Beaujard JWH Indianoc
Beaujard JWH Indianoc
net/publication/236775399
" The Indian Ocean in Eurasian and African World-Systems Before the Sixteenth
Century "
CITATIONS READS
80 1,227
1 author:
Philippe Beaujard
French National Centre for Scientific Research
27 PUBLICATIONS 225 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Philippe Beaujard on 01 April 2015.
philippe beaujard
Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, Centre d’Études Africaines,
École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris, France
* I am grateful to Dr. S. Fee for having translated this article from the French. I thank
Drs. C. Coquery-Vidrovitch, E. Alpers, and M. Garden for their comments on this article.
1
On the Mediterranean, cf. F. Braudel, vol. 1, La Méditerranée et le Monde Méditer-
ranéen à l’Époque de Philippe II, 9th ed. (Paris: A. Colin, 1990), p. 253; and Civilisation
Matérielle, Economie et Capitalisme, XVe–XVIIIe Siècle, vol. 3, Le Temps du Monde (Paris: A.
Colin, 1979), p. 12. K. N. Chaudhuri, in Trade and Civilization in the Indian Ocean: An Eco-
nomic History from the Rise of Islam to 1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985),
explicitly modeled his work on the Indian Ocean after Braudel’s La Méditerranée. On the
unity of the Indian Ocean, cf. M. N. Pearson, The Indian Ocean (London: Routledge, 2003),
p. 5.
411
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 412
2
E. Morin, Science avec Conscience (Paris: Fayard, 1990), pp. 244–245, 252. A system
is more than the sum of its parts, but is also less than the sum of its parts (ibid., pp. 241–243;
also I. Wallerstein, The Modern World-System, vol. 1, Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins
of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century [San Diego: Academic Press, 1974],
p. 8). An explanation is to be found out not only at the level of the whole but through the
interactions between and within the parts, which constitute the whole. Morin undertook
to transpose the theories of the chemist Prigogine in the anthropological field. Cf. I. Prigo-
gine and I. Stengers, Order Out of Chaos: Man’s New Dialogue with Nature (London: Heine-
mann, 1984), and The End of Certainty: Time, Chaos and the New Laws of Nature (New York:
Free Press, 1997).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 413
both complex and dynamic. The system generates both order and dis-
order, unity and diversity. Taking into account these general charac-
teristics of all systems and their implications can aid the interpretation
of the available historical data for the Eurasian and African zone. The
systemic approach provides a new “logic,” and leads to a new under-
standing of world history.
Wallerstein forged the concept of world-system in relation to the
modern era but, in fact, the creation of an Eurasian and African world-
system can be traced much further back in time. He enumerated twelve
characteristics of the “modern world-system,” which include ever-
increasing capital accumulation, a division of labor, growing imbal-
ances of power between cores and peripheries, phases of hegemony—
within a given core—that alternate between a single power exercising
control and several rival powers vying for control, and the existence
of cycles. Frank and Gills argue that these same characteristics have
also been present in world-systems for the past several thousand years.3
According to these authors, for too long scholars have underestimated
the importance of capital accumulation, markets, and individual enter-
prise in ancient societies. Available actual data, however, show the
formation of an Eurasian and African world-system with the Chris-
tian era.
From its origins, the Eurasian and African world-system developed
and was restructured following the rhythm of economic cycles that
lasted several centuries (periods of growth followed by periods of
decline). Understanding these cycles, their nature, and possible ori-
gins provides a key to unlocking the history of the region.
Based on geographic factors and exchange networks, the Asian and
East African maritime zones can be divided into three main areas: the
China Sea, the eastern Indian Ocean, and the western Indian Ocean,
with the latter area being further divided—except during some rare
moments of unity—between the Persian Gulf and the Red Sea. Each
of these subsystems had its own “core” (China, India, western Asia,4
and Egypt) that determined the nature of trade with its peripheries. I
agree with Frank and Gills that transfers of surplus between regions
“necessarily imply” a division of labor, issues of hegemony, and the
3
A. G. Frank and B. K. Gills, eds., The World System: Five Hundred Years or Five Thou-
sand? (London: Routledge, 1993). Before Frank and Gills, cf. K. Ekholm and J. Friedman,
“‘Capital’ Imperialism and Exploitation in Ancient World-Systems,” Review 4, no. 1
(1982): 87–109.
4
As part of my efforts to avoid Eurocentrism, I employ the terms “western Asia” and
“eastern Asia,” in place of the more usual Near East (or Middle East) and Far East.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 414
5
A. G. Frank and B. K. Gills, “The Five Thousand Year World System in Theory and
Praxis,” in World System History: The Social Science of Long-Term Change, ed. R. A. Dene-
mark, J. Friedman, B. K. Gills, and G. Modelski (London: Routledge, 2000), p. 4.
6
The “surplus” represents the difference between what has been produced and what
has been consumed by the producer. On the concept of value, cf. infra.
7
It seems to me that a certain level of integration is required. For Frank and Gills,
“‘mere’ trade makes a system,” but they speak also of a “regular and significant trade” (Frank
and Gills, “Five Thousand Year World System,” p. 6).
8
Braudel, Civilisation Matérielle, vol. 3, p. 20.
9
Following Hansen, it is possible to define city-states as “self-governed cities which
consider themselves as political units” and are recognized as such by the other political
units of the region. These cities may be independent, or dependent through diverse modes
(within a hierarchical ensemble of city-states, within a federation, as a tributary of a macro-
state, and so on). M. H. Hansen, “Conclusion: The Impact of City-State Cultures on
World History,” in A Comparative Study of Thirty City-State Cultures, ed. M. H. Hansen
(Copenhagen: Det Kongelige Danske Videnskabernes Selskab, 2000), pp. 606, 608–609.
10
M. N. Pearson also underlines the key concept of “littoral society” (Indian Ocean,
pp. 37–41). J. Friedman has pointed out that “the wave of discourses on cultural hybridity
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 415
consist of the analysis of cultural elites and their discourses. [. . .] the ideology of hybridity
is primarily an elitist discourse in a world that is otherwise engaged in the opposite.
Hybridization and balkanization are two simultaneous processes of the global shift in hege-
mony” (“Concretizing the Continuity Argument,” in Denemark et al., World System His-
tory, p. 147). The concepts of “fringe culture,” networks, and hybridity get their full mean-
ing only if they are analyzed at the level of the whole through a systemic approach that goes
beyond a holistic perspective, as the latter “expresses only a partial and simplifying vision
of the whole.” Pascal had already expressed this “new paradigm brought by the idea of sys-
tem: ‘I consider as impossible either to know the parts without knowing the whole, or to
know the whole without knowing each of the parts’” (Morin, Science avec Conscience,
p. 240).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 416
religious sites that are also sites of production and trade, religious net-
works become spaces where, following the paths of pilgrims, wealth
and information circulate. Second, transfers of surplus are not the only
means for cores to achieve dominance. This they also accomplish
through ideological and political power acting via diverse strategies,
such as colonization, alliances, religious conversions, intermarriages,
and so forth.
Understanding the processes in the construction of an area unified
by exchanges and contacts, and capturing both the changes and conti-
nuity in the articulation of the network, can be achieved only through
a study of the long term, through a consideration of the very origins of
the Eurasian and African world(s)-system(s), and through a compara-
tive perspective that encompasses the entire region under considera-
tion, that is to say, whole oceans (Indian Ocean, China Sea, Mediter-
ranean) and continents. The study must be both transdisciplinary and
systemic. In essence, it requires an examination of the relationships
between economic, political, and religious data; technological inno-
vations; climatic changes; demographic trends;11 and the grasp of the
dynamics of interaction and organization between the system as a
whole and its constituent parts.
