Brill Publishing Tocqueville in The Ottoman Empire, Rival Paths To The Modern State (2004) PDF
Brill Publishing Tocqueville in The Ottoman Empire, Rival Paths To The Modern State (2004) PDF
Advisory Board
VOLUME 28
TOCQUEVILLE
IN THE
OTTOMAN EMPIRE
Rival Paths to the Modern State
BY
ARIEL SALZMANN
BRILL
LEIDEN • BOSTON
2004
This book is printed on acid-free paper.
ISSN 1380-6076
ISBN 90 04 10887 4
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, translated, stored in
a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic,
mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without prior written
permission of the publisher.
Figures
English spellings have been used for commonly used Middle Eastern
terms (e.g. ulema, vizier, pasha) and place names. Terms with ref-
erence to the broader Islamic world (e.g. Naqshbandiyya, shah, waqf,
shaykh, etc.) have been transcribed from Arabic or Persian without
diacritics or italics.
I adhere to the New Redhouse Turkish-English Dictionary (Istanbul:
Redhouse Press, 8th Ed., 1986) for the transcription of Ottoman ter-
minology with certain modifications: to account for the Arabic sound-
and Persian plural, I use “ât” and “ân” respectively; and I have also
chosen to preserve the original Arabic articles (ul- al-) and Persian
ezafe (-i) instead of a compound: e.g. }eyh"ül-(slam vs. }eyhülislam.
Throughout, I have attempted to reduce the number of diacritical
marks.
English readers unfamiliar with Turkish characters should note the
following: the “ç” is pronounced like the “ch” in church; the “c”
like “j” in jam; the “{” like “sh” in shoe. The “[”, though silent,
lengthens the preceding vowel. As for vowels: the “ı” is like the “i”
in slip; the “ö” as “u” in burr; and the “ü” is pronounced as the
“u” in French.
INTRODUCTION
TOCQUEVILLE’S GHOST
Distracted by the call to prayer that echoed across Divan Yolu from
the mosque at Sultan Ahmad, the guard did not notice as Alexis de
Tocqueville, the historian of the old regime and the scholar of mod-
ern government, slipped quietly past and entered the Prime Minister’s
Archive.1
He strode briskly along the corridor and up a short flight of stairs,
then he turned left toward the reading hall. Heading toward the last
row of desks at the back of the room, he seated himself. The pre-
vious researcher had left at the desk a pile of red-bound registers.
Curious, Tocqueville opened the uppermost document (Fig. 1). He
bent over to get a better look at the unfamiliar handwriting before
realizing that what lay before him was a ledger of contracts issued
on village revenues in a remote province. Scrawled over its pages
were notations that spanned nearly a century, between 1697 and
1793.
As he peeled back the pages, tattered by time and use, Tocqueville
contemplated the profound changes in the style of the chancellery:
unlike the clear and comprehensive registers of the fifteenth and six-
teenth centuries, the ancien régime’s records seemed a patois of
script, cipher, and haphazard numbers.2 He sighed, thinking of the
“clarity and intelligence of the men” who compiled the first cadastral
records of the early sixteenth century. These “obscure, ill ordered,
incomplete, and slovenly” pages did not bode well for the eighteenth-
1
Quotations are from The Old Régime and the French Revolution, trans. Stuart Gilbert
(Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday & Company, 1955). When meaning is unclear, I
have also checked L’ancien régime et la Révolution, ed. J.-P. Mayer (Paris: Éditions
Gallimard, 1967), and François Furet and Françoise Mélonio’s new edition of the
complete text and Tocqueville’s notes, translated by Alan S. Kahan, 2 vols. (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1998). Also see J.-P. Mayer, ed. Oeuvres complètes (Paris:
Gallimard, 1951–) 12 vols.
2
For samples, see Mübahat S. Kütüko[lu, Osmanlı Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik)
(Istanbul: Kubbealtı Akademisi Kütür ve San"at Vakfı, 1998).
2
Fig. 1. A double page (reduced) from a malikâne mukataa “master” register for the
province (eyalet) of Diyarbekir (MMD 9518:17–18). On the right hand side there are
six entries; on the left, five. The transactions between contractors, connected by
flourishes of the pen, span nearly a century. By permission of the Ba{bakanlık Ar{ivi.
’ 3
3
“The progressive decay of the institutions stemming from the Middle Ages can
be followed in records of the period . . . In the thirteenth- and fourteenth-century
registers I examined, I was much impressed by the skill with which they were
drafted, their clarity, and the intelligence of the men compiling them, In later peri-
ods, however, there is a very definite falling off; the terriers become more and more
obscure, ill ordered, incomplete, and slovenly” The Old Régime, 16. Echoes of
Tocqueville ring through Bernard Lewis’ account of Ottoman decline (The Emergence
of Modern Turkey [Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1961, 3d ed., 2002]), 23.
4
France (1788) and the “New Order” fisc ((rade-i Cedid Hazinesi ) in
Istanbul (1793). Yet this defensive centralization only hastened the
downfall of the ancien régime and sealed the fate of both sovereigns,
Louis XVI in 1790 and Selim III in 1807.
Tocqueville suddenly grew disconcerted by his discovery: if the
policies and institutional patterns of the old regime were so similar
in character and so close in timing why did their paths suddenly
divide? Why did France cohere and the Ottoman Empire fall apart?
Tocqueville straightened his waistcoat and closed the ledger. Rising
from his seat, he turned his back on the reading room and walked
deliberately down the stairs, past the guard’s station and into the
street. A thin figure in quaint attire disappeared among the throngs
of tourists milling in the gardens and the teahouses of the Hippodrome.
4
For a selection of his writings on Ottoman Algeria, see Alexis de Tocqueville,
De la colonie en Algérie, ed. Tzvetan Todorovo (Bruxelles: Editions Complexe, 1988);
and Tocqueville, Writings on Empire and Slavery, ed. Jennifer Pitts (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 2001). For one of the most sustained reflections, Tocqueville,
Oeuvres compléte, 3 pt. 1:129–253.
5
On his life and works, see André Jardin, Tocqueville: A Biography, (New York:
Farrar Straus & Giroux, 1988); Cheryl B. Welch, De Tocqueville (Oxford and New
York: Oxford University Press, 2001). As Edward Shills notes (“Tradition, Ecology
and Institution in the History of Sociology,” in The Constitution of Society [Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1982], 359), the revival of Tocqueville in sociological
theory owes to Raymond Aron. See Raymond Aron, Les Étapes de la pensée socio-
logique. Montesquieu. Comte. Marx. Tocqueville. Durkheim. Pareto. Weber. (Paris: Gallimard,
1967), and “Tocqueville retrouvé,” Tocqueville Review (1979): 8–23. I was grateful for
the opportunity to hear Cheryl Welch, “Tocqueville between Two Worlds: France
and Algeria,” and Joyce Appleby, “Does It Matter That Tocqueville Got Some
Things Wrong?” at the special colloquium on Sheldon S. Wolin’s Tocqueville Between
Two Worlds: The Making of a Political and Theoretical Life (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2001), held at the Institute of French Studies of New York University on
April 19, 2002.
’ 5
6
The assumption that the state under the ancien régime achieved a high degree
of institutional centralization appears to filter from Tocqueville through Marx to
modern social science, as David Waldner notes in State Building and Late Development
(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1999), 31. See also Theda Skocpol, States and Social
Revolution: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1979), 178–179. For Durkheim and the concept of centralization,
Bertrand Badie and Pierre Birnbaum, The Sociology of the State (Chicago: University
of Chicago Press, 1983), 12; and Charles Tilly, “Reflections on the History of
European State-Making,” 64, in The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed.
Idem (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975).
7
The list is long. For some well known representatives in historical and politi-
cal sociology, see S. N. Eisenstadt, Modernization: Protest and Change (Englewood Cliffs,
N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1966); and Lucian W. Pye and Sidney Verba, eds. Political Culture
and Political Development (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965). See also Seymour
Drescher, Dilemmas of Democracy: Tocqueville and Modernization (Pittsburg: University of
Pittsburg Press, 1968).
8
Michael Mann (The Sources of Social Power [Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
6
Far from rendering his study of the old regime obsolete, Tocqueville’s
encounter with the Ottoman Empire might further our inquiry into the
inner workings of the early modern state while helping us to exorcize
a nineteenth ghost that still stalks the social scientific imagination.
In Search of an Archive
Like the terriers that provoked the real Tocqueville’s exasperated assess-
ment, the registers and loose documents of the Ottoman ancien-
régime archive have disappointed and baffled many researchers. Yet
this seeming unintelligibility or purported opacity is also a modern
affect, a result of the physical and ideological clean sweep of the his-
torical record during the early nineteenth century. The selective purge
of history began well before the French Revolution and would become
part of the colonial project as well. During the Enlightenment, advo-
cates of statistical knowledge tied numerical precision to the very
image of state power.9 Napoleon’s conquests in the Mediterranean
put these radical alterations to collective memory into effect.
Revolutionary engineers transformed the urban plan, beginning with
the razing of ghetto walls; and bureaucrats reshuffled the contents
of archives, from Papal Rome to Mamluk Cairo.10 By the early nine-
teenth century, historians too entered the fray, claiming the archives
Press, 1986] 1:502–503) insists: “Comparison fails . . . Consider for a moment one
obvious additional case, Islamic civilization. Why did the Miracle not occur there? . . .
One distinctive feature of Islam has been tribalism; another, that religious funda-
mentalism recurs powerfully, usually from desert tribal bases . . . The comparative
method has no solution to these problems, not because of any general logical or
epistemological defects it might have but because, in dealing with the problems we
simply do not have enough autonomous, analogical cases.” For one response, see
Rifa'at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State: The Ottoman Empire Sixteenth to
Eighteenth Centuries (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991). For some
important qualifications of the comparative method, see R. Bin Wong, China
Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of the European Experience (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1997).
9
On the “statistical” school of Göttingen University, see Theodore M. Porter,
The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820 –1900 (Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1986), 23. Ausgust Ludwig von Schlözer was an early student of the Ottoman
Empire and an exponent of the new “scientific” method.
10
On the impact on Italy, see Silvana Patriarca, Numbers and Nationhood: Writing
Statistics in Nineteenth-Century Italy (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press,
1996), 8.
’ 7
as their own. Some, most notably Leopold von Ranke, who directed
the Prussian state archives, even busied themselves with reworking
the very raw materials of their craft.11 Already a symbol of the sov-
ereignty of the modern nation state, industrial might and colonial
domination allowed the European archive to subsume the world’s
past.12
If revolutionary fervor remade the past, as Tocqueville’s own dis-
claimer acknowledges (“. . . [W]hen great revolutions are successful
their causes cease to exist and the very fact of their success has made
them incomprehensible”), modern historians have had an even freer
hand in rewriting the history of states that failed to make the late
eighteenth-century transition.13 This is not simply because the his-
toricist rewriting of the Ottoman past came from implacably hostile
and religiously-biased corners of the globe.14 Rather, the distortions
of the Ottoman past, owe first and foremost to the empire’s loss of
sovereignty over the raw materials of memory. Unlike the defeated
colonizing nation-state—such as France, which covered its retreat
from North American in 1763 and two century later from Algeria,15
clutching the fig leaf of its “archives de souverainté”—Ottoman
archival materials were spoils that fell to the great powers or the
new states of the Balkans.16 After World War I, the Ottoman past
11
George G. Iggers, New Directions in European Historiography (Hanover, N.H.:
University of New England, 1984), 19.
12
E.g. Leopold von Ranke, The Ottoman and the Spanish Empires, in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries (Philadelphia: Lea & Blanchard, 1845). This is not simply a ques-
tion of ignoring the world’s history, but effectively of putting “history” itself on sep-
arate and unequal empirical and methodological tracks. Ranke justified very different
methods for classical, biblical, and non-Western history. Iggers, New Directions in
European Historiography, 15–17.
13
Tocqueville, The Old Régime, 5.
14
On the impact of orientalism on Ottoman history, see Suraiya Faroqhi, Approaching
Ottoman history: An Introduction to the Sources (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1999); and for a critique of historicism on Indian historiography, see Dipesh
Chakrabarty, Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Difference (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 2000).
15
While robbing other peoples of their past, European states seem to have con-
sidered the return of archives to be part of the gentleman’s rules of war. Article
22 of the treaty concluding the Seven Years War specified the return of French
administrative documentation. Zenab Esmat Rashed, The Peace of Paris, 1763
(Liverpool: University Press, 1951), 212–229.
16
(smet Binark, ed., Ba{bakanlık Osmanlı Ar{ivi Rehberi (Ankara: Turkish Republic
Ba{bakanlık Devlet Ar{ivileri Genel Müdürlü[ü Osmanlı Ar{ivi Daire Ba{bakanlı[ı,
1992), 14–34.
8
17
The literature continues to reinforce this divide by focusing on either provin-
cial social and political history or on central-state institutional studies. For a sam-
pling of studies that try to surmount this frontier, see Abdul-Karim Refeq, The
Province of Damascus, 1723–1783 (Beirut: Khayats, 1966); Stanford Shaw, Between Old
and New: The Ottoman Empire under Sultan Selim III, 1789–1807 (Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1971); Madeline Zilfi, The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the
Postclassical Age (1600–1800) (Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988); T. Naff and
R. Owen, eds., Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History (Carbondale: University of
Southern Illinois Press, 1977); Robert W. Olson, The Siege of Mosul and Ottoman-
Persian Relations, 1718–43 (Bloomington: Indian University Press, 1975). One of the
most comprehensive studies to date on Ottoman fiscality is Yavuz Cezar, Osmanlı
Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im Dönemi XVIII Yüzyıldan Tanzimat"a Mali Tarih (Istanbul:
Alan Yayıncılık, 1986).
18
Leaving to one side Hamilton A. R. Gibb and Harold Bowen’s outdated
overview of the “Arab provinces,” (Islamic Society and the West: A Study of the Impact
of Western Civilization on Moslem Culture in the Near East, 2 vols. [London: Oxford
University Press, 1950 and 1957]) an introduction to the last generation of eight-
eenth-century studies may to be found in Bruce McGowan, “The Age of the Ayan,”
in An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalcık with Donald
Quataert (Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 637–743; and Robert
Mantran et al., Histoire de l’Empire Ottoman (Paris: Fayard, 1989).
19
A point well taken by Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State, 6.
’ 9
20
Despite casting my net wide, I have scraped only the surface of many of the
new collections in the Ba{bakanlık Ar{ivi in Istanbul. In 1994, I was able to con-
sult the Ottoman judicial court records ({er"iye sicilleri ) for eighteenth-century Mardin
and Diyarbekir that had been transferred to Milli Kütüphane in Ankara. For more
on the local court records found in the Republic of Turkey, see Ahmet Akgündüz
et al., eds., }er "iye Sicilleri, 2 vols. (Istanbul: Türk Dünya{i Ara{tırmaları Vakfı, 1988).
21
Ph.D. diss. Columbia University, 1995.
22
Mehmet Genç, “A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity,” in The Ottoman
Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri Islamo[lu-Inan (Cambridge UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1987), 345–373.
10
23
Jean-Pierre Thieck, “Décentralisation ottomane et affirmation urbaine à Alep
à la fin du XVIIIème siècle,” in Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq,
ed. Mona Zakaria et al. (Beirut: Centre d’Études et de Recherches sur le Moyen-
Orient Contemporain, 1985), 118–168. For an expanded version of this seminal
article as well as the journalistic writings of “Michel Farrère”) see Gilles Kepel, ed.,
Passion d’Orient (Paris: Éditions Karthala, 1992).
24
See Ariel Salzmann, “An Ancien Régime Revisited: Privatization and Political
Economy in the 18th Century Ottoman Empire,” Politics & Society 21 (1993): 393–423.
25
For more on Istanbul’s arbitrage policies, see Halil Sahillio[lu, “The Role of
International Monetary and Metal Movements in Ottoman Monetary History,
1300–1700,” in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F.
Richards (Durham, N.C.: Carolina Academic Press, 1983), 269–304; and }evket
Pamuk, “The Recovery of the Ottoman Monetary System in the Eighteenth Century,”
in Kemal Karpat, The Ottoman Past and Today’s Turkey (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000),
188–211.
’ 11
26
For another example, see Michael Robert Hickok, Ottoman Military Administration
in Eighteenth-Century Bosnia (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1997).
27
See, in particular, Richard van Leeuwen, Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon:
12
The Khazin Sheikhs and the Maronite Church (1736–1840) (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995); Jane
Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[lı (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1997); Thabit A. J. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, and
Murder: The Political Economy of Trade in Eighteenth-Century Basra (Albany: State University
of New York Press, 2001); Dina Rizk Khoury, State and provincial society in the Ottoman
Empire: Mosul, 1540–1834 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Beshara
Doumani, Rediscovering Palestine: Merchants and Peasants in Jabal Nablus, 1700–1900
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995).
28
For Arabic sources, see Reinhard Schulze, “Was Ist Die Islamische Augklärung?”
Die Welt Des Islams 36 (1996): 277–325.
’ 13
29
Dr. Yılmazçelik kindly provided me with a copy of his dissertation, “XIX.
Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır, 1790–1840,” (Fırat University, 1991) 2 vols., dur-
ing my visit to Elazı[/Harput in 1992; given discrepancies in documentation, I cite
from both the dissertation as well as the resulting monograph, XIX. Yüzyılın ilk
Yarısında Diyarbakır, 1790–1840 (Ankara: Türk Tarih Kurumu, 1995).
30
On revisions to the classic notions of sovereignty, see John Ruggie, “Territoriality
and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations,” International
Organisation, 47 (1993): 139–74; and Thomas J. Biersteker and Cynthia Weber, eds.,
State Sovereignty as a Social Construct (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
31
S. N. Eisenstadt, The Political System of Empires (New York: Free Press, 1969),
17–23. For an early critique, see Norman Izkowitz, “Eighteenth Century Ottoman
Realities,” Studia Islamica 16 (1962): 73–94.
14
32
See Abou-El-Haj, Formation of the Modern State.
33
Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie, The Ancien Régime: A History of France, 1610–1774
(Oxford and Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1996), 72, 266–267, 273, 630–635;
Halil (nalcık and Cemal Kafadar eds., Suleyman The First and His Time (Istanbul: Isis
Press, 1993) and Cornell H. Fleischer, “The Lawgiver as Messiah: The Making of
the Imperial Image in the Reign of Süleymân,” In Soliman le Manifique et son temps:
actes du colloque de Paris Galeries Nationales du Grand Palais 7–10 Mars 1990, ed. Gilles
Veinstein (Paris: École des Hautes Études en Science Sociales, 1992), 159–77.
34
The Old Régime, bk. 1, ch. 4.
35
Ibid., 10–11. François Furet (The Old Regime, vol. 1, 99) voices frustration over
Tocqueville’s lack of concern for the wars of religion.
’ 15
36
The Old Régime, 27; bk. 2, ch. 11.
37
Charles Tilly, “State and Counterrevolution in France,” Social Research, 56
(1989): 72–73. For references in The Old Régime: on the influence of Paris over the
provinces, 35, 65–72; on the destruction of the nobility, 27, 72–79; on the cen-
tralization process, 34–38, 65 131, 204; on conscription, 104–105; on the rule of
the intendants, 36–38, 134–135, 180.
38
George Rudé, Europe in the 18th Century: Aristocracy and the Buorgeois Challenge
(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1972), 85, 117–119.
39
For the provincial dimension, see Charles Tilly, The Contentious French: Four
Centuries of Popular Struggle (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1986); and
more recently, Pierre Deyon, L’état face au pouvoir local: un autre regard sur l’histoire de
France (Paris: Editions Locales de France, 1996).
40
George T. Matthews, The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth Century France (New
16
York: Columbia University Press, 1958), 3–16; Isser Woloch, The New Regime:
Transformations of the French Civic Order, 1789–1820 (New York: W. W. Norton, 1994),
114–118; and Eugen Joseph Weber, Peasants into Frenchmen: The Modernization of Rural
France, 1870–1914 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1976).
41
François Furet (Penser la Révolution française [Paris: Gallimard, 1978]) was one
of the main proponents of the Tocquevillean turn; see also Roger Chartier, The
Cultural Origins of the French Revolution, trans. Lydia G. Cohrane (Durhan: Duke
University Press, 1991); compare, George C. Comninel, Rethinking the French Revolution:
Marxism and the Revisionists (London: Verso, 1987).
42
Compare, Theda Skocpol, “Introduction: Bringing the State Back In: Strategies
of Analysis in Current Research” in Bringing the State Back In, ed. T. Skocpol, Peter
Evans, and Dietrich Rueschemeyer (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), 21.
’ 17
While the central government was gradually taking over all the pow-
ers of local authorities and coming more and more to monopolize the
whole administration of the country, some institutions which it had
allowed to survive and even some new ones created by itself tended
to check this centripetal movement . . . it had no very clear idea of the
extent of its power. None of its rights was firmly established or unequi-
vocally defined, and though its sphere of action was already vast, it had
to grope, so to speak in the dark and exercise much prudence.43
Of the features Tocqueville describes, fiscal and administrative decen-
tralization remains one of the more intransigent components of the
old-regime paradox.44 It is ironic that precisely because of an error-
ridden social scientific paradigms on “empires,” decentralization,
along with its attendant state involution, have long taken center stage
in eighteenth-century Ottoman studies. Over the past quarter cen-
tury, new political and socioeconomic investigations have shed the
anachronism and reductionism of functionalist sociology, furnishing
early modern historiography with a far more complex analysis of an
evolving institutional structure.45 Approaching the problem of decen-
tralization from different points on the Ottoman map, Albert Hourani
and Halil (nalcık have been at the forefront of this reassessment of
the old regime.46 Although neither scholar addresses Tocqueville
directly, their creative interpretation of Ottoman realities actually
helps us reconsider his classic account of state formation in the eight-
eenth century. For example, Hourani’s characterization of Istanbul’s
43
The Old Régime, 108–109.
44
See Ian Copland and Michael R. Godley,“Revenue Farming in Comparative
Perspective: Reflections on Taxation, Social Structure and Development in the Early-
Modern Period,” in The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites and the Emergence
of the Modern State in Southeast Asia, ed. John Butcher and Howard Dick (New York:
St. Martin’s Press, 1993), 45–68. Helen Nader, Liberty in Absolutist Spain: The Habsburg
Sale of Towns, 1516–1700 (Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press,
1990); Muzaffar Alam, The Crisis of Empire in Mughal North India: Awadh and the Punjab,
1707–1748 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986); Gabriel Ardant, “Financial Policy
and Economic Infrastructure of Modern States and Nations,” in The Formation of
National States in Western Europe, ed. Charles Tilly (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1975), 164–242; Susan Mann, Local Merchants and the Chinese Breaucracy,
1750 –1950 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1987); and Murat Çizakça, A
Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World and Europe with Specific
Reference to the Ottoman Archives (Leiden, E. J. Brill, 1996).
45
Note Virginia H. Aksan, Locating the Ottomans among Early Modern Empires,”
Journal of Early Modern History 3 (1999): 1–32.
46
Albert Hourani, “The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent in the XVIIIth
Century,” Studia Islamica 8 (1957): 89–122, reprinted in Hourani, A Vision of History
(London: Constable & Co. Ltd., 1961), 35–70; and Halil (nalcık, “Centralization
and Decentralization Ottoman Administration,” in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic
History, 27–52.
18
47
Hourani, “The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent,” 100.
48
See (nalcık, “Centralization and Decentralization.”
49
For representatives of this school, see Huri (slamo[lu-Inan, ed. The Ottoman
Empire and the World Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987). For
a superb new monograph, see Edhem Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth
Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999).
50
Mehmet Genç, “Osmanlı Ekonomisi ve }ava{,” Yapıt 49 (1984): 52–61, Tables
49: (1984): 86–93; Genç “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne Sistemi,” in (ktisat Tarihi
Semineri, ed. Osman Okyar and Ünal Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe Üniversitesi
Yay., 1975), 231–96; and Genç, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda: Devlet ve Ekonomi (Istanbul:
Ötüken, 2000).
’ 19
51
“The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households, 1683–1703: A Preliminary Report,”
JAOS 94 (1972): 438–47.
52
Compare, Philip T. Hoffman, Gille Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal,
“Information and Economic History: How the Credit Market in Old Regime Paris
Forces us to Rethink the Transition to Capitalism,” The American Historical Review
101 (1999): 69–94.
53
Nicholas Henshall, The Myth of Absolutism: Change and Continuity in Early Modern
European Monarchy (London: Longman, 1992), esp. Introduction. See also J. P. Nettl,
“The State as a Conceptual Variable,” World Politics 20 (1968): 559–592. On the
morrow of WWI, Harold J. Laski (Studies in the Problem of Sovereignty [New Haven:
Yale University Press, 1917], 1) rendered it thusly: “Hegelianwise, we cannot avoid
the temptation that bids us make our State a unity. It is to be all-absorptive. All
groups within itself are to be but the ministrants to its life; their relativity is the
outcome of its sovereignty since without it they could have no existence.”
54
Sally Falk Moore, Law as Process: An Anthropological Approach (London: Routledge,
1978), 1–31.
20
55
See Philip T. Hoffman and Kathryn Norberg, eds. Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and
Representative Government, 1450–1789 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994).
56
See Charles Tilly, Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990–1990 (Oxford:
Basil Blackwell, 1990); and Otto Hintze, “The Formation of States and Constitutional
Development: A Study in History and Politics,” in The Historical Essays, ed. Felix
Gilbert (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975), 157–178. Edward W. Soja (“Re-
Presenting the Spatial Critique of Historicism,” in Thirdspace: Journeys to Los
Angeles and Other Read-and-Imagined Places [Malden, MA and Oxford: M.I.T.
Press, 1996], 164–185) takes discursive analysis to task and Hayden White’s approach
in particular, for de-territorialing the same contexts they pretend to historicize.
57
The conflation of so-called empires with the colonizing nation-states of the
nineteenth and twentieth centuries only further obscures the contrasts and similar-
ities between historic polities. See Ariel Salzmann, “Toward a Comparative History
of the Ottoman State, 1450–1850” Archív orientální (Oriental Archive) 66 (1998), spe-
cial issue, Supplementa VIII, 351–66.
58
Compare, William Hardy McNeill, Venice: The Hinge of Europe, 1081–1797
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974) and McNeill, Europe’s Steppe Frontier,
1500 –1800 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1964).
22
European state system until the end of the Seven Years War.59 It
was also an active participant in a very unstable West Asian system
of states.
If the empire was the hinge, then Iran might well be considered
the geopolitical epicenter of early modern European and Asian his-
tory. The protracted post-Safavid civil wars raged intermittently
between 1720 and the final assumption of power by the Qajars after
1790. Spilling over into the Caucasus, Iraq, Central Asia, and India,
the wars of the Iranian succession facilitated Russian and British
expansion in Asia. The Ottoman Empire’s own increasing territor-
ial vulnerability during the last quarter of the eighteenth century was
an indirect product of Nadir Shah’s invasion of the Gulf and Mughal
India and a direct consequence of the new global parameters of
power after the Seven Years War. By the late eighteenth century
the Ottoman Empire had lost a French counterweight to Britain in
the Indian Ocean and to Russia in eastern Europe. Lacking a viable
framework for a West Asian order, it also remained isolated from
the emerging central European coalitions.60
Taking as a given the compound makeup of most premodern
polities and the multiplicity of geopolitical contexts in which such
entities operated, territorial scale becomes a historical, rather than
an institutional, ethnic, or demographic question. Whether we con-
sider the multiple divisions of Poland, the relatively lax colonial
regime in North America or the administrative decentralization in
pre-revolutionary France, new lessons were learned on the relation-
ship of state building and the degree of administrative consolidation
in the last quarter of the eighteenth century. To put the modern
state in historical perspective demands that we recognize that in both
59
See Paul W. Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 1763–1848 (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1994); and Thomas Naff, “The Ottoman Empire and the European
State System,” in The Expansion of International Society, ed. H. Bull and A. Watson
(Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), 143–170.
60
There have been several attempts to come to come to terms with the early
modern “Euro-Asian” (Frank Perlin’s term) and African state system. See, for exam-
ple, Marshall G. S. Hodgson, The Venture of Islam: Conscience and History in a World
Civilization. Vol. 3, The Gunpowder Empires and Modern Times (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1974); C. A. Bayly, Imperial Meridian: The British Empire and the World,
1780–1830 (London: Longman, 1989; Sanjay Subrahmanyam, “Connected Histories:
Notes towards a Reconfiguration of Early Modern Eurasia,” Modern Asian Studies,
31 (1997): 735–762; and Victor Lieberman, “Transcending East-West Dichotomies:
State and Culture Formation in Six Ostensibly Disparate Areas,” Modern Asian Studies
31 (1997): 463–546, among others.
’ 23
France and the Ottoman Empire the first blow to the old regime
was not ideological agitation or mass mobilization but fiscal crises,
induced by prior military commitments.61 Yet both reached an impasse.
Ottoman vulnerability to fluctuations in financial markets was exac-
erbated by a political apparatus soldered by credit. As it began to
retract privileges and reached more deeply into provincial pockets,
Istanbul confronted resistance at many levels.
Summoning the will, neither the Ottoman Empire in 1793 nor
France in 1788, could call upon the political, coercive, administra-
tive or legislative means to enforce it. Even a relatively compact
state, such as France (with a land mass that comprised a territory
smaller than even the Ottoman “core” in Asia Minor) came up short
at the end of the century. Although revolutionary mobilization in
the context of a European-wide war overwhelmed the opposition
and counter-revolution, the gap between the state apparatus and
local government in the Ottoman Empire could not be filled by the
emerging unitary state.
A rereading of the Tocquevillean investigation of the emergence
of modern government and correction for its myopia in matters of
geopolitics and world economy, suggests that the reasons for the
parting of political paths between Europe and Asia can be explained
only by considering the common conundrums of power left by the
nearly simultaneous dissolution of the old regime political order. In
all cases, the transition was rocky and protracted. Some states, Venice
and Poland, to name only two, fell by the wayside. The old regime
sputtered to a close over the course of four decades in the Ottoman
Empire. Interruptions and detours in state programs of fiscal cen-
tralization after 1793 allowed provincial elites and local governments
ample time to regroup and dig in their heels. With its many exposed
territorial edges and the fluid geopolitical situation of the Napoleonic
Wars, provincial powers were able to renegotiate their relationship
with the central state with outside support. In sharp contrast to the
care with which statesmen crafted and restored “Europe,” including
61
Among many studies on this subject, see Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capital-
ism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1990), 180–214; and Frank Perlin, “Financial Institutions and Business Prac-
tices across the Euro-Asian Interface: Comparative and Structural Considerations,
1500–1900,” in The European Discovery of the World and Its Economic Effects on Pre-
Industrial Society, 1500–1900: Papers of the Tenth International Economic History Congress,
ed. Hans Pohl (Stuttgart: Franz Steiner, 1990), 257–303.
24
the offending French state after 1815, was the refusal of the Great
Powers to extend equivalent recognition to Ottoman sovereignty or
to guarantee its territorial integrity. This summary dissolution of the
old-regime order and the expulsion of the Ottomans from the mod-
ern state system were rendered in a convenient euphemism: “The
Eastern Question.”62 In the decades that followed every successful
“exit” from the Ottoman Empire, including that of Greece in 1830
and Egypt after 1840, was mediated by foreign powers who not only
conferred the laurels of sovereignty on local leadership but also mil-
itarily imposed new territorial divisions.63
Tocqueville might have learned much from the Ottoman old regime
had he removed his geographical and cultural blinders. Yet he still
would have been stymied for lack of a suitable lexicon. Indeed, one
of the greatest handicaps for those who attempt comparative inves-
tigations of the early modern world, a world before the crude stamp
of colonialism and the nation-state took its toll on the diversity of
cultures and reduced the variations of political organization, has been
the absence of a common historical vocabulary.
For a handle on the premodern polity, we might borrow Toc-
queville’s own all-embracing notion of the “ancien régime” (or old
regime)64 as a short hand for an amalgamated or, what Michael
Hanagan would call, an “unconsolidated” state found in both Europe
and Asia. If this term allows us to gather disparate facets of poli-
tics, society and economy under one historical umbrella, it also blurs
the distinction between capacities that were dispersed in space. Rather
than coining new terms, it might be best to modify existing termi-
nology to acknowledge the inherent disjuncture of powers within the
62
Compare, Biancamaria Fontana, “The Napoleonic Empire and the Europe of
Nations,” in The Idea of Europe: From Antiquity to the European Union, ed. Anthony
Pagden (Cambridge, U.K. and Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2002),
116–138.
63
Consider, Albert O. Hirschman’s Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in
Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1970).
64
For the history of the term, see D. Venturino, “La Naissance de l’Ancien
Régime,” in The Political Culture of the French Revolution, ed. Colin Lucas (Oxford:
Pergamon Press, 1988), 11–40.
’ 25
65
My sense of the “local” differs importantly from Clifford Geertz’s (Local Knowledge:
Further Essays in Interpretive Anthropology [New York: Basic Books, 1983], 167–234) con-
cept of “local knowledge.”
66
By vernacular I appeal to the relationship between the Latinate languages and
26
Latin during the Medieval period. Contrast, Jenny White, Islamicist Mobilization in
Turkey: A Study in Vernacular Politics (Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2003),
esp. Introduction.
67
Gail Bossenga (“Society,” in Old Regime France, ed. William Doyle [Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 2001], 76) comments that “The legal system of the old
regime had its roots in a far more personal and paternalistic society that failed to
distinguish explicitly between personal status, political rule, and rights of property.”
68
Carter V. Findley (Bureaucratic Reform in the Ottoman Empire: The Sublime Porte,
1789 –1922 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980) stresses the singular impor-
tance of the political household in the formation of the Ottoman state. Although I
would not dispute the importance of networks in this or any political organization,
the specific strategies that I describe in chapter 2 are not uniquely Ottoman. In
fact, I believe that they are constitutive of the institutional changes that are associated
with political modernization. See Gernot Grabher and David Stark, eds. Restructuring
Networks in Post-Socialism: Legacies, Linkages, and Localities (Oxford; New York: Oxford
University Press, 1997).
’ 27
69
Tableau général de l’Empire othoman, divisé en deux parties, dont l’une comprend la légis-
lation mahométane; l’autre, l’histoire de l’Empire othoman (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin
Didot] 1787–1820), vol. 3, 370–371. He translated eyalet as “government”; and the
life-lease (malikâne) becomes “ferme fiscale”.
70
Tocqueville (The Old Régime, 36) recounts a quip, made by John Law to the
Marquis d’Argenson, to the effect that the administration of France rested in hands
of two dozen intendants. For France, see J. F. Bosher, French Finances 1770–1795:
From Business to Bureaucracy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970).
71
In many instances, the reluctance to translate reveals an ideological unease
with the consequences of equivalence rather than a penchant for historical specificity.
See Frank Perlin, “Concepts of Order and Comparison, with a Diversion on Counter
Ideologies and Corporate Institutions in Late Pre-Colonial India,” in Feudalism and
non-European Societies, ed. T. J. Byres and Harbans Mukhia (London: Frank Cass
1985), 87–165.
72
See P. R. Coss, “The Formation of the English Gentry,” Past and Present 147
(1995): 38–64. On attempts to redefine the social sense and reference of these
groups, see Deena Sadat, “Notables in the Ottoman Empire: The Ayan,” (Ph.D.
28
world (e.g., ulema, waqf, timar, sipahi, malikâne, etc.). These terms
should form part of the growing lexicon of world and comparative
early modern history. For general readers, in addition to the requi-
site glossary, I have tried cushioning the use of Ottoman terms with
explanatory context to make them comprehensible or have provided
a rough translation in parentheses. Finally, although I do from time
to time make use of the Islamic calendar for the dating of docu-
ments or manuscripts, for simplicity’s sake as much as to engage the
standard, that is, Western, chronology of political change, I have
employed a single, common-era dating system.
Vocabularies and calendars are some of the more obvious imped-
iments to reconceptualizing the modern political time line. In the
case of Islamic history, there has been a particularly insidious imbal-
ance in the visual representation of the past, a veil over history cre-
ated by the prolific output of nineteenth-century Orientalist painters.73
In searching for a new way to narrate socio-organizational change
in a distant time and place, over the past years I have made a con-
certed effort to locate new visual signposts. The result are the images
that I have inserted within these pages. They should not be regarded
as supplements to my text. Rather, these graphic references are an
integral part of the narrative.
Sandwiched between two attempts to reappraise the historiograph-
ical legacy of Tocqueville, are three sketches of the Ottoman old
regime. In chapter 1, questions of territoriality involve a dialogue
with the cartographer and artist who produced one of perhaps three
large polychromic maps on silk completed in the palace in Istanbul
between 1727 and 1728.74 Laden with both graphic and textual infor-
diss. Rutgers University, 1969); and Engin D. Akarlı, “Provincial Power Magnates
in Ottoman Bilad al-Sham and Egypt, 1740–1840,” in La vie sociale dans les provinces
arabes a l’époque ottomane, ed. Abdeljelil Temimi, vol. 3, 41–56 (Tunis: Publications
du Centre d’Études et de Recherches Ottomanes, Morisques, de Documentation et
d’Informations, 1988).
73
There is a wealth of new studies on this subject following Edward Said’s sem-
inal Orientalism (New York: Vintage, 1979) and Alain Grosrichard, The Sultan’s Court:
European Fantasies of the East (New York: Verso, 1998). See for example, Aslı Çirakman,
From the “Terror of the World” to the ‘Sick Man of Europe’: Images of Ottoman Empire and
Society from the Sixteenth Century to the Nineteenth (New York: Peter Lang, 2002).
74
Topkapı Sarayı Museum Library (TKSK) H. 447. The map reproduced here
is a retouched photograph (by Paula Hible) of the outline published as an large
folded insert by Faik Re{id Unat without commentary in Tarih Vesikaları 1 (1941)
’ 29
mation, this unusual map helps modern visitors explore the dimensions
of premodern territoriality and the historical and logistical meanings
of state domination. By setting the West Asian portions of the empire
amidst the space of Eurasia, it also helps to alternate an under-
standing of the geography of sovereignty that has largely been apprized
from its Mediterranean shores.
Chapter 2’s discussion revolves around the portraits of the revelers
and participants in the pageant that preceded the circumcisions of
the sons of Ahmet III in 1720. As an introduction to the masks of
Ottoman absolutism, these portraits of courtly life contain oblique
references to the actual workings of the state. Evaluating position
and repetition of imagery we might discern the increasing concen-
tration of powers, under the omnipresent figures of the grand vizier
and the bureaucracy, the Sublime Porte. We might also consider the
social characteristics of the first and second estates, such as the
members of the religious establishment, or ulema, the military and
the bureaucracy seated at the table of the sultan. Hidden from
view, however, are the imperial circuits of distribution cemented by
the burgeoning market in life-leases (malikâne mukataât) and the Islami-
cate nexus of finance capitalism that tied the ulema, courtiers, and
gentry-officers to the Christian and Jewish bankers of Istanbul and
the merchants of Marseilles.
In chapter 3, we reexamine one of those infamous tax-farm-
ing registers produced by the clerks of the ancien régime.75 Adjusted
for the parallax of modern expectations,76 this document becomes
an eloquent witness of the fluidity of state-government relation-
ships and administrative changes within the province of Diyarbekir.
Tracing the transfer of title from central-state to provincial actors
reveals the shift in the balance of powers. Meandering notations
across the page serve as an apt metaphor for the “creative destruc-
tion” of revenue contracting that dissolved the administrative bound-
aries between town and country laid down in the early centuries of
the empire. Venal offices bring into relief the vernacular government
of provincial cities and the role of the urban gentry, what Tocqueville
might have called a “petty oligarchy,” in perpetuating rule.
After exploring these facets of the old regime in West Asia, this
study returns to the writings of Alexis de Tocqueville and his Ottoman
contemporary, the religious scholar and pro-reform statesmen, Ahmed
Cevdet Pasha. In our conclusion, we consider one among the many
possible sequels to the old regime in the Ottoman Empire while rais-
ing new questions about the nineteenth-century imperatives and prej-
udices which continue to haunt contemporary social scientific thought.
CHAPTER ONE
ON A MAP OF EURASIA
There was no need to inscribe the words “the realms of the exalted
Ottoman state” (memâlik-i Devlet-i Âliye-i Osmaniye) over the broad areas
of early modern maps of Europe and Asia.1 Literate audiences of
the period would have instantly recognized the outline of Ottoman
Empire. Over the span of four centuries the sultans had reassem-
bled virtually all the territories that had once made up the Roman
Empire in Europe, Africa, and Asia, striking terror and awe in the
hearts of the sovereigns of Christendom. Of its continental territo-
ries, Ottoman Asia remained the empire’s largest—nearly twice the
area of its European lands and roughly half of its entirety.2 Despite
letters, treatises, and reports by travelers, merchants, and an occa-
sional natural scientist, Western scholars remained largely ignorant
of Ottoman economic, political, and social geography. Beyond the
sliver of terra firma bordering the Mediterranean and its major trad-
ing towns and highways, Dutch and Italian maps of the day filled
in these lacunae with classical and biblical references.3 Even an
1
In addition to well-known maps by Gerard Mercato (1512–94) and Jodocus
Hondius, Sr. (1563–1612), see Willem Blaeu’s 1617 maps of the “Turcicum Imperium,”
in Joan Blaeu’s widely circulating Atlas Major (1662); reprint, introduced and edited
by Johan Gross (London: Random House, 1997). In 1668, a copy of the Atlas was
presented to the Ottoman court by Justin Collier, the Dutch ambassador, and trans-
lated by Ebu Bekir b. Bahram al-Dimi{ki in 1685 (Ekmeleddin (hsano[lu, Ramazan
}e{en, M. Serdar Bekar, Gülcan Gündüz, and A Hamdi Furat, eds., Osmanlı Co[rafya
Literatürü [Istanbul: IRCICA, 2000], vol. 1, 111).
2
Donald Edgar Pitcher (An Historical Geography of the Ottoman Empire from the Earliest
Times to the End of the Sixteenth Century with Detailed Maps to Illustrate the Expansion of
the Empire [Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1972], 134) estimates the empire’s land surface in
1606 to have been 1,071,000 square miles, including vassals. See also Andreas
Birken, Die Provinzen des Osmanischen Reiches (Wiesbaden: Beihefte zum Tübinger Atlas
des Vorderen Orients, 1976) and logistical maps in Rhoads Murphey, Ottoman
Warfare, 1500–1700 (London: University of London Press, 1999). For comparison
with the Roman Empire’s frontiers along the Danube, Euphrates, and Rhine, C. R.
Whittaker, Frontiers of the Roman Empire: A Social and Economic Study (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 1994).
3
Ir. C. Koeman, Joan Blaeu and His Grand Atlas: Introduction to the Facsimile Edition
of “Le Grand Atlas,” 1663 (Amsterdam: Theatrum Orbis Terrarum, 1970), 84.
32
4
Stato Militare dell’Impero Ottomanno (Amsterdam and Hague: Herm. Uytawerf &
Franc. Changuion, 1732; reprint, Graz-Austria: Akademische Druck Verlagsanstalt,
1972), vol. 1, 9–10, insert. On Ebübekir b. Behrâm’ın Nusretü’l (slâm’s (ad-Dimaski)
maps, see G. J. Halasi-Kun, “The Map of ‘}eki-i Yeni Felemenk Maa (ngiliz’ in
Ebubekir Dimi{ki’s Tercüme-i Atlas Mayor,” Archivium Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 51–70.
On Marsigli, see John Stoye, Marsigli’s Europe, 1680–1730: The Life and Times of Luigi
Ferdinando Marsigli, Soldier and Virtuoso (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1994).
5
“La pluspart des lieux marqués sur ma carte entre Kandahar & l’Indus, je les
dois a la geographie Turque, conpilée par Kiatib-shelebi, sous le titre de Gehan-
Numa (le miroir du Monde),” confesses Jean-Baptiste Bourguignon D’Anville in his
Eclaircissements Geographiques su La Carte de l’Inde (Paris: De l’Imprimerie royale, 1753),
20. For D’Anville’s place in the early cartography, Leo Bagrow, History of Cartography,
2d ed., revised and enlarged by R. A. Skelton (Chicago: Precedent Publishing, 1985),
185–86.
