous of any degree? (If so, which
degree?)
b. Is the function x3y3 + x1/2 homogeneous of any degree? (If so, which degree?)
c. A consumer's (differentiable) demand function for some good is f (p1, ..., pn, w),
where pi is the price of the ith good, and w is the consumer's wealth. This function
f is homogeneous of degree 0. Is there any necessary relationship between
∑i=1n(pi f i'(p1, ..., pn, w)) and w f n+1'(p1, ..., pn, w)?
17
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Solution: a. Given the function (x3 − y3)/(x1/2 + y1/2)= ((tx)3 − (ty)3)/((tx)1/2 + (ty)1/2)
c .Given the function, f (p1, ..., pn, w); which is homogeneous of degree 0
∑i=1npi f i'(p1, ..., pn, w) + w f 'n+1(p1, ..., pn, w) = 0. (Note that f has n + 1 arguments.)
Q=AKαLβ
= α A Kα-1Lβ
= β A KαLβ-1
18
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
= (α+β) (A KαLβ)
= (α+β). Q
a. If (+) = 1, then K +L = Q . If the value of K and L doubled, i.e., 2K and 2L, then
output also doubles; then there is a constant return to scale in the production.
the right hand side adds up to 2(+)Q. If (+) > 1, the output more than doubles, i.e,
there are increasing returns to scale. If (+) < 1, the output is less than double, or the
decreasing returns to scale in production.
Note: A proportional increase in all the values of inputs in a production function increases the
scale of production. If there are constant returns to scale, then output will increase equi-
proportionally to the increase in all inputs. If there are increasing returns to scale, an increase in
all inputs will lead to a more than proportionate increase in output. If there are decreasing
returns to scale, then output will increase less than proportionately with an increase in all inputs.
Example: Consider the following Cobb-Douglas production function, which is homogeneous of
degree 1 in capital and labor Q 50K 0.4 L0.6 . The value of the output (Q) includes the payment
made to the labor, i.e., the wages paid to the labor (wL), which is equal to .L in a competitive
labor market. Also, the value of the output includes the payment made to the capital suppliers
(rK), which is equal to .K. Show that the sum of the total factor payments (wL + rK) equals
the value of the output, i.e., wL + rK = Q, such that wL + rK = Q + (1-) Q, where = 0.6.
Solution: Given the production function
Q= 50 K0.4 L0.6
19
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Therefore,
Hence proved.
Example: Given the following production function; find out the elasticity of substitution:
Solution: partial differentiation the function z = A(aK−ρ + bL−ρ)−m/ρ with respect to L and K
respectively,
therefore,
MRTSK,L = RK,L=
= (RK,L)1/( ρ+1)
Hence,
σK,L= ElRk,L( = .
Example: Without solving the equation, show that 2x2+5xy+y2=19 defines an implicit function
20
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
y(x) for which y(2)=1, and find dy/dx when x=2. Express the answer in geometrical terms.
Solution: Putting x=2 and y=1 in given function 2x2+5xy+y2=19, we see that equation satisfied,
=- = - 13/12
When (x,y)=(2,1). In geometrical terms, this means that the slope of the contour 2x 2+5xy+y2=c
which passes through point (2,1) is -13/12 at that point.
21
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
= a – a(1)
=0
Example: The twice-differentiable function f (x, y) is homogeneous of degree k, and its second
derivatives are continuous. Show that
x2 f "11(x, y) + 2xy f "12(x, y) + y2 f "22(x, y) = k(k − 1) f (x, y) for all (x, y).
Solution: We know that f is homogeneous of degree k which means that f '1 and f '2 are
homogeneous of degree k − 1. Thus by Euler's theorem applied to f '1 and to f '2 we have,
x2 f "11(x, y) + 2xy f "12(x, y) + y2 f "22(x, y) = (k − 1)[x f '1(x, y) + y f '2(x, y)] for all (x, y)
Finally, the term in brackets on the right-hand side of this equation is equal to k f (x,y) by
Euler's theorem, yielding the required result.
Example: A firm uses two inputs to produce a single output. Its production function f is
homogeneous of degree 1. An implication of the homogeneity of f , which you are not asked to
prove, is that the partial derivatives f 'x and f 'y with respect to the two inputs are homogeneous
22
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
of degree zero. Use Euler's theorem to find an expression for the cross partial derivative
f "xy(x, y) in terms of x, y, and f "xx(x, y).
x f "xx(x, y) + y f "xy(x, y) = 0,
3. Exercise:
1. Given Q=440-8P +0.05 Y, where P=15 and Y=12,000. Find the income and price
elasticity of demand.
2. Given Q1= 110-P1+0.75 P2-0.25 P3+0.0075 Y. At P1=10, P2=20, P3=40, and Y=10,000,
Q1=170. Find the different cross elasticities of demand.
f(x,y,w)= 3x2y -
a ) z = 10x + 5y
b) z = x2 + 5xy + 12 y2
c) z= x0.3 + y0.4
d) z = 10 x5 + 10x2y3 +y5
5. Assume the demand for sugar is a function of income (Y), the price of sugar (Ps) and the
price of saccharine (Pc), a sugar substitute, as follows:
Qd f (Y , Pc , Ps ) 0.05Y 10 Pc 5Ps2 .
23
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
Qd Pc
d. Find the cross-price elasticity of demand when Y = 10,000, Ps = 5 and Pc = 7.
Pc Qd
6. Consider the production function y = f(x1,x2) = x1 x2 defined over the domain x1 > 0 and
x2 > 0. Also, consider the functions g(y) = ln(y) and j(y) = y2.
Solution:
24
Homogeneous and Homothetic Function
b. homogenous of degree 2
c. not homogenous
5. Answers:
Qd Qd Qd
a. 0.05; 10; 10 Ps
Y Pc Ps
b. 1.12
c. - 0.56
d. 0.16
5. Answers:
a. homogeneous of degree 2
b. homothetic; not homogeneous in x1 and x2
c. homothetic; homogeneous of degree 4 in x1 and x2
6. Answers:
d. homogeneous of degree 2
e. homothetic; not homogeneous in x1 and x2
f. homothetic; homogeneous of degree 4 in x1 and x2
7. Answers:
a. homogeneous of degree 7/12 (i.e., k=1/12)
and take the partial derivative of the production function with respect to x2 and show that
f2(x1,x2) is homogeneous of degree -5/12.
c. Apply Euler's Theorem.
4. References:
1. K. Sydaster and P. Hammond, Mathematics for Economic Analysis, Person Educational
Asia, Delhi, 2002.
2. M. Hoy et.al, Mathematics for Economics, PHI Learning Private Limited, Delhi, Second
Edition, 2001.
3. J.E. Draper and J.S. Klingman, Mathematical Analysis Bussiness and Economic
Applications, Harper & Row Publishers, New York, 1967.
4. Rosser, Mike, Basic Mathematics for Economists Second Edition, London, 2003.
25