As early as the fourth millennium b.c.e., the rise of the state, espe-
cially interrelated city-states, in Mesopotamia and the expansion of
trade networks with neighboring regions may have resulted in the for-
mation of a world-system, with southern Mesopotamia acting as a
core. This system probably included at least a part of the Persian
11
Unfortunately, we do not have quantitative figures to determine the level of inte-
gration of the various parts of the world-system for the eras that concern us here. Estab-
lishing a direct measure of commercial volume is also, of course, impossible. We must
therefore rely on the indices to be found through archaeological excavations and ancient
writings. They allow us to estimate size and intensity of exchange networks and follow their
expansions and shrinkages (cf. J. Abu-Lughod, Before European Hegemony: The World Sys-
tem A. D. 1250–1350 [New York: Oxford University Press, 1989], p. 368). The number and
size of the principal cities, and their localization, provide precious indications as to the gen-
eral direction of activity (growth or decline) and the internal structure of the world-system
(A. Bosworth, “World Cities and World Economic Cycles,” in Civilizations and World Sys-
tems: Studying World-Historical Change, ed. S. K. Sanderson [Walnut Creek, Calif.: AltaMira
Press, 1995], pp. 206–227). In addition, other methods, such as palynological studies, ice
core analysis, and dendrochronology are useful because they allow for the reconstruction of
historic climatic and environmental conditions, which in turn can be compared to demo-
graphic, economic, and political trends.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 417
Gulf.12 In the third millennium, the Indian Ocean was not yet a uni-
fied space, but a world-system took shape between the urbanized soci-
eties of Mesopotamia, Elam, and Indus through maritime roads in the
Persian Gulf and land routes that ran all the way to Turkmenistan
and Bactria (ca. 2600–1800 b.c.e.).13 Frank and Gills support the idea
that a single system united Egypt, Arabia, Mesopotamia, and the rest
of western Asia from the third millennium b.c.e. “The confluence
occurred . . . about 2700–2400 b.c.” 14 The weakness of the ties
between Mesopotamia and Egypt makes this hypothesis hard to accept.
Up to the eighteenth century b.c.e., bronze was rarely used in Egypt.
In fact, Egypt and Mesopotamia during that period do not follow the
same rhythm.15 As would again later be the case, from 1000 to 600
b.c.e., the exchange networks that can be identified point to the artic-
ulation of two different “spheres of interaction” and not so much to a
supposed unique world-system (Figure 1).16
12
G. Algaze, The Uruk World System: The Dynamics of Expansion of Early Mesopotamian
Civilization (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993).
13
The network may have reached all the way to East Africa (C. Chase-Dunn and T. D.
Hall, “Comparing World-Systems to Explain Social Evolution,” in Denemark et al., World
System History, p. 106) if the copal necklace found in a tomb at Tell Asmar (near Bagh-
dad) and dated to 2500–2400 b.c.e. can be proved with certainty to come from Zanzibar
or its environs (C. Meyer, J. M. Todd, and C. W. Beck, “From Zanzibar to Zagros: A Copal
Pendant from Eshnunna,” Journal of Near Eastern Studies [1991]: 296–297). Some scholars,
such as J. Philipps (“Punt and Aksum: Egypt and the Horn of Africa,” Journal of African His-
tory 38 [1997]: 437), have expressed doubts about this origin.
14
B. K. Gills and A. G. Frank, “The Cumulation of Accumulation,” in The World Sys-
tem, p. 82.
15
Chase-Dunn and Hall’s attempt to compare the size of the empires of Mesopotamia
and Egypt shows two very different growth rates for the period 2500–3000 b.c.e. and
opposing trends from 2000 to 1500 b.c.e. (“Comparing World-Systems,” Fig. 4.9, p. 106).
This opposition in terms of political integration nevertheless does not exclude synchro-
nism on an economic level.
16
Frank and Gills (“Rejoinder and Conclusions,” in The World System) trace the begin-
nings of the Eurasian world to the third millennium b.c.e., but they do not offer “proof ” of
definite cycles (with phases of growth and decline) until after 1700 b.c.e. Wilkinson mean-
while dates the origin of his “central civilization” to 1500 b.c.e. (D. Wilkinson, “Central
Civilization,” in Sanderson, Civilizations and World Systems). A comparison of the cycles put
forward by Frank and Gills with Chandler’s data (Four Thousand Years of Urban Growth: An
Historical Census [Lewiston: The Edwin Mellen Press, 1987]) demonstrates well the diffi-
culties faced by scholars for the period before the first century c.e. Analyses of world-systems
for the Bronze Age and the beginning of the Iron Age face very difficult obstacles (Bos-
worth, “World Cities and World Economic Cycles”). I have stressed that, owing to the lim-
its of archaeology and the paucity of texts, we can ascertain only general tendencies and
sometimes chains of dependency. Ongoing debates on the chronologies of the third and
second millenniums b.c.e. clearly show that the phases of growth and retraction for cer-
tain zones put forward by authors such Frank and Gills can often be taken only as mere
hypotheses (cf., for example, “Just in Time: Proceedings of the International Colloquium on
Ancient Near Eastern Chronology [Second Millenium b.c.],” Akkadica 119–120 (2000),
and D. T. Potts, “Tepe Yahya, Tell Abraq and the Chronology of the Bampur Sequence,”
Iranica Antiqua 38 [2003]: 1–11).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 418
17
The complexity of earlier scripts matched the limited number of their uses and of
their users; simplicity and efficiency of alphabetical scripts transformed not only their social
function but also the relationship of the individual with the different spheres of power.
18
The archaeological discovery of cloves at the site of Terqa on the central Euphrates,
at a stratigraphy dated 1700–1600 b.c.e.—if it can be verified—would, however, point to
contacts between the Austronesian world and the western Indian Ocean from 2000 b.c.e.
G. L. Possehl, “Meluhha,” in The Indian Ocean in Antiquity, ed. J. Reade (London: Kegan
Paul, 1996), p. 190.
19
Evidence of these interconnections includes the introduction of barley, wheat, and
sheep into China in the third millennium b.c.e. and the appearance of horse-drawn char-
iots in China in the second millennium b.c.e. Silk, which has been found in the Sapalli
tombs of Bactria (ca. 2200 b.c.e.) probably came from China (A. A. Askarov, Sapallitepa
[Tachkent: Fan, 1973]). On China in the second millennium b.c.e., cf. L. Liu and X. Chen,
State Formation in Early China (London: Duckworth, 2003).
20
Cf. Figure 10.8 in Chase-Dunn and Hall, Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems
(Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1997), p. 219. Frank and Gills (“Five Thousand Year
World System,” p. 12) hold that a simultaneity in phases can be discerned between east-
ern and western Asia from the middle of the first millennium b.c.e. In my opinion, even if
an interconnection did indeed exist between eastern Asia, India, and western Asia from
the sixth to fifth century b.c.e., the relations do not display the regularity and intensity that
characterize a system; for this period it is difficult to demonstrate synchronous evolution in
the various regions, whereas it can be shown for somewhat later periods.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 420
21
Africa was only gradually incorporated into the spheres of interaction or the
Eurasian and African system(s): Egypt and its hinterland, the coast of the Red Sea, and the
horn of Africa from the third millennium b.c.e. in a system centered on Egypt and its hin-
terland, North Africa from the second millennium b.c.e. in a Mediterranean space, East
Africa and its hinterland around the first century c.e. (or a little earlier) in the global
world-system that takes shape in that time, sub-Saharan Africa from the seventh century
at the latest (but perhaps from as early as the first millennium b.c.e.) in the Mediterranean,
and Egypto-Nubian spheres.
22
See also I. C. Glover, “The Archaeological Evidence for Early Trade between South
and Southeast Asia,” in Reade, Indian Ocean in Antiquity, p. 368 and W. H. McNeill,
“World History and the Rise and Fall of the West,” Journal of World History 9 (1998): 129.
The inconsistencies in Phase B (250/150–100/50 b.c.e.) put forward by Frank would argue
against the existence of an Eurasian and African world-system for this time period (the
Mediterranean and China were enjoying economic expansion while Egypt, Mesopotamia,
Persia, and perhaps India—in the second century b.c.e.—were experiencing some level of
decline). But maybe an Asian unified space was taking shape at that time (cf. J. Bentley,
Old World Encounters: Cross-Cultural Contacts and Exchanges in Pre-Modern Times [Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1993], p. 29). If the regularity and intensity of exchanges must be
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 421
the modern era. The birth of this system accounts for the movements
of Europeans toward the Orient and the voyages of Austronesians
toward the western areas of the Indian Ocean and toward China. It
also explains the development of a pre-Swahili culture in East Africa
and the “Indianization” of Southeast Asia.
taken into account, it is obviously difficult to establish the threshold at which the integra-
tion of several world economies will allow them to constitute a single world-system. Fur-
thermore, the available historical data are richer from the first century c.e., and this might
introduce a bias to the analysis.
23
But see C. Edens on this point (cf. infra).
24
Cf. C. McEvedy and R. Jones, Atlas of World Population History (Harmondsworth:
Penguin Books, 1978), and Bosworth, “World Cities and World Economic Cycles.”