6
TKSK H. 447. The map measures 210 cm. × 150 cm. Faik Re{id Unat (Tarih
Vesikaları 1 [Istanbul, 1941], 160 insert) published an outline of it without com-
mentary, which I have reproduced in Fig. 2; passing mention is made by Ahmet
Karamustafa in J. B. Harley and David Woodward, eds., Joseph E. Schwartzberg,
Gerald R. Tibbetts, and Ahmet T. Karamustafa, assoc. eds., The History of Cartography
vol. 2 pt. 1, Cartography in the Traditional Islamic and South Asian Societies (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1992), 225; Thomas D. Goodrich, “Old Maps in the
Library of the Topkapı Palace in Istanbul,” Imago Mundi 45 (1993): 120–33. Professor
Goodrich calls TKSK H. 447 “the first modern political and economic Ottoman
map.” He attributes the Iranian geography to a map of Iran found in J. B. Homan’s
Neuor Atlas, a copy of which is also in the Topkapı Sarayı Library (H. 2740).
According to Goodrich, another copy of the same map, albeit lacking coloring, is
found in the Istanbul Archeological Museum. I am extremely grateful to him for
his attention to this chapter and for sharing photographs of a third copy, found in
the Kriegsarchiv in Vienna.
Fig. 2 An outline drawing of a map produced in the palace of Ahmed III. One of several
colored copies, the original is found in the Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum Library (H. 447). After
Faik Re×id Unat, ed. Tarih Vesikalaræ 1 (1941): 160–161. By permission of the Türk Tarih
Kurumu and Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
33
7
Generally, Abdulhak Adnan Adivar, Osmanlı Türklerinde Ilım (Istanbul: Maarif
Matbaasi, 1943). Katib Çelebı or Haci Halifa Mustafa ibn Abullah was familiar
with Mercator’s Atlas Major (Bagrow, History of Cartography, 210–211). On the impact
of European science on the Ottomans during the first half of the eighteenth cen-
tury, see Ekmeleddin (hsano[lu et al., eds., Osmanlı Co[rafya Literatürü, vol. 1, 111–43.
In 1732, (brahim Müteferrika published Katib Çelebı’s (Haci Halifa Mustafa b.
Abdullah) Kitab-ı Cihânnüma (Constantinople). On the state of Islamic cartography,
see also David A. King, World Maps for Finding the Direction and Distance of Mecca:
Examples of Innovation and Tradition in Islamic Science (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999); and
Thomas D. Goodrich, The Ottoman Turks and the New World: A Study of Tarih-i Hind-i
Garbi and Sixteenth-Century Ottoman Americana (Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1990). For
sixteenth-century European maps of the Ottoman Empire, see Jerry Brotton, Trading
Territories: Mapping the Early Modern World (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1998).
8
See Turgut Kut and Fatma Türe, eds., Yazmadan Basmaya: Müteferrika, Mühendishane,
Uskudar (Istanbul: Yapı Kredi, 1996); William J. Watson, “(brahim Müteferrika and
Turkish Incunabul,” JAOS 88 (1968): 435–41; Halasi Kun, “(brahım Müteferrika”
(A 5, pt. 2: 896–900; (brahim Müteferrika published Katib Çelebı’s Kitab-ı Cihannuma
in 1732. On the exchange of information between Europe and the empire, Virginia
H. Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace: Ahmed Resmi Efendi, 1700–1783
(Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995), 34–42.
9
There is a Ptolemaic conception of Asia at work; note book 7 of Ptolemy’s
Geography (Lennart Berggren and Alexander Jones, Ptolemy’s Geography: An Annotated
Translation of the Theoretical Chapters [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000]).
See also Karl J. Schmidt, An Atlas and Survey of South Asian History (Armonk, N. Y.
and London: Missouri Southern State College, Sharpe: 1995), 19; and Serpil Ba[cı,
34
Without betraying the secrets behind its commission, much less the
patron’s political aims, the map still resonates with imagined delib-
erations in vizierial chambers concerning history, technology, and
territorial ambitions. The mottled colorings of provinces and terri-
tories contrast with one another in soft blue, red and yellow while
the pale green seas appeal to the aesthetic inclination of the viewer,
as well as enhancing the map’s topographical and regional character.10
It is not improbable that map celebrated the empire’s newest mil-
itary conquests. The armies of Sultan Ahmed III (r. 1703–1730) and
his son-in-law, Grand Vizier Nev{ehirli (brahim Pasha (r. 1718–1730),
were victorious in the lands of what had been their chief Muslim
rival, the Shi’i Safavid shah of Iran. Occupying the cities of Tabriz
and Hamedan, the sultan had annexed the provinces of Azarbayjan,
Kermanshah, and Luristan. The members of imperial council, the
divan, undoubtedly debated the czar’s strategy in the Volga region.
Looking east beyond “Turan”—the great middle ground between
the empires—they might have contemplated the status of the coun-
try of Tibet (already under Manchu rule), which is profiled in upper-
right corner.
In two large cartouches that obscure part of Arabia and Upper
Egypt, the cartographer puts his purposes in more modest terms:
The principal aim and object of this map is to render a pictorial and
written account in accordance with the principles of the science of
geography, the clime, or rather the continent of, Asia; its countries,
towns, territories, seas, mountains and rivers, from the felicitous seat
of the abode of the kingdom, the most excellent Istanbul, eastward to
the lands of India. And within this expanse [its objective] is [also] to
capture to the best of our ability, the breadth and length of the set-
tlements, seas, countries, and lands over which the exalted Ottoman
state rules . . . to record in picture and text those of the land of Iran
otherwise known as “Acem” and those of [the lands of ] Turan, in the
vicinity of the Oxus river, as well as [the region of ] Transoxiana . . .
where today reside the Uzbek, Ça[atay, Turks, Turkmen and Tatar
and other tribes and clans . . .11
The scale of this enterprise appears to intimidate the cartographer.
He seems unsure of his ability to do justice to the many kingdoms
and lands that he has been commissioned to depict. The legends,
commentary, and captions written over the map are more than orna-
ment. They enhance his images with historical explication, orienta-
tion, and institutional relief, compensating in words for the limits of
his visual knowledge. In deference to his sovereign, Istanbul figures
prominently in the upper right of his canvas, but the cartographer
cannot but pay greater homage to Mecca and Medina. He embel-
lishes the symbols for the Holy Cities of Islam and places them at
the nexus of many lines of trade and pilgrimage. Giving short shrift
to the birthplace of the Prophet Muhammad, he apologizes for his
omission of much of the Arabian peninsula by reminding his view-
ers that the areas inhabited by the beduins are so large that “it takes
six and half months to travel the length and breadth.”12
Words allow him to provide potentially useful logistical informa-
tion beyond the empire. He offers the approximate distances between
Georgia and the Black Sea, the length, in farsakhs (farshakh/parasang,
a league or 3 miles) of the province of Azarbayjan. He inscribes
over the Persian Gulf the number of days, thirty-two, it takes mon-
soon winds to speed a dhow from the Makran coast to Oman.
11
The author is presently preparing a translation of the entire text with a detailed
analysis of the map for publication. “Hakki buyurulmaya ki, asitane-i saadet a{iyane-i
belde tayibbe-i Konstantiniye’den ibtidaen olup, {arkta memâlik-i Hindustan’a var-
inca mesafe-i mübeyinde vaki memâlik ve bilad, yerar, bihar, cibel, ve enhar kaide-
i fenn-i co[rafya üzre resm ve tahrir olunmak i{ bu haritada umde ve maksud ul-asl
oldu[una binaen, iklim-i Asya tabir olunur kitaya dahil ve mesafe-i merkumede vaki
olup, tulen ve arzen daire-i Devlet-i Âliye-i Osmaniye’nin hakim oldu[u yer ve bihar
ve memâlik ve bilad al’el-kader ül’[ittikan ?] tersim ve te{kil olunup, Iran-Zemin
tabir olunur Acem dahi bitamam ma’dud resm ve tahrir ve Nehr-i Ceyhun’un
mavaresinde Turan Zeminde . . . hala mesken-i tava’if-i Özbek ve Ça[atay ve Türk
ve Türkmen ve Tatar ve sair kaba’il ve a{a’ir meskunları olan memâlik-i Maave-
raünnehir . . .”
12
“(klim-i Ceziret’ül-Arap, bu iklim on iki kisma taksim olunup . . . bu iklimin
mesafesi ve devri altı buçuk ay mesafe olup, i{ bu haritada tamamen resmine mesaha
olma(ma)[la, Mekke-i Mükereme ve Medine-i Münvvera vaki oldu[u memleket-i
Hicaz’dan ve bâdiyeden bir miktar resm iktifa olunmu{tur . . .” For more on the
Hijaz during this period, see Abdulrahman S. M. Alorabi, “The Ottoman Policy
in the Hejaz in the Eighteenth Century: A Study of Political and Administrative
Developments, 1143–1202.” (Ph.D. diss., University of Utah, 1988).
36
13
See W. Bartold, An Historical Geography of Iran, trans., Svat Soucek (Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1984). Khorasan is rendered as the “clime” (iklim) of
“Hirandan,” though correctly identified by its cities of Herat, Nishapur, and the
site of the tomb of Imam Rıza (i.e., Mashhad). These and other mistakes lead me
to suspect that a painter, rather than a geographer, supervised and executed the
final versions.
14
Henri Lefebvre, The Production of Space (Oxford: Blackwell, 1994), 33. For different
views on the historical meaning of space, see Edward Soja, Postmodern Geographies:
The Reassertion of Space in Critical Social Theory (London: Verso, 1989); Robert D. Sack,
Human Territoriality: Its Theory and History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1986); and David Harvey, “On the History and Present Conditions of Geography:
An Historical Materialist Manifesto,” Professional Geographer 3 (1984): 1–11.
37
and deserts of the Hindu Kush, and along the riverine systems from
the Nile to the Amu Darya.
This is a landscape of classical proportions, drawn in accordance
with modern, that is, mimetic, cartographic standards. As such, it is
not simply another, less familiar way of framing the Ottoman Empire
on a world map. Rather, by inserting this European and Asian state
in a contiguous meridian of state from the Mediterranean eastward,
it emphatically conveys to modern viewers the cultural artifice of
“Europe” and of a “natural” division between Orient and Occident.
Ottoman Asia is not external to but hinges on an intersecting polit-
ical geography. It serves as a check on European expansion in the
Balkans and continues to shape and constrain the ever-changing bal-
ance of power among the great powers of continental Christendom
that emerged in the aftermath of the Treaty of Utrecht in 1714.
Sitting out the exhausting series of dynastic squabbles of the first
half of the eighteenth century, not only that of Spain but of Poland
(1731–35) and Austria (1740–48), the Ottoman military, though weak-
ened, held its forward line in “Europe,” to the consternation of both
the Habsburgs and Russians.
Territorially, however, the gravitational center of this map is not
the Ottoman Empire per se. Rather, by dint of its rendering of
Ptolemaic Asia, it emphasizes Iran, the center of an unfolding drama
whose impact would reverberate globally. The collapse of the Safavid
state in 1722 with an invasion of its former Afghan vassals was not
simply another example of the fragility of dynastic regimes and the
tentative nature of the territorial state. As the opening salvo in a
series of devastating civil wars (resumed in 1747 and again in 1779),
or what should properly be called the Iranian Wars of Succession,
it also proved the tenacity of the Safavid political system, for the
ensuing seven decades of conflict invariably brought forward a claimant
from among the dynasty’s former tribal confederates. Although the
initial phases of the war drew in Iran’s more powerful neighbors,
the Ottomans and Russians, the partition of Iran would not hold.
Moreover, between 1739 and 1741, the Iranian wars fatefully spilled
across the Indian Ocean.15
15
Virginia Aksan’s comments (“Ottoman War and Warfare, 1453–1812,” in War
in the Early Modern World, ed. Jeremy Black [London: University College London
Press, 1999], 147–76) on the military constraints of the empire serve as a much
needed antidote to a rather sweeping and overly simplistic assessment of West Asian
38
Edges of Empires
eds., Caucasia between the Ottoman Empire and Iran, 1555–1914 (Wiesbaden: Reichert,
2000).
18
Aktepe, 1720–1724 Osmanlı-Iran Münasebetleri, 19–32; J. C. Hurewitz, The Middle
East and North Africa in World Politics, 2 vols. (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1975), 1:65–74; and Ernest Tucker’s excellent analysis, “The Peace Negotiation of
1736: A Conceptual Turning Point in Ottoman-Iranian Relations,” TSA Bulletin 20
(1996): 16–37.
19
P. Kahle, “China as Described by Turkish Geographers from Iranian Sources,”
Proceedings of the Iran Society, vol. 11 (London, 1940), 48–59.
20
On the ill-fated negotiations initiated by Kalmyks with the Russians, the
Manchu, and the Ottomans between 1704 and 1714, Michael Khodarkovsky, Where
Two Worlds Met: The Russian State and the Kalmyk Nomads, 1600–1771 (Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1992), 139, 153–55.
21
Sultan Ahmad II (r. 1691–1695) toyed with the idea of joint action against
the Safavids in 1691. However, the Uzbek dynasty itself was fractured. Undoubtedly
this is why the cartographer describes Balkh as a “part of Khorasan [which] has
many rulers and towns. Currently, it is under the rule of Uzbeks.” See also
J. Audrey Burton, “Relations between Bukhara and Turkey,” IJTS 5 (1990–91):
83–103; and on the arrival of the Uzbek ambassador, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi
(1099 –1116/1688–1704), ed. Abdülkadir Özcan (Ankara: Türk Tarihi Kurumu
Basımevi, 2000), 222.
22
On Ottoman claims to the caliphate and relations with the Mughals, see
Naimur Rahman Farooqi, Mughal-Ottoman Relations: A Study of Political and Diplomatic
Relations between Mughal India and the Ottoman Empire, 1556–1748 (New Delhi: Idarah-i
Adabiyat-i Delhi, 1989), 6–71.
40
23
Halil (nalcık, “Imtiyâzât,” EI 2 3: 1178–1189. Ottoman missions to Europe
included Russia (1722–23, 1740–42), Austria (1719, 1730, 1748, 1757–58), France
(1721), and Poland (1730, 1757–58) (Faik Re{it Unat, Osmanlı Sefirleri ve Sefaretnameleri
[Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1987]). See also (brahim Müteferika’s description of the
different forms of government in Europe, Usûl’ûl-Hikem fî Nizâmü’l-Umem, ed. Adel
}en (Ankara: Türkiye Diyanet Vakfı, 1995); and the extremely interesting, though
anonymous, “dialogue” between a Christian and Muslim officer from this period,
published by Faik Re{id Unat, “Ahmed III devrine ait bir Islahat Takiri,” Tarih
Vesikaları 1 (1941): 107–21. For examples of reports and analysis of individual mis-
sions during the first half of the eighteenth century, see Beynun Akyava{, ed.,
Yirmisekiz Çelebi Mehmed Efendi’nin Fransa Sefâretnâmesi (Ankara: Türk Kültürünü Ara{tırma
Enstitüsü, 1993), and Mubadele—An Ottoman Russian Exchange of Ambassadors, anno-
tated and translated by Norman Itzkowitz and Max Mote (Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1970). For an overview of Ottoman-European diplomatic practice,
see Maria Pia Pedani’s meticulous study, In Nome del Gran Signore: Inviati Ottomani a
Venezia della Caduta di Costantinopoli alla Guerra di Candia (Venezia: Deputazione Editrice,
1994) and Aksan’s An Ottoman Statesman.
24
Charles of Sweden sought Ottoman help as early as 1709. Karl A. Roider, Jr.,
Austria’s Eastern Question, 1700–1790 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1982), 18.
25
France, too, dreamed of dividing the empire according to L. Darperon, “Le
Grand Dessein sécret de Louis XIV,” Revue de Géographie 1 (1877): 435–61.
41
between 1728 and 1741, Versailles’ regard for its ally, the Sublime
Porte, may have waxed and waned over the second half of the cen-
tury. Nonetheless, the Porte’s military presence in the heart of Europe
as much as the prospect of furthering Russian territorial gains at
Ottoman expense in the East, remained a sobering thought for
Vienna. Peace held with Istanbul from 1740 to 1769.26
The increasing frequency of diplomatic exchange was bound to
have an impact on the way Ottoman statesmen saw other powers,
as well as on the way both sides came to view the still illusive con-
cept of territorial sovereignty during this period.27 Certainly the bat-
tle cry in Europe to “throw the Turk completely out of Europe,”
remained as loud as ever and, invoking the spirit of the Crusades,
still enlisted the support of Pope Clement XII, who levied a special
tithe on Church properties within Austria itself in 1737. Yet depend-
ing on the context, one might discern that the Realpolitik between
states and the succession crises contributed to an overall muting of
traditional religious and sectarian overtones in favor of respect for
dynastic claims.28 Continued Ottoman negotiations with the last
Safavids (Tahmasp II [r. 1722–29] and 'Abbas III [r. 1729–36]),
although without issue, did have their political motivation. By be-
grudging recognition to both the Sunni Afghan and Tahmasp Kuli
Khan, the Afshar regent who would declare himself sovereign under
the name of Nadir Shah in 1736, indeed, condemning both as rebels,
Ottoman statesmen clung to the fiction of the Safavid dynastic
legitimacy.29
Rather than trying to reconcile the semantic drift among histori-
cal accounts, diplomatic formulae, religious treatises, and internal
26
For more on Habsburg-Ottoman relations, see Roider, Austria’s Eastern Question.
And for an introduction to Russia’s “Iran question,” see Muriel Atkin, Russia and
Iran, 1780–1828 (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1980).
27
Note the utterly contradictory reports of the extravagant Ottoman embassy to
Vienna in 1718. Roider, Austria’s Eastern Question, 59.
28
Much to the unhappiness of Austria, the Ottomans took their inclusion in
intra-European diplomacy quite seriously: they tried to mediate the Austrian war
of succession and sent a protest to Maria Theresa’s after her decision to expel the
Jews of Prague whom she charged with collusion with Prussia. Roider, Austria’s
Eastern Question, 77, 95.
29
Tucker, “The Peace Negotiation of 1736,” 22. Decades of war would even-
tually prod Istanbul into formal recognition of Nadir Shah. But the Safavids con-
tinued in effigy: the last puppet shah, Ismail III, would die in 1773. See J. R. Perry,
“The Last Safavids, 1722–73,” Iran 9 (1971): 59–70.
42
30
Navigation and shipping terminology had long been received multiple influences.
For an example of the hybridity of geographic idiom, see the treatise of Bartınlı
(brahim Hamdi (Cengiz Orhonlu, “XVIII Yüzyılda Osmanlılarda Co[rafya ve
Bartınlı (brahim Hamdi’nin Atlası,” Tarih Dergisi 10 (1959): 115–40). (brahim uses
such locutions as the “European frontier,” (“hudud-i Avrupa”) and translates the
papal state in Rome with the term “hükümet” (reserved in Ottoman parlance for
the enclaves ruled by Kurdish dynasties). This comparison, beyond the bounds of
the present work, must take as its point of departure Katib Çelebi’s Kitab-ı Cihânnüma:
see Gottfried Hagen, Ein osmanischer Geograph bei der Arbeit. Entstehung and Gedankenwelt
von Kâtib Çelebis Cihânnümâ. Ph.D. diss., Freie Universität Berlin, 1996).
31
For a critique of the work of Friedrich Ratzel, the political geographer of
Bismarck’s Germany, see Lucien Febvre’s La terre et l’évolution humaine. introduction géo-
graphique à l’histoire (Paris: Renaissance du Livre, 1922). The literature on sovereignty
is also relevant. For an introduction to European thought on the subject of sover-
eignty, see Jens Bartelson, A Genealogy of Sovereignty (New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1995).
32
The legend makes no mention of the Russian occupation or the the Afghan
43
siege of Isfahan. The cartographer does volunteer logistical information and in the
case of Shirvan, described by its sixteenth-century Ottoman name, Demürkapı,
admits that it has been redivided into seven military districts. (“. . . nevah-i Demürkapı
Devlet-i Âliye canibinden zabt olundukta yedi sanca[a taksim olunmu{, sancakları
bunlardır, }abur, Da[istan, Dahti, Be{ker, Dur, Berrak, Destab).” As for Georgia,
we are finally told that it is “half under the rule of the Ottomans.” (“Memâlik-i
Gürcüstan bilada tahrir oldu[u üzre bu memleketlerin nisf miktarı öteden berü
Devlet-i Âliye"e tâbi ve nisf-i ahri Acem’e tâbi olup, Acem’e tâbi olan yerleri Tiflis
ve Kaht eyaletleri bir kaç tümen ‘ad olunur . . .”) For military appointments to
Tabriz, Erdilan, Genc (Ganja), Rumiye, and Mara[a, see Fahameddin Ba{ar, Osmanlı
Eyâlet Tevcihâtı (1717–1730) (Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1997).
33
Pitcher, An Historical Geography, 140.
34
Over the face of the map, in the vast, uncharted regions of the Kara and
Kızıl Kum, he simply writes, “The tribes of the Tatar, Turk, Turkmen, Kalmyk
and Kalamak, Mongol, Kazak, and other nomadic peoples.”
35
Bartınlı (brahim Hamdi (Orhonlu, “XVIII Yüzyılda Osmanlılarda Co[rafya,”
139) attempts to use terminology with a certain consistency: e.g., “empire” applies
to Spain while Austria and Venice are distinguished with the term clime (iklim). As
on our map of Eurasia, the parts that make up such “compound” polities are often
recognized as having a separate historical identity, such as the “country (memliket)
of al-Andalus” or bundles of semi-sovereign countries, such as the Germanys, “mem-
liket-i Cermanya.” See also Henry Kahane, Reneé Kahane, Andreas Tietze, The Lingua
Franca in the Levant: Turkish Nautical Terms of Italian and Greek Origin (Urbana: University
of Illinois Press, 1958), 594–97.
44
Asia might strike the viewer as overtly menacing.36 Yet in this sim-
ple and telling act, the Ottoman cartographer betrays one of the
great secrets of absolutism. True borders—fully surveyed, mapped,
and continuously demarcated with ditches, fences, and walls, and
monitored by a network of stations and fortresses—were still a rar-
ity and would remain so even in western Europe until the nine-
teenth century. Part of the bluff and bluster of colonizers, they were
hardly relevant to imperial claims or the actual disposition of colonies,
including those in the Americas.37 Thus, despite the obsessive reflection
on the territorial state after the Peace of Westphalia (1648), on many
fronts, including that between Russia and the Ottomans, the cessa-
tion of conflict often meant retaining whatever territories and fortresses
were in hand, in accordance with the venerable Roman principle of
uti possidetis.38
Recently, some exceptions had appeared.39 An unusual clause in
the Treaty of Karlowitz (1699) which dictated the formation of a
commission to survey and physically define a border stretching the
entire length of the Croatian-Ottoman frontier to an exactitude of
two hours from either side, did constitute, as Rifa’at Abou-El-Haj
notes, an “unambiguous declaration of territorial integrity.”40 But
even the foremost scientists of the day, Count Marsigli being one of
36
For reflections on the ideology of expansion, see Pal Fodor, In Quest of the
Golden Apple: Imperial Ideology, Politics, and Military Administration in the Ottoman Empire
(Istanbul: Isis Press, 2000).
37
Compare the gradual formation of frontiers between New World empires in
Richard White, The Middle Ground: Indians, Empires, and Republics in the Great Lakes
Region, 1650–1815 (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991);
and their claims to sovereignty, in Anthony Pagden, Lords of the World: Ideologies of
Empire in Spain, Britain and France, c. 1500–1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1995), 78.
38
The territoriality of the state remained of utmost concern for political thinkers
in Europe of the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries. For more on Hobbes,
Spinoza, Locke, and von Pufendorf, among others, see Quentin Skinner, The Foundation
of Modern Political Thought, vol. 2 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978);
Stoye, Marsigli’s Europe, 101; and Roider, Austria’s Eastern Question, 44–59.
39
Compare Peter Sahlins, Boundaries: The Making of France and Spain in the Pyrennees
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989), 274–75; Stoye, Marsigli’s Europe,
181–83.
40
Rifa"at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj,” The Formal Closure of the Ottoman Frontier in
Europe,” JOAS 89 (1969): 467; see also Stefanos Yerasimos, Questions d’Orient: Frontiers
et Minorités des Balkans au Caucase (Paris: Editions de Decouverte, 1993), and Gunter
E. Rothenberg, The Austrian Military Border in Croatia, 1522–1737 (Urbana: University
of Illinois Press, 1960). For important new studies on Ottoman borders, see Dariusz
45
43
Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 41–77. }erban Constantin, “La
suzerainetée Ottomane a l’égard des pays roumains dans le contexte des relations
internationales Européenes (Sec. XVI–XVII),” Tarih Dergisi 32 (1979): 211–18; M. M.
Alexandrescu-Dersca Bulgaru, “L’approvisionnement d’Istanbul par les Princi-
pautés Roumaines au XVIIIe siecle: Commerce ou Requisition?” RMMM 66 (1992):
73–78; compare Bistra Cvetkova, “Les celep et leur rôle dans la vie économique des
Balkans à l’époque ottomane (XVe–XVIIIe s.),” in Studies in the Economic History of
the Middle East, ed. M. A. Cook (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970), 172–93.
44
A. W. Fisher, “Les rapports entre l’Empire ottoman et la Crimée: L’aspect
financier,” CMRS 13 (1967): 368–81, notes the increased dependency of the khanate
because of the curtailment of the Crimean slave trade in the first decades of the
century; see also Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 1–37.
45
Abou-El-Haj, “The Formal Closure,” 472–74. For French mediation between
Poland and the khans, see Gilles Veinstein, “Les Tatar de Crimée et la seconde
élection de Stanislas Leszczynski,” CMRS 11 (1965): 24–92.
46
For an Ottoman perspective, Münir Aktepe, ed., Mehmed Emni Beyefendi Pa{a"nın
Rusya Sefareti ve Sefaret Namesi (Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1989), 52.
47
47
Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Tarihi, vol. 4, pt. 2, 253–58; Abdallah Laroui, The History
of the Maghrib: An Interpretive Essay (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977),
262–70.
48
See Charles Frazee, Catholics and Sultans: The Church and the Ottoman Empire,
1453–1917 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983). Gregory L. Bruess
(Religion, Identity, and Empire: A Greek Archbishop in the Russia of Catherine the Great
[Boulder: East European Monographs, 1997], 61) notes that Russia insisted on the
dissolution of the Zaporozhian Cossak Host in 1774, precisely to subsume this
“nation” under the larger banner of religion. On the religious frontier in another
setting, see Richard M. Eaton, The Rise of Islam and the Bengal Frontier, 1204–1760
(Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993), 228–67.
49
Conversion to Islam in Albania was a continous process, according to Ferit
Duka, “XV–XVIII. Yüzyıllarda Arnavut Nüfusunun Islamla{ması Süreci üzerine
Gözlemler,” Ankara Üniversitesi Osmanlı Tarihi Ara{tırma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 2
(1991): 63–72. On Bosnia, see Michael Robert Hickok, Ottoman Military Administration
in Eighteenth-Century Bosnia (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1997); and on Lebanon, Richard van
Leeuwen, Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon: The Khazin Sheikhs and the Maronite
Church (1736–1840) (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995).
48
50
D. Sourdel, “Khal fa,” EI 2 4: 946.
51
Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 22; Halil Sahillio[lu, “Dördüncü Murad’in Ba[dad
Seferinin Menzilnamesi,” Belgeler 2 (1965): 1–36.
52
Antoine Abdel Nour, “Le Réseau Routier de la Syrie Ottomane (XVIe–XVIIIe
siècle),” Arabica 30 (1983): 174.
53
TKSK MS. H. 446 (1762–1763) is a record of the post-stations (menzilhane)
and the distances between them in “hours” from Uskudar to Mecca. According to
Marsigili (Stato Militare, vol. 1, 9) “The Turks measure distances between places by
the hours that a horse can traverse at a good pace which corresponds to three
Italian miles.” Murphey (Ottoman Warfare, 65) estimates a typical 4–5 “hour” day
of riding to average 22 kilometers. For general orientation, see Suraiya Faroqhi,
Pilgrims and Sultans: The Hajj under the Ottomans (London: I. B. Taurus, 1994), 156–62.
On the Egyptian caravan, Jane Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt:
The Rise of the Qazada[lı (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 134.
49
54
Halil (nalcık, “The Socio-Political Effects of the Diffusion of Fire-Arms in the
Middle East,” in War, Technology and Society in the Middle East, ed. V. J. Parry and
M. E. Yapp (London: Oxford University Press, 1975), 203–6.
55
See Hathaway, The Politics of Households; and Kenneth M. Cuno, The Pasha’s
Peasants: Land, Society, and Economy in Lower Egypt, 1740–1858 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1992).
56
For a useful model, see G. William Skinner, “Cities and the Hierarchy of
Local Systems,” in The City in Late Imperial China, ed. Skinner (Stanford: Stanford
University Press, 1977), 275–351. For an attempt to estimate the empire’s eigh-
teenth-century population, see Bruce McGowan, “The Age of the Ayan,” in An
Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalcık with Donald Quataert,
Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 666; Following Daniel Panzac,
(“La population de l’Empire ottoman et de ses marges du XVe au XIXe siècle: bib-
liographie (1941–80) et bilan provisoire,” Revue de l’Occident Musulmane et e la Méditerranée.
31 [1981]: 119–37) and others, McGowan estimates the population of the empire
as a whole, circa 1800, to have been between 25 and 32 millions, with all parts
of the empire, but particularly the Asian provinces, lagging behind growth in west-
ern Europe.
50
57
Suraiya Faroqhi, “Camels, Wagons, and the Ottoman State in the Sixteenth and
Seventeenth Centuries,” IJMES 14 (1982): 523–39, 553–54; and F. Taescher, Das
Anatolische Wegenetz nach Osmanischen Quellen, 2 vols. (Leipzig: Mayer & Müller, 1924–26).
58
Cengiz Orhonlu, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[undaunda Derbend Te{kilâtı (Istanbul: Eren,
1984), 128–33. Additionally, many of the Euphrates ports were fortified with heavy
artillery according to (nalcık, “The Social-Political Effects of the Diffusion of Fire-
Arms,” 214.
59
For an appreciation of local dynamics, see Tom Nieuwenhuis, Politics and Society
in Early Modern Iraq (The Hague-Amsterdam: Studies in Social History of the
International Institute of Social History, 1982); Percy Kemp, Territoire de l’Islam: le
monde vu de Moussoul au XVIII e siècle (Paris: Sindbad, 1982); Hala Fattah, The Politics
of Regional Trade in Iraq, Arabia and the Gulf, 1745–1900 (Albany: State University of
New York Press, 1997); and Dina Rizk Khoury, State and Provincial Society in the
Ottoman Empire Mosul, 1540 –1834 (Cambridge; New York: Cambridge University
Press, 1997).
60
To be exact, it took 408.5 hours for the route between Uskudar and Tabriz.
51
Suleymaniye Library, Esad Efendi MS. 2362 pt. 8 (n.d.) Anonymous, Menzilname,
folios 157–59. Special envoys and couriers traveled at a much faster pace. For
example, the Ottoman ambassador who left the capital on 29 May 1724 arrived
in Yerevan on 17 June (Aktepe, 1720–1724 Osmanlı-Iran Münasebetleri, 31–32).
61
In contrast to the eyalet, Marsigli (Stato Militare dell’Impero Ottomanno, 9) trans-
lates “vilayet,” credibly, as “all large countries” (“tutti i paesi vasti”).
62
“Vilayet-i Kürdistan: vilayet-i Hürmüz’den ibtida Malatya ve Mara{ hududunda
müntehi olur; {imalisi Revan, cenubisi Musul ve Irak-ı Arab’dır. Ve asl-ı Cebel-i
Kürdistan Acem diyar[ın?]da Fars ve Kirman hududundan [ahiz ?] edüp, Van’a
ve Erzurum cebeline ula{ır. Cebel-i azime silsile ve muttasıldır. Bazi yerleri sancak
hükümet ve ocaklık ünvanlarıyla Âli Osman’a tâbi, bazi yerleri serhad-ı }ah-ı Acemde
vaki olmu{tur. On sekiz miktar vilayet ‘ad olunur.”
63
From the perspective of the state, this was a zone of economic marginality,
as Lattimore in Inner Asian Frontiers notes, but it also featured a symbiosis between
pastoralism and agriculture. On this point, see A. M. Khazanov, Nomads and the
Outside World (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984).
52
64
Martin van Bruinessen, “The Ottoman Conquest of Diyarbekir and the
Administrative Organization of the Province in the 16th and 17th Centuries,” in
Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, ed. Van Bruinessen and Hendrik Boeschoten (Leiden: E. J.
Brill, 1988), 13–28. The 1555 treaty between the Ottoman sultan and the Kurdish
}erif Han of Bitlis (Nazmi Sevgen, “Kürtler V,” Belgeler 3 [1968]: 70) defined a
hükümet as a hereditary fief that included fortresses, cities, villages, and fields; Hezarfen
Hüseyin Efendi (Sevim Ilgürel, ed., Hezarfen Hüseyın Efendi Telhisü’l Beyan fi Kavanin-i
Al-i Osman [Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 2000], 132) qualifies hükümet with such expres-
sions as “free from accounts” and “possessor of all its fruits” (“mefruzü’l-kalem ve
maktü’ül-kadem olup evbab-ı mahsulatı her ne ise hakimleri mutasarrıfdır”). The
legend gives the same breakdown for Diyarbekir that we find in the mid-seven-
teenth century: five hükümet (Cezire, E[il, Genç, Palu, and Hazzo)and eight ocaklıks
(Sa[man, Kulp, Mihrani, Tercil, Atak, Pertek, Çapakçur, and Çermik) that carried
no hereditary rights. See also, Chèref-ou’ddîne. Chèref-Nâmeh ou Fastes de la Nation
Kourde, trans. François Bernard Charmoy (St. Pétersbourg: l’Académie Impériale des
Sciences, 1873). Naturally, this did not guarantee autonomy in later centuries, as
Kanûn-nâme-i Sultânî li’ Azîz Efendi: 'Aziz Efendi’s Book of Sultanic Laws and Regulation:
An Agenda for Reform by a Seventeenth-Century Ottoman Statesman (ed. and trans. Rhoads
Murphey [Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1985] makes clear; for the eight-
eenth century, see Mouradgea D’Ohsson Tableau général de l’Empire othoman, divisé en
deux parties, dont l’une comprend la législation mahométane; l’autre, l’histoire de l’Empire otho-
man (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin Didot] 1787–1820), vol. 7, 299; and DA
IV:45.
65
Jean Bodin (On Sovereignty: Four Chapters from the Six Books of the Commonwealth,
ed. and trans. Julian H. Franklin [Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992],
56) defines sovereignty juridically and institutionally, not territorially, asserting that
“the first prerogative of sovereignty is to give law to all in general and to each in
particular, the latter part refers to privileges, which are in the jurisdiction of sov-
ereign princes to the exclusion of all others.”
53
and cavalry officer to carry out the cadastration of each eyalet and
component sancak of the empire. These tomes were prefaced by a
kanunnâme, a codification or compendium of customary law and impe-
rial statute as well as relevant Islamic codes, describing the obliga-
tions and rights of subjects.66 Although the types of taxation changed
over the centuries, they overlay a fundamental relationship between
sovereign and subject established with the first local administrative
codes.67 Preparation for war in the eighteenth century still entailed
mustering a wagon load of registers, from texts of treaties, tax receipts,
the numbers of taxable households, provincial complaints and reme-
dies, to the timetable of installments from tax contractors and the
tribute from Egypt. With such guides, paymasters and commanders
could find the names of officials in exile, determine sources of cash
and raw material, and reference important security matters.68
Like a register, the cartographer’s legend guides us on another
tour of West Asia. Keenly aware of logistics, to the extent knowl-
edge and page permit, his commentary is driven by the adminis-
trative space of the Caucasus, Iran, and Central Asia. Like an
architect, he rebuilds the empire itself, beginning with the “inner”
(Kütahya, Karaman, and Sivas) and then the “outer” (the Mediter-
ranean coast and Cyprus) provinces of Anatolia. His geographical
narrative scans the limits of Anatolia on the Euphrates (the province
of Ayintab); then, after a detour through Syria, it returns to the
66
For the classical cadastral system, see Ömer Lûtfi Barkan, “Research on the
Ottoman Fiscal Surveys,” in Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East,” ed.
M. A. Cook (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970), 163–71; D. A. Howard, “The
Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial Registry (Defter-i Hakanî): Mid-
Fifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries,” Archivum Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 213–30;
and H. (nalcık, “Suleiman the Lawgiver and Ottoman Law,” Archivum Ottomanicum
1 (1969): 117–24. Most tahrir were carried out in the sixteenth century and are now
housed in the Ankara’s Tapu Kadastro Kuyûd-ı Kadime Ar{ivi and the Ba{bakanlık
Osmanlı Ar{ivi in Istanbul. For a late European example, Dariusz Kolodziejczyk,
“The Defter-i Mufassal of Kaminiçe from ca. 1681: An example of Late Ottoman
Tahrir, Reliability, Function, Principles of Publication, JOS 13 (1993): 91–98; and
for early-eighteenth-century Tabriz, Zarinebaf-Shahr, “Tabriz under Ottoman Rule,”
115–20.
67
See H. (nalcık, “Osmanlılarda Raiyyet Rüsûmu,” Belleten 23 (1959): 575–600.
68
Feridun M. Emecen, “Sefere Götürülen Defterlerin Defteri,” in Prof. Dr. Bekir
Kütüko[lu’na Arma[an, ed. Mübahat Kütüko[lu (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakültesi Basımevi,
1991), 241–68. For a register that fell into enemy hands before Vienna in 1783,
see H. G. Majer, Das osmanische “Registerbuch der Beschwerden” (}ikayet Defteri) wom Jahre
1675: Österreichische Nationalbibliothek Cod. Mixt. 683 (Wien: Verlag der Österreichi-
schen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1984).
54
69
Compare the cartographer’s list of twenty-one provinces with figures and dates
found in Halil (nalcık, The Ottoman Empire: The Classical Age, 1300–1600 (New York:
Praeger Publishers, 1973), 104–18 and Ayn-i Ali Efendi (Tayyib Gökbilgin, ed.,
Kavânin-i Âl-i Osman der Hülâsa-i Mezâmin-i Defter-i Divân [Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi,
1979].) D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 7, 278–79, speaks of twenty-six “government
generaux” (malikâne-i miri ) and eighteen hundred “ressorts de justices (nahiye)” in the
Middle East.
70
“Eyalet-i Kütahya ibtidaen talu gökse Devlet-i Âliye ebed-i kıyyamdan buna
gelince merâ’at olunan kaide-i mustahsına üzre avn ve inayet-i hak ile feth ve teshiri
müyesser olan memâlik taksim olundukta be[lerbe[li[e . . . bir memleket eyalet itibar
olunup, ol eyalet dahi nice elviye itibar olunageldi[ine binaen, eyalet-i Kütahya on
yedi sancak itibar olunmu{tur.”
71
Cemal Kafadar, Between Two Worlds: The Construction of the Ottoman State (Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1995), 8–9, 76–77; compare, Isenbike Togan, Flexibility
and Limitation in Steppe Formations: The Kerait Khanate and Chinggis Khan (Leiden: E. J.
Brill, 1988).
55
72
Hüseyın Efendi Hazarfen (Hezarfen Hüseyın Efendi Telhısü’l Beyan fı Kavanin-i Al-i
Osman, ed. Sevim Ilgürel [Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 2000], 143) distinguishes between
salaried and nonsalaried forces. On the janissaries generally, see (. H. Uzunçar{ılı,
Osmanlı Devleti Te{kilatından Kapıkulu Ocakları. Acemi Oca[ı ve Yeniçeri Oca[ı (Ankara:
TTK Basımevi, 1943); for Cairo, André Raymond, Le Caire des Janissaires: L’apogée
de la ville ottomane sous Abd al-Rahman Katkhuda (Paris: CNRS Editions, 1995).
73
Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 16–42; and H. (nalcık, “Military and Fiscal
Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 1600–1700,” Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1980):
283–337.
56
(miri ) and disputed the onus of taxation.74 With or without the hair-
splitting treatises of the ulema, Ottoman administrators took care to
ease the incorporation of Muslim elites with special inducements,
ranging from high position, the total exemption from bureaucratic
accounts and fiscal surveys (such as the tribal hukumet), and split-rent
agreements (malikane-divani ) to large military estates (zeamet) and long-
term tax-farming leases.75
The cartographer credits Ottoman administration with remaining
faithful to the original territorial divisions of the Syrian lands, trans-
forming such units as the province of Palestine (cund-i Filistin) and
other realms into full-fledged Ottoman eyalet.76 He is not entirely
accurate. Once the dust had settled after early sixteenth-century con-
quests, the addition of an outer tier of provinces (vilâyat-ı saire), stretch-
ing from the eastern Black Sea southward through the Fertile Crescent,
prompted Istanbul to reconsider its overall organization of procure-
ment and recruitment. Provincial boundaries were drawn and redrawn.
The initial land surveys in the provinces of Syria, Kurdistan, east-
ern Anatolia, and Iraq dedicated a greater share of land to crown
lands and viziers’ estates (hass-ı hümayun) than in western Anatolia.77
74
Colin Imber, Ebu"s-su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition (Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997), 135–37. For the debates, see Baber Johansen, The Islamic Law on Land
Tax and Rent (London: Croom Helm, 1988).
75
Irène Beldiceanu-Steinherr, “Fiscalité et formes de possession de la terre arable
dans l’Anatolie Preottomane,” JESHO 19 (1976): 234–322; I. Beldiceanu-Steinherr,
“Malikâne,” EI 2 4: 227–28; Abdul-Rahim Abu-Husayn, “The Iltizam of Mansur
Faraykh: A Case Study of Iltizam in Sixteenth Century Syria,” in Land Tenure and
Social Transformation in the Middle East, ed. Tarif Khalidi (Beirut: American University
in Beirut Press, 1984), 249–256. For an exhaustive study of one of the provinces
where the Muslim elite went over to the Ottoman side, see M. Mehdi Ilhan, Amid
(Diyarbakır) 1518 Tarihli Defter-I Mufassal (Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 2000).
76
The legend explains that each “cund ” ( jund [in Arabic, a military division or
army]) should be “regarded as a separate realm (memliket)”: “Beyan iklim-i }am.
Bundan akdem }am iklimine mutasarrıf olanlar }am ikliminin muhit oldu[u memâ-
liki be{ kısma taksim edüp, her kısmına cund tesmiye her cundi bir memlekete izafe
etmi{lerdir. Mesala cund-i Filistin, cund-i Ardan, cund-i Dima{k, cund-i Hums, cund-i
Kanasrin gibi. Ve cund dedikleri kurradır. Yani bir kita memâliktir ki med-
den kasabat ve kariye mü{temil ola. Devlet-i Âliye ebed-i kiyyam Osmaniye iklim-i
}am’a mutasarrif oldukta resm-i sabik üzre bir kaç eyalet itibar eylemi{lerdir.) For
the original divisions, see Ruth Kark, “Mamluk and Ottoman Cadastral Surveys
and Early Mapping of Landed Properties in Palestine,” Agricultural History 71 (1997):
46–70.
77
Ömer Lutfi Barkan, “Timar,” (A 12, pt. 1: 288. In comparison to Western
Anatolia, where 26 percent of cultivated lands was set aside for imperial domains
and more than half (56 percent) was held by individual cavalry officers, in Diyarbekir,
57
81
On peasant flight during and after the Celalis, see Wolf-Dieter Hutteroth and
Kamal Abdulfattah, Historical Geography of Palestine, Transjordan and Southern Syria in
Late 16th Century (Erlangen: Frankische Geographische Ges., 1977); Mustafa Akda[,
“Celali Isyanlarından Büyük Kaçgunluk, 1603–1606,” Tarih Ara{tırmaları Dergisi 2
(1964): 10ff.; and MMD 7637:2 (1596); and William Griswold, Political Unrest and
Rebellion in Anatolia 1000–1020/1591–1611 (Berlin: Klaus Schwarz Verlag, 1983).
