Economics 600: Department of Economics University of Maryland
Economics 600: Department of Economics University of Maryland
University of Maryland
ECONOMICS 600
Patricia Tovar August, 2004
Office: Tydings 4118B
Email: [email protected]
Lecture 1
1. Differential Equations
where
dx(t ) d 2 x(t ) d m x(t )
x1 (t ) = , x 2 (t ) = , ... , x m (t ) = ,
dt dt 2 dt m
F is a function ℜ m +1+ p → ℜ
Note: The solution is a function x(t ) that, together with its derivatives, satisfies (1) for
given values of the parameters.
1
• The order of a differential equation is the order of the highest derivative of x that
appears in it. Thus, (1) is an m-th order differential equation.
x 3 (t ) = ax 2 (t ) + bx1 (t ) + x(t )
Define:
y (t ) = x1 (t )
z (t ) = x 2 (t )
Then:
y1 (t ) = x 2 (t ) = z (t )
z 1 (t ) = x 3 (t )
z 1 (t )
az (t ) + by (t ) + cx(t )
y1 (t ) = z (t )
x (t ) y (t )
1
Definition: A particular solution to (1) is a differentiable function x(t) that satisfies (1)
for some subinterval I0 of the domain of definition of t, I. The set of all solutions is called
the general solution, x g (t ) .
To see that the solution to a differential equation is generally not unique, consider the
following example:
x1 (t ) = 2 x(t ) (2)
One solution to (2) is x(t ) = e 2t . But for any constant c, x(t ) = ce 2t is also a solution.
x(t 0 ) = x0
2
x1 (t ) = f [t , x(t )] (3)
x(t 0 ) = x0 , ( x0 , t 0 ) ∈ X × I (4)
The following theorem says that, under certain conditions, every boundary value problem
has a unique solution.
Example 1: If F is not C1 in some neighborhood of (x0, t0), the solution may not be
unique. Consider the boundary value problem:
x1 (t ) = 3 x(t ) 2 / 3 , x, t ∈ ℜ (5)
x(0) = 0 (6)
x(t ) = t 3
and x(t ) = 0
are solutions to (5) and (6). Note that f ( x) = 3 x(t ) 2 / 3 is not differentiable at x = 0 .
Example 2: The solution may not exist globally. Consider the boundary value problem:
x1 (t ) = x(t ) 2 , x, t ∈ ℜ (7)
x(0) = 1 (8)
1
x(t ) =
1− t
3
Steady States and Stability:
4
• Non-isolated steady states:
Consider an equation that is initially at rest at an equilibrium point x , and suppose that
some shock causes a deviation from x . We may want to know if the equation will return
to the steady state, or at least remain close to it, or if it will get farther and farther away
from it over time.
Definition: Let x be an isolated (or locally unique) steady state of the autonomous
differential equation
That is, any solution x(t ) that at some point enters a ball of radius δ around x remains
within a ball of (possibly larger) radius ε .
That is, any solution that gets sufficiently close to x not only remains nearby but also
converges to x as t → ∞ .
5
x1 (t ) > 0 implies that x(t ) is increasing (the “arrows of motion” point to the right), and
x1 (t ) < 0 implies that x(t ) is decreasing (the “arrows of motion” point to the left). Then:
x1, x3 : locally asymptotically stable
x 2 : unstable
Therefore, we can determine the stability property of a steady state by checking the sign
of the derivative of f[x(t)] at x :
6
x1 : locally asymptotically stable
x 2 : unstable
This suggests that we can study the stability properties of a differential equation from the
sign of f '[ x(t )]| x (t )= xi as long as f '[ x(t )]| x (t )= xi ≠ 0 .
The previous analysis suggests that we can study the stability properties of a nonlinear
differential equation by linearizing it, as long as the equilibrium is hyperbolic.
in U.
The theorem says that near a hyperbolic equilibrium x , the nonlinear differential equation
(9) has the same qualitative structure as the linearized differential equation (10). In
particular, if x is (locally) asymptotically stable for (10), then it is locally asymptotically
stable for (9), and if it is unstable for (10), then it is unstable for (9).
7
Application: The Solow Growth Model
Output (Y) is produced using capital (K) and labor (L) according. The production function
takes the form:
Y (t ) = F [ K (t ), L(t )] (11)
F is C1, it has constant returns to scale and positive and diminishing marginal products
with respect to each input.
Using the constant returns to scale property, we can rewrite output as:
K (t )
where k (t ) =
L(t )
Then
Y (t )
y (t ) = = f [k (t )] (12)
L(t )
That is, we can write output per unit of labor as a function of capital per unit of labor. We
also assume that the so-called Inada conditions hold:
The economy is closed, thus savings equals investment, and a constant fraction s of
output is saved. Assume that there is no depreciation of capital. Then:
where I denotes investment. Assume that labor grows at a constant, exogenous rate n:
Then:
L(t )
K (t ) = K (t ) = k (t ) L0 e nt (16)
L(t )
and thus
K 1 (t ) = k 1 (t ) L0 e nt + k (t )nL0 e nt (17)
8
Using (17) and (14) we get:
k 1 (t ) = sf [k (t )] − nk (t ) (18)
k s
k 1 (t ) = 0 ⇔ sf (k ) = nk ⇔ = (19)
f (k ) n
The capital-output ratio: K / Y = k / f (k ) is constant, and the capital stock and output in
steady state grow at the rate of growth of the population, n.