25
B. K. Gills and A. G. Frank, “World System Cycles, Crises, and Hegemonic Shifts,
1700 b.c.e. to 1700 c.e.,” in The World System. But from the beginning of the Christian
era, phases of growth that have been recognized are in accordance to the periods delimited
by Bentley, Old World Encounters, pp. 26–28.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 422
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 423
figure 2. Economic cycles in the Eurasian and African world-system (first through eighteenth centuries).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 424
26
The nature of the recession that occurred in the middle of the seventeenth century
is still being debated (cf. infra).
27
Various authors have underscored China’s pre-eminence in the world-system, cf.
W. H. McNeill, The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Forces and Society since A. D. 1000
(Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1982), chap. 2, and McNeill, “World History and the
Rise and Fall of the West,” pp. 219–220; A. G. Frank, ReORIENT: Global Economy in the
Asian Age (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998), and especially J. Needham, Sci-
ence and Civilisation in China, 20 vols. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1959–
1998). Some scholars have placed an emphasis on the role of central Asia and its nomadic
herders in the system’s dynamics. I would argue that central Asia— even when it attained
political ascendancy in the thirteenth century—was only dancing to the rhythm set by
other players.
28
I agree with Frank (ReORIENT)—as against G. Arrighi (“The World According
to Andre Gunder Frank,” Review 22, no. 3 [1999]: 336)—that demographic growth and
economic gains went hand in hand. Braudel (Civilisation Matérielle, vol. 1, Les Structures du
Quotidien, p. 17). argued a similar point: “if men become more numerous, there is an
increase in production and trade.” Besides the role of the demographic pressure, political
power can force farmers to increase their labor input and to transform the use of land, but
this is more likely to happen in periods of global growth of the system.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 425
map 1. The Eurasian and African world-system from the first to the third century.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 426
map 2. The Eurasian and African world-system from the seventh to the ninth century.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 427
map 3. The Eurasian and African world-system from the eleventh to the early thirteenth century.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 428
map 4. The Eurasian and African world-system in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 429
29
It is processes of growth, however, that tend to give rise to innovations. The use of
inventions takes place only when it becomes profitable to invest in technological develop-
ment. If it is true that a certain demographic density is necessary to allow for the develop-
ment of more efficient transport, I do not agree with the position of Chase-Dunn and Hall
(“Comparing World-Systems,” p. 98) that demographic pressure is generally at the root of
technological progress and is the reason for political expansion. In the case of agriculture,
the spread of plants occurred during moments of increased trade. In the seventh and eighth
centuries, the Arabs transported as far away as Spain fifteen types of vegetal species from
the Indian peninsula. In the tenth century, the Sung dynasty promoted the introduction of
rice varieties from Champa, which made possible two harvests per year. However, while
innovations in manufacturing, the realm of science, and “techniques of power” occur most
often during moments of economic growth, or at the beginning of growth, it appears that
innovations in agricultural domains also take place during phases of decline (indeed,
because they provide solutions). For the relations between demographic pressure and tech-
nological change, see E. Boserup, The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of
Agrarian Change under Population Pressure, new ed. (London: Earthscan Publications, 1993).
In certain cases, unfavorable climatic conditions can lead to innovations in agriculture,
usually through intensification. This is no doubt what happened during the phase of cool-
ing of the Younger Dryas (ca. 11,000–9800 b.c.e.), which played a role in the development
of agriculture and the domestication of plants in western and eastern Asia.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 431
30
Cf. H. P. Ray, The Archaeology of Seafaring in Ancient South Asia (Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press, 2003), p. 11; on Buddhism and Hinduism, Chaudhuri, Trade and
Civilization in the Indian Ocean; and on Islam, A. Wink, “‘Al Hind’: India and Indonesia in
the Islamic World-Economy, c. 700–1800 c.e.,” in Comparative History of India and Indone-
sia, vol. 3, ed. P. J. Marshall et al. (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1988), pp. 33–72.
31
Self-government is one of the main characteristics of city-states. Not all of the city-
states have developed democratic institutions but “even in monarchies, the percentage of
the population involved in the direction of the government is much higher than in other
types of states” (M. Hansen, “The Concepts of City-State and City-State Culture,” and
“Conclusion: The Impact of City-State Cultures on World History,” in A Comparative
Study of Thirty City-State Cultures, p. 18 and p. 607).
32
These trends are even clearer in the economically growing European continent from
the twelfth century. The discovery of Greek and Arabic philosophy and sciences (eleventh
through twelfth centuries) is a prelude to the development of corporations and autonomous
universities (self-governed) and to the initiation by R. Bacon and other scholars of the
experimental method in sciences (thirteenth century). Republican institutions of Italian
city-states allow the individual—within certain limits—freedom of thinking and freedom
of enterprise, which will develop in the fifteenth century during the Renaissance.
33
The development of the state (internal and external) can result from different fac-
tors: growth in population and in production and commerce, increases in social complex-
ity, and innovations. Competition between city-states and states probably explains part of
the technical progress at the time of the Warring States in China (steel production in the
fifth century b.c.e., the invention of the crossbow in the fourth century b.c.e.). It led to
the ascendancy of the Qin state in the third century b.c.e.
34
Imperialist expansion might also represent “an alternative to the domestic redistri-
bution of riches,” a sort of release valve for social tensions.
35
“Investments in socio-political complexity as a problem-solving response often
reaches a point of declining marginal returns. . . . Once a complex society enters the stage
of declining marginal returns, collapse becomes a mathematical likelihood” (A. Tainter,
The Collapse of Complex Societies [Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988], pp.
194–195).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 432
36
The model I describe differs in several ways from that of Chase-Dunn and Hall
(“Comparing World-Systems,” p. 98). Here, I can offer only its outlines. It is indeed likely
that there exists “a plurality of logics,” but all the same I hold, as against Wilkinson, that
there is a “systemic logic” (D. Wilkinson, “ Civilizations, World Systems and Hegemonies,”
in Denemark et al., World System History, p. 78). One example of possible other interactions
is that linking the environment to technological innovations (for example, in eighteenth-
century England, deforestation led to the increasing rarity and value of wood, which led
to the use of charcoal in blast furnaces). Frank and Gills (“Rejoinder and Conclusions,”
p. 305) have called for a new reading of world history that would take into account how
“world system development both altered and was in turn altered by the natural environ-
ment,” but they have not really pursued this line of inquiry.
37
K. Ekholm and J. Friedman (“‘Capital’ Imperialism and Exploitation in Ancient
World Systems,” in Frank and Gills, The World System, p. 73 n. 19) and I. Wallerstein (His-
torical Capitalism [London: Verso, 1983], pp. 59–60) have noted the high military price of
maintaining hegemony.
2JWH_391-465
12/27/05
2:22 PM
Page 433
38
These migrations appear to be tied to increased aridity in central Asia, the south of
Russia, and northern China during this period (R. Brown, History and Climate Change: A
Eurocentric Perspective [London: Routledge, 2001], p. 73).
39
W. H. McNeill, Plagues and Peoples (New York: Anchor Books Editions, 1998).
40
S. C. Chew, World Ecological Degradation: Accumulation, Urbanization, and Deforesta-
tion 3000 B.C.– A. D. 2000 (Walnut Creek, Calif.: AltaMira, 2001). Nevertheless, the rise
in the density of population often induced technological innovations in agriculture that
brought about improvement in soil fertility, thereby initiating a new cycle of economic
growth (Boserup, Conditions of Agricultural Growth, pp. 21–22).
41
G. Bond et al., “Persistent Solar Influence on North Atlantic Climate during the
Holocene,” Science 294, no. 5549 (December 2001): 2130–2136; Feng Sheng Hu et al.,
“Cyclic Variation and Solar Forcing of Holocene Climate in the Alaskan Subarctic,” Sci-
ence 301 (September 2003): 1890–1893. At Arolik Lake in Alaska, “increases in tempera-
ture and moisture apparently corresponded to intervals of elevated solar output and reduced
advections of ice-bearing (cooler) surface waters eastward and southward in the North
Atlantic. Conversely, decreases in temperature and moisture corresponded to intervals of
reduced solar output and increased advections of North Atlantic ice-bearing waters.”