The proportion of ruined (harabe) timar in the tahvil register KK 493, dating from
1694 is particularly high in the urban districts of Amid (22 percent) and Ergani (33
percent).
82
Both (brahim Metin Kunt (The Sultan’s Servants: The Transformation of Ottoman
Provincial Government, 1550 –1650 [New York: Columbia University Press, 1983],
68–69) and Rifa"at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion and the Structure of Ottoman
Politics [Istanbul: Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut te Istanbul, 1984],
43) note a shift in control over appointments over full-time salaried positions toward
central state elites. Karl Barbir (Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 1708–1758 [Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1980]) observes a parallel process in the province within
the capital city during the late seventeenth century and early eighteenth century to
centralize apparatus in the provincial cities under civil and military authority. At
the same time, a great many other duties devolved upon personnel. For an extreme
example of privatization, note the case of poststations and couriers: Colin J. Heywood,
“The Ottoman Menzilhane and Ulak System in Rumeli in the 18th Century,” in
Türkiye’nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Tarihi (1071–1920), ed. Osman Okyar and Halil Inalcık
(Ankara: Hacetepe Üniversitesi, 1980), 182–84.
83
Lütfi Güçer, XVI–XVII Asırlardan Osmanlı Imparatorlu[unda Hububat Meselesi ve
59
Daltaban Mustafa Pasha to put down a revolt in Baghdad. (I thank Dina Khoury
for bringing MMD 3134:126 to my attention). For one of many examples during
the era of Nadir Shah, see MMD 10,168:252 (grain at the rate of, 30 sa[ akçe per
kile or 22,112.5 kuru{ in 1725–26); and Cengiz Orhonlu, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda
unda {ehirçilik ve Ula{ım Üzerine Ara{tırmalar ((zmir: Ege Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi
Yayınları, 1984), 130; and according to Stephen H. Longrigg (Four Centuries of Modern
Iraq [Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1925], 144), in July 1741, a single order to
restock the Baghdad fortress stipulated 36,150 Istanbul kile of wheat and 150,000
Istanbul kile of barley. See also Robert W. Olson, The Siege of Mosul and Ottoman-
Persian Relations, 1718–43 (Bloomington: Indian University Press, 1975).
89
Aktepe, 1720–1724 Osmanlı-Iran Münasebetleri, 18–20, 33–34.
90
For the life and times of Nadir Shah, see Ernest S. Tucker, “Religion and
Politics in the Era of Nâdir Shâh: The View of Six Contemporary Sources,” (Ph.D.
diss., University of Chicago, 1992).
91
Münir Aktepe, ed., }em"dâni-zâde Fındıklı Süleyman Efendi Tarihi Mur"i"t-Tevarih
(Istanbul: Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi Yayınları, 1978) vol. 1A, 113–14.
61
goods across West Asia. Of the highways for commerce and pil-
grimage etched on the map, in 1722 the Ghalzai horsemen took the
one traversing the belly of southwest Asia. From their native Kandahar
they headed toward Khorasan, where they encountered another
Safavid vassal, the Abdali; from there they rode through Kirman
toward Isfahan, the Safavid capital and chief trading entrepot.92
The Ottomans, too, in response to the Russian occupation of the
silk-producing regions of the Caspian, launched their first and sec-
ond offensives through the heart of the East-West trading network.
The second front targeted the northern part of the silk route, which
ran from Tabriz, Iran’s second-most-important trading center, toward
Anatolia and Syria. Nadir Shah was more audacious still. After test-
ing Ottoman defenses in Iraq, he launched a full-scale assault on
the West Asian trading system. In 1738–39 he marched on Delhi;
the new Iranian monarch and his Afghan ally and looted the impe-
rial treasury of the Mughals. Upon his return in 1741, he targeted
the coffee-rich state of Oman.
Unabashedly material motives did not, however, necessarily obtain
the desired results. The war derailed older trading linkages rather
than securing new ones, often driving away merchants and sending
shock waves through commodity markets as far west as Aleppo.93
Chaos within Iran forced merchants to change their routing while
ships avoided the Safavid ports in the Gulf. Conflict choked the
lucrative Iranian silk trade through the Ottoman Empire. Indeed,
Ne{e Erim’s study of the customs post at Erzurum demonstrates how
quickly this conflict extinguished the trans-Anatolian silk trade, which
once accounted for approximately 2 percent of imperial revenues
and furnished an estimated two thousand bales of Caspian silk yearly
for domestic and international markets.94 Mediterranean consumers
soon found alternatives to Iranian goods in Bursa, Syria, Bengal, and
92
The route, including the number of hours between Baghdad and North India,
may be found in an undated but, plausibly eighteenth-century manuscript, Suleymaniye
Library, Esad Efendi MS. 2362 pt. 8, folios 157r–159v.
93
Katsumi Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e siècle d’Alep à Marseille
(Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et d’Ètudes sur le Proche Orient Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985), 22–24.
94
Ne{e Erim, “Onsekizinci Yüzyılda Erzurum Gümrü[ü.” (Ph.D. diss., Istanbul
University, 1984), 13–14. Generally on this trade, see Rudolph P. Matthee, The
Politics of Trade in Safavid Iran: Silk for Silver, 1600 –1730 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1999).
62
95
E. Hertzig, “The Iranian Raw Silk Trade and European Manufacture in the
XVIIth and XVIIIth Century,” Journal of European Economic History 12 (1990): 73–91;
Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East, 196.
96
See Stephen Dale, Indian Merchants and Eurasian Trade, 1600–1700 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1994).
97
There is an enormous literature on the subject, beginning with André Raymond,
Les commerçants au Caire au XVIIIe siècle, 2 vols. (Damas: Institut Français de Damas,
1973–74). For some interesting, recent additions, see Cheryl Ward, “The Sadana
Island Shipwreck,” in An Historical Archaeology of the Ottoman Empire: Breaking New
Ground, ed. Uzi Baram and Lynda Carroll (New York, Boston, Dordrecht, London,
Moscow: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers, 2000), 185–202; and Colette Establet
and Jean-Paul Pascual, Ultime voyage pour la Mecque: Les inventaires apres dèces de pélerins
morts a Damas vers 1700 (Damas: Institut français d’études arabes de Damas, 1998).
98
(dris Bostan, “Rusya"nin Karadeniz"de Ticaret Ba{laması ve Osmanlı (mpara-
torlu[u (1700–1787),” Belleten 59 (1995): 362.
99
Daniel Goffman, Izmir and the Levantine World, 1550–1650 (Seattle: University
of Washington Press, 1990), 10–11, 36–38, 69–70. For later developments, see
Necmi Ülker, “The Rise of Izmir, 1688–1740” (Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan,
1974); Daniel Panzac, “International and Domestic Maritime Trade in the Ottoman
Empire during the 18th Century,” IJMES 24 (1992): 189–206.
100
On Bursa, see Halil (nalcık, “Bursa and the Commerce of the Levant,” JESHO
63
3 (1960): 131–47. Haim Gerber, Economy and Society in an Ottoman City: Bursa,
1600 –1700 ( Jerusalem: Hebrew University Press, 1988). On Syria and Iraq, see
Amnon Cohen, Economic Life in Ottoman Jerusalem (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1989); André Raymond, “The Ottoman Conquest and the Development of
the Great Arab Towns,” IJTS 1 (1979–1980): 84–101; and Antoine Abdel Nour,
Introduction à l’Historie Urbaine de la Syrie Ottomane, (Beirut: Publications de l’Université
Libanaise, 1982), 174.
101
Panzac, “International and Domestic Maritime Trade,” 193.
102
Leila T. Erder and Suraiya Faroqhi (“The Development of the Anatolian
Urban Network During the Sixteenth Century,” JESHO 23 [1980]: 284) speak of
great development. For a detailed study, see Usha M. Luther, Historical Route Network
of Anatolia (Istanbul-Izmir-Konya) 1550’s to 1850’s: A Methodological Study (Ankara: TTK
Basımevi, 1989); see also Suraiya Faroqhi, Towns and Townsmen of Ottoman Anatolia:
Trade, Crafts, and Food Production in an Urban Setting, 1520–1650 (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1984).
103
EA II:201.
104
Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant, 21–27. During the period of recovery,
cotton cloth represented 9.4 percent of cargo shipped from the Levant to France.
105
Orhonlu, Osmanlı Imparatorlu[u"nda Derbend Te{kilâtı, 60–63; and Orhonlu, Osmanlı
(mparatorlu[unda {ehirçilik, 13–16, 48, 71–73, 78–79.
64
106
For the complete works in Turkish, see Mehmet Genç, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda:
Devlet ve Ekonomi (Istanbul: Ötüken, 2000).
107
(nalcık, “Imtiyâzât,” 1180–85; Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance, 194–95;
Genç, “Osmanlı Imparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi,” in V. Milletlerarası Türkiye
Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, ed. Hakkı Dursun Yıldız, (nci Enginün, and Emine
Gürsoy Naskalı (Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1990), 13–25; Zeki Arıkan, “Osmanlı
(mparatorlu[unda (hracı Yasak Mallar,” in Prof. Dr. Bekir Kütüko[lu Arma[an, ed.
Mübahat S. Kütüko[lu (Istanbul: Istanbul Edebiyat Fakültesi Basımevi, 1991),
279–306; Rhoads Murphey, “Conditions of Trade in the Eastern Mediterranean:
An Appraisal of Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Documents from Aleppo,” JESHO
33 (1990): 35–50.
108
Mehmet Genç,”Osmanlı (ktisadî Dünya Görü{ünün (lkeleri,” Sosyoloji Dergisi
Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi, 3rd ser. 1 (1989): 176–85; idem, “Osmanlı Dev-
leti’nde (ç Gümrük Rejimi,” in Tanzimat’tan Cumhuriyet’e Türkiye Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul:
(leti{im Yayınları, 1985) 3:786–89; idem, “Osmanlı Ekonomisi ve }ava{,” Yapıt 49
(1984): 52–61, 86–93; see also Lütfi Güçer, “XVI–XVIII Asırlarda Osmanlı
Imparatorlu[u’nun Ticaret Politikası,” Türk Iktisat Tarihi Yıllı[ı, no. 1 (Istanbul:
Istanbul Üniversitesi (ktisat Fakültesi Türk (ktisat ve (ctimaiyat Tarihi Ara{tırmaları
Merkezi, 1987), 1–55; and Roger Owen, The Middle East in the World Economy,
1800 –1914 (London: Methuen, 1981), 1–23. On “private control” of the Istanbul
customs, see Sarı Mehmed Pasha, Ottoman Statecraft: The Book of Counsel for Vezirs and
Governors of Sarı Mehmed Pa“a (Nasa'ih ul-vuzera ve’l-umera), ed. and trans. W. L. Wright
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1935), 107. For the income in the first half
of the eighteenth century from the Istanbul gümrük, see Ahmet Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dönemine Osmanlı Maliyesi (Istanbul: Dergâh Yayınları, 1986), 95, 232, 237, 269, 274.
65
109
On the trail of epidemics that accompanied expanded trade linkages, see
Daniel Panzac, La peste dans l’empire ottoman: 1700 –1850 (Leuven: Peeters, 1985),
105–33. Between 1717 and 1788, the tax-farm on the transit gümrük station in Tokat
(mukataa-yı amediye) rose tenfold in nominal terms from 6.6 million akçe to 60 mil-
lion akçe, according to Mehmet Genç, “A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-
Century Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity,” in The
Ottoman Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri (slamo[lu-(nan (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1987), 363.
110
Mehmet Genç, “Osmanlı Devleti’nde (ç Gümrük Rejimi,” in Tanzimat’tan
Cumhuriyet’e Türkiye Ansiklopedisi, vol. 3, 786–89; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken,
84–85.
111
On the American coffee trade, see Edhem Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul in
the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999), 75–76. For one perspective on elite
consumption, see Fatma Müge Göcek, Rise of the Bourgeoisie; Demise of Empire: Ottoman
Westernization and Social Change (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996).
112
Panzac, “International and Domestic Maritime Trade,” 191; Halil (nalcık,
“Osmanlı Pamuklu Pazarı, Hindistan ve Ingiltere, Pazar Rekabetinde Emek Maliyetinin
Rolü,” Orta Do[u Teknik Üniversitesi Geli{me Dergisi Özel Sayısı (1979–80): 1–66. Some
sense of the scale of the interstate transit trade may be gauged from the dispute
between the Austrian Paolo and the merchant Abdul Rahman over 13,500 kuru{ in
cash and coffee in 1763–64 (DA III:44); as for the scale of domestic commerce,
see the complaint brought by an Ottoman Jewish merchant to the Diyarbekir judge,
Seyyid Halil, in 1748–49 concerning a robbery in Cizre, involving coffee, nutmeg,
cloves, as well as Baghdadi and Indian cloth (DA I:150). For estimates of the early
nineteenth century, see E. Wirth, “Aleppo im 19. Jahrhundert—ein Beispiel für
Stabilität und Dynamik spätosmanischer Wirtschaft,” Osmanistische Studien zur Wirtschafts-
und Sozialgeschichte. Im memoriam Van o Bo“kov, ed. Hans Georg Majer (Wiesbaden:
Otto Harrassowitz, 1986), 187–206.
66
113
Zarinebaf-Shahr, “Tabriz under Ottoman Rule,” 165. Thabit A. J. Abdullah,
Merchants, Mamluks, and Murder: The Political Economy of Trade in Eighteenth-Century Basra
(Albany, State University of New York Press, 2001), 49.
114
D.B}M 694. The textiles entering Baghdad in 1692, included both Iraqi and
Indian goods. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 58.
115
On the Diyarbekir route, the peak season for traffic to and from the Gulf
was autumn (August, September, and October) in the early nineteenth century. KK
5594 (1823–24).
116
Masters, Origins of Western Dominance, 113. Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 78.
On the routes through Syria, Abdel Nour, “Le Réseau Routier de la Syrie Ottomane
(XVIe–XVIIIe siècle),” Arabica 30 (1983): 174.
117
For highlights of the reintegration of Basra into the empire between 1695 and
1701, see Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 106, 141–59.
118
From Baghdad, the route proceeded toward Kerkuk (8 days), Mosul (4 days),
Mardin (8 days), Urfa (7 days), and Aleppo (5 days), totaling 33 days in the 1750s.
Bartholomew Plaisted, The Desert Route to India Being the Journals of Four Travellers by
the Great Desert Caravan Route between Aleppo and Basra, 1745–51. Narrative of a Journey
from Basra to Aleppo in 1750 (London: Hakluyt Society, 1929), 102–3. See also Ne{e
Erim, “Trade, Traders, and the State in Eighteenth-Century Erzurum,” New Perspectives
on Turkey 5 (1991): 123–50.
67
119
New ships and barges capable of carrying seventy persons and their cargo
were built at the dockyards of Payas near Ayıntab and at Birecik. Orhonlu, Osmanlı
(mparatorlu[unda }ehircilik ve Ulasım, 128–33. Güzelbey and Yetkin, Gaziantep {eri’i
Mahkeme Sicilleri, 5, 12–13, 94. In 1733, officials at Payas (Ayıntab’s port) were
ordered to build 123 new boats, each at a cost of 297 kuru{ 33 para. The rowers
and dümenci were to be paid 98 kuru{ per year.
120
Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 50–60. Masters, The Origins of Western Dominance,
118; Longrigg, Four Centuries of Modern Iraq, 79. Yusuf Halaço[lu, XVIII. Yüzyılda
Osmanlı (mparatorlu[u’nun (skan Siyaseti ve A{iretlerin Yerle{tirilmesi (Ankara: TTK Basımevi,
1991), 46–62, 78–80, 113. Cevdet Türkay, Ba{bakanlık Ar{ivi Belgeleri’ne göre Osmanlı
(mparatorlu[u’nda Oymak, A{iret ve Cemaâtlar ((stanbul: Tercüman, 1979), 809.
68
form of hegemony over much of its Asian and at least part of its
North African empire for most of the eighteenth century. The
Ottomans, in contrast to the Safavid shahs, possessed both an organ-
izational structure tempered by time and the indigenous sources of
silver needed to retrofit this structure.121 These relatively favorable
circumstances cushioned the state against the Mediterranean-wide
financial crises after 1695 and the sea change in the global mone-
tary system at the end of the New World silver boom.122 The con-
traction of precious metal stocks resulting from the technological
impasse in South and Central American mining overcame the Old
World’s reluctance to mine domestically.123 The Ottomans, as did
their neighbors in Central and Eastern Europe, began to rework
older mines in the Balkans and staked new claims in Anatolia, at
Gümü{hane, Keban, Ergani, and Espiye.124
Ottoman reserves never approached those of Russian Siberia, but
they did provide self-sufficiency.125 After a century of currency manip-
ulation, chipped and debased coinage, domestic supply finally sufficed
for the imperial mints: of some twenty-five to forty metric tons of
metal mined between the 1730s and 1760s, 80 percent was turned
into coins. Even as the grand vizier rallied the troops for war in
western Iran, he was completing the final phases of an overhaul of
coinage. The new standards for Ottoman specie emulated the most
stable currencies of oceanic commerce. Thus the new silver kuru{
121
See Willem Floor and Patrick Clawson, “Safavid Iran’s Search for Silver and
Gold,” IJMES 32 (2000): 345–68. Consider too, the global impact of the changes
in funding state debt: Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital
Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 46. Jack
Goldstone, Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World (Berkeley: University of
California Press, 1991); for the critique, Sanjay Subrahmanyam, “Precious Metal
Flows and Prices in Western and Southern Asia, 1500–1750: Some Comparative
and Conjunctural Aspects,” Studies in History 7 (1991): 79–105.
122
Halil Sahillio[lu (“The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements
in Ottoman Monetary History, 1300–1700,” in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval
and Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F. Richards [Durham, N.C.: Carolina Academic
Press, 1983], 269–304, 288–89) notes that Ottoman mines between 1640 and 1687
were inactive because of the abundance of silver arriving from the Americas. On
early modern monetary history, see also }evket Pamuk, A Monetary History of the
Ottoman Empire (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2000); and generally, Pierre
Vilar, A History of Gold and Money, 1450–1920 (London: Verso, 1984).
123
Ian Blanchard, Russia’s ‘Age of Silver’: Precious-Metal Production and Economic Growth
in the Eighteenth Century (London: Routlege, 1989), 169–70.
124
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 161–63.
125
Sahillio[lu, “International Monetary and Metal Movements,” 286–90.
69
(from the German word groschen, also known as piaster) was mod-
eled on the Dutch thaler and fixed at the rate of 120 akçe. The
Venetian ducat served as the measure for a new series of gold coins.126
Despite opportunistic intervention in monetary markets, particularly
to boost receipts into the treasury, Ottoman administrators gener-
ally let the value of gold fluctuate in the market.127 The result of
this monetary policy was positive: a long period of stability for the
Ottoman monetary system and the kuru{, the principal unit of gov-
ernment accounting and market transactions.
Although one might interpret these reforms as evidence of an
increased conformity or even incorporation into the European mar-
ket, Ottoman policy continued to defy the conventional wisdom of
mercantilism.128 There were advocates of controlling imports, and
voices among the Ottoman elite who saw danger in the imbalance
in trade relationships with India, to be sure.129 However, the idea of
restricting imports or dissolving the institutions for procurement of
basic urban and military supplies remained anathema to the empire’s
administrative ideology: “provisionism,” as Mehmet Genç defines it,
prioritized urban consumption in the empire’s major administrative
cities. To assure levels of comfort for the elite as well as to promote
social peace among Istanbul’s working classes and the poor, it was
necessary to maintain a steady supply of goods and raw materials
from luxuries to food staples, regardless of cost or source.130
Although provisionism may well have affected the ability of domestic
manufacturers to compete with certain types of goods, particularly
126
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 161–66. Sahillo[lu, “The Role
of International Monetary and Metal Movements,” 289.
127
Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul, 113–19, 199.
128
For the debate, see Halil (nalcık, “The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects
of the Ottoman Economy,” in Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, ed.
M. A. Cook (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), 207–18, and Fernand Braudel,
“L’Empire Turc est-il une économie-monde?” in Mémorial Ömer Lûtfi Barkan (Istanbul:
Bibliothèque de l’Institut Français d’Études Anatoliennes d’Istanbul, 1980); compare
Sanjay Subrahmanyam, “Of Imârat and Tijârat: Asian Merchants and State in the
Western Indian Ocean, 1400 to 1750,” 37 (1995): 776. M. N. Pearson, Before
Colonialism: Theories on Asian-European Relations, 1500–1750 (Delhi: Oxford University
Press, 1988); K. N. Chaudhuri, Asia before Europe: Economy and Civilization of the Indian
Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1990).
129
Naima was particularly concerned about trade imbalance with India. Lewis
V. Thomas, A Study of Naima, ed. Norman Izkowitz (New York: New York University
Press, 1972), 144–45.
130
Genç, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda: Devlet ve Ekonomi, 68–86.
70
131
On the bullionist tendencies, see Om Prakash, “Bullion for Goods: International
Trade and the Economy of Early 18th Century Bengal,” Indian Economic and Social
History Review 13 (1976): 159–87. On the copper coinage used in Europe and Eurasia
during the 1680s, Vilar, History of Gold and Money, 219–21; Neal, The Rise of Financial
Capitalism, 11–17; Sahillo[lu, “The Role of International Monetary and Metal
Movements,” 288; and Frank Perlin, Unbroken Landscape: Commodity, Category, Sign and
Identity: Their Production as Knowledge from 1500 (Aldershot: Variorum and Brookfield,
V.T.: Ashgate Publishing, 1994), 129.
132
Edwin J. Perkins, American Public Finance and Financial Services, 1700 –1785
(Columbus: Ohio State University Press), 13–28.
133
Eldem, French Trade in Istanbul, 117–18. The ratio in the Istanbul market aver-
aged 14:1, fluctuating between a high of 15:1 and a low of 12.5:1.
134
Ahmet Refik, Hicri On (kinci Asırda Istanbul Hayatı (1100–1200) (Istanbul: Devlet
Matbaasi, 1930), 39, 62–63.
135
Zarinebaf-Shahr, “Tabriz under Ottoman Rule,” 203.
136
Sahillio[lu, “The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements,”
279. Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 180–89.
71
kuru{ edged out rival currencies, both foreign and domestic, in the
cities of Syria, as well as in the Balkans, Anatolia, and parts of
Kurdistan and Iraq, though the Gulf managed to elude its financial
hegemony (as it did Britain’s).137
Yet it should be remembered too that a successful monetary hege-
mony complemented the fiscal system of empire, which was increas-
ingly dependent on private contracts for tax collection and cash
advances on high office, as we will read in the next chapter. Thus
the flow of silver linking Istanbul to an export entrepôt like Izmir,
constituted only part of a circuit of payments, in both bullion and
paper, that united the imperial center with its peripheries and, over
the course of the century, the empire as a whole to the global
financial hubs of Marseilles, Amsterdam, and London.138
Eurasia in Transition
The Ottoman courtiers who studied this map might have regarded
West Asia as slate upon which they could still redraw the lines of
empire. Three centuries later this map—witness to a past political
economy of space and the practices of sovereignty—invites us to con-
sider not only actual outcomes but also a counterfactual one: What
if the partition of Iran between the Ottoman Empire and Czarist
Russia had become permanent? Although the sultan and his advi-
sors might not have dreamt of reconstituting Alexander’s empire,
Azarbayjan was well on its way to becoming an Ottoman province.
Bureaucrats had carried out exhaustive cadastral surveys. Timars and
later, tax farms were distributed to Ottomans and local residents.
The third mint of the new monetary system was established in Tabriz
in 1725.139 If Iran’s division might have brought the czar one step
137
Basra was clearly a credit and monetary frontier, well integrated into the Indian
Ocean system (Abdullah, Merchants, Mamluks, 90). }evket Pamuk (“The Recovery of
the Ottoman Monetary System in the Eighteenth Century,” in Kemal Karpat, The
Ottoman Past and Today’s Turkey [Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000], 188–211) confirms the
strong linkages forged by this currency policy, especially within the Black Sea,
Eastern Mediterranean, and Balkans. However, as we shall see in the following
chapter, this is only part of a complex financial system, circulating paper (titles and
letters of exchange), tax, tribute, and remittances (endowments) in addition to coinage.
138
Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, 188–90.
139
Zarinebaf-Shahr, “Tabriz under Ottoman Rule,” 115–20.
72
140
Jos J. L. Gommans, The Rise of the Indo-Afghan Empire, c. 1710–1780 (Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1995), 99–101. For later developments, see John Perry, Karim Khan Zand:
A History of Iran, 1747–1779 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); Longrigg,
Four Centuries of Modern Iraq; and A. S. K. Lambton, “Persian Trade Under the
Early Qajars,” in Islam and Trade in Asia, ed. D. S. Richards (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1970), 215–44.
141
Gommans, Rise of the Indo-Afghan Empire, 29.
142
See Ashin Das Gupta, Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, c. 1700–1750
(Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1979). Sudipta Sen (Empire of Free Trade: The East
India Company and the Making of the Colonial Marketplace [Philadelphia: University of
Pennsylvania Press, 1998]) follows the impact of changing long-distance trade rela-
tionships on local distribution and production.
73
143
Tucker, “The Peace Negotiation of 1736,” 35.
144
Neither reducing difference to matter of cultural perception and projection,
as Larry Wolf (Inventing Eastern Europe: The Map of Civilization of the Mind of the
Enlightenment [Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994]) nor essentializing cultural
and social forms, such as pastoral nomadism, as C. A. Bayly contends (Imperial
Meridian, 17–18) brings us closer to appreciating the growing imbalance between
European and Asian states during the second half of eighteenth century.
74
145
See Kemal Beydilli, 1780 Osmanlı-Prusya Ittifâkı (Meydana Geli{i-Tahilili Tatbiki)
(Istanbul: Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi Yayınları, 1984).
146
Schroeder, European Politics, 1763–1848, 3–11.
147
Aksan, “Ottoman War and Warfare, 1453–1812,” 167.
CHAPTER TWO
1
On this period, see Ahmet Refik, Lâle Devri (Ankara: Pınar Yayınları, 1912);
Mary Lucille Shaw, The Ottoman Empire from 1720 to 1734: As Revealed in the Despatches
of the Venetian Baili (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1944). For other European
paintings of courtly life in Istanbul, see Jean-Baptiste Van Mour (1671–1737) (Remmet
van Luttervelt, De “Turkse” Schilderijen van J. B. Vanmour en Zijn School [Istanbul:
Nederlands Historisch-Archaeologisch Instituut in het Nabije Oosten, 1958]), a pro-
tégé of the French Embassy.
2
Consider Voltaire, Candide or the Optimism (London: Penguin, 1947), 125. On
the concept of “civilization” under the old-regime and its discontents, see Norbert
Elias, The History of Manners (New York: Pantheon Books, 1978), 39–40.
3
TKSK MS A. 3593. See Esin Atıl and Omer Koc, eds., Levni and the Surname:
The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival (Seattle: University of Washington
Press, 2000); Esin Atıl, “The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival,”
Muqarnas 10 (1993): 181–211; E. Atil, “Surnâme-i Vehbi: An Eighteenth Century
Book of Festivals,” 2 vols. (Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan, 1969); in addition
to the many manuscript copies found in Topkapı Sarayı Müzesi Library, see Seyyit
Vehbi, Sûrnâme: Üçüncü Ahmed’in O[ullarının Sünnet Dü[ünü, ed. Re{ad Ekrem Koçu
(Istanbul: Çigir Kitabevi, 1939).
76
4
Ibn Khaldûn, The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History, ed. and trans. Franz
Rosenthal (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969), 41, attributes the “circle of
justice” to the Sassanian king Khosraw I and Aristotle. Ibn Khaldun claims that
Aristotle in his Book on Politics “arranged his statement in a remarkable circle that
he discussed at length. It runs as follows: ‘The world is a garden the fence of which
is the dynasty. The dynasty is an authority through which life is given to proper
behavior. Proper behavior is a policy directed by the ruler. The ruler is an insti-
tution supported by the soldiers. The soldiers are helpers who are maintained by
money. Money is sustenance brought together by the subjects. The subjects are ser-
vants who are protected by justice. Justice is something familiar (harmonious) and
through it, the world persists. The world is a garden . . . and then it begins again . . .
They are held together in a circle with no definite beginning or end.” An Ottoman
translation of Ibn Khaldun’s Prolegomena was completed by the head of the religious
establishment, }eyh"ül-(slam Mehmed Sa"ib Pirizâde (d. 1749). On Ibn Khaldun’s
influence, see Cornell Fleischer, “Royal Authority, Dynastic Cyclism and ‘Ibn
Khaldunism’ in Sixteenth Century Ottoman Letters,” Journal of Asian and African
Studies 18 (1984): 218–37. Notable Ottoman versions of the “circle of justice” include
77
the sixteenth-century Kınalızade Ali Efendi, Ahlâk-ı Alâi (Cairo: Bulak, 1248), vol. 3,
49 as well as that by the early-eighteenth-century imperial treasurer, Sarı Mehmed
Efendi, Ottoman Statecraft: The Book of Counsel for Vezirs and Governors of Sarï Mehmed
Pasha (Nasa'ih ul-vuzera ve’l-umera), ed. W. L. Wright (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1935), 118.
78
5
Mehmet IV was succeeded by his brothers, Süleyman II (r. 1687–1691)and
Ahmed II (r. 1691–1695) before his sons, Mustafa II (r. 1695–1703) and Ahmed
III (r. 1703–1730). Both of their reigns were cut short by janissary revolts. A. D.
Alderson, The Structure of the Ottoman Dynasty (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1956), 76;
Leslie P. Peirce, The Imperial Harem: Women and Sovereignty in the Ottoman Empire (Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1993), especially 191–218.
6
Norbert Elias, The Court Society (New York: Pantheon, 1983), 91.
7
Atıl, “The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival,” 200. The grand
vizier appears in forty-four scenes; the sultan in only forty-one.
79
8
E. J. W. Gibb, A History of Ottoman Poetry (London: Luzac & Company, 1967)
vol. 4, 111.
9
Tayyip Gökbilgin, “Bâbıâli,” (A 2:174–77. Carter V. Findley, Bureaucratic Reform
in the Ottoman Empire (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980), 47. For the com-
position of the Porte’s staff in the late seventeenth century, see the Anonymous
author of Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi (1099–1116/1688–1704) (ed. Abdülkadir Özcan
[Ankara: Türk Tarihi Kurumu Basımevi, 2000], 184–85), who follows Hezarfen
Hüseyin Efendi (Hezarfen Hüseyın Efendi Telhısü’l Beyan fı Kavanin-i Âl-ı Osman, ed.
Sevim Ilgürel [Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1998], 132).
10
For an overview of the history of the bureaucracy, see Findley, Bureaucratic
Reform; idem., Ottoman Civil Officialdom (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989);
and Virginia Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace, Ahmed Resmi Efendi,
1700 –1783 (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995), 1–14.
11
Colbert’s 1681 consolidation of the largest French tax farms into a single insti-
tution was dissolved one hundred ten years later by the revolutionary government.
See Vida Azimi, Un modèle administratif de l’ancien régime: les commis de la ferme générale
et de la régie générale des aides (Paris: Éditions du Centre National de la Recherche
Scientifique, 1987).
12
Ahmet Mumcu, Hukuksal ve Siyasal Karar Organı Olarak Divan-ı Hümayun (Ankara:
Ankara Üniversitesi Hukuk Fakültesi Yayınları, 1976), 69.
13
(smail Hakkı Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin Merkez ve Bahriye Te{kilâatı (Ankara:
TTK Basımevi, 1984), 338–61; Halil (nalcık, “Re"is-ül-küttâb,” (A 9:672–83.
80
14
See D. A. Howard, “The Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial
Registry (Defter-i Hakanî): Mid-Fifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries,” Archivum
Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 213–30; and Klaus Röhrborn, “Die Emanzipation der
Finanzbürokratie im Osmanischen Reich (Ende 16. Jahrhundert),” ZDMG 122 (1972):
118–39. In the 1750s, these documents were transfered to the palace of princess
Esma Sultan (R. Ekrem Koçu, “Bâbıâli,” (A 4:1446).
15
(smail Hakkı Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin Saray Te{kilâtı (Ankara: TTK Basımevi,
1945), 173–77. On the lives and accomplishments of the senior black eunuchs liv-
ing between 1574 and 1752, see Ahmed Resmi Efendi, Hamiletü’l-Küberâ, ed. Ahmet
Nezihi Turan (Istanbul: Istanbul Kitabevi, 2000).
16
Ahmed Resmi Efendi, Hamiletü’l-Küberâ, 45; Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devleteinin Saray
Te{kilâtı, 173.
81
17
For two examples, see Cemal Kafadar, Between Two Worlds: The Construction of
the Ottoman State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995); and Linda Darling,
Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy: Tax Collection and Finance Administration in the Ottoman
Empire, 1560–1650 (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996).
18
Compare Peter-Christian Witt, “The History and Sociology of Public Finance:
Problems and Topics,” in Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology
of Public Finance, ed. Witt (Leamington Spa, UK: Berg Publishing, 1987), 1–18.
19
Kafadar, Between Two Worlds, 111–13.
20
See Cornell H. Fleischer, Bureaucrat and Intellectual in the Ottoman Empire: The
Historian Mustafa 'Ali (1541–1600) (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986),
100–102; Abou El-Haj, Modern State; and Pal Fodor, “State and Society, Crisis and
Reform in 15th–17th Century Ottoman Mirror for Princes,” Acta Orientalia Academiae
Scientiarum Hungaricae 40 (1986): 217–40.
82
21
Colin Imber, Ebu"s-su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition (Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997), 67.
22
Halil (nalcık, “Kânûnnâme,” EI 2, 4:562–66.
23
For the origins of the provincial treasuries, Fleischer, Bureaucrat and Intellectual,
312–13. On the financial foundations of the rebel Canbulado[lu’s mini-state in
Syria, see William Griswold, Political Unrest and Rebellion in Anatolia, 1000 –1020/
1591–1611 (Berlin: Klaus Schwarz Griswold, 1983), 122.
24
Rhoads Murphey, Ottoman Warfare, 1500–1700 (London: University of London
Press, 1999), 53; Peirce, The Imperial Harem, 122. Darling, Revenue-Raising and
Legitimacy, 70.
25
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 62–65. In 1613, the high point in her
study, there were 188 clerks and accountants.
83
26
Findley, Ottoman Civil Officialdom, 22–23.
27
Cornell Fleischer, “Preliminaries to the Study of the Ottoman Bureaucracy,”
in Raiyyet Rüsumu, Essays Presented to Halil (nalcık (Special Edition of Journal of Turkish
Studies), ed. Bernard Lewis et al. 10 (1986): 140–41.
28
Findley, Ottoman Civil Officialdom, 22–23.
29
See Halil Sahillio[lu, “}ıvı{ Year Crises in the Ottoman Empire,” in Studies
in the Economic History of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, ed.
M. A. Cook (London: Oxford University Press, 1970), 230–33; Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı
Devletinin Merkez ve Bahriye Te{kilâtı; Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 81–119.
84
hand, there was the purely patrimonial treasury of the sultan (hazine-i
enderun), who served as trustee of the commonweal and religious
endowments. On the other hand, there was the true forerunner of
the fisc, the operational treasury, called alternately, the hazine-i birûn
or, more commonly, the hazine-i amire, devoted to the running of the
state, war and the management of the empire’s vast latifundia.30
As controller of the harem, the senior black eunuchs oversaw
palace finances. In effect, the palace treasury received the sultan’s
share of imperial wealth. This included war booty and slaves, the
routine confiscation (müsadere) of the goods of former officials and
officers, gifts, profits from the mint, earnings from mines, the yearly
payment from Egypt, and the tribute paid by conquered or vassal
countries, in addition to a steady stream of gifts ( pi{ke{) that were
mandatory for those ascending the highest rungs of the state hier-
archy. The head of the harem possessed the ability to appoint and
dismiss scholars and preachers to posts in the pious endowments
(waqf/awqâf ) founded by members of the dynasty as well as those
established for the benefit of pilgrims to Mecca and Medina.
The vizier who retained the keys to both vaults, oversaw the oper-
ational treasury. Originally, it received the taxation created by statute
and much of the poll tax levied, usually in aggregate sums, from
Christian and Jewish communities. The vizier could draw upon rev-
enues that were received from miri (state) lands, whether assigned as
timars or collected by nonresident officials and tax farmers.31 In the
sixteenth century, the annualization of the first direct levies, under
the heading of the avârız and the nüzül bedeliyesi, brought in another
large stream of income into this treasury.32 Although established to
run the state and specifically to pay for the upkeep and outfitting
30
Ömer Lûtfi Barkan,”(1669–70) Mali Yılına ait bir Osmanlı Bütçesi ve Ekleri,”
(FM 17 (1955–56): 193–347.
31
Sahillio[lu, “}ıvı{ Year Crises,” 330–33; Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin Merkez
ve Bahriye Te{kilâatı, 328–31.
32
For the history of the first direct tax, known generically as avârız, see Darling,
Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 81–118. On the application of the taille in France, see
James B. Collins, Fiscal Limits of Absolutism: Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France (Berkeley: University of California, 1988); and for the “Turk tax” in Austria,
Kersten Krüger, “Public Finance and Modernisation: The Change from the Domain
State to Tax State in Hesse in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries. A Case
Study,” Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology of Public Finance,
ed. Peter-Christian Witt (Lexington Spa, UK: Berg, 1987), 49–62.
85
33
Barkan, “Mali Yılına ait bir Osmanlı Bütçesi,” 224.
34
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 67, 78–79. Ahmet Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dönemine Girerken Osmanlı Maliyesi (Istanbul: Dergâh Yayınları, 1985), 272–73.
35
Halil (nalcık, “Djizya,” EI 2, 2:563–566; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken,
104–5, 136–43, 157–61, 180. The poll tax became the largest single component
of direct taxation during the eighteenth century; it yielded between 22 percent and
40 percent of the total. By contrast, avârız income sharply declined.
36
On the deteriorating conditions in the countryside, Bruce McGowan, Economic
Life in the Ottoman Europe: Taxation, Trade and the Struggle for Land (Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981), 54–55; Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 140–42,
274, 289; and M. Münir Aktepe, Patrona Isyanı (1730) (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakültesi,
1958), 9–10.
86
37
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 153–61.
38
See Ariel Salzmann, “An Ancien Régime Revisited: Privatization and Political
Economy in the 18th century Ottoman Empire,” Politics & Society 21 (1993): 393–423.
39
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 36–39.
40
Sahillio[lu, “}ıvı{ Year Crises,” 330–33.
41
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 16, 243.
42
MMD 9524:16.
43
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 65. For a detailed study of the process
of expropriation, see Yavuz Cezar, “Bir Âyanın Muhallefatı: Havza ve Köprü Âyanı
Kör (smail-o[lu Hüseyin (Müsadere Olayı ve Terekenin (ncelenmesi),” Belleten 151
(1977): 41–78.
87
44
Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age
of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 11–17.
45
Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy, 123.
46
Mukataât were either assigned as salary to be managed by tax farmers (mül-
tezim), stewards (voyvoda), or revenue agents (emin) or directly to janissaries in lieu of
salary. Some were even awarded on a lifetime basis. Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine
Girerken, 126–28.
47
Yavuz Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im Dönemi (XVIII. Yüzyıldan
Tanzimat"a Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan Yayıncılık, 1986), 51.
48
The standard work on the subject remains Mehmet Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde
Malikâne Sistemi,” in Türkiye (ktisat Tarihi Semineri, ed., Osman Okyar and Ünal
Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe Üniversitesi 1975), 231–296. One does not have to
search far to find reports of deteriorating conditions: KK 3105:11 (1721), for example,
concerns the plight of villages whose taxation, held in an ocaklık, had been farmed
out under short-term contracts. Given terms of contract, however, tax-farmers seemed
reluctant to assume all but the most lucrative contracts, such as Istanbul’s snuff tax
88
(mukataa-ı resm-i duhan), which sold quickly (Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 20). By
contrast, another document (D.B}M 624) reveals that many other contracts, includ-
ing villages in Kars, the customs stations of Erzurum and Baghdad, crown estates
in Mar"a{, zeamets in Urfa, and a soap factory in Bosnia, found no bidders at a
1694–95 auction.
49
MMD 3423 (1695–98) contains copies of the certificates awarded to life-lease
contractors during the first years of auctions.
50
In addition the document reported by Ra{id Efendi, (Mehmed Ra{id, Tarih-i
Ra{id [Istanbul: Matbaa-i Miri, 1282/1865–66] 2:288–89), Genç (“Osmanlı Maliyesinde
Malikâne Sistemi,” 284–88) has located two important decrees in the archive (KK
5040:1–2). Although Avdo Su‘eska (“Malikane,” POF 36 [1986]: 197–229) may be
correct in attributing the edit itself to the reign of Ahmed II; however, as a pol-
icy, the life-lease system is testimony to a growing consensus among the elite of this
period concerning fiscal and administrative matters.
51
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 194–96. Hass accounts are included in
the budget in 1690–91 and provides payments for the palace. On the malikâne-hass,
that is, havass-ı hümayun, awarded under malikâne contracts, see Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde
Bunalım, 39–44, 48–49, 66. Such estates constitute an important component of the
subventions given the Crimean khans. Among the many documents pertaining to
the estates of eighteenth-century princesses, see those for Safiye Sultan (CS 868);
Alem{ah Sultan (CS 4207); Ay{e Sultan (CS 5433); and Hadime Sultan (CS 2902).
89
52
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 37, 48–49.
53
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 104, 289. Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım,
328. Many if not most contracts were awarded from the large financial bureau of
the muhasebe-i evvel, which yielded between 18.8 percent and 38.7 percent of the
general income over the century.
54
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 134.
55
Hüseyin Özde[er, “III. Ahmed’in Varidât ve Defteri,” Türk (ktisat Tarihi Yıllı[ı
(Istanbul Üniversitesi (ktisat Fakültesi Türk (ktisat ve (çtimâiyât Tarihi Ara{tırmaları
Merkezi, 1987), 1:305–52. Whether these are the sultan’s own estates or those of
his sons, such revenues as hass-ı Be[pazarı, hass-ı Haymana-ı Büzürk ve Küçük, hass-ı
Menemen, hass-ı Boynu (ncelü (taifesi), hass-ı Mukataa-i Malatya, hass-ı Esb-Ke{ân ve Boz-
Ulus) do form part of the inner treasury. For another example of shares in hass of
princes “veledân-ı sultan,” see CS 5287.
56
Mouradgea I. D’Ohsson, Tableau général de l’Empire Othoman (Paris: M. Firmin
Didot Imp., 1820–24) vol. 3, 175–76; 368–70. For registration the treasury charged
a 10 percent fee, two thirds of which was paid to the grand vizier and one-third
to the director of the fisc.
57
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 90, 104; Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım,
100–101.
90
58
Jane Hathaway, The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[lı
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 139–64.
59
Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin Saray Te{kilâtı. See also Jane Hathaway, “The
Role of the Kızlar A[ası in Seventeenth-Eighteenth Century Ottoman Egypt,” Studia
Islamica 75 (1992): 141–58.
60
See H. Veli Aydin, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Esham Uygulaması (1775–1840)”
(Ph.D. diss., Ankara University, 1998).
61
The seventeenth-century Hezarfen Hüseyin Efendi (Telhîsü’l-Beyân, 98) states
that 136 yük 22,400 akçe from the mukataa revenues in the hazine-i amire were set
aside for this purpose. But the historian Naima (d. 1716) (Lewis V. Thomas, A
Study of Naima, ed. Norman Itzkowitz [New York: New York University Press, 1972],
104–5) insists that most ulema received stipends from endowments connected to
mosques and other religious institutions and that the customs revenues were used
for the salaries of other officials.
62
KK 4264; KK 4308.