Stability:
x1 (t ) = ax (t ) + b (20)
9
All solutions to (20) can be written as:
x g (t ) = x c (t ) + x p (t ) (21)
123 1 2 3 123
general solution complementary function particular solution
x1 (t ) = ax (t ) (22)
We can use the method of separation of variables to solve (22). Rewrite (22) as:
dx(t )
= ax(t )
dt
Then:
dx(t ) = ax(t )dt
and
dx(t )
= adt (23)
x(t )
1
∫ x(t )dx(t ) = ∫ adt
ln x(t ) = at + c1
e ln x (t ) = e at e c1
x c (t ) = ce at , c = e c1 (24)
Now, to verify that (21) holds, we want to show that if x p (t ) is any solution to (20), then
ce at + x p (t ) also satisfies (20):
d dx p (t )
[ce at + x p (t )] = ace at +
dt dt
= ace + ax p (t ) + b
at
10
= a[ce at + x p (t )] + b
Thus, if we add ce at to any solution, we get another solution. Moreover, we get all
solutions in that way:
dx g (t )
= ax g (t ) + b (25)
dt
dx p (t )
= ax p (t ) + b (26)
dt
dy (t )
= ay (t )
dt
y (t ) = ce at
Therefore, the difference between any two arbitrary solutions has the form ce at , and thus
we can get all solutions by adding ce at to x p (t ) .
To solve (20), we still need to find x p (t ) . The simplest alternative is usually a steady
state solution:
x1 (t ) = 0 ⇔ ax (t ) + b = 0
b
x p (t ) = − , if a ≠ 0
a
Therefore:
b
x g (t ) = ce at − , if a ≠ 0 (27)
a
and
x g (t ) = bt + c, if a = 0 (28)
11
We can pin down the arbitrary constant by means of a boundary condition. Suppose we
have:
x(0) = x0 (29)
Then, if a ≠ 0 ,
b
x(0) = c −
a
b
c = x0 +
a
and the solution to the boundary value problem given by (20) and (29) is:
b b
x g (t ) = x0 + e at − , if a ≠ 0 (30)
a a
and
x g (t ) = bt + x0 , if a = 0 (31)
12
t
Note that the left hand side of (34) is the derivative of x(t )e −α ( t ) . Therefore, (34) can be
rewritten as:
d
dt
( )
x(t )e −α (t ) = b(t )e −α (t ) (35)
The expression e −α (t ) that made the left hand side of (34) the exact derivative of a
function is called an integrating factor.
We can use (35) to derive two (equivalent) forms of the general solution of equation (32):
the backward solution and the forward solution.
∫ ( )
s d s
x(t )e −α ( t ) dt = ∫ b(t )e
−α ( t )
dt
0 dt 0
s s
x(t )e −α ( t ) ∫ b(t )e
−α ( t )
= dt
0 0
s
x( s )e −α ( s ) − x(0) = ∫ b(t )e
−α ( t )
dt
0
s
x( s ) = x(0)e α ( s ) + ∫ b(t )e
α ( s ) −α ( t )
dt (36)
0
This expression gives us the value of x(s ) as a function of its initial value x(0) and a
weighted sum of past values of the forcing term, b(t ) . This form of the solution is
convenient when there is a natural initial condition for x. Otherwise, the second form of
the solution may be more convenient:
d
( )
∞ ∞
∫s dt
x(t )e −α (t ) dt = ∫s
b(t )e −α ( t ) dt
13
∞
lim x(t )e −α ( t ) − x( s )e −α ( s ) =
t →∞ ∫ s
b(t )e −α ( t ) dt
∞
x( s ) = e α ( s ) lim x(t )e −α ( t ) −
t →∞ ∫s
b(t )e α ( s ) −α ( t ) dt (37)
a1 (t ) = ra (t ) + y (t ) − c(t ) (38)
where a(t) denotes assets (or wealth) held at the beginning of period t, y(t) is labor
income received at the beginning of period t, c(t) denotes consumption expenditure
incurred at the beginning of period t, and r is the interest rate.
We can find the forward solution. Multiplying both sides of (38) by e − rt and rearranging:
Note that the left hand side of (39) is the derivative of a (t )e − rt . Therefore, (34) can be
rewritten as:
d
dt
( )
a(t )e −rt = [ y (t ) − c(t )]e −rt (40)
Suppose that a(0) is given, so let’s integrate (40) forward starting from 0:
∞ ∞
a (t )e −rt ∫0 [ y(t ) − c(t )]e
− rt
= dt
0
Then
∞
− a(0) = ∫ 0
[ y (t ) − c(t )]e − rt dt
∞ ∞
∫0 c(t )e −rt dt = a(0) + ∫0 y (t )e −rt dt (41)
14
Note: If the interest rate changes over time, we need to replace r by r(t) and the
t
integrating factor becomes e ∫0
− r ( s ) ds
, yielding:
t t
∞ − ∫ r ( s ) ds ∞ − ∫ r ( s ) ds
∫0 c(t )e 0 dt = a (0) + ∫0 y (t )e 0 dt (42)
15