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 435
42
Gills and Frank have remarked on these phenomena of desynchronism that, they
argue, allow for the restructuration of the world-system. “It is precisely because some regions
and states get out of phase that the transformation and development of and in the system
can take place” (“World System Cycles,” p. 149). They postulate that the rise of certain
powers at a moment of global crisis stems from the weakening of others, but I do not find
this to be sufficient explanation. Why, precisely, is one state better positioned for ascent
than another? Chase-Dunn and Hall (Rise and Demise, pp. 149, 221, 224; “ Comparing
World-Systems,” p. 107) have likewise noted that South Asia and Southeast Asia have
“dynamics . . . less tightly (coupled) to the emerging Afroeurasian world system” than other
regions such as China or western Asia. Growth and decline of states in Southeast Asia
occur often in opposition to those of Chinese and Indian empires. Wilkinson shows that
subregions of the Eurasian continent are often out of sync during phases of slowdown in the
world-system (“Civilizations Are World Systems!” in Sanderson, Civilizations and World
Systems). A final example of desynchronism: the expansion of Byzantium from the late
ninth into the tenth century.
43
For reasons still debated: threat from the Mongols, fear of a massive outflow of cop-
per cash through trade, reactions against the excessive costs of Zheng He’s expeditions,
environmental problems (deforestation due to excessive shipbuilding).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 436
which often moved ahead of the rest of the system: enjoying links to
two systems (India and China), Southeast Asia could more easily
compensate for recessions and take quickest advantage when China
entered an upward trend. For the same reasons, southern India and
Ceylon likewise appear to have escaped the ups and downs of the sys-
tem. Moreover, unlike China or West Asia, these regions were usually
not the targets of foreign invasions. The Indian peninsula was contin-
uously able to take advantage of the multiplicity of commercial routes
to which it was connected.
The rise and fall of cities—whose interconnections form the sys-
tem’s “basic foundation”—serve as useful indicators of economic activ-
ity, the level of interconnectedness of regions, and transformations in
the system(s). T. Chandler’s 1987 calculations of the population of
the twenty-five largest cities are useful in this sense, but they need to
be approached with at least two caveats. First, his estimations for the
oldest periods are questionable, especially for India and China.44 Sec-
ond, his method tends to underestimate the important role of city-
states, whose economic and cultural influences are usually greater than
their demographic standing. The prominent cities belong mainly to the
great powers that control the cores of the system: Luoyang, Chang’an
(Han empire), Rome, Alexandria (Roman empire), and Ctesiphon
(Parthian empire) in the first centuries of the Christian era; Chang’an,
Luoyang (Tang empire), Baghdad (Abbasid empire), Byzantium (Byz-
antine empire), and Cordoba (Umayyad caliphate) from the seventh
till the tenth century; Kaifeng, Hangzhou, Tanzhou, Jizhou (Sung
empire), Merv (Seljukid empire), and Kalyani (Chalukya empire) in
the eleventh and twelfth centuries; Pekin, Hangzhou, Quangzhou
(Yuan empire), Delhi (sultanate of Delhi), and Cairo (Mamluk empire)
in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries; and Pekin, Hangzhou
(Ming empire), Vijayanagara (Vijayanagara empire), Cairo (Mamluk
empire), and Istanbul (Ottoman empire) in the fifteenth and begin-
ning of the sixteenth century. But in that last period, we find also
important towns that are city-states belonging to semiperipheries:
Malacca and Venice.
44
The work of T. Chandler should today be revived and improved upon. The evolu-
tion in the number and size of cities with more than forty thousand inhabitants shows an
abrupt increase in 1400, which can be attributed in large part to the fact that the data used
by Chandler are more consistent than for preceding periods. It is nevertheless remarkable
that the data collected by Chandler show a decrease in size for the twenty-five biggest towns
in the world between 100 and 361 c.e. During this period, the Han, Kushan (ca. 200), and
Parthian (226) empires disappear.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 437
45
A. G. Frank, “Bronze Age World System Cycles,” Current Anthropology 34, no. 4
(1993): 387. Chase-Dunn and Hall (“Comparing World-Systems,” p. 91) contend that the
core/periphery distinction does not necessarily imply hierarchy, but the mechanisms of the
world-system itself would seem to contradict this possibility.
46
Gills and Frank (“Cumulation of Accumulation” and “World System Cycles”) have
not sufficiently explained the mechanisms that assured the transfers of surplus in ancient
times.
47
In effect, India was generally a core with multiple centers (cf. supra). Rome and its
empire formed another center or “core” for the first cycle of the system. Western Europe
acquired the status of a center again only at the end of the fifteenth century in the ancient
Eurasian and African world-system and in a new system that had as peripheries North and
West Africa and the Americas. As cores, Egypt and western Asia were sometimes separate,
sometimes united.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 438
48
On the “development of underdevelopment” and “unequal exchange,” see A. G.
Frank, Le Développement du Sous-développement (Paris: Maspéro, 1970); A. Emmanuel,
L’échange Inégal (Paris: Maspéro, 1973); and S. Amin, L’échange Inégal et la Loi de la Valeur:
La Fin d’un Débat (Paris: Anthropos, 1981).
49
In this regard, I do not share the reservations of Chase-Dunn and Hall, “Compar-
ing World-Systems,” p. 91. Ancient Mesopotamia, which these authors cite, in fact pro-
vides a good example of this process, as it was exporting textiles and metal goods.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 440
50
Moreover, because cores control commercial routes and markets, gains in their indus-
tries’ productivity do not bring about a decrease in profit for their manufactured goods; con-
versely, the profits from gains in productivity that occur in peripheries are recouped by
cores.
51
Versus M. N. Pearson, Port Cities and Intruders: The Swahili Coast, India, and Portugal
in the Early Modern Era (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1998), p. 116, and
P. Sinclair and T. Hakansson, “The Swahili City-State Culture,” in Hansen, A Compara-
tive Study of Thirty City-State Cultures, p. 475.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 441
52
From the sixteenth century, the African inland was a hinge between the two exist-
ing world-systems. At the center of the slave trade networks, Africa provided the West and
the East with slaves. See the map of the slave trades published by C. Coquery-Vidrovitch,
L’Afrique et les Africains au XIXè Siècle (Paris: Colin, 1999), p. 190. Moreover, earlier evi-
dence for links established through the African inland are cowries, which represented a
well-established currency in West Africa from the twelfth until the nineteenth century
(C. Coquery-Vidrovitch, personal communication). These shells—which came ultimately
from the Maldivian islands—were found even earlier at Awdaghust (western Sahara) in
levels belonging to the ninth through tenth centuries (J. Devisse, “Commerce et Routes du
Trafic en Afrique Occidentale,” in Histoire Generale de l’Afrique [UNESCO, NEA, 1990]
p. 450).
53
Unlike S. Amin (“History Conceived as an Eternal Cycle,” Review 22, no. 3, [1999]:
308), I believe that core-periphery relations in periods before the sixteenth century are
already “defined in terms of economic exploitation” (although not uniquely so). Waller-
stein and Amin have unnecessarily assumed that politics and ideology dictated the econ-
omy before the end of the fifteenth century in terms of a “tributary system.” Indeed, the
notion of “a tributary age” (ibid., p. 316) before 1500 runs squarely against the historic
facts.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 442
54
M. Horton and J. Middleton, The Swahili: The Social Landscape of a Mercantile Soci-
ety (Oxford: Blackwell Publishers, 2000), p. 102. Cf. also E. A. Alpers, Ivory and Slaves:
Changing Patterns of International Trade in East Central Africa to the Later Nineteenth Century
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1975); and A. Sheriff, “Trade and Underdevel-
opment: The Role of International Trade in the Economic History of the East African
Coast before the Sixteenth Century,” in Hadith 5: Economic and Social History of East
Africa, ed. B. A. Ogot (Nairobi: East African Literature Bureau, 1976), pp. 1–23.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 443
55
Ivory was not only a by-product of elephant hunting, and searching for gold was not
just an occasional activity to exchange gold for cloth. See The Book of the Wonders of India,
which speaks of Africans working like ants in galleries, and Abu al-Fida’, who quotes Ibn
Sa‘id (beginning thirteenth); G. S. P. Freeman-Grenville, The East African Coast: Select
Documents from the First to the Earlier Nineteenth Century (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1975),
pp. 15, 24. Cf. also Portuguese accounts about the Manica country and the chiefdoms of
Amçoçe and Mazofe (Mazoe) in 1512 and 1573, W. G. L. Randles, L’Empire du Monomo-
tapa du XVe au XIXe Siècle (Paris: Mouton, 1975), pp. 81, 122. Pearson himself acknowl-
edges an export of ten tons of gold a year from the coast of Sofala before the end of the fif-
teenth century (Indian Ocean, p. 84).