91
cial revenue contracts, such as Bursa’s silk tax, paid the salaries of
the ulema of the Holy Cities.63 Provincial tax farms, such as the
voyvodalık of Diyarbekir or the deftardarlık of Damascus, contributed
subventions in cash and grain to local professors and the members
of Sufi orders.64
One of the most important sources of ulema stipends were the
remittances from the excise tax on coffee and tobacco, the so-called
sin taxes (resm-i bid"at). In 1722–23, the coffee tax for Istanbul (includ-
ing income from other major ports such as Salonika) paid out stipends
to 728 pensioners of the palace and 1,160 members of the ulema
(du"â-güyân). Thirty years later the same tax farm made payments to
2,450 members of the ulema (of whom 665 were female relatives).65
As for the tobacco tax, awarded as a tax farm in 1691 and as a
life-lease in 1744–45, its revenues supported 1,586 individuals, of
whom 51 were women.66 In 1772–73, the 623 women who derived
stipends from this tax farm constituted more than one-third of the
total (1,761) number of those listed as members of the “ulema.”67
Naturally, the chief mufti of the empire also received his share: of
the tobacco regie’s annual income of 159,028.5 kuru{, 25,000 kuru{
was paid to him directly, in lieu of salary (bedel ).68
If the operational treasury under the supervision of the Porte was—
as it could be argued—the forerunner of the modern fisc, then it
was the rhizome of financial relations engendered by debt that
expanded and structured the social capacity of the emerging state.
63
A 1780 Summary (KK 4547) assigned 1.23 million akçe to stipend holders and
7.09 million akçe went for du"â-güyân stipends. In 1802, the tax on silk sales in Bursa
(KK 4198) supported ulema resident in Mecca and Medina.
64
D.B}M 2071:2–9 1150–1154 (1737–1741). Provincial tax farm budgets were
much the same; of the three-year income (mal) from the voyvodalık of Diyarbekir,
totaling 31,391,793 akçe, 1,396,461 akçe were devoted to pensioners and du"â-güyân.
65
In 1691, the coffee tax yielded 204 kese, or 10.2 million akçe according to
Tabako[lu (Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 274); see KK 4520 (1722–23) and KK 4530
(1752–53) later income. In 1780 (KK 4557), 1.23 million akçe were subtracted from
it to support pensioners and 7.09 million akçe went to the ulema as “stipends.” They
included their wives and daughters such as Rakiya hanım (at 130 akçe per day) and
Ay{e hatun (80 akçe per day).
66
Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 20–21; KK 4471.
67
KK 4484. The tobacco taxes involved in this farm were collected at many
ports, including Salonika, Drac (Durazzo), Bo[az, Tekfur Da[ı, (negöl, Edirne,
Tripoli, Istanbul, Aleppo, Damascus, and Jaffa. In 1761–62, its gross income
for the fisc was 2900 kese rumi akçe or 145 million akçe/1.21 million kuru{ (CM
26,858).
68
CM 21,369.
92
Hierarchies of Service
69
On this topic, see Donald Quataert, “Clothing Laws, State, and Society in the
Ottoman Empire, 1720–1829,” IJMES 29 (1997): 403–25.
70
Bekir Sitki Baykal, “Mustafa III,” A( 8:702.
93
been diverted from their provincial posts for the occasion, demonstrate
another form of sociopolitical obligation. Their appearance at the
ritual is marked by the presentation of a lavish gift to the sultan.71
Far more intricate than mastering the details of status associated with
dress were the nuances of etiquette (te{rifat) that determined the value
and type of gifts exchanged between superior and subordinate.
Behind the curtain of ceremonial preformances, therefore, rank
and status are also revealed in the expense ledgers of pashas and in
entries under the terms “blandishments” (avaidat ), “honoraria” (caize),
and “presents” (hediye).72 A governorship in eighteenth-century Aleppo,
for example, demanded many such gratuities: to the secretary of
state, his purse-bearer, the chief usher of the Porte, and the direc-
tor of the chancellery, among many other officials and members of
court whose pockets were filled by his largesse. These payments were
over and above the enormous gifts to the grand vizier and his chief
of staff, personal accountant, and clerk.73 Not only did an incoming
governor pass out gifts up and down the Istanbul chain of com-
mand, he was also obliged to confer gratuities in cloth and cash on
the local commander of the fort (dizdar) and the sergeant of the
guard (karakullakina ba{), who in turn paid him homage in money
when seeking transfers or new appointments.74
In a hierarchy defined by service to the state and the presump-
tion of merit and ability, the introduction of such vast sums into the
process of promotion and political mobility produced a tension to
be sure. These exorbitant expenditures for etiquette’s sake, had become
the modus vivendi of the old regime, prompted contemporary observers
to voice their objections to practices that they felt transgressed the
boundaries between a “gift” and outright bribery or extortion.75 Yet
71
See Metin Kunt, “Dervi{ Mehmet Pa{a: Vezir and Entrepreneur: A Study in
Ottoman Political-Economic Theory and Practice,” Turcica 9 (1977): 197–214.
72
D.B}M 3546 (1759); M. Zeki Pakalın, Osmanlı Tarih Deyimleri ve Terimleri Sözlü[ü
(Istanbul: Milli E[itim Bakanlı[ı Yayınları, 1983), 2:58. Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin
Merkez, 199–202.
73
D.B}M 5019 (1780–1781).
74
D.B}M 3546 (1759–1760). Registration fees included 8,467.5 kuru{ for the
grand vizier and 4,233.5 kuru{ for the imperial treasurer. Abdul-Karim Rafeq, The
Province of Damascus (Beirut: Khayats, 1966), 234–39.
75
See Ahmet Mumcu, Tarih (çindeki Genel Geli{imiyle Birlikte Osmanlı Devletinde Rü{vet
Özellikle Adli Rü{vet (Istanbul: Inkilâp Kitabevi, 1985); compare Natalie Zemon Davis,
The Gift in Sixteenth-Century France (Madison: University of Wisconsin, 2000), 85–99.
94
inflation of the concept of the “gift” was inevitable. But this, too,
was relative to status: what might be considered a criminal offense
for an individual of a lower station would be perfectly respectable,
even obligatory for his social superior. Facing the greatly increasing
costs of office and diminished incomes, most appointees to higher
office necessarily fell back on entrepreneurial skills.76
The eighteenth century was a point of transition in imperial hier-
archies. Nonetheless, it seemed for a time that despite the pressure
for material resources for entrance and promotion, good introduc-
tions and proper training could still propel a talented young man
into the orbit of the court and or the bureaucracy. Nev{ehirli (brahim
Pasha is a case in point. He found his way to the top through the
ceremonial helvacılar corps, a position that his father, an Anatolian
intendant for the palace, had secured for him.77 A good education
and eloquence must have brought the poet Hâmi of Amid (b. 1679)
to the attention of Muhsinzâde Abdullah Pasha, the grand vizier’s
chief of staff, in 1709.78 Selected to accompany Vizier Köprülüzâde
Abdullah Pasha on his tour of the poet’s native town in 1717, the
pasha entrusted him with the management of his mukataât.
Ultimately, it was business acumene that paid off. Hâmi invested
his own money in malikâne contracts. This income and experience,
must have eventually helped him, at the rather mature age of fifty-
two, to attain a tenured position in the financial department deal-
ing with such contracts, the malikâne halifesi. In reconstructing the life
of another talented man of provincial origin, Ahmed Resmi of Crete,
whose career began in 1730s, Virginia Aksan remarks on “the appar-
ent serendipity of many of the career paths, an elasticity at the upper
administrative levels in a system otherwise restrictive.”79
Fluidity and serendipity were an even greater factor in appoint-
ments to provincial office in the eighteenth century. In time of war,
the normal channels of promotion could be bypassed completely.
The distinguished field commander Çeteci Abdullah Pasha, whom
we encountered during the first decades of the Wars of the Iranian
76
Kunt, Bir Osmanlı Valisinin Yıllık Gelir Gideri, 48–49; for the income and expenses
of a pasha serving in the Balkans in 1714, see Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım,
50.
77
M. Münir Aktepe, “Nev{ehirli (brahim Pa{a,” (A 9:234–39.
78
Ali Amiri, Tezkere-i }u'ara-yı Amid (Istanbul: Matbu'a-i Amidi, 1328/1910) vol.
1, 187–93, 260; Gibb, A History of Ottoman Poetry, vol. 4, 111.
79
Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman, 14–15.
95
80
}evket Beysano[lu, Diyarbakır Tarihi: Anıtları ve Kitabeleri ile (Ankara: Neyir
Matbaası, 1993), 679–81. With the exception of a posting in Syria and in Erzurum,
his assignments were close to home: initially Rakka at the rank of beylerbeyi, then
as pasha (vali ) of Diyarbekir in 1744, 1750, 1752, and 1759.
81
Rafeq, The Province of Damascus, 234–39. D.B}M 3546 (1759–65) records
payments for office, tax farms, and gifts on the occasion of the appointment of
Osman Pasha “currently the Vizier of Damascus” (pp. 1–18); and expenses for his
son Mehmet to assume office in Tripoli (pp. 20–21).
82
Bekir Kütüko[lu, “Vekâyınüvis,” A( 13:271–87.
83
For more on the bedel-i timar, the special levy (cihet) on endowment income,
and other new impositions on wealth and privilege, Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine
Girerken, 207–12; 270–73.
84
On the nature of politics, see Halil (nalcık, “Military and Fiscal Transformation,”
and Rifa'at 'Ali Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion and the Structure of Ottoman Politics
96
88
Defterdar Sarı Mehmet Pasha (Wright, Ottoman Statecraft, 23) chastises con-
temporaries about the misuse of state resources. For other abuses, see Abou-El-Haj,
The 1703 Rebellion, 116; Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im, 42, 51. The
perception of abuse is not unconnected to the rank and status of the actor. In the
sixteenth century, Mustafa Ali complained about the impudence of low ranking per-
sons (Andreas Tietze, Mustafa Ali’s Counsel for Sultans of 1581 [Wien: Verlag der
Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1979] vol. 1, 58). In the late eight-
eenth century, similar sentiments are expressed by Selim III’s advisor, Abdullah
Efendi Tatarcık (see “Selim-i Sâni devrinde Nizâm-ı Devlet hakkında mutâl"aât,”
Türk Tarihi Encümeni Mecmuası 8 [1333/1914–1915]: 17).
89
The usual formula to confer such immunity is “mefrüzü’l-kalem ve maktü’ül-
kadem”; Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne,” 239; for examples in diplomas,
MMD 9486:6 and DA III:153.
90
Michael Kwass (“A Kingdom of Taxpayers: State Formation, Privilege, and
Political Culture in Eighteenth-Century France,” Journal of Modern History 70 [1998]:
300) suggests that privilege should have been incompatible with tax paying. The
Ottoman nobility of service had similar tax immunities but were forced to con-
tribute in periods of crisis. The new lease brought new obligations. Lease holders
contributed to the cülus bah{i{i, the ascension donation to the janissaries (Defterdar
Sarı Mehmet Pasha, Ottoman Statecraft, 104–5; Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde
Malikâne Sistemi,” 247). In the years of war, they paid the cebelü bedeliyesi, a levy
assessed on contracts at the rate of 10 percent or 15 percent of the bid price.
91
J. R. Jones (“Fiscal Policies, Liberties, and Representative Government during
the Reigns of the Last Stuarts,” in Hoffman and Norberg, Fiscal Crises, 67–95) pro-
vides a useful discussion on the difference between liberties, such as property, and
privileges, such as tax farming.
98
Although some courtiers and high officials may have welcomed the
loophole furnished by the malikâne edit which provided for some form
of intergenerational devolution,92 there was no reason to allow the
gentry and ulema to take advantage of this provision because they
had no legal barriers to inheritance. Every aspect of the new con-
tract seemed to assure that the third estate would benefit from such
special provisions or from any ambiguities arising from an overly
generous interpretation of Islamic laws on private property.93
The bureaucrat’s fears proved largely unfounded. Despite attempts
to conflate contract and property, ordinary contractors rarely suc-
ceeded in gaining state recognition of their claims.94 Whether as
beneficiaries of the income of high yielding revenue sources in their
lifetime or as a member of an elite network of shareholders, it was
the courtier and the high ranking officer who benefited dispropor-
tionately from this fiscal dispensation. They, too, had the best chance
of converting, often in stages, a public resource into private property.95
Rather than the cause, the new contract may have been another
symptom of the pronounced closing of state ranks to outsiders that
occurred in the eighteenth century. A clique of households and
92
D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 3, 368–69. Although the principle of devolving
shares to a surviving male relative, the “evlâdiyet {urûtu,” was a well-established
practice, disputes (note MMD 9494:23 [1702–03]) did arise.
93
The Hanefite legal school recognizes overlapping but analytically distinct pro-
prietary claims on the usufruct and ownership of assets, according to Chafik Chehata,
Essai d’une theorie générale de l’obligation en droit Musulman (Cairo: Nury Publishers, 1936)
1:173.
94
For example, in 1696 (MMD 3426:56) the sons of a certain Yahya Beg (per-
haps a janissary or a timar holder) petitioned the Porte for the life-lease on the dye
house in Aleppo, arguing that they were entitled to the lease because their father,
the previous tax farmer, had made substantial capital investments in the building.
Indeed, the brothers seemed to have proprietary claims. Jean-Pierre, “Décentralisation
Ottomane et affirmation urbaine à Alep à la fin du XVIIIème siècle,” in Mouvements
communautaires et éspaces urbains au Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria, et al. [Beirut: Centre
d’études et de recherches sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain, 1985], 129) came
across a complaint that had been brought against them in the court of Aleppo.
Craftsmen accused the sons of insisting that the new contract made them owners
outright of the dye house.
95
For the gradual privatization of the dye house of Çünkü{, originally a tax
farm, MMD 9519:81 and D.B}M 1069 (n.d.) For other instances of converting con-
tract into property, Abou-El-Haj, The 1703 Rebellion, 9, 51, 116. Of these attempts,
the conversion of contracts into endowments seems to have been the most secure
route: In 1710 Grand Vizier Ali Pasha converted a malikâne holding into a pious
endowment (waqf ) that supported the building of a mosque-imaret-dershane complex
in Istanbul.
99
96
See Abou-El-Haj, “The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households:” Tülay Artan,
“From Charismatic Leadership to Collective Rule,” Toplum ve Ekonomi 4 (1993):
53–94; Madeline Zilfi, The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the Postclassical Age
(1600 –1800) (Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988); Suraiya Faroqhi, “Civilian
Society and Political Power in the Ottoman Empire: A Report on Research in
Collective Bibliography, 1480–1830,” IJMES 17 (1985): 109–17.
97
See Joel Shinder, “Career Line Formation in the Ottoman Bureaucracy,
1648–1750: A New Perspective,” JESHO 16 (1973): 216–37.
98
Shinder, “Career Line Formation,” 228–29, 233–35.
99
See Madeline Zilfi, “Elite Circulation in the Ottoman Empire: Great Mollas
of the Eighteenth Century,” JESHO 26 (1983): 318–20.
100
According to Aksan (An Ottoman Statesman, 14–15, n. 47) there was little or no
tracking within the civil bureaucracy allowing clerks to acquire expertise in a vari-
ety of fields.
101
In 1793, the Porte issued a new kanunname aimed at reducing the number of
the top tier of rical, the pasha elite. Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 344–45.
100
102
Beysano[lu, Diyarbakır Tarihi, 679–81.
103
The sons of Vizier Süleyman Pasha 'Azmzâde (d. 1743), pasha of Damascus,
shared title to tax farms valued at 52,330 kuru{.
104
On gentry accumulation during this period, see Margaret Meriwether, “Urban
Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo, 1770–1830,” IJTS 4 (1987): 55–73; Yuzo
Nagata, Some Documents on the Big Farms (Çiftliks) of the Notables in Western
Anatolia (Tokyo: Institute for the Study of Languages and Cultures of Asia and
Africa, 1976); and Suraiya Faroqhi, “Wealth and Power in the Land of Olives:
Economic and Political Activities of Müridzâde Hacı Mehmed Agha, Notable of
Edremit,” in Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East, ed. Ça[lar Keyder
and Faruk Tabak (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991), 77–96. For
an approach to accumulation in early modern South Asia, see Sanjay Subrahmanyam
and C. A. Bayly, “Portfolio Capitalists and the Political Economy of Early Modern
India,” in Merchants, Markets and the State in Early Modern India, ed. Sanjay Subrahmanyam
(Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1990), 242–54.
105
KK 786. I am grateful to Mehmet Genç for sharing this record with me.
101
They recorded payments from the four corners of the empire: 42,060
kuru{ from Belgrade, sent by an agent, Osman Efendi; a down pay-
ment of 10,000 kuru{ on a tax farm from Kara Halil in Kütahya;
revenues from a plantation in Siroz, administered by Muhurdarzâde
Hasan Pasha; and income on the shares in the recently reorganized,
state-run tobacco regie in Istanbul, among many other holdings and
ventures.
By reinforcing a divided hierarchy, the market in malikâne leases
perpetuated the dominance of the Istanbul elite while, as we shall
see in the next chapter, extending a certain range of the benefits of
state office to the gentry. Such disparities were, however, build in
to the system. The initial commands establishing provincial auctions
explicitly restricted the type of tax contracts that could be sold out-
side the capital and discouraged provincials from obtaining shares
in another region. The most valuable commercial and aggregate tax-
grants remained in the hands of the state elite.106 Istanbul’s insatiable
demand for highly liquid revenues, such as customs and excise taxes,
undoubtedly dictated the extension of this form of contracting into
specific regions and economic sectors.107 By 1741, cumulative malikâne
investments in the empire (as measured in surety payments) reached
4.3 million kuru{, of which fully one-quarter were located in the
Morea and the Aegean islands. Another third of the investments
were located in the Balkans.108 As the number of Istanbul investors
D.B}M 4666 records deposits from Aleppo made by poliçe to Istanbul between 1776
and 1781.
106
MMD 10,143:164 (pertaining to Diyarbekir); in Damascus (MMD 3423:570)
the auctioneer was restricted from offering ocaklık mukataa as proprietary contracts.
107
MMD 1637; MMD 730 (copy). Of 1,442 new contracts in 1703, more than
half (871 contracts) were awarded on Balkan resources. There were 571 contracts
in Damascus, Malatya, Diyarbekir, Mosul, Adana, and }ehrizor; the remaining con-
tracts were held in the regions of Western Anatolia, Aleppo, and Tokat-Sivas. In
effect, of the 897,705 kuru{ taken in by the treasury in the form of cash advance
(muaccele) payments, less than half (361,835 kuru{) fell within the geographical zone
originally designated by the edit; one-third pertained to the Balkans (322,278 kuru{).
A little less than a quarter were on contracts in Anatolia (213,592 kuru{).
108
Forty-three percent were located in Anatolia, Syria, Kurdistan, and Iraq.
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 134, and CM 5001 (1741) provide figures for
the Balkans (172,610,160 akçe); Anadolu, Damascus, Aleppo, Baghdad, Mosul, and
Diyarbekir (268,525,200 akçe); Morea, Crete, and other islands (79,732,320 akçe).
MMD 6981 provides a running tally of new contracts awarded between 1721 and
1723 for Aleppo (which rose by 67,905 kuru{); Tokat sales nearly doubled (15,181
kuru{, on top of an existing 16,391.5 kuru{ in contracts). Sales in Adana, Ayıntab,
Malatya, Diyarbekir, Erzurum, Mosul, and Baghdad increased at slower rates. For
sales within Crete see also MMD 9511.
102
and partnerships rose from 771 in 1768 to 963 in 1789,109 their share
of the malikâne market as a whole rose from approximately two-thirds
of the total (65 percent) to nine-tenths (87 percent).110
109
Murat Çizakça, A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World
and Europe, with Specific Reference to the Ottoman Archives (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996), 173.
110
Ibid., 174. MMD 9524:10. By 1734, central state investors held 633 kese and
9 kuru{ in contracts and the provincials had invested about half as much, or 334
kese and 460 kuru{ (50,000 akçe per kese). Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne
Sistemi,” 282. Note: the percentage (87) is based on records from 1789, not 1787.
111
See Serpil Ba[cı, Priscilla Mary I{in, and Selmin Kangal, eds. The Sultan’s
Portrait: Picturing the House of Osman (Istanbul: Tükiye ({ Bankası, 2000).
112
TKSA MS 3593: 22b–23a.
113
On the upheavals of the first half of the century, see Abou-El-Haj, The 1703
Rebellion; Lavender Cassels, The Struggle for the Ottoman Empire (London: Murray, 1966);
Robert Olson, “The Esnaf and the Patrona Halil Rebellion of 1730: A Realignment
in Ottoman Politics?” JESHO 17 (1974): 329–40; and idem, “Jews, Janissaries, Esnaf
and the Revolt of 1740 in Istanbul: Social Upheaval and Political Realignment in
the Ottoman Empire,” JESHO 20 (1978): 185–207; and M. Münir Aktepe, Patrona
Isyanı (1730) (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakültesi, 1958).
103
114
Abou-El-Haj (The 1703 Rebellion) emphasizes this point. For other studies, see
Sabra F. Meservey, “Feyzullah Efendi: An Ottoman Seyhülislam” (Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1966); Suraiya Faroqhi, “An Ulama Grandee and his Household,”
JOS 9 (1989): 199–208; and Ahmet Türek and F. Çetin Derin, “Feyzullah Efendi"nin
Kendü Kaleminden Hal Tercümesi,” Tarih Dergisi 23 (1969): 204–8; Tarih Dergisi
24 (1970): 69–92.
115
Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 221–27.
116
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 297.
117
Mumcu, Osmanlı Devletinde Rü{vet, 232–33. See also idem, Osmanlı Devletinde
Siyaseten Katl (Ankara: Birey ve Toplum Yayınları, 1985).
118
Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 224.
119
Ibid., 225. The author of this anonymous history attributes the origins of the
rebellion against Mustafa II to a squabble over a malikâne lease in Adana that
involved one of Feyzullah Effendi’s followers, Telhisi Mehmet A[a.
120
Ibid., 224. “He buys a malikâne for 1000 kuru{ at auction, paying only half
the price, explaining that the vizier or defterdar would pay the balance.”
104
121
Deftardar Sarı Mehmed Efendi, Ottoman Statescraft, 70; Ra{id Efendi, Tarih-i
Ra{id, vol. 2, 100–1, 122, 301, 424; 4:30, 284. Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken,
296–98; Abou-El-Haj, The 1703 Rebellion, 12–13.
122
Charles Tilly reminds me that this form of accumulation is in many ways
analogous to guild practices in early modern England and Italy. For some thoughts
on how to rehabilitate the notion of patrimonialism, see Susanne Hoeber Rudolph
and Lloyd I. Rudolph, “Authority and Power in Bureaucratic and Patrimonial
Administration: A Revisionist Interpretation of Weber on Bureaucracy,” World Politics
31 (1979): 195–227.
105
123
He did retain a cash foundation. (smail Kurt, Para Vakıfları Nazariyat ve Tatbikat
(Istanbul: Ensar Ne{riyat, 1996), 163.
124
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 297.
125
Norman Izkowitz, “Men and Ideas in the Eighteenth Century Ottoman
Empire,” in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History, ed. T. Naff and R. Owen
(Carbondale: University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977), 19.
126
On the kapı, see Abou-El-Haj, “The Ottoman Vezir and Pasha Households,
1683–1703.”
127
Uzunçar{ılı, Osmanlı Devletinin Merkez, 207. Onik Jamgocyan (“Les finances
de l’Empire Ottoman et les financièrs de Constantinople, 1732–1853” [Thèse de
doc., Université de Paris I [Sorbonne] 1988], 231–32) concludes that the size of
pasha households actually increased over the century.
106
128
See (smail Hakkı Uzunçar{ılı, “Üçünçü Mustafa’nın kızı }ah Sultan’a Borç
Senedi,” Belleten 25 (1961): 97; and idem, “Sultan III. Mustafa’nın Hüzün Verici
Bir Borç Senedi,” Belleten 22 (1968): 595–98.
129
According to CS 4051, a document that Michael Hickok kindly brought to
my attention, princesses also operated their own firms of tax farms, dividing shares
among female and male household members. For other examples, see MMD
9565:10–11, which contains the holdings of various royal women (Emine, Fatma,
and Zeyneb Hanım); TKSA D 4477 is the esham register of Hatice Hanım; TKSA
D 6573 is a register of Habibe Hanım, the wife of Moralı Ahmed. In Egypt,
Mamluk women played an important role in preserving household wealth (See Susan
Staffa, “Dimensions of Women’s Power in Historic Cairo,” Islamic and Middle Eastern
Studies: A Festschrift in Honor of Professor Wadie Jwaideh, ed. Robert Olson et al.
[Brattleboro, Vt.: Amana, 1987], 62–99). They invested in tax farms. In the rest
of the empire, however, local women were poorly represented. Only one woman
tax farmer appears in the local accounts for eighteenth-century Diyarbekir (MMD
9518:52) and she resided in Istanbul. The situation changes at the end of the old
regime. Between 1848 and 1860, three Diyarbekir women (MMD 9519:122, 130,
137) held shares in village tax farms.
130
MMD 9565, entry no. 655.
131
On the practice of assigning revenues to members of a rical’s household, see
Thomas, A Study of Naima, 105 and Kunt, The Sultan’s Servants, 88.
132
MMD 367 is undated. Internal evidence (Ne{e Erim identified Süleyman
Efendi as one of contractors on the customhouse of Erzurum) suggests that it belongs
to the 1736–37 war period. Süleyman Pasha, another individual, was governor of
107
Damascus between 1734 and 1738 (Rafeq, The Province of Damascus, 119). 322 per-
sons held investments (based on their muaccele) of less than 10,000 kuru{; 51 per-
sons, between 10–25,000 kuru{; 26 persons, between 25–50,000 kuru{; three persons,
between 50–100,000 kuru{; and three persons, above 100,000 kuru{.
133
MMD 367. One son, Mehmed, held a quarter share in Anatolia (in the
Voyvodalık of Tokat) valued at 10,850 kuru{.
134
MMD 367. For example, the sons of former Vizier Ali Pasha, (smail Bey,
Selim, Ahmed, and Mehmed, held 34,475 kuru{ in shares on various malikâne farms,
principally located in the mainland Greece (the Morea). In the case of a civil bureau-
crat, Kasariyeli Hacı Ahmed Efendi, once head of a treasury bureau dealing with
accounts receivable (ruznamçe evvel ), held malikâne contracts valued at 57,650 kuru{
together with his son Ebü Bekir A[a, a nephew (or grandson) Mehmed A[a; a son-
in-law, Mehmed; and an unidentified individual, Ahmed A[a (perhaps his steward
or head of household).
135
For the social fluidity of the pool of “provincial” elites and return migration,
see Karl K. Barbir, “From Pasha to Efendi: The Assimilation of Ottomans into
Damascene Society, 1516–1783,” IJTS 1 (1979–80): 68–83.
136
Investment distribution continues to be extremely skewed. Only one in ten
individuals held shares valued at 25,000 kuru{ or higher; four out of five invested
far below 10,000 kuru{. A considerable sum of money, 10,000 kuru{ was the equiv-
alent of 2,500 Venetian ducats and represented many times the lifetime wealth of
an ordinary officer. Consider that the entire worldly goods of a low-ranking officer
of the Arsenal in 1766–67 amounted to 3,040 kuru{ (I}MS K-A, 293:2–3); Esseyyid
108
Ebübekir, the cavu{ a[ası, head courier of the grand vizier, left an estate of 26,604
kuru{ (I}MS 181:1–3); a deputy judge, a naib (Ibid., 11–12) in Rumeli owned goods
and a house together estimated at 9,498 kuru{.
137
MMD 367. For some examples: Ahmet A[a ve Küçük Mehmed A[a, ân
etbâ-i Sa"adullah Efendi, 4500 kuru{; Mustafa A[a, ân müteferrikân-ı gedikluyân ân
etbâ-i müteveffa Karakulak Ali A[a, 312 kuru{.
138
Çizakca, Business Partnerships, 173.
109
139
MMD 9565:1–5.
140
Some of their shares might include crown estates. Many investments were
concentrated within discrete regions. For example, the shares of Vizier Gül Ahmed
Pasha and household members, including his kethüda-i harç, Mustafa A[a; his meh-
terdar, Süleyman A[a; and his children, Feyzullah Bey, Ali Bey, and (smail Bey,
were all held in the Aegean—the Morea, Crete, and Izmir.
141
For examples of ceding (kasr-ı yed ) shares, see MMD 9896:138; MMD 9494:23.
On the legal methods of transferring/relinquishing title ( fera[ ), see the judge’s hand-
book (circa 1784) Süleymâniye Library MS Izmir 782 no. 1, folios 66a–67b.
142
In 1705–6, a Diyarbekir seyyid re-registered his contract through an Istanbul
intermediary (MMD 9896:138).
143
On the difficulties of finance and credit in the provinces, see Araks }ahiner,
“The Sarrafs of Istanbul: Financiers of the Empire,” (M.A. thesis, Institute of Social
Sciences, Master of Arts in History, Bo[aziçi University, 1995), 30. Bartholomew
Plaisted, Narrative of a Journey from Basra to Aleppo in 1750 in The Desert Route to India
Being the Journals of Four Travelers by the Great Desert Caravan Route between Aleppo and
Basra, 1745–51, ed. Douglas Carruthers (London: Hakluyt Society, 1929), 104. Bruce
110
Masters,The Origins of Western Dominance in the Middle East: Mercantilism and the Islamic
Economy in Aleppo, 1600–1750 (New York: New York University Press, 1988), 151–52.
144
Halil (nalcık, “Hawala,” EI 2 3: 284; D’Ohsson, Tableau générale, vol. 1, 248–49;
for examples of transfers of funds, see D.B}M 4666 (1776–80), a register belong-
ing to Lala Mustafa A[a whose income was sent from Syria. For an example of a
payment by local administrators through the judge in Diyarbekir, D}S 360:35
(1739–1740).
145
Telhisi Mehmet A[a, for example, entrusted his malikâne holdings to a sub-
farmer or his own deputy (suba{ı). Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 225. On subcon-
tracting, see Defterdar Sarı Mehmet Efendi, Zubde-i Vekayiat (Süleymâniye Library,
Ms. Esad Efendi, No. 2387) folios 288b–289a, cited in Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine
Girerken, 132 n. 30.
146
HA IV:1 (1781–82); although a 1715 order attempted to restrict subleasing,
absentee contracting was commonplace. In 1767 orders were issued to standardize
the practice. Avdo Su‘eska, “Malikana.” Prilozi za orientalnu filologiju 36 (1986):
209; Genç, “Malikâne Sistemi,” 240, n. 17.
111
147
For their social backgrounds, see Onik Jamgocyan, “Les finances de l’Empire
Ottoman,” and }ahiner, “The Sarrafs of Istanbul.”
148
See Ali (hsan Ba[ıs, Osmanlı Ticaretinde Gayrı Müslimler: Kapitülasyonlar-Beratlı
Tüccarlar, Avrupa ve Hayriye Tüccarları (1750–1839) (Ankara: Turhan Kitabevi, 1983),
21–38.
149
Consider France, Janine Garrison, L’Edit de Nantes et sa révocation: Histoire d’une
intolerance (Paris: Éditions du Seuil, 1985).
150
Robert Olson, “Jews, Janissaries, Esnaf and the Revolt of 1740 in Istanbul:
Social Upheaval and Political Realignment in the Ottoman Empire,” JESHO 20
(1978): 199.
151
}ahiner, “The Sarrafs of Istanbul,” 24.
152
D.B}M 5019. Mouradgea d’Ohsson, (Tableau générale, vol. 3, 175–6) historian
112
have seen, assuming office also meant taking the responsibility for
the large malikâne contracts.153
While the court was the focal point of status, and the Porte, the
source of patronage, the city itself furnished the personnel and services
for financial capitalism within the empire. Over the century there devel-
oped a degree of regional specialization among the financiers them-
selves. Greek influence held sway in the Aegean and the Black Sea;
Jewish firms rose to prominence in Syria, Iraq, and for at time, Egypt.154
Armenian companies dominated the financial hub of the empire. Mem-
bers of the upper strata or amira class of their community, the Arme-
nian financiers served as personal agents for the upper echelon of the
aristocracy of service.155 They filled almost every one of the seventy-
two fully accredited (gedik) posts allowed to deal directly with the fisc.156
Yet, this number does not begin to capture the scope of imperial
high finance. In addition to the gedik-holding financiers, a 1761 doc-
ument records another 137 individuals who practiced some form of
financial services (sarraflık) under the title of purchasing agents (mubayaacı),
silver dealers/silversmiths (gümü{ciyân), or as their apprentices (mülâ-
zimler) in Istanbul alone.157 These bankers preformed duties that
of the Ottoman Empire and son-in-law of the financier Abraham Kuleliyan, recorded
interest rates ranging between 12 percent and 24 percent. See }ahiner, “The Sarrafs
of Istanbul,” 33 and Jamgocyan, “Les finances de l’Empire Ottoman,” 285–86.
Ronald Jennings notes (“Loan and Credit in Early 17th Century Judicial Records,
The Shari"a Court of Anatolia and Kayseri,” JESHO 16 [1973]: 184, 190, 214)
that interest rates ran as high as 20–24 percent per year.
153
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 134–35. Entire provinces—Adana, Tripoli,
Rakka (Urfa), and the entire tax farm apparatus of a region, such as the muhassılık,
of the Morea, Cyprus, and Aydin, were awarded to local gentry or incoming gov-
ernors. According to D’Ohsson (Tableau générale, vol. 6, 279), twenty-two sancaks (out
of sixty-three) were held directly as malikâne-i miri (imperial malikâne). For one exam-
ple, see D.B}M 3546 (1759–60).
154
The Carmona, Aciman, and Gabay family firms were associated with the
janissaries. For more on this connection, see Robert W. Olson, “Jews in the Ottoman
Empire in Light of New Documents,” Jewish Social Studies, 41 (1979): 75–88.
Syrian Christians served as bankers of the Egyptian elite, after Ali Bey who had
broken his Jewish bankers. See John William Livingston, “Ali Bey al-Kabir and the
Jews,” Middle Eastern Studies 7 (1971): 221–28.
155
Many sarraf families traced their origins to northeastern Anatolia, near the
cities of Van, Sivas and Harput, at the crossroads of the long-distance transit trade
in silk and proximate to the silver mines of Gümü{hane, Keban, and Ergani. Hagop
Levon Barsoumian, “The Armenian Amira Class of Istanbul.” (Ph.D. diss., Columbia
University, 1980), 90. D’Ohsson, Tableau générale, vol. 3, 175–76; Jamgocyan, “Les
finances de l’Empire Ottoman,” 285–86.
156
}ahiner, “The Sarrafs of Istanbul,” 71. CDp 193.
157
Ahmet Refik, Hicrî On (kinci Asırda Istanbul Hayatı (1100–1200) (Istanbul: Devlet
113
Matbaası, 1930), 193–94. Credit for monetary reform in the eighteenth century
must also be given to the financiers. The Armenian Duzian family assumed the
position of intendant (emin) of the imperial mint in 1757.
158
(nalcık, “Hawala,” 283–85; M. Zeki Pakalın, Osmanlı Tarih Deyimleri ve Terimleri
Sözlü[ü (Istanbul: Milli E[itim Bakanlı[ı Yayınları, 1971) vol. 2, 58. Çizakca, Business
Partnerships, 141. See also Halil Sahillio[lu, “Bir Mültezimin Zimmet Defterine göre
XV. Yüzyıl Sonunda Osmanlı Darphane Mukataaları,” IFM 23 (1963): 145–218.
Jamgocyan, “Les finances de l’Empire Ottoman,” 308. After 1788 the state tried
to borrow directly from the financiers. Rates of interest varied (}ahiner, “The Sarrafs
of Istanbul,” 33, 55) according to the relationships between the parties. Financiers
also borrowed (or invested) monies from high officers and courtiers. On Selim III’s
policies concerning credit for contracts, see Yücel Özkaya, “III Selim’in Imparatorluk
Hakkındaki Bazi Hatt-ı Humayunları,” Ankara Üniversitesi Osmanlı Tarihi Ara{tırma ve
Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 1 (1990): 341–42.”
159
CS 884 (1743) is a petition from Seyyid (brahim, cuhadarba{ı of the palace
requesting special exemptions for Mikail, son of Bo[az, in recognition of twenty
years of loyal service.
160
Özcan, Anonim Osmanlı Tarihi, 22. A century later we hear the same com-
plaints and accusations. Abdullah Efendi Tatarcık (“Selim-i sâni devrinde Nizâm-ı
Devlet hakkinda mutâl"aât,” Türk Tarihi Encümeni Mecmuası 8 (1333/1914–1915): 17),
an advisor to sultan Selim III (r. 1789–1807), made a blanket accusation: “Every
Armenian from Kemah or E[in who possesses a few thousand kuru{,” uses a Muslim
front for their own operations; for this thousand they are able to milk the peas-
antry of “300–500 kese of akçe [125,000 to 208,000 kuru{] in an iltizam.” See also
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 144–48.
161
D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 3, 175–77. From 12 to 24 percent interest,
“depending on the circumstances.”
114
162
Çizakca, Business Partnerships, 155–58.
163
Tabako[lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken, 131, n. 28. A 1714 rescript prohibited
the sale of malikâne mukataa to non-Muslims.
164
Ahmet Kal’a, Ahmet Tabako[lu, Salih Aynural, et al. eds., (stanbul Ahkâm
Defterleri (stanbul Finans Tarihi (1742–1787) (Istanbul: Istanbul Ara{tırmaları Merkezi,
1998) vol. 1, 61.
165
Hamilton A. R. Gibb and Harold Bowen, Islamic Society and the West: A Study
of the Impact of Western Civilization on Moslem Culture in the Near East (London: Oxford
University Press, 1950 and 1957) vol. 1, pt. 2,24, n. 4; Wright, Ottoman Statecraft,
77; Özde[er, “III. Ahmed"in Varidât ve Defteri,” 321, 331, 343.
166
MMD 9613 (1809–1810), “ân yed-i sarraf.”
167
Süleyman Efendi, }em"dâni-zâde Fındıklı Süleyman Efendi Tarihi Mur"i"t-Tevarih,
ed. M. Münir Aktepe (Istanbul: Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi Yayınları,
1978) vol. 2A, 68–69.
168
Mumcu, Osmanlı Devletinde Rü{vet, 226, 237.
115
169
“. . . Gerçi bu hususda bunlar {er"an katle müstahak de[iler-idi,” Süleyman
Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, 2A: 68–69.
170
See Joseph E. Matuz,“Contributions to the Ottoman Institution of the (lti-
zam,” JOS 11 (1991): 237–49; Bistra Cvetkova, “Recherches sur le systeme d’affermage
(Iltizam) dans L’Empire Ottoman au cours du XVIe XVIIIe s. par rapport aux con-
trées Bulgares,” Rocznik orentalistyczny 27 (1964): 111–32 and Bruce McGowan,
Economic Life in the Ottoman Europe, 61.
171
Khaled Abou El Fadl, “Tax Farming in Islamic Law (Qibalah and Daman
of Kharaj): A Search for a Concept,” Islamic Studies 31 (1992): 5–32.
172
KK 5040:2.
116
to the chief mufti himself, who would represent their interests before
the sultan.173 Given ulema involvement at all levels in the tax farm-
ing system, by the time of the Hanefite scholar Ibn Abidin
(d. 1836–37) the very question had become moot.174
Formative, too, was the role of the religious establishment in cre-
ating the legal foundations for private finance in Istanbul and Bursa,
as well as other Anatolian and Balkan cities. The debate surround-
ing the innovation of vakıf al-nukud, that is, a foundation or trust
(waqf ) based on liquid capital remains one of the stranger chapters
in Hanefite jurisprudence. The debate raged between jurists and pro-
fessors during the first half of the seventeenth century. Here, the
contravention of Islamic law was scarcely a matter of interpretation.
The laws on endowments dedicated to pious or family ends specifically
dictate the use of rents from fixed capital, such as urban real estate
or agricultural lands.175 These discrepancies had not troubled Ottoman
elites and by the time the practice came to the notice of leading
jurists, the practice was widespread, particularly in Istanbul and
Edirne. In addition to pleasing their patrons, Istanbul ulema’s will-
ingness to bend the rules may also speak of a certain degree of altru-
ism. Coinciding with a period of rising taxation, the cash endowment
might have functioned as a type of credit union that offered crafts-
men, traders, and town residents needed loans as well as providing
support for orphans and widows.
Istanbul Muslims established an average of five new cash endow-
ments a year in the period between 1685 and 1781. Many, perhaps
most, of these endowments functioned as investment banks. They
realized “rents” by furnishing Jewish and Christian financiers with
capital at prime rates of interest, ranging between 6 and 15 percent.176
173
D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 3, 175–76. On transfer of title or ceding shares,
the fees were set at 2 percent for the chief herald or çavu{ba{ı, 2.5 percent for the
kadıasker (chief judge) of the Balkans, and .75 percent for the kadıasker of Anatolia.
174
See Abou El Fadl, “Tax Farming in Islamic Law.” For an example of how
malikâne-iltizam contracts were used privately, Kal"a et al. eds., (stanbul Ahkâm Defterleri,
vol. 1, 147.
175
Jon E. Mandaville, “Usurious Piety: The Cash Waqf Controversy in the
Ottoman Empire,” IJMES 10 (1979): 291–98.
176
}ahiner, “The Sarrafs of Istanbul,” 32–33, 38–39, 45. After 1763, the rate of
interest offered by endowments appears to have been fixed at 7 percent. See also
Haim Gerber, “The Monetary System of the Ottoman Empire,” JESHO 25 (1982):
308–324.
117
Many of the 1,624 cash endowments at the end of the century were
located in neighborhoods closest to the Porte and state offices.177
State debt involved the religious authorities in other ways. As
judges, the ulema were actively involved in many transactions between
lender and debtor.178 They ruled on disputes between financiers.179
Together with local military authorities, judges helped collect prin-
cipal and interest on “Islamically sanctioned loans” (cihet-i karz-i {er"îyle)
owed to non-Muslim bankers.180 In general, they carried out their
duties with fairness and stood by the credit system regardless of the
rank of the borrower.181 Whether it be the governor who owed 16,565
kuru{, the business transaction of the wealthy merchant (bazirgân)
named Sarkis,182 or far more modest debtors,183 the entire central-
state and provincial apparatus was set into motion to make sure that
some payment was made. Months of correspondence and investiga-
tion were often needed to disentangle layers of credit and debt com-
plicated by subfarming.184
Given state supervision of financial institutions and collection, it
should come as no surprise that Ottoman officials initially balked
when it came to accepting foreign instruments of credit and pay-
ment, despite having signed an article governing letters of exchange
177
Kurt, Para Vakıfları Nazariyatı, 91, 162. In a half century Istanbul added 886
new cash waqfs.
178
Jamgocyan, “Les finances de l’Empire Ottoman,” 226–33.
179
DA III:55. In 1763–64, orders were sent from Istanbul to collect funds in the
amount of 10,000 kuru{ from a Mardin resident, Sama"ano[lu Karbas Yorgi.
180
A hüküm (DA III:231) sent on behalf of two Armenian financiers in Istanbul
to officers overseeing the city of Mardin ordered the payment of balance 5,750
kuru{ on a debt that was being repaid in installments between 1757 and 1762. In
another case we find a certain Agop in pursuit of a Mardin resident by the name
of }eyhzâde Hacı Ahmed (DA IV:77 [1783–84]); the text speaks of an “Islamically
contracted loan” (cihet-i karz-i {er"iyle) of which 5,100 kuru{ remained outstanding.
For other examples of collection through the state, see DA III:267, DA II:6, and
DA II:282.
181
A hüküm (DA III:267) was issued in 1775 to the governor and the kadı of
Mosul on behalf of Anton, resident in Istanbul, who was seeking repayment of 1500
kuru{ from the probate estate of the former governor of Tripoli, Abdülfattah Pa{azâde
Mir Abdürrahman, who had been the borrower.
182
DA III:231.
183
DA II:6; DA II:282.
184
Ohannes and Mardus (DA II:191) from Istanbul demanded 9,485 kuru{ from
the voyvoda of Çar{ınacak, Osman A[a. The voyvoda in turn claimed his own remit-
tance was delayed because the subfarmers had failed to pay him; for examples from
Sivas and Aleppo, see respectively SA XIII:28 and HA IV:11, 72; for loans between
non-Muslims, see Kal"a et al., eds., (stanbul Ahkâm Defterleri, vol. 1, 25.
118
185
Edhem Eldem, “The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills,” in V. Milletlerarası
Türkiye Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, ed. Hakkı Dursun Yıldız, Inci Enginün, and
Emine Gürsoy Naskalı (Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1990), 579–89 and idem, “Le
Commerce Français d’Istanbul au XVIIIe Siècle” (Thèse de doc., University of
Provence, Aix-Marseille I, 1988), 131–37, 199. On letters of exchange, see also
Pierre Vilar, A History of Gold and Money (London: Verso, 1984), 216–21, 242–43,
273–76.
186
See Edhem Eldem, “The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills,” 579–89.
187
Michael Gilsenan noted the parallels with the Roman “sparsio.” See Alain
Caille and Jean Starobinski, Critique de la Raison Utilitaire: Manifeste du Mauss (Paris:
La Découverte, 1989). For gold policy under Ahmed III, see Edhem Eldem, French
Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999), 113–19; and Ekrem
119
More than symbolic, Ahmed III’s reign did bequeath his nephew,
Mahmud I (r. 1730–1754), a state on solid financial foundations,
thanks in part to his vizier’s staggering fortune that passed into the
state’s coffers. Yet the solidity of the empire’s political economy was
not only the product of currency reform and good accounting. It
owed to the gradual merging of two treasuries under the aegis of
the Porte’s administrative apparatus. A complex system of contracts
and patronage helped orchestrated this gradual integration while del-
egating many duties to the upper-ranking members of the ruling
estate and, as we shall see in the next chapter, to the provincial
gentry.188
Fiscal patronage anticipated formal bureaucratization of the state.
The contracting system expanded rapidly over the first half of the
century, although oversight lagged.189 Under Ahmed III’s son Mustafa
III (1757–1774) and his vizier Koca Ragıp Mehmed Pasha (1757–1763),
the pace of financial consolidation picked up speed. One of the last
redoubts of palace autonomy, the crown endowments for the Holy
Cities, finally surrendered to the grand vizier’s oversight and the
once powerful kahya of the palace was banished. Yet the challenge
to the consolidation of the “state” remained: on the one hand, to
circumscribe the autonomy of those who controlled the privy purse
of the sultan and, on the other, to cultivate the financial ties among
and beyond the aristocracy of service all the while maintaining the
political subordination of the cadres, individuals, and clans who car-
ried out the tasks of provincial administration.190 With the pretext of
pressing military and financial needs, in the wake of the disastrous
defeat by the Russians in 1774, the bureaucracy would withdraw
some of the most valuable revenues from the malikâne market entirely.
Kolerkiliç, Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda Para Tarihi (Ankara: Do[u{, 1958), 99–100; Anonim
Osmanlı Tarihi, 250.
188
The treasury was swollen with sureties from the malikâne. Tabako[lu, Gerileme
Dönemine Girerken, 298.
189
Already in 1698–99 (KK 4050:37–38) there were complaints about subad-
ministrators (muba{ir) who were remiss in their payment of the nominal mal, that
was due in three installments annually. A “münavebe” or “rotation” system was
adopted later in the century, making one of the largest shareholders responsible for
collecting the rents and dividing the profits among the partners. Mehmet Genç,
“Iltizam,” Islam Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul: Türkiye Diyanet Vakfı, forthcoming), cited in
Çizakca, Business Partnerships, 174.
190
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 100–101.
120
191
Aydin, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Esham Uygulaması,” 154–58. See appendices,
table XII.
192
Süleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 31. Mehmet Genç, “Esham,” Islam
Ansiklopedisi (Istanbul: Türkiye Diyanet Vakfı, 1995), 11:375–80. Norman Itzkowitz,
“Mehmed Raghib Pasha: The Making of an Ottoman Grand Vizier” (Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1959).
193
Ms. Canay Sahin, a Ph.D. candidate at Bilkent University, is in the process
of editing the register of one of Istanbul’s financiers whose clients included mem-
bers of the gentry throughout the empire.
121
the reader might discern the logic of rule and appreciate the bases
of the empire’s social cohesion. By bringing the reader into this
charmed circle, Vehbi also imparted a certain knowledge of the
whole, a view from the summit denied the ordinary subject.
Each reader might find something to suit his own tastes. The vis-
itor who brought a copy back to Cairo might have been captivated
by the descriptions of monumental candy gardens, the performances
of agile acrobats, or the marvelous products of the capital’s gifted
craftsmen. The memories of the drumbeat of the military band, the
parades of guards in formation, and the lavish banquets awaiting
the men of the state, may have inspired a commander (serasker) by
the name of Ali Pasha, to purchase a copy before leaving on assign-
ment to Diyarbekir. Auctioned along with his personal effects, the
manuscript eventually found its way back—hundreds of kilometers
from his last posting—to the imperial treasury.194
194
For the location of other copies of this work, see Atıl and Koc, Levni and the
Surname, 43. In 1744, Ali Pasha’s personal copy (TKSK MS. B 223) was confiscated
by the state.
CHAPTER THREE
While the painters in the palace atelier were re-creating the candy
flowers and wreaths of court pageant long past, the clerks of the
Bâb-ı Âli tended another garden.
The imperial archive represents the “art of governing” writ large.
Through its reports, orders, certificates, requisitions, and audits, the
state ruled over many peoples and provinces. Yet where chapter 1’s
map and chapter 2’s festival book crack open a window on a read-
ily discernible (if nonetheless misleading) visual order, the ledgers of
the empire’s eighteenth common era, or twelfth century after the
Hijra, seems to slam shut a dialogue with modernity.
Indeed, in the mirror of one of its many registers—say, a page
drawn from a master accounting of malikâne revenue contracts in the
“province of Diyarbekir” (figs. 3 and 4)—the archive seems less a
garden than an overgrown thicket: a chaotic jumble of entries inscribed
across a now-tattered and worm-eaten Venetian folio. Its caption,
the names of a pair of villages, “Kürd Hasan” and “Meslahî,” cor-
responds to no designation on the contemporary map.1 Nor does it
follow firmly in the tradition of cadastration perfected in the empire’s
earlier centuries; in place of neat rows describing crop types and
yields, we see knots of scribal shorthand, or siyakat, tangled refer-
ences, notations, and the minutiae of dates and formulae that overflow
the page.2 Rather than an exhaustive accounting of rural population
or current income from crops on a sancak-by-sancak basis,3 nearly an
1
MMD 9518:17. Only one of the two settlements bears some type of spacial ref-
erence (to the district of Çermik, a town some fifty kilometers northwest of present-
day Diyarbekir).
2
MMD 9518. This is but one of many “master” registers for the networks of
provincial tax farming: for Tokat, MMD 9543, 9559; for Athens, MMD 9512; for
Mosul, MMD 9611; for Damascus, MMD 9530, 9538; for Erzurum, MMD 9517;
for Crete, MMD 9503; for Bosnia, MMD 9520; for Aleppo, MMD 9482.
3
For an exhaustive treatment of Ottoman diplomatics, see Mübahat S. Kütüko[lu,
Osmanlı Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik) (Istanbul: Kubbealtı Akademisi Kütür ve San"at
Vakfı, 1998). For facsimiles of the classic register, see L. Fekete, Die Siyaqat-Schrift
in der Türkischen Finanzverwaltung (Budapest: Akademiai Kiadó, 1955), esp. vol. 2.
123
Son, Seyyid
Sons, Seyyid
Ömer
Salih & Elhac Ibrahim
1724
Seyyid 1726
Feyzüllah
1725
entire century’s worth of tax revenues from two villages (or likewise,
tribes and commercial revenues scattered throughout town and coun-
tryside) is subsumed in a perfunctory table: the initial amount of
3,485 akçe is rounded up to 12,000 akçe in 1708–9, after which there
is no further reassessment of value.4
Like the “obscure, ill ordered, incomplete, and slovenly” pages of
the tax registers that greeted Tocqueville in his foray into the ancien-
régime archive, these unseemly documents might strike us as evi-
dence of the “progressive decay” that brought low a great empire.5
Yet such an idealized vision of a classical age past and a naive appre-
ciation of the bright future of transparent government only further
confound our passage through the tangled forests of the Ottoman
old regime archive.6 Enlightenment authors did advocate a new sci-
ence of statecraft, a “governmentality,”7 they bequeathed to the
Physiocrats and Prussian statisticians. Most, like Colbert, who in 1679
dreamt of a comprehensive cadastral map that would document the
agrarian state of France in its entirety, found it impossible to real-
ize their projects. Foreign conquest and colonialism did unfetter the
bureaucrat’s imagination. Without the impediment of a potent aris-
tocracy or deference to local custom, colonial administrators, such
as William Petty, deployed “political arithmetic” to reduce the sev-
enteenth-century Irish economy to numbers, just as Lord Cornwallis
would annex eighteenth-century Bengal with his surveyors.8
4
My initial assumption was that these registers were kept in the provinces by
provincial treasurers, or even local voyvodas and muhassıls because their period coin-
cides with the Nizam-ı Cedid (1793–1807) and the Tanzimat (1839–76). For provin-
cial record keeping, Yavuz Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im Dönemi (XVIII.
Yüzyıldan Tanzimat’a Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan Yayıncılık, 1986), 331.
5
Alexis de Tocqueville, The Old Régime and the French Revolution (Garden City,
N.Y.: Doubleday & Company, 1955), 16.
6
Cf. Brinkley Messick, The Calligraphic State: Textual Domination and History in a
Muslim Society (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).
7
See Graham Burchell and Colin Gordon, eds., The Foucault Effect: Studies in
Governmentality: With Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1991).
8
Although the short leases on the Great Farm of the English customs were
phased out in the early seventeenth century, Britain continued to farm revenues in
Canada until the mid-nineteenth century and in India until the “Permanentment
Settle” with Bengal in 1793. See Ranajit Guha, A Rule of Property for Bengal: An Essay
on the Idea of Permanent Settlement (Durham: Duke University Press, 1996), and Anthony
Pagden, “Dispossessing the Barbarian: The Language of Spanish Thomism and the
Debate over the Property Rights of the American Indians,” in The Languages of
Political Theory in Early-Modern Europe, ed. A. Pagden (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987), 79–98.
126
9
Article 22 of the Treaty of Paris (1763) specified the fate of French archives,
allowing for “Tous les Papiers, Lettres, Documens, et Archives, qui se sont trouvés
dans les Pays, Terres, Villes, et Places qui sont restituté et ceux appartenans aux
Païs cédés, seront délivrés, ou fournis respsectivement, et de bonne Foy, dans le
mêmes Tems, s’il est possible, de la Prise de Possession . . .” See Zenab Esmat
Rashed, The Peace of Paris, 1763 (Liverpool: University Press, 1951). Theodore M.
Porter (The Rise of Statistical Thinking, 1820–1900 [Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1986], 25) attributes the peculiarities of the pre-modern archive to an epis-
temology fixed on status rather than economics and social stratification.
10
“Papers of the remotest date, if singly the year of the transaction is known,
may be found at the Porte; every command granted at that time, and every reg-
ulation then made can be immediately produced.” Observations on the Religion, Law,
Government and Manners of the Turks (Dublin: Printed for P. Wilson, 1768) vol. 2, 131.
11
See Mehmet Genç, “A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Financial Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity,” in The Ottoman
Empire in the World Economy, ed. Huri Islamo[lu-Inan (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987), 345–373; and Ariel Salzmann, “Measures of Empire: Tax Farmers and
the Ottoman Ancien Régime” (Ph.D. diss., Columbia University, 1995), introduction.
127
Questions of Jurisdiction
As one turns the first pages of the register, the eye searches for a
signpost, a label. The round, clear script employed for cataloging
promises a “Register pertaining to the Life-leases here-indicated
[ located] in the [ jurisdiction] of the province of Diyarbekir” (“Defter-i
Mukataât-ı Malikânehâ-i Mezkûre der Eyâlet-i Diyarbekir”).
Yet like much else of the old regime, this register is not exactly
what it appears to be. The province, or eyalet, which we first encoun-
tered in chapter 1, was as much an historical as a territorial notion
of space. The jurisdictional lines produced in the empire’s first decades
in this region were buffeted by the political, economic, and social
tempests of later centuries. While retrofitting its administrative archi-
tecture, Istanbul clung to the formalities of a command structure
that bound cavalry to district captains, governor-commanders, and
12
For more on the city of Amid (today’s Diyarbekir/Diyarbakır in Turkey) and
the province of Diyarbekir, see Yılmazçelik, “XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır
1790–1840,” 2 vols. (Ph.D. diss., Fırat University, 1991) (hereafter, “XIX. Yüzyılın
ilk Yarısında”), and his monograph XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır, 1790–1840
(Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1995) (hereafter, Diyarbakır).
128
viziers. Even as new officials came to fill the gaps between older
forms of administration and the new, or simply to carry out mun-
dane functions of governance, the Porte continued the convention
of issuing directives (hüküm) to the vali or beylerbeyi on such issues as
security at the frontier, policing the province, the collecting of debts
and taxes, and the enforcing of land administration.
Older jurisdictional forms would continue to cast long shadows
over the archive. However, the bureaucrat who consulted this reg-
ister must necessarily have been apprized of another reality on the
ground. The caption on the first entry brings us to the point: it is
not, as one might have expected a summary of the administrative
code of a district or the income accruing to the governor’s estate.
Instead, an expanding column of taxes, dues, and levies is subsumed
below the heading “The tax units [that form part of ] the voyvodalık
of Diyarbakir and dependencies and [values] current from the first
of Mart 1149 (1737).”13 Beneath this is the sum of the annual remit-
tance (10,352,231 akçe) and a table listing multiple adjustments and
additional revenues. Income from a Sufi lodge, special dues from a
battalion of soldiers ( gilman), unassigned imperial estates in Arabgir
and Çemi{gezik, an unassigned timar in Mardin, and, after 1776, a
share in the import tax on tobacco, magnify the jurisdictional space
and enlarge the range of contractual relationships represented within
this single tax farm.
The term voyvodalık does not only signify a large and aggregate
malikâne contract with an intendant of its own or a valuable resource
that attracted some of Istanbul’s most prominent rical. As a kalam
or eklâm, it was also a provincial fiscal bureau that had absorbed a
considerable portion of the state-designated wealth of this province,
but particularly the interstitial dimension of its fiscal and political
structure as well as most of the life-leases awarded within this region.
Its etymology contains a microhistory of a polyglot, Eurasian regime.
Whereas eyalet traces its roots to the Arabic lexicon and Islamic prece-
dent, the term voyvodalık derives from a Slavic noun. A voyvoda refers
to a subcommander. In the sixteenth century, it was the title of the
civil governor of the Black Sea states under Ottoman suzerainty.
Recycled through the machinery of the imperial administration from
the Balkans to northern Anatolia and Kurdistan, the title stuck to
13
MMD 9518:1–2.
129
14
This is but one of many names for an analogous phenomenon: provincial trea-
suries largely made up of revenue contracts that are supervised by intendants. These
provincial treasuries are called, alternately defterdarlık (for Damascus), muhassıllık (for
Aleppo), and nezaret (in Silstre and Rusçuk). For the state of many of these tax
farms in Diyarbekir before this reorganization under new provincial bureaus (eklâm),
see Rhoads Murphey, Regional Structure in the Ottoman Empire: A Sultanic Memorandum
of 1636 A.D. Concerning the Sources and Uses of the Tax farm Revenues of Anatolia and the
Coastal and Northern Portions of Syria (Wiesbaden: Otto Harrassowitz, 1987), 181.
15
MMD 10,143:233. Phraseology reproduces this ambiguity, referring to tax
farms “within and outside the jurisdiction of the voyvodalık, that is in the judiciary
districts of Ergani, Siverek, Çüngü{, Hani and Barzani [Birazî] . . .” (der canib-ı
Diyarbekir harec-i voyvodalık ve dahil-i voyvodalık).
16
The number of constituent districts (sancak) in the eyalet grew from 19 in 1733,
to 27 in 1747, and finally to 30 in 1797 (Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 128–29). D}S
360:50 (1736) adds the districts of Mihrani and Çe{ke. See also Mouragea D’Ohsson,
Tableau général de l’Empire othoman, divisé en deux parties, dont l’une comprend la législation
mahométane; l’autre, l’histoire de l’Empire othoman (Paris, Imp. de monsieur [Firmin Didot]
1787–1820) 6:300; and F. Akbal, “1831 Tarihinde Osmanlı Imparatorlu[unda Idari
Taksimat ve Nufus,” Belleten 15 (1951): 621–22 which records the following sancak
130
Fig. 5 Shifting jurisdictions in Ottoman Asia. After (brahim Yilmazçelik, XIX Yüyzıllın (lk
Yarısında Diyarbekir (1790–1840) Ankara Türk Tarih Kurumu. 1995 appendix 4.
Courtesy of Türk Tarih Kurumu.
131
in 1831: Amid, Hani, Mazgird, Mifarkin, Harput, Sincar, Isiirt, Siverek, Ergani,
Anade (?), Hısnkeyf, Çemi{gezik, Nisiybin, Çapakçur, Sa[man, Çermik, Kulp, Iklis,
Penbek, and Pertek, in addition to the hükümet of Palu, Genç, Cizre, E[il, Hazzo,
Tercil, and Savur.
17
On the back and forth of branches of the Milan tribe between 1711 and 1724,
see Halaço[lu, (skan Siyaseti, 52, 114. For later efforts, see the “Tribal Settlement
Registers” of 1146/1733 published by Cevdet Türkay: Ba{bakanlık Ar{ivi Belgeleri"ne
göre Osmanlı mparatorlu[u"nda Oymak, A{iret ve Cemaâtlar (Istanbul: Tercüman, 1979).
18
Mustafa Cezar, Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler (Istanbul: Güzel Sanatlar Akademisi,
1965), 434–35. For events in neighboring provinces of Mosul, see Kemp, Territoire
de l’Islam; and Yasin al-'Umari, al-Durr al-Maknûn fî al-Ma"âthir al-Mâdiya min al Qurun,
3 vols., critical ed. by Sayyar Kawkab 'Ali al-Jamil (Ph.D. diss., University of St.
Andrews, 1983); Herbert L. Bodman, Political Factions in Aleppo, 1760–1826 (Chapel
Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1963); T. Niewenhuis, Politics and Society
in Early Modern Iraq, Studies in Social History (The Hague-Amsterdam: International
Institute of Social History, 1982).
19
Cezar, Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler, 294, 434–35.
20
Xavier de Planhol, “L’évolution du nomadisme en Anatolie et en Iran. Étude
comparée,” in Viehwirtschaft und Hirtenkultur. Ethnographische Studien, ed. L. Földes
and B. Gunda (Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1969), 69–93. These were the quasi-
132
24
MMD 9518:73.
25
DA III:50, 164; IV:71–72.
26
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 170. These “tribes” were officially recognized in the
province of Mardin in 1747: the Mihi, Tausi, Piran-o-Zencir, Karadar, Ri{ail,
Kabalı, Maski, Birnek, Cevzat, Hindülü, Telermen, Karacahisar, Ihrahimiye, Bilali,
Kalemtra, }eyhhan-i Zencir, Kültülü, Selah, Tekük, }i[levan, Kavus, Telfeyyaz,
Makbele, Kiki, Ömeriyan, Milli (Milan) }arkiyan, Kalenderan, Mir Sinan, Bayraklı,
Araban, Büyükhan, and Behdire.
27
Timars and Zeamets in the province of Diyarbekir
Sources: 'Ayn-i 'Ali Efendi, Kavanin-i Al-i Osman, ed. M. Tayyib Gökbilgin (Istanbul, 1960); KK
493:1–30.
134
28
Cti 4668.
29
MMD 9518:75.
30
M}S 195:12. Although in 1764 the governor of Diyarbekir apparently made
the rounds of Mardin to collect his “salyane” (see also DA III:276); typically, how-
ever, Istanbul deferred to the local administrators. See DA III:221 addressed to the
Mardin judge and voyvoda concerning the claims of a sipahi in a canton still within
Amid sancak in 1771.
31
On the extension of the province of Baghdad to the east and north, Niewenhuis,
Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq, 240; also Suavi Aydin, Kudret Emiro[lu,
Oktay Özel, and Süha Ünsal, Mardin A{iret-Cemaat-Devlet (Istanbul: Tarih Vakfı,
2000), 164–65. For a travel account from 1766, Carsten Niebuhr, Reisebeschreibung
durch Syrien und Palästina nach Zypern und durch Kleinasien und die Türkei nach Deutschland
und Dannemark (Hamburg: Friedrich Berthes, 1837) vol. 2, 395–96.
32
Niewenhuis, Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq, 24. MMD 9518:101. The
contracts on these farms were ceded in 1751 to Suleyman Pasha; and in 1769 for
110,000 kuru{ to Ömür Pasha, also of Baghdad. Other contracts were administered
directly by Mardin’s voyvoda (see MMD 9518:103 [1731]).
135
33
DA II:243.
34
Aydin et al., Mardin A{iret-Cemaat-Devlet, 182–83, 197.
35
Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 122–23. For eighteenth-century infor-
mation relative to the reassignment of timar, see also DA IV:45; DA III:191. In
1795–96, 624 timars and zeamets paid 177,000 kuru{ (Cezar, Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler,
464).
36
D}S 360:35–38. The number of avârız hanes (an accounting unit representing
a number of fiscal “houses”) dropped from 2,022 in 1701 (808,900 akçe) to 2015.5
in 1723–24; however, income rose to 999,600 akçe. (MMD 1347:2; MMD 5781:8;
MMD 10,166:231). As for the avariz in Diyarbekir in the sixteenth century, see
MMD 7637:2–4 for the year 1003 (1594–95); the rate was 2 kuru{ per household
in the city, and 3 kuru{ per household in the district (kaza); ciziye was based on
70,000 persons.
37
On the famine of August 1758, see MMD 10,200:230; for later occurrences,
see Süleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 25; Charles Issawi, ed., The Fertile
Crescent, 1800–1914: A Documentary Economic History (Oxford: Oxford University Press,
136
1988), 96; and Antoine Abdel Nour, Introduction à l’historie urbaine de la Syrie Ottomane
(Beirut: Publication de l’Université Libanaise, 1982), 70.
38
Cti 4668. In Amid’s eastern district ({ark-ı Amid), the toll was somewhat less:
of 75 timar, 15 were ruined and another 17 “no longer existed.”
39
On the drastic decline of timar holdings in Aleppo, compare Jean-Pierre Thieck,
“Décentralisation ottomane et affirmation urbaine à Alep à la fin du XVIIIème
siècle,” in Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq, ed. Mona Zakaria
et al. (Beirut: Centre d’Études et de Recherches sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain,
1985), 129.
40
MMD 9518:3. In 1719–20, it was assumed by the former inspector of the
imperial mint, Suleyman Efendi, together with Seyyid Abu Bakr Efendi, for 1,200
kuru{. Typically, there was a “local” partner, such as Mustafa A[a from Erzurum
in 1726–27 and later Huseyn A[a, who, we are told, was a member of the retinue
of (brahim, the former voyvoda of Diyarbekir, 1728–29. Another contract regarding
the defunct estate of the provincial treasurer (mukataât-ı hass-ı defterdarlık-ı hazine-i Diyarbekir
nam-ı di[er çeske). This too was in the hands of central-state officers (see TKSA E
10,129). They also relied on local subcontractors: in 1740–41 (D}S 360:35), three
Diyarbekir residents, Elhac Ali A[a, Huseyin A[a, and Halil registered, making
their payments to Istanbul partners.
41
Thus Çermik, which held no timar in 1609, recorded thirty-one at the end of
the century. See n. 27 above.
137
42
DA III:14 (1758–59); MMD 3677:11 (for rates of rice in 1697); Van Bruinessen,
Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 40, 167–79, 193; D.B}M 5508; DA III:78 (1764–65); DA
II:92.
43
Charles Issawi, ed. An Economic History of Turkey (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1980), 218–20. Wheat was sown in the early fall and barley from November
to February, both were harvested in June and July; they were milled and stored in
August.
44
Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 23. In the seventeenth century, Amid
provided about 50 percent of the levies; Harput, 11 percent; and Ergani, 10 per-
cent. According to MMD 9891:224 in 1741, a century later, the distribution of
wheat levies was as follows: of 1 million kilos of flour (39,300 kile/25.64 kilos)
requested, the capital district provided approximately 10 percent (99,996 kilos or
99.9 metric tons); Hani and Çermik furnished 76,920 kilos; Harput, Ergani, and
E[il, nearly 20 percent (184,608 kilos); Hisnkeyf (205,120 kg); Siird (128,200 kg);
Çapakcur, Palu, Savur, Atak, Mihrani, and Tercil provided more than a quarter
of the total (284,604 kg). On the basis of the cizye of 1797 (D.B}M 6292, 81,950
kuru{), one finds that non-Muslim populations, presumably the largely Armenian vil-
lagers and town-dwellers, were particularly concentrated in the central districts of
the province (Eastern and Western Amid and in Amid itself ) and to the west and
north in the districts of Harput, Palu, and Çar{ınacak.
45
MMD 9518:93.
138
the rank of kapıcıba{ı, between 1740 and 1774, the intendant of mines
actually superseded the governors of Sivas and Diyarbekir in mat-
ters pertaining to production and supply in the mine.46 Within his
districts, he resettled miners and requisitioned carters. He comman-
deered wood for firing into coal, wax for candles to illuminate the
shafts, beasts of burden for hauling, and grain for fodder.47
Few examples illustrate more vividly the complex and overlapping
lines of jurisdictional control under the old regime, or the total inver-
sion of prior categories of rule, than the role of the Ergani complex
with respect to the eyalet hierarchy. As a member of the aristocracy
of service with access to the Istanbul auction, the intendant of mines
might hold a share in Diyarbekir’s voyvodalık, the large, composite
tax farm administered by the province’s voyvoda. By awarding short-
term tax contracts, subfarming his own, confirming guild appoint-
ments, recognizing members of the gentry, and encouraging members
of his own family and household to acquire tax farms in the dis-
tricts under the command of the governor of Diyarbekir, the mine
administrator built his own sociopolitical infrastructure in the region.48
In a final episode that turned the military and administrative hier-
archy of the sixteenth century on its head, in 1794 Yusuf Ziya Pasha,
whose tenure as intendant of mines was one of the longest, absorbed
the governorship of Diyarbekir itself.49 Shunning the provincial cap-
ital, he ruled from Ergani, while consolidating his control over the
industry by acquiring shares in the valuable life-lease on the smelt-
ing factory of Amid.50
46
DA III:52 (1774–75). Instructions are sent to the Ergani intendant to track
down a “bandit” living in Amid itself.
47
Fahrettin Tızlak, Osmanlı Döneminde Keban-Ergani Yöresinde Madencilik (1775–1850)
(Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1997), 15; see the register of the Intendant of Mines edited
by Hasan Yüksel, 1776–1794 Tarihli Maaden Emini Defteri (Sivas: Dilek Matbaası,
1997), 108–9, 121, 126–28.
48
Tızlak, Osmanlı Döneminde Keban-Ergani, introduction, 76; Yüksel, 1776–1794
Tarihli Maaden Emini, 109; a former intendant of the Keban Mine, Mehmed A[a,
held a quarter share in 1723.
49
Mehmed Süreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osmanî; yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i Osmaniye (Istanbul:
Matbaa-i Âmire, 1308–15/1890–97), vol. 4, 670–71. Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"arâ-i
Amid (Istanbul: Matbua-i Amidi, 1328/1910–1911) vol. 1, 141. Yusuf Ziya Pasha
began his career as a clerk in 1789. He was promoted to the position of mir-i miran
in 1793–94 as intendant of mines. In 1798, he was promoted to grand vizier and
then returned to Ergani as intendant of mines in 1807. The income of the inten-
dant of mines between 1795 and 1802 was 117,776 kuru{ (Tızlak, Osmanlı Döneminde
Keban-Ergani, 58–63). See also n. 206 below.
50
MMD 9519:9 (1795).
139
51
Traian Stoianovich, “The Segmentary State and La Grande Nation,” in Geographic
Perspectives in History, ed. E. Genovese and L. Hochberg (Oxford: Oxford University
Press, 1989), 258–59. D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 7, 299, translates nahiye ( judi-
ciary districts) as canton as well.
52
When I first showed these registers to Nejat Göyünç, one of the foremost
authorities on land tenure in this region, he threw up his hands in despair, com-
menting that the term “nahiye” had a very elastic meaning. For lists of villages in
the eighteenth-century district of Amid (both Eastern and Western), see Yılmazçe-
lik, Diyarbakır, 151–60. Register MMD 9518 includes tax farms in different desig-
nations, including villages in the judicial districts (kaza) of Garb-ı Amid (2), }ark-ı
Amid (6), Amid (16), }ark-i and Garb-i Amid Mixed (6), Savur (16), Hani (30),
Hani and Savur (11), Kaza-yı Çermik (17), Barzani (13), Birecik (1), Atak (1), Kulp
(7), Ergani (30), and Kuh-i Mardin (2). In addition, there were 45 unidentified
“makataât” and one “maktuât ” as well as 33 tribes (a{iret).
53
The large imperial estates created in the original administrative division of
Syria and Kurdistan account for many of these tax farms. Barkan, “Timar,” 288,
estimates that 31 percent of the land in Diyarbekir itself was set aside in crown
estates.
54
For the lists of villages in the eighteenth century, see Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır,
140
144–60. The 46 or more villages under proprietary contract represent in the aggre-
gate a considerable percentage of the district composed of 154 villages in 1758.
55
Both Hanebazar and Dervi{ Hasan do appear on the nineteenth-century map
prepared by Yılmazçelik in his Diyarbakır, appendix. A great many may be within
two kilometers east of the provincial capital. For lists of villages from 1518, see
Ibid, 144, 149; Monla Kuçuk, in Western Amid, figures in the cadastral survey of
1565.
56
We might attribute this disappearance to the very fact of their being “priva-
tized” (bilcümle serbest olma[la) and hence no longer subject to bureaucratic oversight.
But this does not explain registration of the village of }ukru"llah (in Western Amid)
on the lists for 1733, 1747, and 1797, though not in 1738 or 1755; similarly,
}evketlü in 1797 (also Ali Bardak, due north of Amid; Develü in Western Amid
in 1797; Akviran in Eastern Amid, appears on the list for 1747, as two villages,
“upper” and “lower”; and Nureddin in Western Amid, which appears only in
1738–39). Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 151–62.
57
At present, our purpose is not to map the province, particularly given the flux
in settlement and the inconsistent use of geographical descriptions, but to sketch
out the basic political relationships that emerged from these overlapping jurisdic-
tions and the contractualization of property and rent relations.
58
KK 3105 (1721); MMD 9518:90 (1734–35).
141
59
MMD 9518:75. Regarding timars in the canton of Mardin, which originally
turned over to the voyvoda of Diyarbekir. In 1777, the miralay of Mardin, Seyyid
Abdullah, purchased the contract on these villages for 150 kuru{.
60
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 41–42.
61
MMD 9815:77 (1781).
62
DA IV:19; DA II:97; DA I:52, 68.
63
There was not always a distinction between post and resources. During the
years 1689–94 (TT 831:38 (1689–94/1100–1105) the voyvodalık was held twice as
a two-year tax farm by other tax farmers by the names of }ahban A[a, Uzun Ali
A[a, and Mehmed A[a, quite probably local janissaries. Uzun Ali had a guaran-
tor named Ahmed A[a.
64
MMD 10,168:252 (1725–26). The number of “hane” (a fiscal unit, or household)
in the eyalet of Diyarbekir was 2015.5 for the avarız and 2704 for the bedel-i nüzül,
which yielded 20,788 kuru{ esedi. See also MMD 9518:73, a lump sum farm (maktu)
of the avarız and the bedel-i nüzül for villages “East and West in Diyarbekir which
are off the register.”
142
from Istanbul carried out a roll call of contractors to collect the spe-
cial wartime levy demanded of all malikâne holders, it was the voyvoda
who handled much of the day-to-day management of the tax farms.
He must have supervised auctions, requested adjustments or new
certificates.65 He handled the retration (refi, zapt, ibka) of shares or
entire contracts that had been improperly awarded or were poorly
managed.66
As violence escalated in the countryside, the voyvoda’s coercive abil-
ities must have grown apace. His personal guard could not have
been inferior to that of the voyvoda of Siverek (technically subordi-
nate to him), who, we are told in a 1742 judgment against him,
routinely sent his deputy (vekil ) and scribe (kâtib) with “thirty or forty
horsemen” to villages to demand 5 to 10 kuru{ in special gifts ( pi{ke{),
in addition to legitimate requests for avârız, the imdad-ı hazariyye, and
the imdad-ı seferiyye.67 Indeed, in 1777 the voyvoda (smail, of whom I
will speak again, raised two thousand mercenary troops for the defense
of Iraq against the Zand armies, a number equal to that raised by
the governor of Mosul.68
Beyond the chain of payments and certificates that linked them
to the voyvoda or to high-ranking partners or benefactors in Istanbul,
contractors were fairly autonomous. By 1717, 156 individuals were
listed as holders of malikâne mukataât in Diyarbekir. This was far fewer
than in the larger and wealthier district of Aleppo but still greater
than the number of contractors in Damascus. In 1717, local con-
tractors held 179 tax farms in Diyarbekir (venal offices, villages, fields,
and tribal resources). In 1730, that number reached 205.69 In 1787,
the global value of sureties paid on malikâne contracts in the region
had risen to 147,863.5 kuru{ approximately double that of 1717
(78,029.5 kuru{).70 Yet the agriculture sector, especially the small con-
65
MMD 4748:2; MMD 9518:50, “by request of the voyvoda” (“ba arz-ı voyvoda”);
MMD 9518:44, 50.
66
DA I:127 (1747–48). A tax farm on a settlement with seventeen peasants who
were growing cotton in the vicinity of Western Amid was retracted by order of the
treasurer to the Diyarbekir voyvoda Elhac Ahmad. The period of the 1730s and
1740s saw the highest rate of repossession. Of these, the Suvidî a{iret (“tevâbi
Mehmed ve Hasan kethüda”), valued at 1,150 kuru{, was revoked in 1740 and again
eight years later. MMD 9518:21, 22, 28, 33, 42, 43, 50, 51, 64, 71, 73.
67
DA I:17.
68
Cezar, Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler, 454–57. Each soldier was paid 36.8 kuru{.
69
Central-state investors’ bids outstripped those of locals four to one (MMD
4748:75, 48, 16, 76).
70
MMD 3677:2–3, 12–16.
143
71
MMD 9566 (1787) (excluding those in Ergani).
72
The need for codes and a new cadastral survey was noted in a preface to a
register on Sivas and Tokat (MMD 9481:1–2, 34 (1692–1717). Land sales in the
“vicinity of the city” were subject to a 10 percent surcharge.
73
Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 177–79.
74
A peasant çiftlık ranged from 80 to 150 dönüm in Diyarbekir depending on land
quality. (Halil (nalcık, “Osmanlılarda Raiyyet Rüsûmu,” Belleten 23 (1959): 582, n. 27).
However, the meaning of the çiftlık in the following contexts is far from clear: one
reads of three “çiftlik bagçesi ” belonging to a member of the ulema, Seyyid Hacı
Osman; DA I:50; in 1744–45 a çiftlik in Sa[man district; a mülk çiftlik (“ma"alum al-
hudud ”) in 1767–68 (DA III:173); Mustafa Kasem and Isa petitioned in the same
year concerning 5 mülk çiflik (DA III:176); in 1755–56, Fatma Hatun in Çemisgezik
claimed a çiftlik bequeathed by her father, DA II:52; Yuzo Nagata, too, notes that
a çiftlik can be any tract of land (Tarihte Âyânlar: Karaosmano[lulları üzerinde bir (nceleme
[Ankara: TTK Basımevi, 1997], 98).
75
DA I:206. A 1750 rescript given to a central-state officer (Mehmed Silahsôr)
in the district of Mardin; similarly D}S 360:57, a plot awarded because it was not the
“imperial estate, zeamet or timar or vakıf of anyone, [but] off the books (harez az defter).”
76
MMD 9518:75.
144
77
Nonetheless, there were many cases of overlapping jurisdictional rights involv-
ing malikâne, timar, vakıf, and ocaklık. DA II:279; DA I:68; DA III:173.
78
DA I:134, 199, 206, 219; DA II:97.
79
MMD 9486:6.
80
See also DA II:94; DA III:141; and DA III:143, which concerns a certain
Emine Hatun petitioning Istanbul over a çiftlik in a village in Pertek in 1766.
81
DA III:195; DA II:192; MMD 9486:6.
82
DA II:315. In 1760–61, this included a mülk çiftlik and ninety-one peasants,
which the state declared a crown estate, part of the havass-ı hümayun and not pri-
vate property (mülk).
83
Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne Sistemi,” 284–88.
145
84
DA II:23.
85
DA III:141.
86
DA I:127; DA III:4.
87
Compare Göksu canton (DA II:214) in 1760 with Savur (DA I:199) in 1750
and the çiftlik in Ergani (DA I:134) in 1748.
88
DA II:16.
89
Nagata, Tarihte Âyânlar, 100.
90
DA II:26; also in Tokat (1714) MMD 3139:188.
91
DA I:244. On the maktu see also Halil (nalcık, “Military and Fiscal Transforma-
tion in the Ottoman Empire, 1600–1700,” Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1980): 334.
146
92
DA II:241.
93
DA II:250; DA III:141; DA I:16.
94
DA III:434; DA II:218; DA I:160.
95
DA II:42.
96
DA I:160.
97
DA II:93; DA I:26.
98
DA II:21; DA I:108.
99
DA II:216.
100
DA II:23. Be{ir, also of Istanbul, accused the entire provincial administration—
from the mir-i mirân, the mir alayı, the mütesellim, and the voyvoda, to the alay beyi—
of routine, illegal intervention in his contracted villages.
147
narrow margin between legal taxes and subsistence. Even in the best
of times legal taxation represented only the tip of the iceberg of
quasi-legitimate payments cultivators paid to those holding land as
contract or tax fief. The private accounts of an Istanbul courtier
from 1728 to 1737 concerning “our share-croppers” (bizim ekiciler)
for villages, apparently in coastal Anatolia, provide some idea of this
burden: farmers paid not only annual revenues from olive oil, bar-
ley, and wheat but also special fees such as the pi{in akçesi, taken in
cash or in kind, in addition to payments of interest on previous
loans.101 Peasants were often unable to meet their annual taxes and
required loans of seed, animals, or equipment to make the next
planting. Money lending by tax farmers trapped the peasant in a
cycle of debt. It also anchored the contractor’s claims for genera-
tions because Ottoman judges recognized villagers’ debt and held
them liable for repayment of principal and interest even after the
contract lapsed or passed to another party.102
Such conditions might drive cultivators to take drastic actions. We
know the names of the inhabitants of Misr Kale village in the dis-
trict of Ergani who declared a strike, refusing to pay tithes during
the famine years of 1759, 1760, and 1761. Bilalo[lu Ali, (brahimo[lu
Mustafa, }eyho[lu Kara Ali, Kurt Hüseyino[lu Ali, Mecnuno[lu
Mecnun, and Osmano[lu Hasan all suffered the consequences: beat-
ings and even death.103 Others voted with their feet, fleeing tax-lord
oppression and debt.104 Not a few, like the peasants of the district
of Hani who headed toward so-called askerî çiftlikler (perhaps some
form of ocaklık?) may have sought the promise of better soil and
lower rents.105 In response to two military officers who complained
that the villagers from their malikâne holdings under the jurisdiction
101
D.B}M 1624:65–66. Compare Abdul-Karim Rafeq, “Changes in the Relationship
between the Ottoman Central Administration and the Syrian Provinces in the
Sixteenth to the Eighteenth Centuries,” in Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History,
ed. Thomas Naff and Roger Owen (Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press,
1977), 53–77.
102
Compare Margaret Meriwether, “Urban Notables and Rural Resources in
Aleppo, 1770–1830,” IJTS 4 (1987): 69–72; Abdel Nour, Introduction à l’historie urbaine
de la Syrie Ottomane, 394–95.
103
DA III:9. A peasant who was accused of rebelliousness in Ergani was sen-
tenced to exile. Yüksel, 1776–1794 Tarihli Maaden Emini Defteri, 113–15.
104
In the district of Savur in 1746, peasants had already deserted a maktû settle-
ment of 2,000 akçe awarded as a malikâne. DA I:261–62.
105
DA III:283.
148
106
DA II:222. They fled to former tribal lands, in Hani, Tercil; the state con-
tacted the deputy judges of Mehranî and Atak, as well as Eastern and Western
Amid, with descriptions of the former inhabitants of the village of Cevre named
Musa, Osman, Resul, another Osman, and the “sons of the Circassian” who had
left to settle in “some towns and villages and askerî çiflikler,” and ordered that “in
whatever region they were found they should be removed and sent back and reset-
tled in their own villages.” (See DA III:116; DA III:132; DA IV:84.)
107
DA III:129.
108
Flight was a problem throughout the Asian provinces. See Yucel Özkaya,
“Osmanlı Imparatorlu[unda XVIII. Yuzyılda Göç Sorunu,” Ankara University DTC
Fakultesi, Tarih Arastırmaları Dergisi 14 (1983): 171–203.
109
Salzmann, “Measures of State,” 173–75. MMD 1637:730; MMD 3677:4–8.
In 1703, 195 individual contracts were awarded in Diyarbekir; 259 in Aleppo; and
210 in Tokat. In contrast, only 222 were awarded in all of the Balkans.
110
Villages in Diyarbekir over the period 1714–91 (MMD 9518:14, 15, 18, 20,
27, 38, 40, 42, 45, 50; not all of these entries had sufficient data to include in this
analysis).
111
Our register does not tell who these individuals are—were they townsmen
149
who had resettled in the countryside, yeoman farmers, or village heads? However,
their presence in the villages themselves during the last decades of life-term con-
tracting coincides with the emergence of the class of village strongmen (the “agha”
or “a[a”) who figure in subsequent Kurdish agrarian history. Haim Gerber, The
Social Origins of the Modern Middle East (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1987), 114.
112
For the ulema in Aleppo: Mohammad Tahazâde, a former nakib"ül-e{râf (rep-
resentative of the descendants of the Prophet), alone possessed 18.5 percent of the
total state contracts, much in the fertile district of Jabal Sima'an. The recent cat-
aloging of provincial finance records holds must promise. See, for example, D.B}M-
MLK 1:13 (Hazine-i Musul) berat awarded to Dervis Seyyid Mehmet “from among
the ulema” for half a share in a field (mezraa) (1730–31).
113
DA IV:168 concerns the appointment of an imam in a town outside Diyarbekir
in 1786–87.
114
MMD 9566 (1786–87).
115
DA II:104. Three Naqshbandi shaykhs named Mustafa, Mehmed, and Sadrullah
put a better-armed sipahi, Osman, on the defensive, forcing him to turn to the state
to ascertain whether their contract on Kırk Paykar, with its twelve registered peas-
ants and two çiftliks (valued at 8,811 akçe) in Ergani, overlapped with his own 11,450
akçe timar at Tuna Viran.
116
A certain seyyid, Mühiddin of Palu (DA II:237), insisted on his rights con-
cerning an iltizam, bolstered by a fetvâ (religious opinion) issued in his favor by the
}eyh"ül-(slâm. Molla Seyyid Hüseyin, who held a malikâne mukataa in the eastern
district of Amid, was granted permission to pass these rights to his son, along with
a fruit tree grove (DA I:17). A woman named Sofiya Hatun appealed to the state
for protection against the demands of a certain malikâne holder who claimed her
private field; she received an opinion that was to be put into effect by the state
authorities (DA I:237; DA II:35).