56
Cf. the effects of long-distance trade on the construction of hierarchical societies as
in the Limpopo area and Great Zimbabwe between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries.
According to M. N. Pearson, the Swahili and foreign merchants were able to make their
“huge profits” without any recourse to exploitation. Instead, “Overall, the advantage lay
with Africa. . . . Africans could work as much or as little as they wanted” to extract gold
and acquire imported products that “were discretionary rather than necessities in their
agricultural and hunting lives, except for cloth on the plateau.” Thus, for Pearson, cloth is
bought only for protection against the cold. It is not tied to social status, about which Pear-
son has little to say anyway. Pearson, Port Cities and Intruders, pp. 117, 124. Moreover, it is
certainly erroneous to consider that in the fifteenth or sixteenth century, “the traders from
the [East African] coast had to try and create a market de novo” (ibid., p. 113). Exchanges
have been developing between coast and interior for more than a thousand years. If it was
so difficult for the traders to sell their products, how did they manage to make such “huge
profits”?
57
It is as if the razzias for slaves carried out by coastal groups did not inflict any harm
or social damage on the peripheral societies. These razzias probably are just part of the
“benign” effects of the trade mentioned by Pearson (Port Cities and Intruders, p. 119). The
effects of the slave trade were all the more devastating because women probably formed the
larger number of slaves. On the East African coast, women play an essential role in agri-
cultural production.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 444
subject to domination were those within the core itself, both the geo-
graphic edges and weaker social groups. With the advent of European
capitalism, the chasm between the core and the periphery widened
deeply, owing in part to the rapid rate of technological innovation,
which was much more marked than in the system(s) of the ancient
world. But innovation was only one of the tools of power.
The instruments of economic exploitation and/or cooperation were
moreover embedded in ideological influence and domination. The
spread of Islam and Christianity appear to have been tied to economic
and political relations. “The Missionaries teach the natives that they
are naked and the merchants sell them cloth.” 58 Religious men often
become traders. Thus scholars who argue that societies have “choice”
in their trade relations overlook the glaring issues of power relations
and the fact that the desirability of products is largely the result of pro-
cesses of domination.
Contacts between cores, semiperipheries, and peripheries can be
violent or pacific. In East Africa, the establishment of relations with
the outside world stimulated trade far inland and gave rise to the cre-
ation of ruling chiefdoms and city-states on the coast, whose relations
with the interior tended to be formed through alliances rather than
military force,59 even if the continued existence of local slavery and
the exportation of slaves resulted in raids and wars.60 This ability to
form alliances—combined with their geographic advantage—no
doubt explains the stability of the Swahili cities despite their seem-
ingly fragile position.
As a different strategy for cores or semiperipheries, the creation of
an empire is a policy to control directly—through force—the totality
of routes and accumulation centers in a system (or a part of a system)
and therein to increase the level of surplus extracted. Various political
constructions have aspired to become “universal” empires: the Achae-
menid empire, the Greek empire under Alexander the Great, and the
Mongol empire under Gengis Khan and his successors.
When points of trade are separated by long distances, the extrac-
tion of resources tends to be accomplished through commerce and
58
A. Sherratt, “Envisioning Global Change: A Long-Term Perspective,” in Denemark
et al., World System History, p. 121.
59
For the case of Southeast Asia, see P.-Y. Manguin, “The Amorphous Nature of
Coastal Polities in Insular Southeast Asia: Restricted Centres, Extended Peripheries,”
Moussons 5 (2004).
60
Cf. for example Ibn Battuta on Kilwa: “They are devoted to holy wars because their
country is near pagan Zenj” (Ibn Battuta, Voyages, vol. 2, De La Mecque aux Steppes Russes
[Paris: F. Maspéro, 1982], p. 90).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 445
The succeeding cycles in the system are at once similar and different.
Any changes that do occur do not affect the structure or the nature of
the system. Fundamental transformations are noticeable at only two
moments: (1) from 3500 to 2400 b.c.e. in western Asia and Egypt and
in the second millennium in China, when the state was born along
with private means of accumulation, which broke with the former
mode of accumulation based on kinship relations, and (2) toward the
middle of the eighteenth century, during the Industrial Revolution—
which also represents an ideological revolution—when the capitalist
mode of accumulation became, for the first time, preeminent in a
world-system that would henceforth link America, Africa, and Eura-
sia. The sixteenth century, however, also represents a decisive moment,
when a new ocean, the Atlantic, was joined to the Indian and Med-
iterranean Oceans—linked since ancient times—a moment when
Europe emerges as core of a new space.
Each new period of growth creates a new spatial division of labor,
although it builds on the preceding one. With the exception of the
oscillations between rival regions mentioned above, commercial routes
—at least the principal ones—vary little over time. Secondary net-
works are more flexible, widening and becoming more dense during
phases of growth in the world-system and contracting during periods
of regression, as these secondary routes arise or disappear according to
61
Cf. C. Chase-Dunn and T. D. Hall, “The Historical Evolution of World-Systems,”
Sociological Inquiry 64, no. 3 (1994): 271.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 447
62
Some ports, however, that served as warehouses and crossroads had practically no
hinterland and owed their success entirely to their strategic geographic location. This was
the case for Hormuz and Malacca.
63
I therefore disagree with Bosworth who sees a “tension” between land and sea routes
and argues for the existence of cycles that alternated between silk routes by land and spice
routes by sea (Bosworth, “The Evolution of the World-City System, 3000 bc to ad 2000,”
in Denemark et al., World System History, p. 282).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 448
Not only was there continuity in commercial routes, there was also
continuity in the types of products being exported. India, for example,
was exporting cotton cloth as early as the first century c.e., along
with beads and precious stones. The general trend has been for certain
basic types of goods and products to influence commerce and the move-
ments of peoples over the course of several centuries; such products
include metals (both precious and nonprecious), clothing items, lux-
ury goods for body adornment, perfumes, medicines (for religion and
health), aromatics (for health and cooking), means of production
(slaves, tools, and so forth), means of transport (for example, ships),
instruments of war (weapons, horses, elephants), food, rare goods, and
sacred objects.
This continuity was embedded in a general trend of expansion and
intensification that itself was linked to technological innovation and
social developments brought about, in part, through economic con-
straints and sometimes—especially in the case of agriculture—demo-
graphic and ecological factors.64 This rhythm could intensify in certain
times and in certain places. The free trade promoted by the Sung in
China from the tenth to the thirteenth century gave rise to innova-
tion and growth. The competition between states in Europe from the
sixteenth century had the same effects. As I have underscored, progress
in agriculture played a crucial role, as it is the cornerstone for urban-
ization and the development of handicraft or semi-industrial produc-
tion that fuels trade in both internal and external markets.
Progress in ship building, especially in the twelfth and thirteenth
centuries, reduced transport times and influenced the types of products
that were shipped. It allowed for the transport of ever-larger loads of
heavy and inexpensive materials (for example, raw materials, agricul-
tural products, and so forth). This point is important for our discussion
of world-systems. Wallerstein rejects “Frank’s so-called world-system”
before the sixteenth century on the grounds that it traded only in lux-
ury goods, not staple items, and thus, in consequence, it could not
have been organized by the “axial division of labor” that characterizes
the modern world. This reasoning, however, does not hold up under
64
Building on Julian Steward’s notion of “cultural ecology” (Theory of Culture Change:
The Methodology of Multilinear Evolution [Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1955]), J. Dia-
mond uses data from archeology, history, genetics, and molecular biology to argue that envi-
ronmental conditions gave rise to the development of agriculture and conferred a decisive
advantage on Eurasian societies (Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies [New
York: W. W. Norton, 1997]).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 449
65
I. Wallerstein, “World System Versus World-Systems: A Critique,” in World System:
Five Hundred Years, pp. 293–294; and Chase-Dunn and Hall (“Comparing World-Sys-
tems,” p. 92) also contend there was “no movement in raw materials” in ancient times.
66
Cf. L. Casson, Periplus Maris Erythreai (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press,
1989).
67
Cf. R. T. J. Cappers, “Archaeobotanical Evidence of Roman Trade with India,” in
Ray, Archaeology of Seafaring, pp. 51–69, W. Z. Wendrich et al., “Berenike Cross-Roads:
The Integration of Information,” Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 46,
no. 1 (2003): 46–87.
68
B. K. Gills, “ Capital and Power in the Processes of World History,” in Sanderson,
Civilizations and World Systems, p. 146.
69
Wallerstein, Modern World-System, vol. 1, pp. 41–42.
70
J. Schneider, “Was There a Pre-Capitalist World-System?” Peasant Studies 6, no. 1
(1977): 20–29; P. Peregrine, “Prehistoric Chiefdoms on the American Mid-Continent: A
World System Based on Prestige Goods,” in Core/Periphery Relations in Precapitalist Worlds,
ed. C. Chase-Dunn and T. D. Hall (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1991), pp. 193–211;
Chase-Dunn and Hall, Rise and Demise, pp. 13–14.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 450
from the eighth to the thirteenth century, and the Karimi Egyptians
from the twelfth to the fourteenth century (even if the latter was not
strictly a guild). Increasing monetarization occurs over the centuries,
although at different, sometimes opposing, rhythms from region to
region.71 The creation of large political entities (for example, the Abba-
sid empire, the Delhi Sultanate, the various Chinese empires) natu-
rally facilitated the spread of monetary systems over wide zones.
Precious metals—in the form of merchandise and/or money—and
their flow played an important role in the structuring of the world-sys-
tem and its evolution. Precious or highly sought-after objects, which
sometimes served as money (a standard of value and/or means of
exchange), were spread along commercial routes. Cowries were used
from Bengal to Assam, in Burma and Yunnan, as well as in Thailand
and Annam. Silk, of course, was ubiquitous in caravan and maritime
networks and served in different regions as a means of exchange and
also as a unit of value (for example, Nanzhao in the ninth century, or
Cambodia from the eighth to the thirteenth century).
Cores that lacked precious or semiprecious metals sometimes over-
came the shortfall and created a tool of economic expansion through
the development of credit, as was the case for the Muslim world from
the eighth to the tenth century, in Ayyubid Egypt, and in China from
the ninth century.
From ancient times, market prices played a role in the movements
of goods. In the first century c.e., the Periplus records that Egypt
exported copper to Barygaza (Gujarat), and that this same port also
exported copper (either of Egyptian origin or coming from production
centers in the Northwest of India) to Apologos (near Basra). Marco
Polo described a favorable gold-to-silver ratio that encouraged mer-
chants to transport silver from Yunnan to Burma.
Commercial routes, however, were not the only networks that con-
tributed to the birth and evolution of the world-system; other types of
networks intersected with those of merchants. Religion, for example,
played a key role in the history of the Indian Ocean and the China
Sea. The development of Buddhism, Christianity, and then Islam,
which saw the worshipper’s relation to the divinity move toward an
increasingly individualized encounter, occurred within the context of
71
For Southeast Asia, see, for example, R. S. Wicks, Money, Markets, and Trade in Early
Southeast Asia: The Development of Indigenous Monetary Systems to AD 1400 (Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press, 1992).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 451
72
L. Dumont (Essays on Individualism: Modern Ideology in Anthropological Perspective
[Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 1986], p. 27) writes, “There is no
doubt about the fundamental conception of man that flowed from the teaching of Christ:
as Troeltsch said, man is an ‘individual-in-relation-to-God.’” Cf. also M. Augé, Génie du
Paganisme (Paris: Gallimard, 1982), p. 139, about the figure of an individual human destiny
shaped by Christianity. “Salvation, Transcendence and the Mystery,” Augé continues (ibid.,
p. 14), “are essentially absent . . .” from paganism. The importance of the individual was
established in schools of thought from Hellenistic times (e.g., Cynics, Epicurians, Stoics).
Dumont holds that Christianity’s emphasis on the individual reached its peak with Calvin
during the Reformation: “the individualist value now rules without contradiction or restric-
tion” (Dumont, Essays on Individualism, p. 57).
73
H. P. Ray, The Winds of Change: Buddhism and the Maritime Links of Early South Asia
(New Delhi: Manohar, 1994); D. Lombard, “Y a-t-il Une Continuité des Réseaux March-
ands Asiatiques?” in Marchands et Hommes d’Affaires Asiatiques dans l’Océan Indien et la Mer
de Chine: 13e–20e Siècles, ed. D. Lombard and J. Aubin (Paris: EHESS, 1988), pp. 11–18.
74
As M. N. Pearson underlines it (“The Indian Ocean and the Red Sea,” in The His-
tory of Islam in Africa, ed. N. Levtzion and R. L. Pouwels [Athens: Ohio University Press;
Oxford: James Currey; Claremont: David Philip, 2000], p. 44), “the hajj is a remarkably
efficient method of integrating the worldwide [Muslim] community.”
75
See S. D. Goitein, “From the Mediterranean to India: Documents on the Trade to
India, South Arabia, and East Africa from the Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries,” Speculum:
A Journal of Mediaeval Studies 29 (1954): 181–197, for the networks linking Egypt and
India.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 452
Data show that from the first millennium b.c.e., private capital has
played an important role, alongside state capital. Characteristics con-
sidered particular to the modern capitalist system—increasing produc-
tion of goods, enterprises seeking maximal profit, salaried labor, tech-
nological progress—are in fact present before the sixteenth century
in numerous states. In some periods, the state is the major engine of
accumulation; in others, private entrepreneurs. Recent research has
questioned the presumed importance of the state in the development
of commerce in ancient Mesopotamia, Maurya India (fourth through
third centuries b.c.e.), and the Roman empire in its relations with
south Asia.79 In any event, it is clear in other cases such as the period
today known as “medieval,” in the Abbasid caliphate (eighth and
ninth centuries), southern India (eighth to eleventh centuries), Ayyu-
bid Egypt (twelfth to thirteenth centuries), the sultanates of Bengal
(fourteenth to fifteenth centuries) and Gujarat (fifteenth century),
that capitalism came to dominate the spheres of production and com-
merce, a phenomenon that has been qualified incorrectly as “mer-
chant” capitalism. As would later be the case in Europe, these entre-
preneurs were at the same time producers, merchants, and financiers.
Indeed, a general trend can be observed for “a complex mixture or
articulations of modes (of accumulation) at all times in the develop-
76
J. Aubin, “Y a-t-il Interruption du Commerce par Mer Entre le Golfe Persique et
l’Inde du XIe au XIV e Siècles?” in Lombard and Aubin, Marchands et Hommes, p. 197.
77
As but one example, Mahmud Gawan was a learned man and horse merchant whose
family originated in Gilan. He served as a minister in the Bahmani sultanate of India while
his brother, Ahmad, was based in Egypt. One of Ahmad’s sons did business with India while
two others, Koranic scholars, lived in Mecca. On the importance of diasporas and networks
that bypassed “ethnicity” and nations, see also P. Curtin, Cross-Cultural Trade in World His-
tory (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984).
78
Goitein, “From the Mediterranean to India,” p. 197.
79
For example, cf. Ray, Archaeology of Seafaring, pp. 188–189, 192.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 454
80
Frank and Gills, “The 5000-Year World System: An Interdisciplinary Introduc-
tion,” in The World System, p. 46. Here I am in agreement with Frank, at least for the peri-
ods preceding the eighteenth century. Frank holds that it is illusory to try to distinguish a
qualitative difference in phases of the world-system based on modes of production. There
was never a progressive succession of modes of production; instead, the various types of
modes could be operating simultaneously, in different combinations and relations. Indeed,
Frank goes so far as to say “This received conceptualization has continued to divert our
attention away from the much more significant world systemic structures and processes”
(ReORIENT, p. 331).
81
Chase-Dunn and Hall (Rise and Demise, pp. 212–213, and “Comparing World-
Systems,” p. 101) make reference to the “oscillation between state-based and private cap-
italist accumulation.”
82
Chase-Dunn and Hall, Rise and Demise, p. 47. Gills, however, argues, “the entire
Eurasian world-economy/system of the thirteenth century was perhaps already ‘capitalist’
(and perhaps even that of) the tenth century” (“Capital and Power,” p. 139). It does, in
fact, appear that capitalism played an increasingly important role from one cycle to the
next.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 455
83
The city-states of the Malaysian world in fact appear much earlier (P.-Y. Manguin,
“City-States and City-State Cultures in Pre-15th Century Southeast Asia,” in Hansen, A
Comparative Study of Thirty City-State Cultures, pp. 409–416), as well as the city-states of
the Swahili East African coast (Sinclair and Hakansson, “Swahili City-State Culture”).