150
Although our register does little to aid us in our search for coordi-
nates and addresses, auction records and ledgers of new certificates
do provide the names and a few other pertinent details about new
contractors. Among the first to purchase tax farms in the Diyarbekir
region was Shaykh Kasim Efendi, one of the two muftis of Amid,
who invested a sizable sum, 310 kuru{, for the lease on a village,
Monla (molla, in Diyarbekir’s dialect). Mustafa and his partner, Ebu
Bekir, acquired a village contract, as did Sa"ad Shaykh Ahmed,
117
CM 28,020.
118
CM 14,147.
119
CM 28,020.
120
In addition to the quarter share in (drislü village in Eastern Amid, he also
held the contracting rights to another three villages in the district of Hani for a
total investment of 753 kuru{ at the time of death. CM 14,147.
121
D.B}M 6772. His share was half an Amidî mud (220 cubic decimeters) of
wheat flour, as was his sister Rakiye’s (Raziye?) and his two brothers Mesud’s and
151
Mehmed’s, among thirty-six other distinguished members of the ulema and broth-
erhood or tarikat. In the same year (1799–1800), total payments in local salaries,
stipends, and subsidies from the local budget came to 5255.5 kuru{ or 630,660 akçe.
122
MMD 3677:1–3, 12–15.
123
MMD 10,143:233.
124
Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 33–34.
125
Yılmazçelik, “XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında,” 208.
126
The first Carmelite mission in Basra was established by the Portuguese in
1622; a Catholic Presbyter was found in Diyarbekir by 1730. (Herman Gollancz,
ed., Chronicle of Events between the Years 1623 and 1733 Relating to the Settlement of the
Order of Carmelites in Mesopotamia [Bassura] [London: Oxford University Press, 1927],
634.) Walter J. Fischel, ed. and trans., Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels
of Rabbi David D’Beth Hillel (1824–1832) (New York: Ktav Publishing House, 1973),
72–74. It is difficult to gauge the size of the Christian population in the eighteenth
century. After the 1819 uprising, which devasted the population, the survivors were in
roughly equal numbers Muslim and Christian. M. Fahrettin Kırzıo[lu, “Kara-Âmid’te
152
man and his family. Moreover, Amid did not lack for well-trained
scholars and lawyers who had graduated from its many fine religious
academies. Thus, Istanbul appointees began to delegate their author-
ity and duties, albeit at the lower rank of deputy judge, naib, to local
dignitaries.138
Graduates from the Amid academies also held temporary and full-
time positions in other municipal offices, including clerkships in the
courts. Occasionally, as we saw in chapter 2, a talented and ambitious
man might make his way into the ranks of the central-state bureau-
cracy. Perhaps the increased opportunity for service within the province
contributed to a lack of “outward” mobility. The Porte certainly rec-
ognized the substantive contribution of the ulema to the order of
urban life, and it rewarded Amid’s scholars and the leaders of the
local Gül{eni and Naqshbandiyya brotherhoods with special stipends
and honoraria. This was a regular part of the voyvodalık budget under
the heading of du"â-güyân, guardians of local morality.139 Their tax-
exempt status was reconfirmed by the }eyh"ül-(slâm, who also verified
claims of membership in the e{râf, descendants of the Prophet.140
Rather than being strictly representatives of the central state, the
provincial officers who staffed the citadel and the fortresses of the
province and who acted as the urban gendarmarie functioned as a
bridge between Istanbul and Amid. Although there is no evidence
of a parallel corps of janissaries the so-called yerli recruits, as in
Damascus or Aleppo, the members of Amid’s corps cultivated con-
nections in many directions. On one hand, they maintained close ties
to central authority, through the governor, who could recommend
promotions to the rank of fortress captain (kale kethüdası, dizdar). Local
officers remembered to offer the captain of the janissary corps in
Istanbul “gifts” (câize) to obtain new postings, such as Cairo.141 Not
138
Yılmazçelik, “XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında,” 436–37, 431. Other court posi-
tions, such as ba{katıp, also appear to have been filled by local appointees.
139
D.B}M 6772; 7336; 1814; MMD 19,080. Compare with Damascus: Barbir,
Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 81; Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 51; Hamid
Algar, “The Naqshbandi Order. A Preliminary Survey of Its History and Significance,”
Studia Islamica 44 (1976): 123–52.
140
DA III:216; DA III:158; DA III:153–54; DA III:55; DA I:16. This in part
explains the ambiguous role of the local ulema during this period; they actively
sought perquisites like tax farms and malikâne and yet often seconded petitions by
peasants against spurious taxation. DA I:25.
141
Jane Hathaway, “Years of Ocak Power: The Rise of the Qazdagli Household
and the Transformation of Ottoman Egypt’s Military Society, 1670–1750 (Egypt)”
155
the income (voyvoda kalemiyesi ) over to the governor. At this time, the voyvoda was
responsible for collecting the avârız and the bedel-i nüzül; he received fees for the
military district (sancak) and military appointments (tahvil ); the son, Yunus Bey was
appointed the revenue agent (emin) of the stamp tax on cloth (damga) as well as
supervisor of the çeske (once the estate of the provincial defterdar). Kunt, Bir Osmanlı
Valisinin Yıllık Gelir Gideri, 42,49, 53, 70, 204, 255, 280–81, 329, 159, 144; CD 2819
(1777) suggests a three-year appointment. See also Cezar, Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler,
454–56; Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 200–3.
147
D.B}M 6538 (1798) audit of the income of the voyvodalık from 1797 onward.
148
MMD 10,143:233.
149
Nonetheless, local bidders were successful in this sector. They included Küçük
Ali, whose large farm on the excise tax (bac-ı ubur) was later rescinded; an associ-
ate of Hadarzâde, Mehmed Emin the janissary Mustafa, the çavu{ a[ası Kara Ali;
as well as a merchant (bazirgân) and Kasim Efendi one of the two muftis of Amid.
MMD 3139:247, 369. For registers of certificates see the kalemiye register, MMD
777:21.
157
bership in the urban community was not only the mosque or the
church but also the trade association, or esnaf.150 Craftsmen, shop-
keepers, and small-time traders all participated in such associations.
Although we lack a complete roll of all such professions or a full
description of their organization, a 1792 register of taxes carried out
the kadı lists forty-two individual associations. They include whole-
sale and retail businesses such as coffee sellers and cotton whole-
salers ( pembeçiyân), dealers in ready-made goods (oturakçı), and associations
that come closest to the notion of a guild, such as the manufactur-
ers of mixed cotton and silk cloth (bezzazân). At this time, the high-
est dues were paid by the wealthiest tradesmen, such as the grocers
(bakkalân) and dyers (boyaciyân), and by a guild whose trade was prob-
ably the most widely practiced in the city, the weavers (hallacân).151
A traveler who visited the city in 1815 estimated that there were
some 1,500 workshops, among them 500 were devoted to cotton-
stamping, 300 to leather working, and 100 to ironsmithing.152
The contracting of guild dues affected both guild leaders or shaykhs
and the rank and file in unpredictable ways. To the extent that it
turned the position of head of the guild into a venal office, it may
merely have given official sanction to a preexisting trend toward con-
centrating the position of shaykh, and therefore power within the
guilds, among certain families.153 This seems to have been the case
with the position of maktuât of the cotton-fluffers (cullahân). It was sold
in 1715 for 100 kuru{ to two men wealthy enough to have made
the pilgrimage to Mecca, residents of the quarter named for the
Iskender Pasha Mosque, and their nephew, who lived near the Mardin
Gate. The family retained at least a 25 percent share of the contract
150
Gabriel Baer, “Ottoman Guilds: A Reassessment,” in Türkiye"nin Sosyal ve Ekono-
mik Tarihi (1071–1920), ed. Osman Okyar and Halil (nalcık (Ankara: Meteksan/
Hacettepe University, 1980), 96; Haim Gerber, “Guilds in Seventeenth-Century
Anatolia Bursa,” Asian and African Studies 11 (1976): 59–86. Compare this case with
Manisa; see M. Ça[atay Uluçay, XVII inci Yüzyılda Manisa"da Ziraat, Ticaret ve Esnaf
Te{kilâtı (Istanbul: Resimli Ay Matbaası, 1942).
151
MMD 9519:81; see also D.B}M 1069:4. In 1717, the total protoindustrial
installations in Çünkü{ yielded 10,200 kuru{ in taxes; the dye house alone was worth
1,025 kuru{. See Yılmazçelik, (Diyarbakır, 605–10) for another list.
152
Buckingham, Travels in Mesopotamia including a Journey from Aleppo, 80, 195, 214.
153
In an important manufacturing city such as Aleppo, the intrafamilial nature
of guild appointments in this period is very pronounced; for empirewide trends, see
Tuncer Baykara, Osmanlı Ta{ra Te{kilatında XVIII. Yüzyılda Görev ve Görevliler (Anadolu)
(Ankara: Vakıflar Genel Müdürlü[ü Yayınları, 1990), 118–37.
158
154
MMD 9518:68; MMD 9519:102.
155
MMD 9518:62, 68; MMD 9519:95, 102.
156
CM 14,097. One of Istanbul’s müderris, Seyyid San"allah Efendi, petitioned in
1786, complaining that his share on the weavers’ association dues was being mis-
managed by his local partner, Süleyman “so and so,” who engaged in pilfering
monies and illegally collecting duties ( fuzulî ahz ve kabz). Despite holding a smaller
share (only one-fifth), the local partners’ familiarity and proximity gave them unde-
niable advantages. The complaint prompted an audit by an officer from the palace,
the silah{ör Abdullah A[a, and a ruling in favor of the Istanbul partner.
157
A malikâne contract conferred upon the position of head shaykh ({eyhlik ) of the
guilds was awarded in 1743.
158
CB 1375. Elhac Osman had held the office of kethüda or steward of the mar-
159
ket (bedestan) as a three-year tax farm or iltizam with an annual payment of 25 kuru{
until the farm was converted into a malikâne contract.
159
MMD 9518:62, 77; MMD 9519:111.
160
On this point, see Baber Johansen, “Amwal Zahira and Amwal Batina: Town
and Countryside as Reflected in the Tax System of the Hanafite School,” in Studia
Arabica and Islamica Festschrift for Ihsan 'Abbas on his 60th Birthday, ed. Widad al-Qadi
(Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1981), 247–63.
161
Ömer Lûtfi Barkan, XV. ve XVI. inci Asırlarda Osmanlı Imparatorlu[unda Ziraî
Ekonominin Hukukî ve Malî Esaslari (Istanbul: Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi
Türkiyat Enstitüsü Ne{riyatı, 1943) vol. 1, 549–52.
162
CM 12,742, “maktû dellâllık-ı yuban bezi der Diyarbekir.”
163
KK 5249. The document consists of two main sections: a lengthy itemized
section dating from the 1790s and an appendix dating from 1807–13, when }eyhzâde
(brahim became the de facto ruler of the city. The annotations, which were added
by the judge, appear to have been made after (brahim Pasha’s death in 1814.
160
164
Ibid. Indian generic cotton stuffs (metâ"i ) (and perhaps yarn) were taxed in
bulk. Kurdistani and Syrian goods warehoused in the city and taxed by animal-
load (donkey load, 68 para [60 para equaled one kuru{]; camel-load, 820 para; and
horse-load, 34 para), such as soap, mazu dye, henna, and possibly Mosul cloth, and
in the late eighteenth century, the copper processed in the local refinery (kalhâne),
which was exempt from such taxation. A. S. K. Lambton (“Persian Trade Under
the Early Qajars,” in Islam and Trade in Asia, ed. D. S. Richards (Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1970), 221) estimates a camel load as 400 pounds, a mule load
at 240, and a horse load at 130.
165
For the scale of proto-industrialization, see Peter Kriedte, Peasants, Landlords
and Merchant Capitalists: Europe and the World Economy, 1500–1800 (Warwickshire: Berg
Publishers, 1983), 70–76. On the specificity of the regional market in manufactures,
see comments by James Brant, “Journey through a Part of Armenia and Asia Minor
in the Year 1835,” Journal of the Royal Geographical Society 10 (1841): 383.
166
J. S. Buckingham (Travels in Mesopotamia, 84, 214), notes that stamping cotton
“renders the cloth in that state nearly double the price it bears when white.”
161
167
MMD 9519:81; see also D.B}M 1069:4. In 1717, the total protoindustrial
installations of Çünkü{ yielded 10,200 kuru{kuru{kuru{ in taxes yearly; the dye house
alone was worth 1,025 kuru{.
168
MMD 9916:110.
169
The kadı’s glosses above the itemized section of KK 5249 already show con-
siderable discrepancy between the “official” prices and current prices upon which
ad valorem taxes (of 5 percent) were based. In an 1814 report (MMD 10,262:219),
administrators noted that the gross underestimation of tax on Indian cloth resulted
in an eight to ten times underpayment (at the rate of 30 para per batman of goods).
Already in the last decade of the eighteenth century, the actual rates of internal
gümrük stations were subject to much variation, depending on local agreements and
rivalries between regimes. Also, Issawi, The Fertile Crescent, 178–79.
170
Katsumi Fukasawa, Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e siècle d’Alep à Marseille
(Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et d’Ètudes sur le Proche Orient Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985).
162
cottons woven in towns like Mardin, Çermik, Hazzo, Palu, and Har-
put, all within Diyarbekir province itself.171 When entrepreneurial
janissaries attempted to purchase cotton manufactures or perhaps to
engage in forms of putting out in the surrounding countryside,172 the
guilds had no need to rise to the occasion. Instead, the tax farmer
defended the interests of Amid’s weavers, objecting to the fact that
the janissaries’ actions allowed them to evade payment of the black
stamp tax (damga-ı siyah).173
The main impact of tax farming seems to have been to reinforce
the hierarchy of wealth, power, and influence within the esnaf and the
primacy of the urban market. The privilege of holding such con-
tracts was restricted to Muslims, a symptom of the progress of ver-
nacular government generally. Did this privilege accentuate the
differences between confessional groups? In economic terms, proba-
bly not. By early modern standards, Amid was a fairly integrated
city; one of every three of its townsmen lived in a confessionally
mixed neighborhood.174 Both Muslims and Christians were counted
among the largest esnaf, though they reported to different masters,
shaykhs and ostads, respectively.175 Both groups benefited from the
protectionism afforded by the tariff system and the emphasis on
maintaining the city’s monopoly on value-added, higher-skilled occu-
pations in manufacturing. Contracts embracing aggregate resources
spread liabilities among ordinary tradesmen, whether Muslim, Chris-
tian, or Jew. For example, the farm on the taxes on the sale of bees-
wax and leather (mahsül-ü rusumât-ı bal-ı mum ve çarm) actually affected
primary materials for two different guilds, one dominated by Muslims
(leather workers), and the other, by Christians (candle makers).176
The question, however, was not merely an economic one. In addi-
tion to reinforcing the trend toward the inheritance of offices such
as guild shaykh, which widened the political and economic gap
between rich and poor tradesmen, tax farming must have altered
the expectations of Muslim elites toward government generally. By
171
KK 5249; see also C( 432 (1797–98), a malikâne on the damgha for cloth pro-
duced in Çar{ınacak and Palu.
172
CM 12,742.
173
MMD 10,246:119. In 1804, this tax, combined with the ihtisab, commanded
a bid of 32,000 kuru{.
174
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 30–31, 46–47, 115–17.
175
CZ 1364.
176
MMD 9518:62, 67.
163
177
MMD 9518:68; MMD 9519:102.
178
Halil (nalcık (“Military and Fiscal Transformation,” 331–32) considers them
a “well-defined” group. See also Albert Hourani, “Ottoman Reform and the Politics
of Notables,” in Beginnings of Modernization in the Middle East: The Nineteenth Century,
164
183
MMD 2931:122. A certain }eyhzâde Ebu Bekir, who took the office of voyvoda
in 1683 with the financial backing of a certain Abidin (based in Istanbul?).
184
Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"arâ-i Amid (Istanbul: Matbua-i Amidi, 1328/1910–1911)
vol. 1, 222–30, 239, 253–54, 115–17, 368–69. Thanks to David Waldner, I was
able to obtain a copy of M. Fahrettin Kırzıo[lu’s “Kara-Âmid"te 1819 da A"yandan
}eyhzâdeler"in Öncülü[ünde Milli Deli-Behram Pa{a"ya Kar{ı Ayaklanma Ve Sonucu,”
Kara Âmid Dergisi 2–4 (1956–58): 350–378, which refers extensively to Abdulgani
Bulduk’s (1864–1951), El-Cezire"nin Muhtasar Tarihi, an important source that was
otherwise unavailable to me.
185
(nalcık, “Centralization and Decentralization,” 33.
186
CZ 541; CM 25,214 (December 1813) pertains to the expropriation order of
(brahim among others.
187
Sakao[lu, Anadolu Derebeyi Ocaklarından Köse Pa{a Hanedanı, 105. The voyvoda of
E[in also volunteered according to Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 108.
188
CZ 541 (1790–91); Mehmed Süreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osmanî; yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i
Osmaniye (Istanbul: Matbaa-i Âmire, 1308–15/1890–97), 1:151; Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır,
43–44, 91.
189
MMD 2931:122. The evolution from tax farmer to intendant occurs over the
166
second half of the seventeenth century. In 1683, Ebu Bekir needed a guarantor, a
certain Abidin (based in Istanbul?), to take charge of three-year iltizam. His duties
included collection of revenues totaling 19,607,908 akçe, of which 2,430,180 akçe
were the avârız and bedel-i nüzül (100 akçe/kurus) In 1689–94 (TT 831:38 [1689–
94/1100–1105]), the voyvodalık (both the position and its revenues) was held twice
as a two-year tax farm by other tax farmers, {ahban A[a, Uzun Ali A[a, and
Mehmed A[a, all of whom were probably local janissaries. Uzun Ali had a guar-
antor named Ahmed A[a.
190
In other cases, such as eighteenth-century Ayintap, the position of voyvoda was
venal and held as a three-year iltizam. See Güzelbey, Gaziantep {eri’i Mahkeme Sicilleri,
103–4. MMD 2931:122 (1683).
191
DA I:151. Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 200.
192
Van Bruinessen, Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir, 124–27.
193
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 238.
194
D}S 315:73–80. He owed money to Vezir Mime{ Pasha, and Çeteçi Abdullal
Pasha of Kerküt; he left his wife 28,454 kuru{. For the follow-up investigations, see
D.B}M 12,532 (1741). For some of the financial networks in Diyarbekir, see the
case of Halil, a former voyvoda at the rank of kapucuba{ı, who lent 7,625 kuru{ to
Mahmud, the sancakbeyi of Çermik (DA I:151). Compare with MMD 9740:82
(1782–83) concerning the former muhassıl Hunkârlizâde elhac Ahmed A[a and his
son Mehmet. MMD 10,000:368 (1768–69) is an example of subfarming of a share
in the voyvodalık by the voyvoda. Compare Suraiya Faroqhi, “Wealth and Power in
the Land of Olives: Economic and Political Activities of Muridzâde Haci Mehmed
Agha, Notable of Edremit,” in Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East,
ed. Ça[lar Keyder and Faruk Tabak (Albany: State University of New York Press,
1991), 77–96.
167
for abuse. But even a voyvoda could not operate with impunity. He
came under the scrutiny, on one side, of a variety of contractors,
venal officeholders, and provincial authorities; on the other, of the
shareholders in the super-tax farm for which he served as either an
employee or intendant. As a contractor himself, he could see his
lucrative holdings retracted and reassigned to others.195 Overall, this
division of labor between shareholders and administrators in the
peculiar type of tax farm known as the voyvodalık provided an addi-
tional firewall against a monopolization of legal, financial, and coer-
cive control.196 But the system of checks and balances worked only
so long as the largest shares remained in the hands of central-state
investors. It broke down, in 1784, for example, when the voyvoda
(smail A[a and a son, (brahim, obtained half the shares themselves.197
It was the inherently divergent interests in the institution of tax
farming, as Jürgen Habermas has opined, that provided an opening
for the “public” in local governance.198 Petitions to Istanbul and
records of subsequent investigations document the misdeeds of then
voyvoda (smail }eyhzâde, who had conspired with the janissary com-
mander (serdar) Gavuro[lu in Diyarbekir to extort money from many
of the city’s residents, including its most prominent citizens.199 Accord-
ing to a final resolution in 1777, their operations had apparently
195
Meriwether, “Urban Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo,” 69. The for-
mer nakib"ül-e{râf of Aleppo, Muhammad Tahazâde, who held nearly one-fifth of
all malikâne lands in the surrounding districts in the last quarter of the century, pro-
vides an apt example. He was exiled and his holdings were expropriated in 1775;
reinstated a decade later, he was shorn of many of his tax farms.
196
In this way it functioned better than Aleppo’s muhassıl: On his “bankruptcy,”
Ahmed Efendi Vâsıf, Mehâsinü "l-Âsâr ve Hakâikü "l-Ahbâr, trans. and ed. Mücteba
Ilgürel (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakültesi Basımevi, 1978), 189. In 1798–99, Aleppo’s
muhassıllık farm was placed in the esham system.
197
MMD 9896:29–30. An early account of the malikâne on the voyvodalık gives its
value as 764,334 kuru{ tâm. In 1700–1701 (MMD 19,080:1), the annual payment
(mal) totaled 13,023,123 akçe; in 1781, the annual remittance from the farm was
10,928,630 akçe (MMD 9518:1, MMD 9519:1–4). The voyvoda held shares in the
voyvodalık during the following years: 1697; 1700–1704 (MMD 1637:152); 1705–6
(MMD 9896:29). Naturally, the entire family, in the case of a local notable might
benefit from these political connections. In 1777, while his father served as voyvoda,
(brahim himself took hold of five-eighths of the total shares in the highly valued
contract on the tobacco taxation (MMD 9519:22).
198
Jürgen Habermas, The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere: An Inquiry into
a Category of Bourgeois Society (Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 1991), 16–19.
199
CD 2819 (1777). On the plague of 1799–1800, which took the life of (brahim
Pasha’s father (smail A[a (as noted by our Baghdad-based historian), see Yasin al-
'Umari, al-Durr al-Maknûn fî al-Ma"âthir al-Mâdiya, 487.
168
continued for quite some time before Amid’s enraged citizenry de-
nounced both men for collusion and oppression of local taxpayers.200
Townsmen not only brought their prestige to the prosecution of
their case against the voyvoda but also took advantage of personal
experience and involvement in Amid’s system of vernacular govern-
ment. As we have seen, more than a hundred of the city’s residents,
including the leading members of the ulema, were contractors them-
selves. They understood the conditions placed on those who held
contracts. They were familiar with the apparatus in Istanbul and
had personal links to members of the religious and administrative
hierarchy. Having identified the parties and interests involved, the
townsmen pursued their greivance. They addressed a petition to the
Istanbul bureaucracy. They also sent separate letters ( ferdân ferdân)
to Abdul Rahman Efendi, Mehmed Tahir A[a, and Ahmed Efendi,
the aristocratic shareholders of the malikâne in Istanbul.
Their strategy worked well enough. The malikâne contractors, who
had invested a very large sum—78,512.5 kuru{ to be exact—as surety,
were naturally concerned about the management of their investment.
The voyvoda was already in arrears in payments.201 The contractors
joined their voices to those agitating for the dismissal of the gentry-
voyvoda, (smail A[a. He was replaced by a certain Seyyid Ahmed
Bey who hailed from nearby Ergani.202
The treasury, however, in the throes of fiscal crises brought on
by the conclusion of the Russo-Ottoman war, including the huge
war indemnity demanded under the treaty of Küçük Kaynarca of
1774, used the uproar as a pretext to take over the tax farm and
reassess its value. A revenue agent was dispatched from Istanbul.203
In what turned out to be the beginning of a more activist posture
by the state, at least once in every decade (1777, 1785, 1786, 1798,
and 1802) the central treasury intervened and replaced local agents
with salaried central-state employees. In doing so, the bureaucracy
acted as a trustee of the voyvodalık, dividing the “earnings” among
200
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 113–14.
201
That is not to say that the system in Diyarbekir was trouble free. See CM
29,248 (1761), addressed to Mustafa Pasha and the kadı of Diyarbekir regarding
collection of 30,386.5 kuru{ arrears.
202
MMD 10,190:170.
203
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 198. The voyvodalık was an emanet in 1777, 1785, 1796,
1802, 1803, and 1819.
169
the imperial treasury and the contractors who held the malikâne.204
The tenacity of vernacular government was proven in the face of
the Nizam-ı Cedid, “New Order,” a program of military and fiscal
reforms initiated after 1793. One of its aims was to reintroduce state
control by the appointment of rical to provincial offices or by reshuffling
local magnates within the larger region of Syria, Eastern Anatolia
and Kurdistan.205 In Diyarbekir, gentry-pashas and appointees from
the aristocracy of service alternated the office of governor. The mobil-
ity of gentry-pashas continued to be circumscribed regionally. After
a brief tour of duty as governor of his native province,206 }eyhzâde
(brahim, one of the former voyvoda (smail’s sons, was assigned to
other posts within West Asia, including the governorship of Jidda in
1800, before returning to Diyarbekir again in 1801. Diyarbekir’s gov-
ernorship was also awarded to other provincial elites, including lead-
ers of the Kiki and Milan tribes, members of the Köseo[lu clan of
Sivas, and (brahim A[a, a retainer of Muhmamad Tahazâde of
Aleppo.207 The differences in career paths remained striking. A cen-
tral-state appointee like Yusuf Ziya Pasha, who rapidly rose from
clerk to intendant of mines, to grand vizier, and to provincial gov-
ernor, might dabble in both center and periphery—indeed, his sons
and associates purchased many village contracts in Diyarbekir dur-
ing his tenure.208 Where Yusuf Ziya Pasha’s investments spanned the
empire, (brahim Pasha made his investments locally. Where Yusuf
Ziya Pasha climbed to the grand vizierate, only with the interreg-
num between 1807 and 1813, could (brahim Pasha aspire to rule
uncontestedly in his native province.209
204
Ibid.
205
To name but two: Cezar Pasha in Sidon who resisted Napoleon; the reform-
oriented Capano[lu of Central Anatolia who countered the Canıkli of Trebizond
and Erzurum.
206
CZ 541 (1205); Sicill-i Osmanî, vol. 1, 151; See also Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır,
43–44, 91–92, 112–13, 172–73, 191–96, 200–202, 250–53.
207
Meriwether, The Kin Who Count, 61.
208
Ali Emiri, Tezkere-i }u"arâ-i Amid, vol. 1, 141. Mehmed Süreyya Bey, Sicill-i
Osmanî, vol. 4, 670–71. His sons and associates held numerous tax farms in the
region, beginning with his first tenure in office. (For holdings of sons Mehmet Beg
and Sabit Yusuf Beg, MMD 9518:27, 28, 33, 38, 57, 78, 98, 104, and 106; and
of his retainers, 84, 85, and 91.) For his income as grand vizier, see D.B}M 7016
(1802–5). He also held a half share in the copper refinery in Amid in 1795–96
(MMD 9519:9). For his earlier career see n. 49 above.
209
Mehmed Süreyya Bey, Sicill-i Osmanî, vol. 1, 151; Diyarbekir Salnamesi (1286/
1869–70), 26; CM 25, 214 (1813).
170
210
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 208.
211
CD 2173. In May 1801, increases in the alum tax were announced in the
Asian provinces Karahisar-ı }ark, Aleppo, Damascus, Arabia, Van, Kars, Tokat,
Erzurum, Sivas, Diyarbekir, Rakka, Beyrut, and Iskenderiye.
212
Süleyman Efendi, Mur"i"t-Tevarih, vol. 2A, 25.
213
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 110–13, 247–51.
171
214
CZ 1364 (30 July 1803) contains a summary of events and includes a copy
of the deposition.
215
Ibid. In his dissertation (“XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında,” 221 [based on D}S
336:79–80]), Yılmazçelik notes that there was only one non-Muslim among the
ninety-eight “rioters” involved.
216
MMD 9518:62, 77; MMD 9519:111. The malikâne contract dates to 1755. On
the mengene taxes, see MMD 9519:10; Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 325. In
May of 1797 (CI 199; CM 14,123), and repeated on October 1804 (MMD 10,246:230):
all cloths—alaca, beyazlı, kutni, gazi, and atlas—were to pay at 30 akçe per bolt.
217
Yılmazçelik (Diyarbakır, 113–14) describes this event in detail, referring not
only to the relevant court documents (D}S 536:79–80) but also to the memoirs
and papers of an early-nineteenth-century administrator, (brahim b. Muhammed
(“Diyarbakır Mutasarrıfı (brahim b. Muhammed"in Hatırat ve Mektupları,” found
in the Elazı[ Museum Archive [Ms. 137]).
218
CM 8741; C( 697. In 1800–1801, (brahim Re{id Efendi, held three-quarters
of the contract; one-quarter was in the hands of the voyvoda Halil A[a.
219
Yılmazçelik, Diyarbakır, 238, 255.
172
Final Entries
220
Ibid., 219–20. In 1804, the esnaf split the cost with the contractor for the
repair of the building (MMD 9519:10).
221
D.B}M 14,094.
173
Fig. 6 Note the difference in the style of a Nizâm-i Cedid register. The top
entry on the last page records the maktu (lump sum tax) owed by several
villages in the kaza of Hani. The lower two entries furnish names of con-
tractors holding various urban offices, including the kethudalık of the bedesten
of Diyarbekir, the delalba{ılık of the “black” bazar and the delallık of the city’s
beyt’ ül-mal. In his summary, the clerk disparages local authorities.
174
rent only for a given year. Written in the well-formed nesih script,
its pages are free of shorthand, siyakat, the bane of the modern
researcher. Despite the remarkable clarity and uniformity of his
expression, the clerk concludes on a sour note. He complains that
he was forced to write the contents out in full: provincials “are unable
to read siyakat,” the trademark of a properly trained bureaucrat.
Feigning mutual unintelligibility, the Istanbul clerk distances him-
self in culture and in social status from his provincial counterparts.
He too was complicit in the denial of a system of government that
had existed with the full approval of the statesmen in Istanbul.
Without formal redrafting, provincial boundaries were redrawn
by combinations of economic and social pressures. Throughout the
Balkans, Anatolia, Syria, and Kurdistan, the treasury awarded hun-
dreds of small contracts on villages and commercial taxes. The con-
tractors, by default, assumed their place in provincial government;
brokers expanded their networks across the province and cultivated
links to larger, transimperial circuits of credit and finance. Although
unwilling and probably unable to assume their duties, clerks and
bureau chiefs in Istanbul used reports and marginalia to vent their
accumulated resentment toward the “petty oligarchy” of local gen-
try, ulema, and officers who constituted the de facto vernacular gov-
ernment.222 In his audit of the finances of Aleppo in 1776, another
Istanbul bureaucrat commented that “for many years, [the tax farm
on the muhassıllık] has been assigned to persons living in the region;
the greatest part of the holders of mukataât being âyan-ı memleket, their
relatives, and their clients (taâllukât) who are chiefly concerned with
their own interests and not with the affairs of the muhassıllık itself . . .”223
Not only are the gentry unworthy of their responsibilities and devoid
of civic virtue, it is impossible to ascertain the true state of affairs
because “the records of the muhassıllık in Aleppo are unreliable and
full of falsification.”224
Indeed, in 1785 the treasurer ordered a full-fledged investigation
of provincial accounting. He targeted provinces with “müfrez” (inde-
222
Tocqueville (The Old Régime, 43) expresses essentially the same sentiment.
Municipal government was run by a “petty oligarchy,” who kept “a watchful eye
on their own interests, out of the sight of the public and feeling no responsibilities
toward less privileged citizens.”
223
Cited in Thieck, “Décentralisation ottomane et affirmation urbaine à Alep à
la fin du XVIIIème siècle,” 125.
224
Ibid.
175
225
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 331–33 (CM 12,343, document dated June
24, 1785). A year before the announcement of the New Order Treasury (Irade Cedid
Hazinesi ) in 1793, the director of the fisc circulated a summary of an investigation
that claimed that the largest portion of the new share-system (esham) had passed
into the hands of “obscure ladies” and “unidentifiable men” resident in the provinces
(see MMD 11,669:2).
226
Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 156, 169; Stanford Shaw, Between Old and
New: The Ottoman Empire under Sultan Selim III 1789–1807 (Cambridge, M.A.: Harvard
University Press, 1971), 19.
CHAPTER FOUR
By the time Tocqueville gathered his notes for The Old Régime and
the French Revolution, a tidal wave of images, words, and armies had
washed away many of the semblances between the old regimes of
Europe and Asia.1 The ideological and material forces unleashed by
the French Revolution, the Empire, the Bourgeois Monarchy, the
revolutions of 1848, and finally, Louis Napoleon’s power seizure had
all but submerged reliable if largely descriptive and chronological
narratives of the Ottoman past written at the turn of the century.2
The bureaucratic state appeared triumphant in the West while the
government of the Ottoman Empire, once the paragon of despotic
centralism, seemed to shatter against the shoals of modernity. Blending
1
Orientalist painting played a role, to be sure. Eugene Delacroix’s “Collection
of Arab Taxes” (1863), today in the National Gallery in Washington, D.C., might
illustrate Tocqueville’s notion that the Ottomans were a “government by conquest.”
A horseman, with drawn sword, is ready to pounce on a hapless peasants. See also,
Henry Laurens, Les origines intellectuelles d’expédition d’Égypte, l’orientalisme Islamisant en
France (1698–1798) (Istanbul: Isis, 1987); Alain Grosrichard, The Sultan’s Court: European
Fantasies of the East (New York: Verso, 1998); and M. S. Anderson, The Eastern
Question, 1774 –1923, A Study in International Relations (Houndmills, Basingstoke,
Hampshire: Macmillan Education, 1987).
2
Mouradgea D’Ohsson, Tableau général de l’Empire othoman, divisé en deux parties, dont
l’une comprend la législation mahométane; l’autre, l’histoire de l’Empire othoman (Paris, Imp.
de monsieur [Firmin Didot] 1787–1820) 12 vols.; Joseph Freiherr von Hammer-
Purstall’s (1774–1856) monumental Geschichte des osmanischen Reiches (Histoire de l’Empire
ottoman depuis son origine jusqu’a nos jours), 18 vols. [Paris, Bellizard, Barthes, Dufour
& Lowell, 1835–43) was to be republished in 1859 in Tours by the Bibliothèque
de la jeunesse chrètienne (Ad Mame).
: 177
3
His involvement in Algerian politics dates to 1828. André Jardin, Tocqueville: A
Biography (New York: Farrar Straus Giroux, 1988), 62, 322–34. See also Alexis de
Tocqueville, Oeuvres compléte: Écrits et discours politique, ed. Jean-Claude Lamberti (Paris,
Gallimard, 1991) 2: 288–309; compare, C. F. Volney, The Ruins, or Meditation on the
Revolution of Empires: and The Law of Nations (Baltimore: Black Classics Press, 1991),
49. M. Alexandre Laya (Études Historiques sur la vie Privée politique et Littéaire de M. A.
Thièrs [1830–1846] [Paris: Chez Furne, 1846] 2:133) the political biographer of
Thièrs, Tocqueville’s archpolitical rival, considered this moment a watershed in
Europe’s perspective on Ottoman sovereignty, commenting that “no more could the
Ottoman Empire be regarded as eternal, as [an entity] that could not die, or even
that it must be saved . . .” For English perspectives on Mehmet Ali Pasha, see
Khaled Fahmy, All the Pasha’s Men: Mehmed Ali, his Army, and the Making of Modern
Egypt (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997).
4
Jardin, Tocqueville, 66, 249–250, 267, 322, 334–335. For a selection of his
writings on these subjects including the epigraph on the previous page, see Alexis
de Tocqueville, Writings on Empire and Slavery, ed. Jennifer Pitts (Baltimore: Johns
Hopkins University Press, 2001).
178
5
His interest in Algerian affairs dates to 1828. Jardin, Tocqueville, 62. Andre
Jardin’s comments (Tocqueville, 322–34) on his attachment to colonial project are
balanced but unsparing.
6
Jardin, Tocqueville, 318. In De la Démocratie en Amérique I (1835) (Oeuvres Complètes,
ed. Jean-Claude Lamberti and James T. Schleifer [Éditions Gallimard, 1992], vol.
2, 104). Tocqueville argued that “Turkish populations never took part in the direc-
tion of the affairs of their society; had they not witnessed the triumph of the reli-
gion of Mohammed with the conquests of the sultans they could have accomplished
great things. Today, religion is gone; all that remains is despotism.” For the some
of the key texts, see Pitts, Writings on Empire as well. Melvin Richter, (“Tocqueville
on Algeria,” Review of Politics [1963]: 362–98) is of the opinion that Tocqueville’s
colonial politics are in flagrant contradiction to his theories of democracy.
7
Pitts (Writings on Empire, “Introduction,” xxxiii) notes that although Tocqueville
at the outset disagreed with J. S. Mill on the need for despotic government to con-
trol “barbarism,” he does not seemed to have opposed the 1848 provision that
demanded Algerians renounce Islam in order to gain French citizenship. See Uday
Singh Mehta, Liberalism and Empire: A Study in Nineteenth-Century British Liberal Thought
(Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999).
8
Jardin, Tocqueville, 334–35.
9
In 1848, Algerians who wanted to gain French citizenship were forced to
: 179
renounce Islam. Compare, Ann Thomson, Barbary and Enlightenment: European Attitudes
toward the Magreb in the Eighteenth Century (Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1987). Sudhir Hazareesingh,
From Subject to Citizen: The Second Empire and the Emergence of Modern French Democracy
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998), 232.
10
Voltaire criticized Montesquieu’s indiscriminate application of the term despo-
tism to all Asian governments. (“Commentaire Sur l’Esprit des Lois”) Oeuvres com-
plètes de Voltaire (Paris: Chez Th. Desoer, Libraire Rue Christine, 1817) vol. 6, 968;
see also comments in Vol. 4, 79. In History of the Latin and Teutonic Nations, Francis
I’s alliance with the Ottomans became an act of betrayal that Leopold von Ranke
held against the French in particular.
11
Ahmed Cevdet Pasha, Tarih-i Cevdet (Istanbul: Matbaa-yı Osmaniye, 1309/1893)
vol. 2, 256. The loosening of the reins over state and government in the periphery
was a constant worry of the bureaucracy as Ya{ar Yücel, (“Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda
Desantralizasyona (Adem-i Merkeziye) Dair Genel Gözlemler.” Belleten 38 (1974):
180
149–52, 657–708) points out. For his advocacy of the policies of the New Regime,
see Christoph K. Neumann, Das indirekte Argument: ein Plädoyer für die Tanzimat ver-
mittels der Historie. Die geschichtliche Bedeutung von Ahmed Cevdet Pa{as Ta"rih. Münster:
Lit Verlag, 1994.
12
On the impact of Küçük Kaynarca on political and military thinking see
Virginia Aksan, An Ottoman Statesman in War and Peace, Ahmed Resmi Efendi, 1700–1783
(Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995); and Mariia Todorova, Imagining the Balkans (New York:
Oxford University Press, 1997).
13
Paul W. Schroeder, The Transformation of European Politics, 1763–1848 (Oxford:
Clarendon Press, 1994), 5–23; Stanford Shaw, Between Old and New: The Ottoman
Empire under Sultan Selim III 1789–1807 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press,
1971), 55–73; Emmanuel Le Roy Ladurie, The Ancien Regime: A History of France,
1610 –1774 (Oxford and Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell, 1996), 447.
14
See Norma Saul, Russia and the Mediterranean, 1797–1807 (University of Chicago,
1970).
: 181
15
After the second partition of Poland, Carl von Clausewitz (On War, ed. and
trans. Michael Howard and Peter Paret [London: Everyman’s Library, 1993],
449–450) asks: “Could Poland really be considered a European state, an equal
among the European community of nations . . .” No, he concludes. It was for that
reason that Europe “yielded Poland like the Turks yield the Crimean Tatar state.”
On Ottoman-French relations during the republican period, see Ismail Soysal, Fransiz
(htilâli ve Türk-Fransiz Diploması Münasebetleri (1789–1802) (Ankara: Türk Tarih Kurumu
1999) and the special issue of RMMM 52/53 (1989) entitled, “Les Arabes, Les Turcs
et la Révolution Française,” ed. Daniel Panzac.
16
See Brendan Simms, The Impact of Napoleon: Prussian High Politics, Foreign Policy
and the Crisis of the Executive, 1797–1806 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1997).
17
See Ranajit Guha, A Rule of Property for Bengal: An Essay on the Idea of Permanent
Settlement (Durham & London: Duke University Press, 1996).
18
Ahmed Efendi Vâsıf, Mehâsinü"l-Âsâr ve Hakâikü"l-Ahbâr, transcr. and ed., Mücteba
Ilgürel (Istanbul: Edebiyat Fakültesi Basımevi, 1978), 367–368; Abd al-Rahman
Jabarti, Napoleon in Egypt: Al-Jabarti’s Chronicle of the French Occupation, 1798, ed. and
trans. S. Moreh (Princeton, NJ: Marcus Wiener Publishers, 1993), 64.
19
Simms, The Impact of Napoleon, 305–312.
182
the Ottoman planners contended with the sheer scale of its territo-
ries and the multiplication of potentially hostile fronts, especially with
the escalation of British and Russian expansion in Asia.20 Istanbul
had lost suzerainty over the restive Crimean khans and was forced
to concede Russian sovereignty over Georgia. While countering British,
French, and Russian overtures to the magnate-governments of Ali
Pasha in Albania and Pasvano[lu Osman Pasha in Bulgaria,21 the
new sultan’s advisors looked nervously across the Kurdish frontier
to Iran, where the last of the Safavid’s tribal offshoots, the Qajars,
had begun to install a more enduring ruling structure. With uncer-
tainty hanging over the succession to pashalik of Baghdad as well,
a leading religious intellectual, Tartarcık Abdullah Efendi tendered
a new administrative map of Iraq. He foresaw the subdivision of the
province into smaller administrative units to contain the Kurdish
tribes and to prevent concentration of powers in Baghdad. Istanbul-
appointed governors would take charge of provincial finance and
military recruitment, duties that had long been delegated to the local
lords and gentry.22
It is such plans for sweeping organizational change that have led
nineteenth-century the regime of scholars, like Cevdet Pasha to com-
pare the regime Sultan Selim III (r. 1789–1807) with the enlight-
ened policies of earlier sultans, including Ahmed III.23 Attentive to
military training, the sciences and engineering, the new sultan also
20
André Raymond, Les commerçants au Caire au XVIII e siècle (Damas: Institut Français
de Damas, 1973–74) vol. 1, 43–50. See also Shaw, Between Old and New, and François
Crouzet, “Wars, Blockade and Economic Change in Europe, 1972–1815.” Journal
of Economic History 24 (1964): 567–88.
21
See Katherine Elizabeth Fleming, The Muslim Bonaparte: Diplomacy and Orientalism
in Ali Pasha’s Greece (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999).
22
Abdullah Efendi Tatarcık, “Selim-i Sâni Devrinde Nizâm-ı Devlet Hakkında
Mutâla"ât,” Türk Tarihi Encümeni Mecmuası 8 (1333/1914–1915), 18–19. The coun-
cil, as Uriel Heyd (“The Ottoman 'Ulemâ and Westernization in the Time of Selim
III and Mahmud II,” in Studies in Islamic History and Civilization, ed. U. Heyd
[ Jerusalem: The Magnes Press, 1961] vol. 9, 83) points out frequently met in the
villa of the }eyh"ül-Islam. Istanbul could not, however, prevent Davud Pasha’s rise
to power 1816 and enlistment of European advisors for his military. Rabbi David
D’Beth Hillel, Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels of Rabbi David D’Beth Hillel
(1824 –1832), ed. and trans. Walter J. Fischel (New York: Ktav Publishing House,
Inc., 1973), 83; and generally, T. Niewenhuis, Politics and Society in Early Modern Iraq
(The Hague-Amsterdam: International Institute of Social History, 1982).