84
Manguin, “ City-States and City-State Cultures.”
85
Hansen, “ Concepts of City-State and City-State Culture,” p. 16. Hansen proposes
to use this term “country-state” or “macro-state” instead of “territorial state.”
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 456
pur” 86 —were extremely efficient, owing in part to the low cost of the
state sector and, even more so, to their dynamic momentum, which
attracted capital and skilled labor. But they were also evidently a vul-
nerable and tempting prey for territorial states. Thus, they were always
careful to build up forms of defense, create alliance networks (for exam-
ple, the relations between Swahili cities and groups in the interior),
and take the best advantage of their geographic location (for example,
the cities of the Straits of Malacca). Even guilds and private merchants
made recourse of men at arms; examples include the great Indian
guilds of the fifth to fourteenth centuries, the ships of the west coast
of India in the fourteenth century, and Chinese junks during the same
time period. Concerning the princes who engaged in commerce, two
interpretations are possible: they might represent merchants who pre-
figured capitalist entrepreneurs, or they may have acted as predators.87
Ibn Battuta provides numerous examples of flotillas owned by gov-
ernment officials. His descriptions reveal the close ties that existed
between commerce, political power, and also piracy, as illustrated in
the case of the sultan of Honavar, Jamal al-Din (fourteenth century).88
Likewise, within the core of a system, certain periods of weak polit-
ical integration seem to have encouraged the development of produc-
tion and commerce: competition between states or city-states stimu-
lated the economy, and private entrepreneurs enjoyed greater liberty
than those operating in stronger states. C. Edens has clearly demon-
strated this phenomenon for Early Dynastic III (in the middle of the
third millennium b.c.e.) and for the Isin-Larsa period in western Asia
(beginning of the second millennium b.c.e.).89 This point is essential
for understanding the evolution of capitalism in Europe.
86
Braudel, Civilisation Matérielle, vol. 3, p. 88.
87
Cf. M. Morineau, “Eastern and Western Merchants from the Sixteenth to the Eigh-
teenth Centuries,” in Merchants, Companies and Trade: Europe and Asia in the Early Modern
Era, ed. S. Chaudhury and M. Morineau (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Maison
des Sciences de l’Homme, 1999), pp. 116–144.
88
S. Digby, “The Maritime Trade of India,” in The Cambridge Economic History of
India, vol. 1, c. 1200– c. 1750, ed. T. Raychaudhuri and I. Habib (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1982), p. 155.
89
C. Edens, “Comments” on the article of A. G. Frank, Current Anthropology 34, no.
4 (1993): 408. The end of the Spring-and-Autumn period and the Warring States period
(fifth through fourth centuries b.c.e.) might represent another example of growth in a time
of intense competition. I do not, however, agree with Edens’s rejection of Frank’s causal tie
between volume of trade and levels of urbanization. Regarding the first point, Friedman
goes further than Edens when he writes “centralized empires were often a symptom of slow-
down or even decline. . . . Expansion is most often and systematically linked to political
decentralization” (J. Friedman, “Comments” to the article of A. G. Frank, Current Anthro-
pology, 34, no. 4 [1993]: 409). He disputes the idea that the decline of an empire serves as
evidence for a B phase in the cycle (slowdown). Available data, however, would seem to
support Frank.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 457
90
K. N. Chaudhuri, Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilization in the Indian Ocean
from the Rise of Islam to 1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 256, 387.
Gills, “ Capital and Power,” p. 139.
91
Ancient Egypt offers an example of growth being directly instigated by actions of the
state, through its technological innovations (the invention of writing, irrigation, etc.) and
especially through its efforts to stimulate demand (D. Warburton, “Before the IMF: The
Economic Implications of Unintentional Structural Adjustment in Ancient Egypt,” Jour-
nal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient 43, no. 2 [2000]).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 458
92
Burma provides a good example of the contradictions that can arise between the
development of religious entities and state interests. Periodically, in phases of “purifica-
tion,” the state seized the wealth that had been amassed by religious orders. From 843 to
845, the Chinese emperor likewise confiscated the belongings of Buddhist monasteries.
93
Ibn Battuta notes for example the warm welcome given to traders by the lords of
Kulam and Calcutta, but also the practices of extortion and piracy inflicted by local lords
of the west coast of India (Voyages, vol. III, Inde, Extrême-Orient, Espagne et Soudan, pp.
206–207, 213–214).
94
Lombard, “Y a-t-il une Continuité,” p. 117. Also Aubin, “Y a-t-il Interruption du
Commerce,” pp. 88–89. Aubin (ibid.), however, makes reference to “condottieri mer-
chants,” “who were both viziers and military leaders.”
95
M. Gaborieau, “L’Islamisation de l’Inde et de l’Asie Orientale,” in Etats, Sociétés et
Cultures du Monde Musulman Médiéval, ed. J. C. Garcin, M. Balivet, T. Bianquis, H. Bresc,
J. Calmard, M. Gaborieau, P. Guichard, and J.-L. Triaud (Paris: PUF, 1995), p. 456. Indeed,
the merchant Ibn al-Kawlami became governor of Cambaye through the auspices of the
sultanate of Delhi (Ibn Battuta, Voyages, vol. 3, pp. 102–103).
96
S. Digby (“Maritime Trade of India,” p. 52) gives the example of the Tibi family,
which played the role of kingmakers in the Pandya kingdom of South India at the end of
the thirteenth century.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 459
writes that “in the Indies, in China, in the Arab world . . . merchants
[were] permanently integrated into the aristocratic minority and so had
no reason to wish to change the society.” 97
Capitalist entrepreneurs oscillated between two strategies: remain-
ing outside politics to try to reduce the role of the state (but capitalist
networks could hardly do without the state because they require a sta-
ble world to develop their operations and/or a military force to defend
their access to vital resources), or investing in the state. On the other
hand, the elites of the state had to choose between taking control of
the economy or encouraging success in the private sector and then
taxing its activities.
The history of the Indian Ocean to the sixteenth century shows its dif-
ferent regions becoming progressively integrated into the Eurasian and
African world-system, as can be seen in the economic cycles synchro-
nized with political, social, and ideological evolutions; the develop-
ment of urbanization; the general growth of commerce and production;
and the simultaneous development of hierarchical relations between
cores and peripheries within the international division of labor. This
early history also sheds light on the period that would follow—the
emergence of the capitalist world-system—and perhaps also provides
some hints as to the possible futures of the system.
Whether or not the beginnings of the sixteenth century represent
a true break in world history is still debated. The arrival of the Portu-
guese in the Indian Ocean occurred during an ascendant phase of a
cycle, a phase that would continue throughout the sixteenth century.
Their appearance most likely does not represent a rupture, but rather
a temporary disturbance. Far too few in number, the Portuguese did not
have the means to implement the maritime policy that they tried to
assert. Moreover, the real break had already occurred earlier in China
in 1433, when the Ming prohibited trade with its southern seas. All
the same, coming just after the discovery of America, the arrival of the
Portuguese in the Indian Ocean signifies the creation of a new order
97
This situation contrasts with that of Europe, which accounts for the fact, according
to Y. Lacoste (La Géographie du Sous-développement, 5th ed. [Paris: PUF, 1982], p. 270),
that it was in Europe that capitalism emerged as the dominant system and paved the way
for the Industrial Revolution.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 460
98
Braudel, Civilisation Matérielle, vol. 3, p. 44. Marx also expressed that the “biogra-
phy of capital begins in the sixteenth century.”
99
G. Arrighi, “Capitalism and the Modern World-System: Rethinking the Nondebates
of the 1970s,” Review 21, no. 1 (1998): 127–128, and The Long Twentieth Century: Money,
Power and the Origins of Our Times (London: Verso, 1994), chaps. 1–2.