23
Avigdor Levi, “Military Reform and the Problem of Centralization in the
Ottoman Empire in the Eighteenth Century,” Middle Eastern Studies 18 (1982): 227–49.
: 183
24
Cevdet, Tarih, vol. 6, 143.
25
See Alan Fischer, Russian Annexation of the Crimea 1772–1783 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1970).
26
In Egypt (Raymond, Les commerçants au Caire, vol. 1, 43) the silver para lost half
of its value between 1770 and 1798; Edhem Eldem (“Le commerce Français d’Istanbul
au XVIIIe siècle,” Ph.D. Diss. Université de Provence-Aix-Marseille I, 1988, 188)
notes that Istanbul witnessed an equivalent devaluation a decade later: between
1800 and 1812 the kuru{ fell from two francs to one.
27
Gabriel Ardant (“Financial Policy and Economic Infrastructure of Modern
States and Nations,” in The Formation of National States in Western Europe, ed. Charles
Tilly [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975], 216–7) in many ways concurs
with Tocqueville, noting that “the French Revolution manifested itself by the dis-
integration of the state due in large part to the illusion of reformers.”
28
Mouradgea D’Ohsson, Tableau général, vol. 3, 367; As Kemal Beydilli points
out (Ignatius Mouradgea D’Ohsson [Muradcan Tosunyan]: Ailesi Hakkında Kayıtlar,’
“Nizâm-ı Cedîd’e dâire Lâyihası ve Osmanlı Imparatolu[lyndaki Siyâsî Hayatı” in
Prof. Dr. M. C. }ehâeddin Tekinda[ Hatıra Sayısı (Special issue) ed. M. Cavîd
Baysun, Tarih Dergisi (Istanbul Üniversitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi 34 (1983–84): 247–314)
remained an Ottoman patriot.
29
On the impact of the French Revolution on financial markets throughout
Europe: Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the
Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), 180–214.
184
of fiscal privilege from the social fabric woven by the old regime.
The state pressured its creditors. It exacted forced loans from non-
Muslim bankers and compelled them to assume direct financial
responsibility for provincial audits and accounts.30 To raise funds for
the Irade-i Cedid treasury and pay the salaries of the new army, the
Sublime Porte redirected agricultural revenues from the resident cav-
alry and tapped into the life-lease market. Proceeding cautiously at
first, the bureaucrats of the new treasury recycled revenue revenues
into general funds upon the death of the contractor or by attrition.
But there was no mistaking the ultimate aim of the New Order:
to phase out both the classical organizational infrastructure of the
empire, particularly the old-regime military orders, the timar-cavalry
and the janissaries, and to dissolve the semiprivatized revenue sys-
tem that structured of vernacular government.31
Across empire, Nizam-i Cedid policies provoked mistrust, conster-
nation, dissatisfaction and protest. The creation of new military units
and alterations to organizational charters threatened long-standing
immunities of the military corps, such as the janissaries.32 Expropriation
of life-leases over and above a general decline in the income of
shares that had once yielded returns of 35 to 40 percent per annum
as well as increased state fees, struck at the very foundation of the
corporate patrimonialism of the Istanbul elite.33 In provincial cities
30
Sultan Selim III’s decree (Yücel Özkaya “III. Selim"in (mparatorluk hakkında
Bazı Hatt-ı Hümâyûnları,” Osmanlı Tarihi Ara{tırma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi 1
(1990): 341) refers to the “rural gentry and magnates (derebey)” as “usurpers who
fleece the peasantry as tax-farmers . . . [and the] voyvodas and police . . . [as those
who] oppress the poor and have come to have the power of viziers and military
commanders.”
31
Yavuz Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im Dönemi (XVIII. Yüzyıldan
Tanzimat "a Mali Tarih) (Istanbul: Alan, 1986), 155–7; 302–9. See also Joshua M.
Stein, “Habsburg Financial Institutions Presented as a Model for the Ottoman
Empire in the Sefaretname of Ebu Bekir Ratib Efendi,” in Habsburgisch-osmanische
Beziehungen (Colloque sous le patronage du Comité international des études pré-
ottomanes et ottomanes, Vienna 26–30, Sept. 1983), ed. Andreas Tietze (Vienna:
Verlag des Verbandes der Wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften Österreichs, 1985),
233–242.
32
By 1804–1805 (KK 4499), the number of beneficiaries in the tobacco tax dis-
cussed in chapter 2 fell from 1,586 (in 1774–5; KK 4484) to 763 individuals; more
than half (386) were wives and daughters of religious figures.
33
Mehmet Genç, “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne Sistemi,” in Türkiye Iktisat Tarihi
Semineri, ed. Osman Okyar and Ünal Nalbanto[lu (Ankara: Hacetepe Üniversites
Publishers, 1975), 246, 252. On the decline of tax-farming rents in Egypt after mid-
century, Kenneth M. Cuno, The Pasha’s Peasants: Land, Society and Economy in Lower
Egypt, 1740 –1858 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), 44.
: 185
like Diyarbekir, rising prices for raw materials and loss of markets,
and a variety of taxes, including special wartime levies, pushed arti-
sans into outright rebellion.
While the specific conditions varied widely across Europe and Asia,
ultimately, key aspects of the old-regime impasse remained the same:
an enormous gap in capacities and powers that left the “state” unable
to extract the wealth necessary to pay for its military upkeep or to
subdue the many vernacular governments of the provinces.
With no history of aristocratic assemblies, Selim III could not sum-
mon the third estate to Istanbul to ratify its his program. Instead,
court and bureaucracy steered a course of contradictory policies. On
one hand, they tried to undercut local power by the abolishment of
gentry-held offices, such as the city-steward and the army-recruiter,
and by transferring important tax contracts to in-coming governors.
On the other, still undermanned militarily and administratively,
Istanbul encouraged the powerful magnates along its perimeters, such
as Cezzar Pasha who controlled the Lebanese coastline, Mehmet Ali
Pasha of Cairo, and Bayraktar Mustafa Pasha, heir to Tir{inikli (smail
in Thrace and Rusçuk, to built up private armies.34 Both Suleyman
Pasha in Baghdad and Cezzar Pasha in Sidon trained modern mil-
itary units.
These appeasements notwithstanding, the advocates of state con-
solidation found their fiercest critics in the capital. A janissary coup
d’état overthrew the new regime in 1807.35 Although the Istanbul
barracks fired the first shots, many parties in the Ottoman court and
in the mosques who feared the end of fiscal privilege and actively
encouraged the soldier’s actions.
From the provinces this turn of events seemed ominous. Many
gentry and not a few townsmen who had embraced the New Order
with reservations realized they had more to fear from a janissary-
controlled state and the reassertion of a rigid estate hierarchy. Rural
magnates and the urban gentry of Anatolia and the Balkans rallied
in Rusçuk under the leadership of Bayrakdar Mustafa, one of the
34
Bruce McGowan, “The Age of the Ayan,” in An Economic and Social History of
the Ottoman Empire, ed. Halil (nalcık with Donald Quataert, Cambridge UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1994), 666. Amnon Cohen (Palestine in the Eighteenth Century [ Jerusalem:
Magnes Press, 1973], 163) estimates that agriculture provided much of Cezzar
Pasha’s wealth.
35
Shaw, Between Old and New, 23.
186
36
Ibid., 397–98; Anatolii F. Miller, Mustafa Pasha Bayraktar (Bucarest: Association
International d’Études du Sud-Est européen: 1975), 298–99.
37
(smail Hakkı Uzunçar{ılı, Me{hur Rumeli Âyanlarından Tirsinikli (smail Yılık O[lu
Suleyman A[a ve Alemdar Mustafa Pa{a (Istanbul: Türk Tarıh Kurumu Yayınıları, 1942),
141–42; note the variation in texts found in Ataullah Mehmet }anizade, Tarih-i
}anizade (Istanbul: Ceride-Havadis Matbaası 1290/1873) vol. 1, 63 and Cevdet,
Tarih, vol. 9, 5.
38
Halil (nalcık, “Sened-I (ttifak ve Gülhane Hatt-ı Hümâyunu,” Belleten 28 (1964):
607–69. The text is found in }anizade, Tarih-i }anizade, vol. 1, 66 and Cevdet, Tarih,
vol. 9, 178.
39
Shaw, Between Old and New, 90; compare. Bernard Lewis, “Dustûr,” EI2 2:
: 187
A Federalist Alternative?
640–47; and Kemal Karpat, “The Transformation of the Ottoman State, 1789–1908,”
IJMES 3 (1972): 252–54.
40
(nalcık, “Sened-i (ttifak,” 610.
41
Jardin, Tocqueville, 208–9. Sudhir Hazareesingh, From Subject to Citizen: The Second
Empire and the Emergence of Modern French Democracy (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1998), 182–83.
188
42
See Richard Franklin Bensel, Yankee Leviathan: The Origins of Central State Authority
in America, 1859–1877 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990).
43
Miller, Mustafa Pasha Bayraktar, 318.
44
Although this did not mean that attempts to consolidate the fisc stoped entirely
(Cezar, Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım, 243), Mehmet Genç (“Osmanlı Maliyesinde
Malikâne Sistemi,” in Türkiye (ktisat Tarihi Semineri, ed., Osman Okyar and Ünal
Nalbanto[lu [Ankara: Hacetepe Üniversites Publishers, 1975], 282) calculates that
the percentage of overall investments held by provincial life-lessors rose from a low
of 19.8% in 1801 (during the New Order) to 23.6% in 1810. Note the trends in
provincial investments in life-leases:
1787 1800 1812
Diyarbekir 147,864.5 103,332 155,375.7
Aleppo 198,271.5 178,888.75 273,120.5
Tokat 234,393.5 286,238 366,340.5
Sources: MMD 9561:109–115; KK 5161:29, 77, 53, 18–29, 18; MMD 9624:182,
309, 307, 218. (Figures in kuru{).
: 189
45
Elizabeth Thompson, “Ottoman Political Reform in the Provinces: The Damascus
Advisory Council in 1844–45,” IJMES 25 (1993): 457–475.
46
On the life and times of }eyhzâde (brahim Pasha, CZ 541 (1789); CZ 1298
(1795); CZ 3392 (1812); CM 30,953. Ali Emiri, Tezkerei, 1:222–230; Mehmed Süreyya,
Sicill-i Osmanî; 1:151. M. Fahrettin Kırzıo[lu, “Kara-Âmid’te 1819 da A’yandan
}eyhzâdeler’in Öncülü[ünde Milli Deli-Behram Pa{a’ya Kar{ı Ayaklanma Ve Sonucu.”
Kara Âmid Dergisi, 2–4 (1956–58): 356.
47
Yılmazçelik, “XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında,” 484.
48
MMD 2931:122.
190
imports. His tariff agents continued to impose the full gümrük tax
(and not simply a fee, the bac) on the transit trade that passed through
the city.49 In a particularly troubled decade, when Wahhabi incur-
sions into Najd and the resulting disruption of traffic through Basra
cost Baghdad some quarter million kuru{ in customs revenues, his
militias policed the highways leading southward and guarded traffic
from the depredations of Kurdish tribes.50 Personal wealth was invested
in infrastructure. (brahim dedicated one of several large family waqf
to the building of a forty-one room caravansaray complete with sta-
bles within the city walls.51
The ruling elite’s portfolio of assets, private and public, also sug-
gests a certain balance in policies and a vested interest in reconcil-
ing the concerns of the city’s long-distance and regional merchants
with those of its artisans and tradesmen. The pasha, his family, and
members of his advisory council, the divan, maintained their hold-
ings in contracts on local and regional products. In addition to agri-
cultural rents and revenues, they possessed contracts on local manu-
facturing taxes, such as the fees on white cotton twist.52 Since his
first public office as intendant in 1796, (brahim had held the lucra-
tive malikâne on the excise tax on the interregional trade in snuff.53
That is not to say that (brahim opposed opening the town’s mar-
ket to long distance goods. A notarized appendix to the Diyarbekir
tariff lists the new commodities that the governor’s “own traders”
introduced into the city. Most were European goods, including
Flemish, presumably, manufactured cotton thread.54
49
On inter-urban rivalries over tariff: MMD 10,241: 230 (1798); CD 3582 (1811);
CI 990 (1815).
50
(brahim Yılmazçelik,” XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır 1790–1840,” 2 vols.
(Ph.D. diss., Fırat University, 1991), 216–217; (brahim }eyhzâde 1784–85 merited
an entry in Yasin al-'Umari’s contemporary history of Iraq (al-Durr al-Maknûn fî
al-Ma"âthir al-Mâdiya min al-Qurun, critical ed., Sayyar Kawkab 'Ali al-Jamıl (Ph.D.
diss. University of St. Andrews, U.K.), 443; CD 9713.
51
Yılmazçelik, “XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır,” 178.
52
MMD 9519:102,80,23. One of the shareholders in 1816–1817 was Ishak Efendi,
“müderris (scholar) and the secretary of the administrative council (divan) of the defunct
}eyhzâde (brahim.”
53
MMD 9519:22. MMD 9722:43. }amlu Ebü Bekir (d. 1793–94) was an appointee
as tariff keeper ( gümrükçü) as early as (brahim Pasha’s tenure as voyvoda.
54
KK 5249:18. Stamped by the judge of Amid, Seyyid Mehmed, it lists the
goods transported by “his [}eyhzâde’s] merchants.”
: 191
55
CM 25,214.
56
On the Young Ottomans, see }erif Mardin, The Genesis of Young Ottoman Thought:
A Study in the Modernization of Turkish Political Ideas (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 1962); and (lber Ortaylı, Tanzimattan Cumhuriyete Yerel Yönetim Gelene[i (Istanbul:
Hil Yayınları, 1985); idem, (mparatorlu[un En Uzun Yüzyılı (Istanbul: Hil Yayınları,
1987). For later variations, see Yusuf Akçura’s Osmanlı Devletinin Da[ılma Devri (XVIII
ve XIX asırlarda) (Ankara: Türk Tarih Kurumu Basımevi, 1988). For more on decen-
tralization, see Niyazi Berkes, Türkiye’de Ca[da{lama (Istanbul: Do[u-Batı Yayınları,
1978), 102. The emphasis on centralization in late Ottoman and Turkish Republican
political thought is often attributed to Durkheim. See also, Bertrand Badie and
Pierre Birnbaum, The Sociology of the State, trans. Arthur Goldhammer (Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press, 1983), 12.
192
Dervi{ Pasha, the lord who controlled the critical leg of the transit
route between the Iranian frontier and Diyarbekir, on one side, and
the Black Sea region on the other.57 His regime was well entrenched.
Troops from Erzurum, Mu{, Çıldır, Sivas, Bozuk (Yozgat), Trabzon,
and Diyarbekir were needed to carry out the final assault on the
fortified city of Van.
The province of Diyarbekir lay south of Van. According to the
strategic map of the modern state drawn by the sultan’s advisors, its
capital, Amid, was next on the list of governments to be brought
back into the imperial fold. Here, however, the state was forced to
consider other tactics. Unlike Van, Diyarbekir’s government was not
merely one-man rule. Undoubtedly fearing popular resistance, Istanbul
searched for a pretext for intervention. It found one in a contro-
versial candidate for the governorship. Behram Pasha, the new gov-
ernor, was a member of the Deli branch of the Kurdish Milan tribe
and a sworn enemy of the house of the }eyhzâde. His appointment
seems to have been calculated to incite the urban elite. His mission,
as the historian }anîzade sanitizes it, was to put “in order” (tertib
edüp) Diyarbekir’s urban affairs, ending, once and for all, gentry’s
hold on the deputy governorship.
Although official and provincial accounts differ widely, there is no
dispute over the scale and intensity of popular resistance to Behram
Pasha. In the official annals the city’s opposition to the new gover-
nor was no long a matter of rebellion (ihtilal ) as it had been recorded
in 1802. In 1819, the town’s defiance constituted outright civil war
( fitna).58 Absent local testimony, there might be no means of chal-
lenging the Istanbul version of the last days of federalism in Diyarbekir.
Fortunately, one witness’ account is preserved in a later provincial
history.59 Its author, Hacı Ragıb Bey, who suf-fered exile because of
his involvement, described the denouement of the rebellion: The new
governor entered the city’s basalt portals on July 18, 1819. Behram
57
Local opinions on the government of Van prior to the campaign of 1818 were
not unfavorable to the lord according to James Brant, “Journey through a part of
Armenia and Asia Minor in the Year 1835,” Journal of the Royal Geographical Society
10 (1841): 395.
58
}anizade, Tarih vol. 3, 54.
59
The manuscript has been lost. Kırzıo[lu’s source (“Kara-Âmid’te 1819’da
A’yandan }eyhzâdeler,” 350–58, 375–76) is the manuscript of Abdulghani Bulduk,
an early twentieth-century historian of the city of Diyarbekir, who cites from it
extensively.
: 193
60
See Cemal Tukin, “Mahmud II. Devrinde Halep Isyanı: 1813–1819,” Tarih
Vesikaları 1 (1941): 256–264.
194
61
Cevdet Pasha (Tarih, vol. 11, 65, 67–9, 83) refers to (brahim’s brutal repres-
sion of the Viran{ehir branch of the Milan tribe and his repeated reprisals against
the Deli Milan during his long tenure between 1807–8 and 1814.
62
Cevdet, Tarih, vol. 6, 221.
63
See Huri Islamo[lu, “Property as a Contested Domain: A Reevaluation of the
Ottoman Land Code of 1858,” in New Perspectives on Property and Land in the Middle
East, ed. Roger Owen (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000), 3–63.
64
A point taken up Selim Deringil, The Well-Protected Domains: Ideology and the
Legitimation of Power in the Ottoman Empire, 1876–1909 (London: I. B. Tauris, 1998).
: 195
65
Hazareesingh, From Subject to Citizen, 96–7, 130–31; 171–72; 191.
66
Jardin, Tocqueville, 203, 208, 318–22.
67
Ibid., 248; Tocqueville, Oeuvres compléte, vol. 3, pt. 1, 29–253.
196
France. With it, came the dangers of despotism: the full, unmedi-
ated force of the world’s most dangerous weapon on the individual
was no longer blunted by the peculiar government-state relationship
of the old regime or the aristocratic hierarchy. At one extreme the
modern state could be a prison, like Czarist Russia. In a country of
pashas and paupers, like Mehmet Ali’s Egypt, the state could become
forced-labor factory.68 Although Tocqueville regarded these examples
as a travesty of modern polity and assured himself that only the
most extraordinary conditions, such as a state of total anarchy or
revolution, could bring despotism to Western Europe,69 he realized
that Europeans had reason to be wary. The future of democratic
government would rest more heavily on the individual. As in nine-
teenth century Britain, it could be corrupted by the passivity of its
citizenry or the excessive influence of money.
With the 1851 coup d’état that suspended the bourgeois consti-
tution and brought Napoleon III (r. 1852–1870) to power, Tocqueville
confronted the perils of the modern state close at hand. Although
he retired from active participation in the political arena, his biog-
rapher André Jardin notes that his voluminous correspondence between
1851 and his death in 1859 continued to run the gamut of domes-
tic and foreign policy.70 Despite poor health, he eagerly awaited
Gobineau’s letters from Iran and continued to condemn slavery as
a violation of the most basic concepts of Christianity.71
On one topic, however, Tocqueville is inexplicably silent. For a
politician who had been consumed by colonial affairs for decades,
it is remarkable that he ceased to comment on France’s colonial pol-
icy in Africa. Was he frustrated by the character of colonial rule
after the defeat of 'Abd al-Qadir in 1847 and the incorporation of
the colons as citizens after 1848? Did his inclusion of an appendix
on Canada in The Old Régime merely express nostaglia for empire
lost or was the comment “colonies bear the imprint of the metro-
pole,” in fact a pointed reminder to his countrymen that posterity
would judge the nation by its legacy of imperialism in North Africa?
Or had his political philosophy itself been altered? One might ask
whether his silence might have signaled that the neat, binary divi-
68
Jardin, Tocqueville, 69–70; 375, 266. Tocqueville, Oeuvres compléte, vol. 2, 300–13.
69
Jardin, Tocqueville, 267–68.
70
Jardin, Tocqueville, 333.
: 197
sion between European states and their non-Western rivals had begun
to disintegrate. Recent experience had given him reason for pause.
In contrast to the cooperation of the Ottoman representative in Rome
who readily agreed to take in the refugees from 1848, a down pay-
ment on their obligations as a future member of the Concert of
Europe, there was the utter intransigence of the Vatican. While
Istanbul embraced reforms, the Papacy rebuffed even the most minor
effort toward political change. And then there were the events in
France itself: in what way did the caudillismo of Latin America differ
from Bonapartism? Although the Congress of Vienna had insured
France’s territorial integrity, did not the rocky transition from the
old regime, the radical swings between revolution, monarchy, repub-
lic and empire, mirror to an uncomfortable degree, the decades of
civil war, restoration, and the quasi-constitutional sultanate of the
Ottoman Empire?
Tocqueville might have reassured himself with the thought that
barring extreme conditions, European societies could not produce a
despotism like that of Russia or the “Turks.” However, in the wake
of the Revolutions of 1848 and the putsch of 1851, such confidence
in the internal regulating principles of Europe’s political society was
no longer firm.72 In his last political essay, The Old Régime and the
French Revolution, he turned away from the present to search for the
roots of modern institutions and social relationships in the last cen-
tury of the ancien régime. By turning the clock backward, long before
the French Revolution, he may have hoped to find in those cahiers
evidence of the enduring virtues of the nation, to cast a conceptual
anchor amid the turbulent nineteenth-century political sea.
In writing the first of what was planned to be two volumes on
the history of the French Revolution, Tocqueville carefully demar-
cates the geographical limits of his inquiry. Despite furnishing ample
evidence to the contrary, he repeatedly reminds his readers of the
inevitable emergence of the modern state from the baroque cocoon
of the old regime. In rehabilitating the eighteenth-century, he admits
many of the paradoxes while creating an overarching sense of order,
71
For his correspondence with Arthur de Gobineau from Switzerland and Iran,
after 1851 see Tocqueville, Oeuvres complètes, 9: 157 ff.
72
Hazareesingh (From Subject to Citizen, 231–32), calls this the “liberalism of fear.”
John Keane, “Despotism and Democracy,” in Civil Society and the State: New European
Perspectives, ed. idem (London: Verso, 1988), 65.
198
73
Tocqueville, The Old Regime, 197, 204–5.
74
“Because the Revolution seemed to be striving for the regeneration of the
human race even more than the reform of France, it lit a passion which the most
violent political revolutions had never before been able to produce. It inspired con-
versation and generated propaganda . . . it itself became a new kind of religion, an
incomplete religion, it is true, without God, without ritual, and without a life after
death, but one which nevertheless, like Islam flooded the earth with its soldiers,
apostles, and martyrs. The Old Régime, 101. He repeats this metaphor. Tocqueville,
Notes on the French Revolution and Napoleon, The Old Regime and the French Revolution
(L’ancien régime et la Révolution), ed. François Furet and Françoise Mélonio, trans. by
Alan S. Kahan (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1998) vol. 2, 180, 263, 446, 459.
As Furet and Melonio (ibid., 459) point out, for this metaphor as well, he is indebted
to a royalist writer, Mallet du Pan.
: 199
Plate 1. The procession of the esnaf (guilds) began with the farmer, the miller and the
bread maker. A young man reads verses from the Qur}an on camel-back. From Levni’s
illustrated Surnâme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 72a). Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ
Museum.
60 chapter two
Plate 2. Sultan Ahmed III and his son-in-law, Grand Vizier `brahim Pasha view the
festivities. From Levni’s illustrated Surnâme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 71b).
Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
terminal histories and arthurian solutions 31
Plate 3. A vision of order: the Øeyh} ül-`slam, jurists and ulema are at the top rung; they
are followed by viziers, ministers, generals, members of the divan-æ hümayun, and finally
the treasurers. Janissaries guard the perimeter. From Levni’s illustrated Surnâme-i Vehbi
(TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 21a). Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
60 chapter two
Plate 4. A vision of disorder: the janissaries trip over themselves and one another in a
mad dash to claim their plates of rice. From Levni’s illustrated Surnâme-i Vehbi (TKSK
Ms. A 3593, fol. 23a). Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
terminal histories and arthurian solutions 31
Plate 5. The French ambassadors seated in front of the stern faced Russian emissaries
seem to be amused by the scene of raucous firemen, clowns, and the float of the
weavers of gold cloth. From Levni’s illustrated Surnâme-i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol.
140a). Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
60 chapter two
Plate 6. The sultan has returned to the palace at the conclusion of the festivities. He
rewards his servants with a distribution of gold coins. From Levni’s illustrated, Surnâme-
i Vehbi (TKSK Ms. A 3593, fol. 175a). Courtesy of Topkapæ Sarayæ Museum.
GLOSSARY
Unpublished Sources
(Muallim) Cevdet:
Adliye, Askeriye, Bedeliye, Dahiliye, (ktisat, Maliye, Timar, and Zaptiye.
Ahkâm Defterleri:
Diyarbekir vols. I (1155–67/1742–54); II (1167–76/1754–63); II (1176–80/1763–80);
IV (1194–1202/1780–88); V (1206–28/1792–1813).
Istanbul vols. I–IV; Sivas vols. I–IV; Haleb vols. I–V; and Erzurum vols. I–V.
(selections).
Bâb-ı Defteri Ba{muhâsebe Kalemi/Diyarbekir Hazinesi.
Bâb-ı Defteri Mevkûfât Kalemi.
Ba{muhâsebe Kalemi.
Kâmil Kepeci Defteri.
Maliyeden Müdevver Defterleri.
Ali Emiri. Tezkere-i }u"arâ-yı Amid. Vol. 1. Istanbul: Matbua-yı Amidi, 1328/1910–1911.
Alorabi, Abdulrahman. “The Ottoman Policy in the Hejaz in the Eighteenth Century:
A Study of Political and Admistrative Developments, 1143–1202 A.H./1731–1788
A.D.” Ph.D. diss., University of Utah, 1988.
[Altınay]. Ahmet Refik. Istanbul Hayatı (1100–1200). Istanbul: Devlet Matbaası, 1930.
——. Lâle Devri. Istanbul: Hilmi Kitabhanesi, 1932.
Anderson, M. S. The Eastern Question, 1774–1923: A Study in International Relations.
Houndmills: Macmillan Education, 1987.
Anderson, Perry. Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso, 1974.
Anville, Jean Baptiste Bourguignon d’. Éclaircissements géographiques sur la carte de l’Inde.
Paris: De l’Imprimerie royale, 1753.
Arapyan, Kalost. Rusçuk Ayânı Mustafa Pa{a’nın Hayatı ve Kahramanlıkları. Ankara: TTK,
1943.
Ardant, Gabriel. “Financial Policy and Economic Infrastructure of Modern States
and Nations.” In The Formation of National States in Western Europe, 164–242. Edited
by Charles Tilly. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.
Ardel, Ahmed, ed. “Güneydo[u Anadolu"da Co[rafî Mü{ahedeler.” Türk Co[rafya
Dergisi 17 (1961): 140–148.
Arıkan, Zeki. “Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda (hracı Yasak Mallar.” In Prof. Dr. Bekir
Kütüko[lu Arma[an, 279–306. Edited by Mübahat S. Kütüko[lu. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakültesi Basımevi, 1991.
Aron, Raymond. Les étapes de la pensée sociologique. Montesquieu. Comte. Marx. Tocqueville.
Durkheim. Pareto. Weber. Paris: Gallimard, 1967.
Arrighi, Giovanni. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origins of Our Times.
London: Verso, 1984.
Artan, Tülay. “From Charismatic Leadership to Collective Rule.” Toplum ve Ekonomi
4 (1993): 53–94.
Atan, Turhan. Türk Gümrük Tarihi. Vol. 1. Ba{langıçtan Osmanlı Devletine Kadar. Ankara:
TTK, 1990.
Atıl, Esin. “Surnâme-i Vehbi: An Eighteenth Century Book of Festivals.” 2 vols.
Ph.D. diss., University of Michigan, 1969.
——.” The Story of an Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Festival.” Muqarnas 10 (1993):
181–211.
——. and Ömer Koc, eds. Levni and the Surname: The Story of an Eighteenth-Century
Ottoman Festival. Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2000.
Atkin, Muriel. Russia and Iran, 1780–1828. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota
Press, 1980.
Avery, Peter, Gavin Hambly, and Charles Melville, eds. The Cambridge History of
Iran. Vol. 7: From Nadir Shah to the Islamic Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1990.
Aydin, Veli H. “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Esham Uygulaması, 1775–1840.” Ph.D. diss.,
Ankara Üniversitesi, 1998.
Aydin, Suavi, Kudret Emiro[lu, Oktay Özel, and Süha Ünsal. Mardin: A{iret-Cemaat-
Devlet. Istanbul: Tarih Vakfi, 2000.
Ayn-i Ali Efendi. Kavânin-i Âl-i Osman der Hülâsa-i Mezâmin-i Defter-i Divân. Edited
by Tayyib Gökbilgin. Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi, 1979.
Azimi, Vida. Un modèle administratif de l’ancien régime: les commis de la ferme générale et de
la régie générale des aides. Paris: Éditions du Centre National de la Récherche
Scientifique, 1987.
Azîz Efendi. Kanûn-nâme-i Sultânî li" Azîz Efendi. 'Aziz Efendi’s Book of Sultanic Laws and
Regulation: An Agenda for Reform by a Sevententh-Century Ottoman Statesman. Edited and
trans. by Rhoads Murphey. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1985.
Badie, Bertrand, and Pierre Birnbaum. The Sociology of the State. Trans. Arthur
Goldhammer. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1983.
206
Baechler, Jean, John A. Hall, and Michael Mann, eds. Europe and the Rise of Capitalism.
New York: B. Blackwell, 1988.
Baer, Gabriel. “Ottoman Guilds: A Reassessment.” In Türkiye"nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik
Tarihi (1071–1920), 95–102. Edited by Osman Okyar and Halil (nalcık. Ankara:
Meteksan, 1980.
Ba[cı, Serpil. “Osmanlı Dünyasında Efsanevi Yönetici (mgesi Olarak Büyük (skender
ve Osmanlı (skendernamesi.” In Humana Boskurt Güvenç’e Arma[an, 111–131. Istanbul:
Kültür Bakanlı[ı, 1994.
——., Priscilla Mary I{in, and Selmin Kangal, eds. The Sultan’s Portrait: Picturing the
House of Osman. Istanbul: Türkiye ({ Bankası, 2000.
Ba[ı{, Ali (hsan. Osmanlı Ticaretinde Gayrı Müslimler: Kapitülasyonlar-Beratlı Tüccarlar,
Avrupa ve Hayriye Tüccarlar (1750–1839). Ankara: Turhan Kitabevi, 1983.
Bagrow, Leo. History of Cartography. 2nd edition, revised and enlarged by R. A.
Skelton. Chicago: Precedent Publishing, 1985.
Bailey, Anne, M., and Josep R. Llobera, eds. The Asiatic Mode of Production: Science
and Politics. London: Routledge & Keegan Paul, 1981.
Bakhit, Muhammad Adnan. The Ottoman Province of Damascus in the Sixteenth Century.
Beirut: Librairie du Liban, 1962.
Barbir, Karl K. “From Pasha to Efendi: The Assimilation of Ottomans into Damascene
Society, 1516–1783.” IJTS 1 (1979–80): 68–83.
——. Ottoman Rule in Damascus, 1708–1758. Princeton: Princeton University Press,
1980.
Barkan, Ömer Lûtfi. “Türk-(slâm Toprak Hukuku Tatbikatının Osmanlı (mpara-
torlu[unda Aldı[ı {ekiller: Mâlikâne-Divânî Sistemi.” Türk Hukuk ve (ktisat Tarihi
Mecmuası 2 (1932–39): 119–163.
——. “Malikâne-Divânî Sistemi.” Türk Hukuk ve (ktisat Tarihi Mecmuası 2 (1939):
119–184.
——. “}ark Ticaret Yolları Hakkında Notlar.” IFM 1 (1940): 448–456.
——. “1669–70 Mali Yılına Ait bir Osmanlı Bütçesi ve Ekleri.” IFM 17 (1955–56):
193–303, 303–347.
——. “Research on the Ottoman Fiscal Surveys.” In Studies in the Economic History
of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, 163–171. Edited by Michael
A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970.
——. “The Price Revolution of the Sixteenth Century: A Turning Point in the
Economic History of the Near East.” IJMES 4 (1976): 3–28.
——. Türkiye"de Toprak Meselesi. Toplu Eserler. Vol. 1. Istanbul: Gözlem, 1980.
——. “Caractère religieux et caractère séculier des institutions ottomanes.” In
Contributions à l’histoire économique et sociale de l’Empire Ottoman, 11–58. Edited by
Jean-Louis Bacqué-Grammont and Paul Dumont. Leuven: Éditions Peeters, 1983.
Barsoumian, Hagop Levon. “The Armenian Amira Class of Istanbul.” Ph.D. diss.,
Columbia University, 1980.
Barthold, W. An Historical Geography of Iran. Trans. Svat Soucek. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1984.
Ba{bakanlık Osmanlı Ar{ivi Rehberi. Ankara: T. C. Ba{bakanlık Devlet Ar{ivleri Genel
Müdürlü[ü Osmanlı Ar{ivi Daire Ba{bakanlı[ı, 1992.
Baykal, Bekir Sıtkı. “Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda XVII ve XVIII. Yüzyıllar boyunca
Para Düzeni ile (lgili Belgeler.” Belgeler 4 (1967): 49–77.
——. “Mustafa III.” (A, 8:700–708.
Baykara, Tuncer, ed. Osmanlı Ta{ra Te{kilatında XVIII. Yüzyılda Görev ve Görevliler
(Anadolu). Ankara: Vakıflar Genel Müdürlü[ü Yayınları, 1990.
Bayly, C. A. Imperial Meridian: The British Empire and the World, 1780–1830. London:
Longman, 1989.
Baysun, Cavid M. “Müsadere.” (A, 8:669–673.
Behar, Cem, and Alan Duben. Istanbul Households: Marriage, Family and Fertility,
1880 –1940. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 1991.
207
Brotton, Jerry. Trading Territories: Mapping the Early Modern World. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press, 1998.
Bruess, Gregory L. Religion, Identity and Empire: A Greek Archbishop in the Russia of
Catherine the Great. Boulder: East European Monographs, 1997.
Bruinessen, Martin van. Agha, Shaikh and State: The Social and Political Structures of Kur-
distan. London: Zed, 1992.
Buckingham, J. S. Travels in Mesopotamia including a Journey from Aleppo, Across the
Euphrates to Orfah . . . London: Henry Colburn, 1827.
Burchell Graham and Colin Gordon, eds. The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality:
With Two Lectures by and an Interview with Michel Foucault. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1991.
Bulgaru, M. M. Alexandrescu-Dersca. “L’approvisionnement d’Istanbul par les
Principautés Roumaines au XVIIIe siècle: commerce ou requisition?” RMMM
66 (1992): 73–78.
Burton, Audrey J. “Relations between Bukhara and Turkey.” IJTS 5 (1990–91):
83–103.
Butcher, John, and Howard Dick, eds. The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business
Elites and the Emergence of the Modern State in Southeast Asia. New York: St. Martins,
1993.
Byres, T. J., and H. Mukhia, eds. Feudalism and Non-European Societies. London: Frank
Cass, 1985.
Çadırcı, Musa. Tanzimat Döneminde Anadolu Kentleri"nin Sosyal ve Ekonomik Yapıları.
Ankara: TTK, 1991.
——. “Tanzimat"ın Sıralarında Türkiye"de Yönetim (1826–1839).” Belleten 51 (1987):
1215–1240.
Caille, Alain and Jean Starobinski. Critique de la Raison Utilitaire: Manifeste du Mauss.
Paris: La Découverte, 1989.
Cassels, Lavender. The Struggle for the Ottoman Empire, 1717–1740. London: John
Murray, 1966.
Cevdet Pasha (Ahmed). Tarih-i Cevdet. 12 vols. Istanbul: Matbaa-yı Osmaniye,
1309/1893.
Chèref-ou’ddîne. Chèref-Nâmeh ou Fastes de la Nation Kourde. Trans. François Bernard
Charmoy. St.-Pétersbourg: l’Académie Impériale des Sciences, 1873.
Çesmi-zade Mustafa Re{id. Çesmi-zade Tarihi. Edited by Bekir Kütüko[lu. Istanbul:
Istanbul Edebiyat Fakültesi, 1959.
Cezar, Mustafa. Osmanlı Tarihinde Levendler. Istanbul: Güzel Sanatlar Akademisi, 1965.
——. Typical Commercial Buildings of the Ottoman Classical Period and the Ottoman Construction
System. Istanbul: Türkiye ({ Bankası, 1983.
Cezar, Yavuz. “Bir Âyanın Muhallefatı: Havza ve Köprü Âyanı Kör (smail-O[lu
Hüseyin (Musadere Olayı ve Terekenin (ncelenmesi).” Belleten 151 (1977): 41–78.
——. “Osmanlı Mali Tarihinde ‘Esham’ Uygulamasının (lk Dönemlerine (li{kin
Bazı Önemli ve Örnek Belgeler.” Toplum ve Bilim 2 (1980): 124–143.
——. Osmanlı Maliyesinde Bunalım ve De[i{im Dönemi (XVIII. Yüzyıldan Tanzimat"a Mali
Tarih). Istanbul: Alan, 1986.
Chakrabarty, Dipesh. Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Difference.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000.
Chartier, Roger. The Cultural Origins of the French Revolution, Trans. Lydia G. Cohrane.
Durhan: Duke University Press, 1991.
Chaudhuri, K. N. Asia Before Europe: Economy and Civilisation of the Indian Ocean and the
Rise of Islam to 1750. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
Cheddadi, Abdessalam. “Le système du pouvoir en Islam d’après Ibn Khaldun.”
Annales économies, sociétés, civilisations 35 (1980): 534–550.
Chehata, Chafik. Essai d’une theorie générale de l’obligation en droit Musulman. 2 vols.
Cairo: Nury, 1936.
209
Cin, Halil. Osmanlı Toprak Düzeni ve bu Düzenin Bozulması. Ankara: Ankara Kültür
Bakanlı[ı Yayınları, 1978.
Çizakça, Murat. “A Short History of the Bursa Silk Industry (1500–1900).” JESHO
23 (1980): 142–152.
——. “Incorporation of the Middle East into the European World-Economy.” Review
8 (1985): 353–378.
——. A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships: The Islamic World and Europe with
Specific Reference to the Ottoman Archives. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996.
Çirakman, Aslı. From the “Terror of the World” to the ‘Sick Man of Europe’: Images of
Ottoman Empire and Society from the Sixteenth Century to the Nineteenth. New York: Peter
Lang, 2002.
Clark, John R. “The Mapping of the Maliyeden Müdevver 7075.” TSA Bulletin 13
(1989): 79–90.
Clausewitz, Carl von. On War. Edited and trans. by Michael Howard and Peter
Paret. London: Everyman’s Library, 1993.
Coase, R. H. The Firm, the Market and the Law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1988.
Cohen, Amnon. Palestine in the Eighteenth Century. Jerusalem: Magnes Press, 1973.
——. “On the Realities of the Millet System: Jerusalem in the 16th century.” In
Christians and Jews in the Ottoman Empire. vol. 2, 7–14. Edited by Benjamin Braude
and Bernard Lewis. London: Holmes and Meier, 1982.
——. Economic Life in Ottoman Jerusalem. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
Collins, James B. Fiscal Limits of Absolutism: Direct Taxation in Early Seventeenth-Century
France. Berkeley, CA.: University of California Press, 1988.
Comninel, George C. Rethinking the French Revolution: Marxism and the Revisionists.
London: Verso, 1987.
Constantin, }erbanö. “La suzeraineté ottomane a l’égard des pays roumains dans
le contexte des rélations internationals européenes (sec. XVI–XVII).” Tarih Dergisi
32 (1979): 211–218.
Cook, Michael A. Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East. London: Oxford
University Press, 1970.
——, ed. Population Pressure in Rural Anatolia 1450–1600. London: Oxford University
Press, 1972.
Copland, Ian and Michael R. Godley. “Revenue Farming in Comparative Perspective:
Reflections on Taxation, Social Structure and Development in the Early-Modern
Period.” In The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming: Business Elites and the Emergence of
the Modern State in Southeast Asia, 45–68. Edited by John Butcher and Howard
Dick. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1993.
Coss, P. R. “The Formation of the English Gentry.” Past and Present 147 (1995): 38–
64.
Crouzet, François. “Wars, Blockade and Economic Change in Europe, 1792–1815.”
Journal of Economic History 24 (1964): 567–588.
Cuinet, Vital. La Turquie d’Asie: Géographie administrative statistique déscriptive et raisonnée
de chaque province del’Asie-Mineure. 4 vols. Paris: Ernest Leroux, 1890–1894.
Cunningham, A. B. “The Journal of Christophe Aubin: A Report on the Levant
Trade in 1812.” Archivum Ottomanicum 8 (1983): 5–132.
Cuno, Kenneth M. The Pasha’s Peasants: Land, Society and Economy in Lower Egypt,
1740 –1858. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.
Cvetkova, Bistra. “Recherches sur le système d’affermage ((ltizam) dans l’Empire
Ottoman au cours du XVIe–XVIIIe s. par rapport aux contrées bulgares.” Rocznik
Orientalistyezny 27 (1964): 111–132.
——. “Les celep et leur rôle dans la vie économique des Balkans à l’époque ottomane
(XVe–XVIIIe s.).” In Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, 172–193.
Edited by Michael A. Cook. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1970.
210
——. Les institutions ottomanes en Europe. Wiesbaden: Franz Steiner Verlag, 1978.
Çiçek, Kemal, Ercümen Kuran, Nejat Göyünç, (lber Ortaylı, et al., eds. The Great
Ottoman-Turkish Civilization. 4 vols. Ankara: Yeni Türkiye, 2000.
D’Beth Hillel, Rabbi David. Unknown Jews in Unknown Lands: The Travels of Rabbi
David D’Beth Hillel (1824–1832). Edited and trans. by Walter J Fischel. New York:
Ktav Publishing House, 1973.
Dainville, François de. Le langage des géographes: termes, signes, couleurs des cartes anciennes,
1500 –1800. Paris: A. et J. Picard, 1964.
Dale, Stephen F. Indian Merchants and Eurasian Trade, 1600–1700. New York: Cambridge
University Press, 1994.
Dankoff, Robert. The Intimate Life of an Ottoman Statesman. Albany: State University
of New York Press, 1991.
Darling, Linda T. Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy: Tax Collection and Finance Administration
in the Ottoman Empire, 1560–1660. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1996.
Das Gupta, Ashin. Indian Merchants and the Decline of Surat, c. 1700–1750. Wiesbaden:
Franz Steiner, 1979.
Davis, Natalie Zemon. The Gift in Sixteenth-Century France. Madison: University of
Wisconsin, 2000.
Davis, Ralph. Aleppo and Devonshire Square: English Traders in the Levant in the Eighteenth
Century. London: Macmillan, 1967.
——. “English Imports from the Middle East, 1580–1780.” In Studies in the Economic
History of the Middle East from the Rise of Islam to the Present Day, 45–68. Edited by
Michael A. Cook. London: Oxford University Press, 1970.
Davison, Roderic H. Reform in the Ottoman Empire 1856–1876. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1963.
Deringil, Selim. The Well-Protected Domains: Ideology and the Legitimation of Power in the
Ottoman Empire, 1876–1909. London: I. B. Tauris, 1998.
Dessert, Daniel. Argent, pouvoir et societé au Grand Siècle. Paris: Fayard, 1984.
Deyon, Pierre L’état face au pouvoir local: un autre regard sur l’histoire de France (Paris:
Editions Locales de France, 1996
Dickson, P. G. M. Finance and Government under Maria Theresia, 1740–1780. 2 vols.
Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987.
Diderot, Denis. Encyclopédie. Edited by John Lough and Jacques Proust. Paris:
Hermann, Editeurs des Sciences et des Arts, 1976.