100
Frank and Gills, however, do not support this interpretation. According to these
authors (“Rejoinder and Conclusions,” p. 304), the Americas were a periphery to a core
situated in Europe, but the latter was not the core of a discrete world-system. The gold and
silver from the Americas only “(permitted) the Europeans to participate more actively” in
exchanges in the system (Frank and Gills, “Five Thousand Year World System,” p. 7). Yet,
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 461
elsewhere, Frank (ReORIENT, pp. 277–279, 316) does describe a world-system centered
in Europe. This debate ties in with the question of whether European states of the six-
teenth century were qualitatively different from other states and if the logic of the system
changed with the rise of modern Europe. It could be argued that the Netherlands in the
seventeenth century, before England, represent the first example of a capitalist state. But,
asks Braudel (Civilisation Matérielle, vol. 3, p. 161), “Can the United Provinces be called a
‘state’?” The East India Companies, in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, offer a
good example of association between state and capitalism.
101
M. Mazoyer and L. Roudart, Histoire des Agricultures du Monde du Néolithique à la
Crise Contemporaine (Paris: Seuil, 1998), p. 313.
102
The discovery of silver mines at Potosí (Bolivia) in 1545 and at Zacatecas (Mex-
ico) in 1548 would, in the decades to come, greatly augment the silver supply in the trade
circuits of the ancient world. Access to this silver, along with gold, enabled Europe to com-
pensate for its commercial trade deficit with Asian states. The influx of precious metals also
became a factor for growth in production and commerce in the Eurasian and African zones.
103
The notion that mass education can provide a structural base for technological
innovation was developed only in the twentieth century.
104
L. Dumont, Essays on Individualism, p. 92. In addition, see the “Bill of Rights
adopted by certain (American) States and particularly that of Virginia of 1776” (ibid.,
p. 93).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 462
105
J. E. McClellan III and H. Dorn, Science and Technology in World History: An Intro-
duction (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999), p. 292.
106
D. Christian, “Silk Roads or Steppe Roads? The Silk Roads in World History,”
Journal of World History 11 (2000): 25.
107
It is noticeable that the emergence of rational thinking in Greece took place in the
context of city-states that developed democratic institutions. The Mohist Chinese wave of
logician thinking appeared at the same period (fifth through fourth centuries b.c.e.), but it
will not have the same posterity, because of very different political and social contexts
(within a strong central state marked by Confucianism). As in the Greek cities of antiq-
uity, some freedom of thinking along with liberty to conduct business existed in Sung
China, with different kinds of limitations (the importance of external threats nevertheless
constituted an inhibiting factor for growth in both cases). Freedom is restricted in Ming
China by state power, based on a neo-Confucianist philosophy; in the Muslim world, by
religious power itself.
108
Lacoste, La Géographie du Sous-développement, pp. 269–270. According to Lacoste
(and to Marx), it is the unique character of the European feudal system that explains the
creation of a revolutionary bourgeoisie, the triumph of its ideology, and the advent of cap-
italism as the dominant mode of production. Open to question, however, is Lacoste’s con-
tention that “in a country without feudal structures, merchants did not constitute a bour-
geoisie,” but were part of the ruling aristocracy (ibid., pp. 260, 267, 273). Likewise refutable
is Lacoste’s assertion—made in order to fit with Marx’s “Asian mode of production”—that
there was no private ownership of land in Asia. For the Tang, Sung, and Ming, cf. J. Ger-
net, Le Monde Chinois (Paris: Armand Colin, 1999), pp. 230, 275–278, 360.
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 463
109
Frank, ReORIENT, pp. 301–306. Before broaching the topics of population
increase and the resulting imbalances, Frank puts forward a seemingly paradoxical argu-
ment. The assets of Asian cores were also the source of their weakness: the growing supply
of silver resulted in “increased purchasing power, income, and demand on domestic and
export markets in the world economy. That presumably increasingly skewed the distribution
of income, which could have led to constraints on effective demand and growing political
tensions” (ReORIENT, p. 267). But why would the influx of money be extremely benefi-
cial to Asian economies in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries and then suddenly
become nefarious in the eighteenth century? The argument makes sense only if it assumes a
reverse in the cycle, induced by growing demographic pressure and a decline in the levels
of profits. Frank emphasizes the unequal distribution of income in Asia, which I mentioned
above. Other authors see a phase of decline in the seventeenth century, but the character
of the recession of the mid-seventeenth century is still under debate. Was it a global event
affecting the entire world-system or a more localized recession? Was it a slowdown at the
end of a long phase or the second phase of a Kondratieff cycle? Frank (ReORIENT, p. 231)
today rejects the idea of a generalized economic crisis in the seventeenth century. How-
ever, there was a decrease in the population of the ancient world between 1600 and 1650
(McEvedy and Jones, Atlas of World Population History; C. Clark, Population Growth and
Land Use [London: McMillan, 1977]) and a global decrease in temperature in what is called
the Little Ice Age (1640–1705). Moreover, “in the period 1640–1650, the white metal from
America no longer arrived in Spain in large quantities” (F. Braudel, “Monnaies et Civili-
sations de l’Or du Soudan à l’Argent d’Amérique: Un Drame Méditerranéen,” Annales-
économie, Sociétés, Civilisations 1 [1946]: 20). According to Frank, Europe has (only) taken
advantage of the weakness of the Asian cores in the eighteenth century, thus managing to
acquire a dominant position, which leads I. Wallerstein to say ironically that “Frank proves
the European miracle” (“Frank Proves the European Miracle,” Review 22, no. 3 [1999]:
365–371). Considering the existence of only one world-system in the eighteenth century,
which is Frank’s view, we are led to ask ourselves why this B phase (phase of decline) that
he describes (a B phase valid “at least for Asia,” says Frank, ReORIENT, p. 259), brings
about a general demise in Asia and a spectacular upturn in Europe. It seems to me neces-
sary to think of the competition between two world-systems, the old Eurasian and African
one (maybe truly in a B phase before the Industrial Revolution) and a new one centered
on Europe (and then North America)—a situation that Frank himself seems to describe
(ReORIENT, p. 283): “While the Europeans were gathering strength from the Americas
and Africa, as well as from Asia itself, Asian economies and polities were also becoming
weakened during part of the eighteenth century—so much so that the paths finally crossed.”
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 464
110
Hansen “Conclusion,” pp. 612–613. The United Provinces after 1579 provide a
more recent example of a federation (ibid.). “Republicanism and federalism represent
major aspects of the modern state which have their roots in the cultures of city-states.
Before the end of the eighteenth century, they were practically only to be found in the city-
states” (ibid., p. 616). When they eventually managed to emerge (in India, Southeast Asia,
but not in China), Asian city-states were not able to impose their ideology to the regional
states.
111
Chase-Dunn and Hall (“ Comparing World-Systems,” p. 108) predict a collapse
circa the “year 2020.” Some experts think that oil supply could stay at reasonable prices in
the world until 2030, but “these forecasts are not the most probable” (P. Testard-Vaillant,
“Pétrole: Les Raisons de la Tourmente. Pourquoi les Prix Flambent-ils?” Le Journal du
CNRS 178 [2004]: 19).
2JWH_391-465 12/27/05 2:22 PM Page 465
direction advocated by Meadows and his team, and although the con-
clusions struck many at the time as being overly pessimistic, today their
accuracy is becoming more apparent. “The period 2000–2050 will
thus be chaotic.” 112 The pressing question for us now then is “whether
the fall will take place in totalitarianism and barbarity or whether it
will . . . be channeled through humanism and democracy,” 113 guided by
a new economic model. Here, echoing Wallerstein, I believe we must
decide what kind of society we want to see develop in the new world-
system that will evolve.114
112
I. Wallerstein, “The World We Are Entering, 2000–2050 (32 Propositions),” in
The World We Are Entering, 2000 –2050, ed. I. Wallerstein and A. Clesse (Amsterdam:
Dutch University Press, 2002), p. 22. “The modern world-system (which is a capitalist
world-economy) is in a structural crisis and it will not be able to go on functioning under
the historic way it took. The system enters a chaotic period of transition towards something
different” (ibid., p. 17). “The crisis of the system disfavours the survival of the capitalist
world-economy as a historic system.” “During this period (of chaos), there will be a politi-
cal struggle about the nature of the system which will follow” (“Introduction,” in World We
Are Entering, p. 7).
113
La Décroissance, 2004, p. 2. Cf. N. Georgescu-Roegen, La Décroissance: Entropie,
Écologie, Économie (Paris: Sang de la Terre, 1995). S. Latouche, Survivre au Développement
(Paris: Mille et Une Nuits, 2004).
114
I. Wallerstein, Utopistics, or Historical Choices of the Twenty-first Century (New York:
New Press, 1998), and “Introduction,” in World We Are Entering, p. 8.