Diyarbekir Vilâyet Salnamesi. 1276/1859–60.
D’Ohsson, Mouradgea I. Tableau général de l’Empire othoman, divisé en deux parties, dont
l’une comprend la législation mahométane, l’autre, l’histoire de l’Empire othoman. 7 vols. Paris:
M. Firmin Didot Imp., 1820–24.
Doyle, William. Venality: the Sale of Offices in Eighteenth-Century France. New York:
Clarendon Press, 1996.
——, ed. Old Regime France. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001.
Darperon, L. “Le Grand Dessein sécret de Louis XIV,” Revue de Géographie 1 (1877):
435–61.
Doumani, Bishara. Rediscovering Palestine: Merchants and Peasants in Jabal Nablus,
1700 –1920. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1995.
Duara, Prasenjit, Culture, Power and the State: Rural North China, 1900–1942. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University Press, 1988.
Duka, Ferit. “XV–XVIII. Yüzyıllarda Arnavut Nüfusunun Islamla{ması Süreci Üzer-
ine Gözlemler.” Ankara Üniversitesi Osmanlı Tarihi Ara{tırma ve Uygulama Merkezi Dergisi
2 (1991): 63–72.
Düzda[, M. Ertu[rul. }eyhülislâm Ebussuûd Efendi Fetvaları. Istanbul: Enderun Kitabevi,
1983.
Edney, Mathew. Mapping an Empire: The Geographical Construction of British India,
1763–1843. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990.
211
Eisenstadt, S. N., ed. Modernization: Protest and Change. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice
Hall, 1966.
——. The Political Systems of Empires. New York: The Free Press, 1969.
——. Political Sociology: A Reader. New York: Basic Books, 1971.
Eldem, Edhem “La circulation de la lettre de change entre la France et Constantinople
au XVIIIe siécle.” In L’Empire Ottoman, la Republique de Turquie et la France, 87–97.
Edited by Hâmit Batu and Jean-Louis Bacqué-Grammont. Istanbul-Paris: Isis, 1986.
——. “Le commerce français d’Istanbul au XVIIIe siècle.” Thése de Doctorat.
Université de Provence-Aix-Marseille I, 1988.
——. “The Trade in Precious Metals and Bills.” In V. Milletlerarası Türkiye Sosyal ve
(ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, 579–589. Edited by Hakkı Dursun Yıldız, (nci Enginün and
Emine Gürsoy Naskalı. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
——. French Trade in Istanbul in the Eighteenth Century. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1999.
Elias, Norbert. The History of Manners. New York: Pantheon, 1978.
——. The Court Society. New York: Pantheon, 1983.
Elvin, Mark. The Pattern of the Chinese Past. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1973.
Emecen, Feridun M. “Sefere Götürülen Defterlerin Defteri.” In Prof. Dr. Bekir
Kütüko[lu’na Arma[an, 241–68. Edited by Mubahat Kütüko[lu. Istanbul: Edebiyat
Fakültesi Basımevi, 1991.
Encyclopedia of Islam. 2nd Edition. Eds. B. Lewis, V. L. Menage, Ch. Pellat and
J. Schacht. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1971–.
Erder, Leila T. “The Measurement of Pre-Industrial Population Changes in the
Ottoman Empire from the 15th to the 17th Century.” Middle Eastern Studies 11
(1975): 284–301.
Erder, Leila T. and Suraiya Faroqhi. “The Development of the Anatolian Urban
Network During the Sixteenth Century.” JESHO 23 (1980): 265–303.
Ergenç, Özer. “Osmanlı Klasik Dönemindeki ‘E{raf ve A'yan"üzerine Bazı Bilgiler.”
JOS 3 (1982): 105–118.
Ergin, Osman Nuri. Mecelle-i Umur-u Belediye. Istanbul: Istanbul Büyük{ehir Belediyesi
Kültür ({leri Daire Ba{kanlı[ı, 1922.
Erim, Ne{e. “Onsekizinci Yüzyılda Erzurum Gümrü[ü.” Ph.D. diss., Istanbul Üniver-
sitesi, 1984.
——. “Trade, Traders, and the State in Eighteenth-Century Erzurum.” New Perspectives
on Turkey 5–6 (1991): 123–50.
Evans, Peter B., Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skopcol, eds. Bringing the State
Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
Evliya Çelebi. Evliya Çelebi in Bitlis: The Relevant Section of the Seyahatname. Edited and
trans. by Robert Dankoff. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1990.
——. Evliya Çelebi in Diyarbekir. Edited and trans. by Martin Van Bruinessen and
Hendrik Boeschoten. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1988.
Fahmy, Khaled. All the Pasha’s Men: Mehmed Ali, his Army, and the Making of Modern
Egypt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
Farooqi, Naimur Rahman. Mughal-Ottoman Relations. A Study of Political and Diplomatic
Relations between Mughal India and the Ottoman Empire, 1556–1748. New Delhi: Idarah-i
Adabiyat-i Delhi, 1989.
Faroqhi, Suraiya. “Notes on the Production of Cotton and Cotton Cloth in XVI
and XVII Century Anatolia.” The Journal of European Economic History 8 (1979):
405–417.
——. “Sixteenth-Century Periodic Markets in Various Anatolian Sancaks: (çel, Hamid,
Karahisar-i Sahib, Kütahya, Aydın and Mente{e.” JESHO 27 (1979): 32–80.
——. “Textile Production and the Arab Provinces: Geographic Distribution and
Internal Trade (1560–1650).” JOS 1 (1980): 61–83.
——. “Camels, Wagons, and the Ottoman State in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth
Centuries.” IJMES 14 (1982): 23–39.
212
——. Towns and Townsmen of Ottoman Anatolia. Trade, Crafts and Food Production in an
Urban Setting, 1520–1650. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
——. “Civilian Society and Political Power in the Ottoman Empire: A Report on
Research in Collective Bibliography, 1480–1830.” IJMES 17 (1985): 109–17.
——. “Political Initiatives “From the Bottom Up” in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth-
Century Ottoman Empire: Some Evidence for Their Existence.” In Osmanistische
Studien zur Wirtschafts-und Sozialgeschichte in Memoriam Vanco Bo“kov, 23–33. Edited
by Hans Georg Majer. Wiesbaden: Harrassowitz, 1986.
——. “An Ulama Grandee and his Household.” JOS 9 (1989): 199–208.
——. “Introduction: Special Issue on Ottoman Trade.” New Perspectives on Turkey
5–6 (1991): 1–28.
——. “Traders and Customs Officials in 1660s Iskenderun.” New Perspectives on Turkey
5–6 (1991): 107–122.
——. “Wealth and Power in the Land of Olives: Economic and Political Activities
of Muridzade Haci Mehmed Agha, Notable of Edremit.” In Landholding and
Commercial Agriculture in the Middle East, 77–96. Edited by Ça[lar Keyder and Faruk
Tabak. Albany: State University of New York Press, 1991.
——. “Introduction.” The Journal of Peasant Studies (special issue) 18 (1991): 3–17.
——. Pilgrims and Sultans: The Hajj under the Ottomans. London: I. B. Tauris, 1994.
——. Approaching Ottoman History: An Introduction to the Sources. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1999.
Fattah, Hala. “The Politics of Grain Trade in Iraq, c. 1840–1917.” New Perspectives on
Turkey 5–6 (1991): 151–166.
Fekete, L. Die Siyàqat-Schrift in der Türkischen Finanzverwaltung, Beitrag zur türkischen
Paläographie. 2 vols. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1955.
Findley, Carter V. Bureaucratic Reform in the Ottoman Empire: The Sublime Porte, 1789–1922.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1980.
——. Ottoman Civil Officialdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989.
Fischer, Alan. “Les rapports entre l’Empire ottoman et la Crimée: L’aspect financier.”
CMRS 13 (1967): 368–381.
——. Russian Annexation of the Crimea 1772–1783. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1970.
Ferguson, R. Brian, and Neil L. Whitehead, eds. War in the Tribal Zone: Expanding
States and Indigenous Warfare. Santa Fe: School of American Research Press, 1992.
Finkel, Caroline. “The Provisioning of the Ottoman Army During the Campaigns
of 1593–1606.” In Habsburgisch-osmanische Beziehungen (CIEPO 26–30 September 1983),
107–123. Edited by Andreas Tietze. Vienna: Verband der Wissenschaftlichen
Gesellschaften Österreichs, 1985.
——. The Administration of Warfare: the Ottoman Military Campaigns in Hungary, 1593–1606.
Beihefte zur Wiener Zeitschrift für die Kunde des Morgenlandes, no. 14. Vienna:
Verband der Wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften Österreichs, 1988.
Fleischer, Cornell H. “Royal Authority, Dynastic Cyclism and ‘Ibn Khaldunism’ in
Sixteenth Century Ottoman Letters.” Journal of Asian and African Studies 18 (1984):
218–237.
——. Bureaucrat and Intellectual in the Ottoman Empire: The Historian Mustafa 'Ali
(1541–1600). Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986.
——. “Preliminaries to the Study of the Ottoman Bureaucracy.” Journal of Turkish
Studies. Raiyyet Rüsumu. Essays Presented to Halil (nalcık. Edited by Bernard
Lewis et al., 10 (1986): 135–142.
——. “The Lawgiver as Messiah: The Making of the Imperial Image in the Reign
of Süleymân.” In Soliman le Manifique et son temps: actes du colloque de Paris Galeries
Nationales du Grand Palais 7–10 Mars 1990, 159–177. Edited by Gilles Veinstein.
Paris: École des Hautes Études en Science Sociales, 1992.
Fleming, Katherine Elizabeth. The Muslim Bonaparte: Diplomacy and Orientalism in Ali
Pasha’s Greece. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1999.
213
Floor, Willem, and Patrick Clawson. “Safavid Iran’s Search for Silver and Gold.”
IJMES 32 (2000): 345–368.
Fodor, Pal. “State and Society, Crisis and Reform in 15th–17th Century Ottoman
Mirrors for Princes.” Acta Orientalia Academiae Scientiarum Hungaricae 40 (1986): 217–
240.
——. In Quest of the Golden Apple: Imperial Ideology, Politics, and Military Administration
in the Ottoman Empire. Istanbul: Isis, 2000.
Fontana, Biancamaria. “The Napoleonic Empire and the Europe of Nations.” In
The Idea of Europe: From Antiquity to the European Union, 116–138. Edited by Anthony
Pagden. Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center Press, 2002.
Foucault, Michel. The Archaeology of Knowledge and The Discourse on Language. New York:
Harper and Row, 1972.
Frangakis, Elena. “The Balance of Trade and the Balance of Payments between
Izmir and France, 1700–1789.” In Communications grecques présentées au Ve Congrès
International des Etudes du Sud Est-Européen (Belgrade: 11–17 Septembre 1984), 127–138.
Athens: Comité National Grec, 1985.
——. The Commerce of Smyrna in the Eighteenth Century, (1700–1820). Athens: Center
for Asia Minor Studies, 1992.
Frank, André Gunder. “A Theoretical Introduction to 5,000 Years of World Systems
History.” Review 13 (1990): 155–250.
——. Re-Orient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1998.
Fukasawa, Katsumi. Toilerie et commerce du Levant au XVIII e siècle d’Alep à Marseille.
Marseille: Groupe de Recherche et d’Ètudes sur le Proche Orient. Centre Regional
de Publication de Marseille, 1985.
Furet, François. Penser la Revolution française. Paris: Gallimard, 1978.
Garrison, Janine. L’Édit de Nantes et sa révocation: histoire d’une intolerance. Paris: Édi-
tions du Seuil, 1985.
Genç, Mehmet. “Osmanlı Maliyesinde Malikâne Sistemi.” In Türkiye (ktisat Tarihi
Semineri, 231–296. Edited by Osman Okyar and Ünal Nalbanto[lu. Ankara:
Hacetepe Üniversitesi/Meteksan, 1975.
——. “Osmanlı Ekonomisi ve }ava{.” Yapıt 49 (1984): 52–61; Tables, 86–93.
——. “Osmanlı Devleti’nde (ç Gümrük Rejimi.” In Tanzimat"tan Cumhuriyet’e Türkiye
Ansiklopedisi. Istanbul: (leti{im, 1985, vol. 3: 786–789.
——. “A Study on the Feasibility of Using Eighteenth-Century Ottoman Financial
Records as an Indicator of Economic Activity.” In The Ottoman Empire in the World
Economy, 345–373. Edited by Huri (slamo[lu-(nan. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1987.
——. “Osmanlı (ktisadî Dünya Görü{ünün (lkeleri.” Sosyologi Dergisi (Istanbul Üniver-
sitesi Edebiyat Fakültesi, 3rd ser. 1 (1989): 176–185.
——. “Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi.” In V. Milletlerarası Türkiye
Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi, 13–25. Edited by Hakkı Dursun Yıldız, (nci Enginün
and Emine Görsoy Naskalı. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
——. Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda Devlet ve Ekonomi. Istanbul: Ötüken, 2000.
——. “Esham.” (A2, 11: 375–380.
Genet, Jean-Philippe, and Michel le Mené, eds. Génèse de l’état moderne: prélevement et
redistribution. Paris: Editions du Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique,
1987.
Genier, J. Y. “La demande sous l’Ancien Régime.” Annales économies, sociétés, civi-
lizations 42 (1987): 497–528.
Genovese, E. and L. Hochberg, eds. Geographic Perspectives in History. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1989.
Gerber, Haim. “Guilds in Seventeenth Century Anatolian Bursa.”Asian and African
Studies 11 (1976): 59–86.
——. “The Monetary System of the Ottoman Empire.” JESHO 25 (1982): 308–324.
214
Hagen, Gottfried. “Ein osmanischer Geograph bei der Arbeit. Entstehung and
Gedankenwelt von Kâtib Çelebis Cihânnümâ.” Ph.D. diss., Freie Universität
Berlin, 1996.
Halaço[lu, Yusuf. XVIII. Yüzyılda Osmanlı (mparatorlu[u"nun (skan Siyaseti ve A{iretlerin
Yerle{tirilmesi. Ankara, TTK, 1991.
Halasi-Kun, G. J. “The Map of ‘}eki-i Yeni Felemenk Maa (ngiliz" in Ebubekir
Dimi{ki’s Tercüme-i Atlas Mayor.’ ” Archivum Ottomanicum 11 (1988): 51–70.
——. “(brahım Müteferrika.” (A, 5, pt. 2: 896–900.
Hambly, Gavin. “An Introduction to the Economic Organization of Early Qajar
Iran.” Iran 2 (1964): 69–82.
Hamilton, Alastair, and Alexander H. de Groot. Friends and Rivals in the East: Studies
in Anglo-Dutch Relations in the Levant from the Seventeenth to the Early Nineteenth Century.
Leiden: E. J. Brill, 2000.
Hammer-Purgstall, Joseph Freiherr von. Geschichte des osmanischen Reiches (Histoire de
l’Empire ottoman depuis son origine jusqu’a nos jours). 18 vols. Paris, Bellizard, Barthes,
Dufour & Lowell; 1835–43.
Harley, J. B. and David Woodward, eds. The History of Cartography: Cartography in the
Traditional Islamic and South Asian Societies. 2 vols. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press, 1992.
Harvey, D. “On the History and Present Conditions of Geography: An Historical
Materialist Manifesto.” Professional Geographer 3 (1984): 1–11.
——. The Condition of Postmodernity: An Enquiry into the Origins of Cultural Change. New
York: Basil Blackwell, 1989.
Hathaway, Jane. The Politics of Household in Ottoman Egypt: The Rise of the Qazada[lı.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997.
——. “Years of Ocak Power: The Rise of the Qazda[li Household and the
Transformation of Ottoman Egypt’s Military Society, 1670–1750 (Egypt).” Ph.D.
diss., Princeton University, 1992.
Hazareesingh, Sudhir. From Subject to Citizen: The Second Empire and the Emergence of
Modern French Democracy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998.
Henshall, Nicholas. The Myth of Absolutism: Change and Continuity in Early Modern European
Monarchy. London: Longman, 1992.
Heyd, Uriel. “The Ottoman 'Ulemâ and Westernization in the Time of Selim III
and Mahmud II.” In Studies in Islamic History and Civilization. Vol. 9, 63–96. Edited
by Uriel Heyd. Jerusalem: The Magnes Press, 1961.
Hinz, Walther. Islamische Masse und Gewichte umgerechnet ins metrische System. Leiden:
E. J. Brill, 1970.
Hezarfen, Hüseyın Efendi. Telhisü"l Beyan fi Kavânin-i Âl-i Osmân. Edited by Sevim
Ilgürel. Ankara: TTK, 2000.
Hintze, Otto. “The Formation of States and Constitutional Development: A Study
in History and Politics.” In The Historical Essays, 157–78. Edited by Felix Gilbert.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1975.
Hirschman, Albert O. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations,
and States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970.
Hodgson, Marshall G. S. The Venture of Islam: Conscience and History in a World Civilization.
3 vols. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974.
Hoexter, Miriam. Endowments, Rulers and Community: Waqf al-Haramayn in Ottoman
Algiers. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1998.
Hoffman, Philip T., Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660–1870.
Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2000.
—— and Kathryn Norberg, eds. Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and Representative Government,
1450 –1789. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1994.
——, Gille Postel-Vinay, and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, “Information and Economic
History: How the Credit Market in Old Regime Paris Forces us to Rethink the
Transition to Capitalism.” The American Historical Review 101 (1999): 69–94.
216
Hourani, Albert. “The Changing Face of the Fertile Crescent in the XVIIIth
Century.” Studia Islamica 8 (1957): 89–122.
——. “Ottoman Reform and the Politics of Notables.” In Beginnings of Modernization
in the Middle East: The Nineteenth Century, 41–68. Edited by William R. Polk and
Richard L. Chambers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1968.
Howard, D. A. “The Ottoman Timar System and Its Transformation, 1563–1656.”
Ph.D. diss., University of Indiana, 1987.
——. “The Historical Development of the Ottoman Imperial Registry (Defter-i
Hakanî): Mid-Fifteenth to Mid-Seventeenth Centuries.” Archivum Ottomanicum 9
(1988): 213–230.
Hulliung, Mark. Montesquieu and the Old Regime. Berkeley: University of California
Press, 1976.
Hurewitz, J. C. The Middle East and North Africa in World Politics. 2 vols. New Haven:
Yale University Press, 1975.
Wolf-Dieter Hütteroth and Kamal Abdulfattah. Historical geography of Palestine, Transjordan
and Southern Syria in the late 16th Century. Erlangen: Fränkische Geographische Ges.
Palm und Enke, 1977.
Ibn Khaldûn. The Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History. Trans. Franz Rosenthal,
Bollingen Series. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1969.
Ibrahim Müteferika. Usûl"ûl-Hikem fî Nizâmü"l-Ümem. Edited by Adel }en. Ankara:
Türkiye Diyanet Vakfi, 1995.
Igger, George G. New Directions in European Historiography. Hanover, N.H.: University
of New England, 1984.
(hsano[lu, Ekmeleddin, Ramazan }e{en, M. Serdar Bekar, Gülcan Gündüz, et al.,
eds. Osmanlı Co[rafya Literatürü. 2 vols. Istanbul: IRCICA, 2000.
(lhan, M. Mehdi. Amid (Diyarbakır). Ankara: TTK, 2000.
——. “Studies in the Medieval History of Diyarbekir Province: Some Notes on the
Sources and Literature.” Belleten 53 (1989): 199–231.
Imber, Colin. Ebu"s-Su"ud: The Islamic Legal Tradition. Stanford: Stanford University
Press, 1997.
(nalcık, Halil. “Osmanlılarda Raiyyet Rüsûmu.” Belleten 23 (1959): 575–600.
——. “Bursa and the Commerce of the Levant.” JESHO 3 (1960): 131–114.
——. “Sened-i (ttifak ve Gülhane Hatt-ı Hümâyunu.” Belleten 28 (1964): 605–690.
——. “The Nature of a Traditional Society.” In Political Modernization in Japan and
Turkey, 42–63. Edited by R. E. Ward and D. A. Rustow. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1964.
——. “Capital Formation in the Ottoman Empire.” Journal of Economic History 29
(1969): 97–140.
——. “Suleiman the Lawgiver and Ottoman Law.” Archivum Ottomanicum 1 (1969):
117–124.
——. “The Ottoman Economic Mind and Aspects of the Ottoman Economy.” In
Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, 207–18. Edited by Michael A.
Cook. London: Oxford University Press, 1970.
——. The Ottoman Empire: The Classical Age, 1300–1600. New York: Praeger, 1973.
——. “The Socio-political Effects of the Diffusion of Firearms on the Middle East.”
In War, Technology and Society in the Middle East, 195–217. Edited by V. J. Parry
and M. E. Yapp. London: Oxford University Press, 1975.
——. “Centralization and Decentralization in Ottoman Administration, 27–52.” In
Studies in Eighteenth Century Islamic History. Edited by T. Naff and R. Owen.
Carbondale: University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977.
——. “Impact of the Annales School on Ottoman Studies and New Findings.”
Review 1 (1978): 69–96.
——. “Osmanlı Pamuklu Pazarı. Hindistan ve (ngiltere, Pazar Rekabetinde Emek
Maliyetinin Rolü.” Orta Do[u Teknik Üniversitesi Geli{me Dergisi (1979–80): 1–66.
217
——. “Men and Ideas in the Eighteenth Century Ottoman Empire.” In Studies in
Eighteenth Century Islamic History, 15–26. Edited by T. Naff and R. Owen. Carbondale:
University of Southern Illinois Press, 1977.
——. and Max Mote, eds. Mubadele: An Ottoman Russian Exchange of Ambassadors.
Chicago: University of Chicago, 1970.
Izady, Mehrdad. The Kurds: A Concise Handbook. Washington: Crane Russak, 1992.
Jabarti, Abd al-Rahman. Napoleon in Egypt: Al-Jabarti’s Chronicle of the French Occupation
(1798). Trans. and edited by S. Moreh. Princeton: Marcus Wiener Publishers, 1993.
Jackson, Peter and Laurence Lockhardt, eds. The Cambridge History of Iran. Vol. 6:
The Timurid and Safavid Periods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.
Jamgocyan, Onik. “Les finances de l’Empire Ottoman et les financièrs de Constan-
tinople, 1732–1853.” Ph.D. diss., University of Paris I (Sorbonne), 1988.
Jardin, André. Tocqueville: A Biography. New York: Farrar Straus Giroux, 1988.
Jennings, Ronald. “Loan and Credit in Early 17th Century Judicial Records. The
Shari"a Court of Anatolia and Kayseri.” JESHO 16 (1973): 168–216.
——. “Firearms, Bandits, and Gun-Control: Some Evidence on Ottoman Policy
toward Firearms in the Possession of Reaya, from Judicial Records of Kayseri,
1600–1627.” Archivum Ottomanicum 6 (1976): 229–258.
——. “Urban Population in Anatolia in the 16th Century: A Study of Kayseri,
Karaman, Amasya, Trabzon and Erzurum.” IJMES 7 (1976): 21–57.
——. “Kadı, Court and Legal Procedure in 17th Century Ottoman Kayseri.” Studia
Islamica 48 (1978): 133–172.
Johansen, Baber. “Amwal Zahira and Amwal Batina: Town and Countryside as
Reflected in the Tax System of the Hanafite School.” In Studia Arabica and Islamica
Festschrift for Ihsan 'Abbas on his 60th Birthday, 247–263. Edited by Widad al-Qadi.
Beirut: American University of Beirut, 1981.
——. The Islamic Law on Land Tax and Rent. London: Croom Helm, 1988.
Jones, J. R. “Fiscal Policies, Liberties, and Representative Government during the
Reigns of the Last Stuarts.” In Fiscal Crises, Liberty, and Representative Government,
1450–1789, 67–95. Edited by Philip T. Hoffman and Kathryn Norberg. Stanford:
Stanford University Press, 1994.
Joudah, Ahmad Hasan. Revolt in Palestine in the 18th Century: The Era of Shaykh Zahir
al-Umar. Princeton: The Kingston Press, 1989.
Kafadar, Jamal. Between Two Worlds. Berkeley: University of California, 1994.
Kahane, Henry, Reneé Kahane, and Andreas Tietze, The Lingua Franca in the Levant:
Turkish Nautical Terms of Italian and Greek Origin. Urbana: University of Illinois Press,
1958.
Kahle, P. “China as Described by Turkish Geographers from Iranian Sources.”
Proceedings of the Iran Society (London) 11 (1940): 48–59.
Kal"a, Ahmet, Ahmet Tabako[lu, and Salih Aynural, et al., eds. (stanbul Ahkâm
Defterleri. (stanbul Finans Tarihi (1742–1787). Istanbul: Istanbul Ara{tırmaları Merkezi,
1998.
Karal, Enver Ziya. Selim III"ün Hatt-ı Hümayunları. Nizam-ı Cedit: 1789–1807. Ankara:
TTK, 1988.
Karpat, Kemal. “The Land Regime. Social Structure in the Ottoman Empire.” In
The Beginnings of Modernization in the Middle East, 69–90. Edited by William Polk
and Richard Chambers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1969.
——. “The Transformation of the Ottoman State, 1789–1908.” IJMES 3 (1972):
243–281.
——. “The Stages of Ottoman History: A Structural Comparative Approach.” In
The Ottoman State and Its Place in World History, 79–98. Edited by Kemal Karpat.
Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1974.
Kâtip Çelebi. Bozuklukların Düzeltilmesinde Tutulacak Yollar (Düstûru"l-Amel li-Islahi"l-Halel)
Edited by and trans. Ali Can. Ankara: Kültür ve Turizm Bakanlı[ı Yayınları,
1982.
219
——. Bir Osmanlı Valisinin Yıllık Gelir Gideri: Diyarbakır, 1670–71. Istanbul: Bo[aziçi
Üniversitesi, 1981.
——. The Sultan’s Servants: The Transformation of Ottoman Provincial Government, 1550–1650.
New York: Columbia University Press, 1983.
Kurmu{, Orhan. “The 1838 Treaty of Commerce Re-Examined.” In Economie et
Societé dans l’Empire Ottoman, 411–417. Edited by Jean-Louis Bacqué-Grammont
and Paul Dumont. Paris: CNRS, 1983.
Kurt, (smail. Para Vakıfları Nazariyatı ve Tatbikat. Istanbul: Ensar Ne{riyat, 1996.
Kut, Turgut, and Fatma Ture, eds. Yazmadan Basmaya: Müteferrika, Mühendishane, Üskü-
dar. Istanbul: Yapı Kredi, 1996.
Kütüko[lu, Bekir. “Vekâyınüvis.” A(, 13:271–287.
Kütüko[lu, Mübahat S. Osmanlı-(ngiliz Iktisâdî Münâsebetleri (1580 –1838). Vol. 1.
Ankara: Türk Kültürünü Ara{tırma Enstitüsü, 1974.
——. “1009/1600 Tarihli Narh Defterine Göre Istanbul"da Çe{itli E{ya ve Hizmet
Fiatları.” Tarih Enstitüsü Dergisi 9 (1978): 1–86.
——. Osmanlılarda Narh Müessesesi ve 1640 Tarihli Narh Defteri. Istanbul: Enderun
Kitabevi, 1983.
——. Osmanlı Belgelerinin Dili (Diplomatik). Istanbul: Kubbealtı Akademisi Kültür ve
San"at Vakfi, 1998.
Kwass, Michael. “A Kingdom of Taxpayers: State Formation, Privilege, and Political
Culture in Eighteenth-Century France.” The Journal of Modern History 70 (1998):
295–339.
Ladurie, Emmanuel Le Roy. The Ancien Regime: a History of France, 1610–1774. Oxford:
Blackwell, 1996.
Lambton, Ann K. S. “Persian Trade Under the Early Qajars.” In Islam and Trade
in Asia, 215–244. Edited by D. S. Richards. Oxford: Oxford University Press,
1970.
Lane, Frederic C. “Force and Enterprise in the Creation of Oceanic Commerce.”
In Journal of Economic History (Supplemental issue: The Tasks of Economic History)
10 (1950): 19–31.
——. “Economic Consequences of Organized Violence.” Journal of Economic History
18 (1958): 401–417.
——. Venice and History: The Collected Papers of Frederic C. Lane. Edited by
a Committee of Colleagues and Former Students. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press,
1966.
Laroui, Abdallah. The History of the Maghrib: An Interpretive Essay. Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1977.
Laski, Harold J. Studies in the Problem of Sovereignty. New Haven: Yale University Press,
1917.
Lattimore, Owen. Inner Asian Frontiers of China. New York: Oxford University Press,
1940.
Laurens, Henry. Les origines intellectuelles de l’expedition d’Égypte: l’orientalisme islamisant en
France (1698–1798). Istanbul: Isis, 1987.
Laya, M. Alexandre. Études Historiques sur la vie privée politique et littérare de M. A. Thièrs
(1830 –1846). 2 vols. Paris: Chez Furne, 1846.
Leeuwen, Richard van. Notables and Clergy in Mount Lebanon: The Khazin Sheikhs and
the Maronite Church (1736–1840). Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995.
Lefebvre, Henri. The Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell, 1994.
Lemercier-Quelquejay, Chantal. “Les Kalmuks de la Volga entre L’Empire russe
et l’Empire ottoman sous le regne de Pierre le Grand.” CMRS 7:63–73.
Levy, Avigdor. “Military Reform and the Problem of Centralization in the Ottoman
Empire in the Eighteenth Century.” Middle Eastern Studies 18 (1982): 227–249.
Lewis, Bernard. The Emergence of Modern Turkey. 2d ed. London: Oxford University
Press, 1961.
221
Matthews, George T. The Royal General Farms in Eighteenth Century France. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1958.
Matthee, Rudolph P. The Politics of Trade in Safavid Iran: Silk for Silver, 1600–1730.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999.
Matuz, Joseph E. “Constributions to the Ottoman Institution of the (ltizam.” JOS
11 (1991): 237–249.
McCabe, I. B. The Shah’s Silk for Europe’s Silver: The Eurasian Trade of the Julfa Armenians
in Safavid Iran and India (1530–1750). Atlanta, GA: Scholars Press, 1999.
McGowan, Bruce. Economic Life in the Ottoman Europe: Taxation, Trade and the Struggle
for Land. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981.
——. “The Study of Land and Agriculture in the Ottoman Provinces within the
Context of an Expanding World Economy in the 17th and 18th Centuries.” IJTS
2 (1981): 57–63.
——. “The Age of the Ayan.” In An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire,
637–743. Edited by Halil (nalcık with Donald Quataert. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1994.
McNeill, William. Europe’s Steppe Frontier, 1500–1800. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1964.
——. Venice: The Hinge of Europe, 1081–1797. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1974.
——. The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Force, and Society since A.D. 1000. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1982.
Mehmed Süreyya Bey. Sicill-i Osmanî yahut Tezkere-yi Me{ahir-i Osmaniye. 4 vols.
Istanbul: Matbaa-i Âmire, 1308–15 (1890–97).
Meriwether, Margaret, L. “Urban Notables and Rural Resources in Aleppo,
1770–1830.” IJTS 4 (1987): 55–73.
——. The Kin Who Count: Family and Society in Ottoman Aleppo, 1770–1840. Austin:
University of Texas Press, 1999.
Mert, Özcan. XVIII. ve XIX. Yüzyıllarda Çapano[ulları. Ankara: Kültür Bakanlı[ı, 1980.
Meservey, Sabra F. “Feyzullah Efendi: An Ottoman Seyhülislam.” Ph.D. diss.,
Princeton University, 1966.
Messick, Brinkley. The Calligraphic State: Textual Domination and History in a Muslim
Society. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.
Miller, Anatolii F. Mustapha Pacha Bairaktar. Bucarest: Association International
d’Études du Sud-Est Européen, 1975.
Mitchell, Timothy. Colonising Egypt. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988.
Mo"in, Mohammad. An Intermediate Persian Dictionary. Tehran: Amir Kabir, 1996.
Montesquieu. Oeuvres complètes. Edited by Roger Caillois. 2 vols. Paris: Bibliothèque
de la Pléiade, 1949–51.
Moon, David. “Peasant Migration and the Settlement of Russia’s Frontiers, 1509–
1897.” The Historical Journal 40 (1997): 859–893.
Moore, Sally Falk. Law as Process: An Anthropological Approach. London: Routledge
Kegan, 1978.
Morgenthau, Hans. Politics among Nations. New York: Knopf, 1967.
Motika, Raoul and Michael Ursinus, eds. Caucasia between the Ottoman Empire and Iran,
1555–1914. Wiesbaden: Reichert, 2000.
Moutachieva, Vera P. “L’institution de l’ayanlık pendant les dernieres décennies du
XVIIIe siècle.” Études Balkaniques 2–3 (1965): 233–247.
——. Agrarian Relations in the Ottoman Empire in the 15th and 16th Centuries. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1988.
Mumcu, Ahmet. Hukuksal ve Siyasal Karar Organı Olarak Divan-ı Hümayun. Ankara:
Ankara Üniversitesi Hukuk Fakültesi Yayınları, 1976.
——. Tarih (cindeki Genel Geli{imiyle Birlikte Osmanlı Devletinde Rü{vet: Özellikle Adlı Rü{vet.
Istanbul: (nkılâp Kitabevi, 1985.
223
Tabak, Faruk. “Local Merchants in Peripheral Areas of the Empire: The Fertile
Crescent during the Long Nineteenth Century.” Review 11 (1988): 179–214.
——. “Agrarian Fluctuations and Modes of Labor Control in the Western Arc of
the Fertile Crescent, c. 1700–1850.” In Landholding and Commercial Agriculture in the
Middle East, 135–155. Edited by F. Tabak and Ca[lar Keyder. Albany: State
University of New York, 1991.
Tabako[lu, Ahmet. Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanlı Maliyesi. Istanbul: Dergâh
Yayınları, 1985.
——. Türk (ktisat Tarihi. Istanbul: Dergâh Yayınları, 1986.
Taeschner, Franz G. Das Anatolische Wegenetz nach Osmanischen Quellen. 2 vols. Leipzig:
Mayer & Müller, 1924–1926.
Tatarcık, Abdullah Efendi. “Selim-i Sâni Devrinde Nizâm-ı Devlet Hakkında Mutâ-
la"ât.” Türk Tarihi Encümeni Mecmuası 8 (1333/1914–1915): 15–24.
Tekeli, Ilhan. “On Institutionalized External Relations of Cities in the Ottoman
Empire: A Settlement Model Approach.” Études Balkaniques, 8 (1972): 49–72.
Thieck, Jean-Pierre. “Décentralisation ottomane et affirmation urbaine à Alep à la
fin du XVIIIème siècle.” In Mouvements communautaires et espaces urbains au Machreq,
116–178. Edited by Mona Zakaria et al.. Beirut: Centre d’Études et de Recherches
sur le Moyen-Orient Contemporain, 1985.
——. Passion d’Orient. Edited by Gilles Kepel. Paris: Éditions Karthala, 1992.
Thomas, Lewis V. A Study of Naima. New York: New York University Press,
1972.
Thompson, Elizabeth. “Ottoman Political Reform in the Provinces: The Damascus
Advisory Council in 1844–45.” IJMES 25 (1993): 457–475.
Thomson, Ann. Barbary and Enlightenment: European Attitudes toward the Magreb in the
Eighteenth Century. Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1987.
Tietze, Andreas, ed. Mustafa Ali’s Counsel for Sultans of 1581. 2 vols. Wien: Verlag
der Österreichischen Akademie der Wissenschaften, 1979.
——, ed. Habsburgisch-osmanische Beziehungen: relations habsbourg-ottomanes. Wien, 26.–30.
September 1983. Colloque sous le patronage du Comité International des Études pré-Ottomanes
et Ottomanes. Vienna: Verlag des Verbandes der wissenschaftlichen Gesellschaften
Österreichs, 1985.
Tilly, Charles. “Reflections on the History of European State-Making.” In The
Formation of the National States in Western Europe, 3–83. Edited by Charles Tilly.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.
——. “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime.” In Bringing the State
Back In, 169–191. Edited by Peter B. Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda
Skopcol. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985.
——. The Contentious French: Four Centuries of Popular Struggle. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1986.
——. “State and Counterrevolution in France.” Social Research 56 (1989): 71–97.
——. Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990–1990. Oxford: Blackwell, 1990.
Tızlak, Fahrettin. “Osmanlı Devletinde Ham Bakır ({leme Merkezleri Olarak Tokat
ve Diyarbakır.” Belleten 59: (1995): 643–659.
——. Osmanlı Döneminde Keban-Ergani Yöresinde Madencilik, 1775–1850. Ankara: TTK,
1997.
Tocqueville, Alexis. Oeuvres complètes. 18 vols. Edited by J. P. Mayer. Paris: Gallimard,
1951–.
——. The Old Régime and the French Revolution. Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday &
Company, 1955.
——. L’ancien régime et la Révolution. Edited by J. P. Mayer. Paris: Éditions Gallimard,
1967.
——. “The European Revolution” & Correspondence with Gobineau. Westport, Conn.:
Greenwood, 1974.
231
Witt, Peter-Christian, ed. Wealth and Taxation in Central Europe: The History and Sociology
of Public Finance. Leamington Spa: Berg, 1987.
Wolff, Larry. Inventing Eastern Europe: The Map of Civilization on the Mind of the Enlightenment.
Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, 1994.
Wolin, Sheldon S. Tocqueville Between Two Worlds: The Making of a Political and Theoretical
Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001.
Woloch, Isser. The New Regime: Transformations of the French Civic Order, 1789–1820.
New York: W.W. Norton, 1994.
Woodhead, Christine. “‘The Present Terrour of the World’: Contemporary Views
of the Ottoman Empire c. 1600.” History ( Journal of the Historical Association,
G.B.) 72 (1987): 20–37.
Woods, A. C. A History of the Levant Company. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1935.
Yaman, Talat Mümtaz. “Osmanlı (mparatorlu[u Te{kilatında Mütesellimlik Müesse-
sesine Dair.” Türk Hukuk Tarihi Dergisi 1 (1941–42): 75–105.
Yavuz, Muhsine Helimo[lu. Diyarbakır Efsaneleri üzerine Ara{tırma: Derleme, (nceleme. 2
vols. Ankara: M. H. Yavuz, 1989.
Yediyıldız, Bahaeddin. “Türk Vakıf Kurucularının Sosyal Tabakala{madaki Yeri,
1700–1800.” JOS 3 (1982): 143–164.
——. Institution du vaqf au XVIII e siecle en Turquie: étude socio-historique. Ankara: Imprimerie
de la Société d’Histoire Turque, 1985.
Yıldız, Hakkı Dursun, (nci Enginün, and Emine Gürsöy Naskalı, eds. V. Milletlerarası
Türkiye Sosyal ve (ktisat Tarihi Kongresi: Tebli[ler. Istanbul 1989. Ankara: TTK, 1990.
Yılmaz, Nazım, Osman Yıldırım, and Necla Büyükkırcalı. Osmanlı Ar{ivinde Bulunan
Muâhedenâmelerden Örnekler. Ankara: T. C. Ba{bakanlık Devlet Ar{ivleri Genel
Müdürlü[ü Osmanlı Ar{ivi Daire Ba{kanlı[ı, 2000.
Yılmazçelik, (brahim. XIX. Yüzyılın (lk Yarısında Diyarbakır, 1790–1840. Ankara: TTK,
1995.
——. XIX. Yüzyılın ilk Yarısında Diyarbakır, 1790–1840. Ph.D. diss., 2 vols. Fırat
Üniversitesi (Elazı[), 1991.
Yınanç, Mükrimin, H. “Diyarbekir.” (A, 1 (1945): 601–605.
Yirmisekiz Çelebi, Mehmed Efendi"nin Fransa Sefâretnâmesi. Edited by Beynun Akyava.
Ankara: Türk Kültürünü Ara{tırma Enstitüsü, 1993.
Yücel, Ya{ar. “Osmanlı (mparatorlu[unda Desantralizasyona (Adem-i Merkeziye)
Dair Genel Gözlemler.” Belleten 38 (1974): 657–708.
——. Osmanlı Devlet Düzenine Ait Metinler. Kitâb Müstetâb. Ankara: Ankara Üniversitesi
Dil ve Tarih Co[rafya Fakültesi, 1974.
Zarinebaf-Shahr, Fariba. “Tabriz under Ottoman Rule, 1725–1730.” Ph.D. diss.,
University of Chicago, 1991.
Zilfi, Madeline. “Elite Circulation in the Ottoman Empire: Great Mollas of the
Eighteenth Century.” JESHO 26 (1983): 318–364.
——. The Politics of Piety: The Ottoman Ulema in the Postclassical Age (1600 –1800).
Minneapolis: Bibliotheca Islamica, 1988.
This page intentionally left blank
INDEX
Abou-El-Haj, Rifa"at 6 n. 8, 18, 44, Auction, of tax farms 26, 88–9, 96,
88, 104–105, 194 99, 101, 103, 109, 134, 138, 140,
Abdulfattah, Kamal 58 n. 81 150–1; (in provinces) 26, 134, 138,
Adana 67 140, 150–1; of esham 119; of
Afghan 37 personal effects. See Müsadere
Ahmad Shah Durrani 72 Ayan. See Gentry
Ahmed II 88 n. 50 Ayıntab 53
Ahmed III 30, 39, 75–78, 118–19, Azarbayjan 34, 35, 38, 39, 71
179, 182 Abbas III, Safavid Shah 41
Ahmed Cevdet Pasha 30, 180, 182, 194 Azov 40
Ahmed Efendi Vâsıf 181, n. 18 Azam (also 'Azamzâde, clan of
Ahmed Resmi Efendi 94, 99 Damascus) 95, 107
Akarlı, Engin 164
Aksan, Virginia 79, 94, 180 n. 12 Bab-ı Âli. See Sublime Porte
Albania 47 Baghdad 11, 13, 48, 50, 61, 65–67,
Aleppo 10, 59, 61, 63, 65–67, 92–93, 74, 100, 111, 129, 131–35, 153,
111, 122 n. 2, 129, 132, 135, 142, 163, 165, 182, 185, 190, 193
148 n. 109, 161, 164, 169, 174 Ba[çı, Serpil 33 n. 9
Algeria 176–8, 195 Bandits 131, 145–6
Ali Bey al-Kabir 49, 74, 112 n. 154, Balkans 7, 8, 37, 47, 49, 55, 68, 71,
180 89, 101, 186
Amid, city of 12, 127 n. 12, 129, Barbir, Karl 18, 58 n. 82, 59 n. 87,
134–40, 146–51, 154–75; sancak 107 n. 135
of 133 n. 27, 135–6, 141, 145; Basra 66, 74
(eastern) nahiye of 135, 139 n. 52; Battle, of Çe{me 74; of Plassey 72;
(western) nahiye of 136–7, 139 n. 52 of Pruth 38
Amsterdam 71 Bengal 61, 72, 125
Alexander the Great 33 Bessarabia 181
Anatolia 128, 129, 147, 149, 153, Bandar Abbas 62
163, 169, 174 Bayraktar Mustafa Pasha 185–8, 191
Ancien régime (old regime, old order) Beyazid I 81
12–17 Black Sea 33, 35, 40, 45–46, 54, 56,
Ankara 62 62, 70, 72, 74, 75, 112, 128, 180,
Arabia 34 192; Principalities of 45, 72. See also
Archives 7; of Algeria 7, 176; of Moldavia and Wallachia
France 126 n. 9; of Harput 171 Borders 44–45
n. 217; of Prussia 7; Ottoman Bosnia 47
79–80 Britain 70
Aristocracy of Service 26. See also Bucak 72
Rical-i devlet Bureaucracy 29, 78, 82–85, 92–102
Armenia 51 Bursa 54, 63, 161
Armenian 27, 111–13, 117 n. 180, Byzantine Empire 81
120, 134
Asia 33, 53, 61, 151, 176, 176, 179. Calendar 86
See also West Asia Canada 197
Asia Minor 36. See also Anatolia Cartography 31–34
Atıl, Esin 78 Caspian Sea 33, 38, 39, 61–62
236