Scoring Poverty Philippines 2002
Scoring Poverty Philippines 2002
Mark Schreiner
Abstract
How poor are participants of development projects in the Philippines? This paper uses
the 2002 Annual Poverty Indicators Survey to construct an easy-to-use, objective
poverty scorecard that estimates the likelihood that a participant has income below the
national poverty line. The scorecard uses 10 simple indicators that field workers can
quickly collect and verify. Scores can be computed by hand on paper in real time. With
99-percent confidence, estimates of groups’ overall poverty rates are accurate to within
+/–1 percentage points. The poverty scorecard can help programs target services, track
changes in poverty over time, and report on poverty rates.
Version note
This version replaces that of April 27, 2007, which, due to an incorrect Purchase Power
Parity conversion factor, used an incorrect $2/day line. The correct $2/day line turns
out to be almost the same as the “very poor” line defining the poorest half below the
national poverty line. The $3/day line, in turn, is almost exactly the national poverty
line. Therefore, this version reports on the $4/day line. These changes affect Section 8
and Figures 26–29; everything else is unchanged. Organizations that have applied the
poverty scorecard here should simply discard their $2/day figures and associate their
existing scores with the correct poverty likelihoods for $4/day, using Figure 26.
Acknowledgements
This paper was commissioned by Grameen Foundation USA and funded by the
Consultative Group to Assist the Poorest under the CGAP/Ford Social Indicators
Project. Data were provided by the National Statistics Office of the Republic of the
Philippines. Thanks go to Aniceta Alip, Malika Anand, Nigel Biggar, Cecilia del
Castillo, Ron Chua, Melany Grecia-Viajante, Gretel Guzmán, Syed Hashemi, Lalaine
Joyas, Anthony Leegwater, Gilbert Maramba, Lourdes Medina, Vincent Morris D.
Olaivar, Luca David Opramolla, Don Sillers, and Jeff Toohig.
A Simple Poverty Scorecard for the Philippines
1. Introduction
Indicators in the scorecard were derived from the 38,014 households surveyed in
the 2002 Annual Poverty Indicators Survey (APIS). Selection criteria included:
All scorecard weights are positive integers, and scores range from 0 (most-likely
“poor”) to 100 (least-likely “poor”). The scorecard is easy to understand, and field
probability of being poor. For a group, the overall poverty rate (the so-called “head-
count index”) is the average poverty likelihood of the individuals in the group. For a
group over time, progress (or regress) is the change in its average poverty likelihood.
The poverty scorecard here should qualify for certification for the reporting
practical to use. Also, it accurately and objectively estimates the likelihood of having
income below the national poverty line. With 90-percent confidence, a household’s
estimated poverty likelihood is accurate within +/–6 percentage points, and a group’s
estimated overall poverty rate is accurate with 99-percent confidence to within +/–1
percentage points.
The analysis uses the 38,014 households in the 2002 APIS from the Philippines’
National Statistics Office. This is the best, most recent household survey available with
This paper divides the APIS households into three random samples (Figure 1),
with one-half the households used for constructing the scorecard, one-fourth used for
associating scores with estimated poverty likelihoods, and one-fourth used for measuring
APIS is fielded annually and measures income but not expenditure. The official
poverty lines are in terms of income, and the Philippine government applies them only
to a larger, more detailed survey, the triennial Family Income and Expenditure Survey
(FIES). The 2003 FIES is not available, but Ericta (2005) reports that it gives a
This paper applies the official poverty lines to the income meaure in the 2002
APIS. While APIS uses different questions than FIES to measure income, the resulting
overall poverty rate is 31.8 percent, remarkably close to FIES’ 30.4 percent.
1
The rural poverty rate in APIS was 46.4 percent, while urban was 17.3 percent.
This paper presents a single scorecard for use anywhere in the Philippines, as evidence
from India and Mexico (Schreiner, 2006 and 2005a) suggests that there are only small
Figure 2 shows the official poverty lines by urban/rural for each province. It also
shows the “half lines” that demarcate the very poor, that is, the poorest half of the poor.
The second-to-last section of the paper looks at poverty by the $4/day-or-less standard.
3. Scorecard construction
• Household and housing characteristics (such as cooking fuel and type of floor)
Each indicator’s ability to predict poverty was tested first with the entropy-
rather than continuous ones (such as “square meters of floor space”). About 120
indicators were then selected for further analysis. Figure 3 lists the top 50, ranked by
2
Many indicators in Figure 3 are similar in terms of their link with poverty. For
example, most households who have a television also have electricity. If a scorecard
already includes “has a television”, then “has electricity” is superfluous. Thus, many
indicators strongly linked with poverty are not in the scorecard because similar
The scorecard also aims to measure changes in poverty through time. Thus, some
powerful indicators (such as education of the female head/spouse) that are unlikely to
(such as the number of radios) that are more likely to change. All the indicators of
consumption (such as “In the past six months, how much on average per week did the
household spend on dairy products and eggs”) were not selected because they cannot be
The scorecard itself was constructed using Logit regression. Indicator selection
combined statistics with the judgment of an analyst with expertise in scoring and
development. Starting with a scorecard with no indicators, each candidate indicator was
improvement in accuracy for each indicator was recorded using the “c” statistic.1
1
Higher “c” indicates greater ability to rank households by poverty status. For a Logit
regression with a categorical outcome (such as poor/not poor), “c” is a general measure
of explanatory power, much like R2 in a least-squares regression on a continuous
outcome. “c” is equal to the Mann-Whitney statistic (also known as the Wilcoxon rank-
sum statistic) that indicates how much two distributions overlap (here, the distributions
are of the estimated poverty likelihoods for poor and non-poor households). “c” is also
equivalent to the area under an ROC curve—discussed in more detail later—that plots
3
After all indicators had been tested, one was selected based on several factors
(Schreiner et al., 2004; Zeller, 2004). These included the improvement in accuracy, the
validity” in terms of experience, theory, and common sense), the ability of the indicator
to change values as poverty status changes over time, variety vis-à-vis other indicators
The selected indicator was then added to the scorecard, and the previous steps
were repeated until 10 indicators were selected. Finally, the Logit coefficients were
transformed into non-negative integers such that the lowest possible score is 0 (most
likely poor) and the highest is 100. The final poverty scorecard appears in Figure 4.
This statistical algorithm is the Logit analogue to the stepwise “MAXR” in, for
example, Zeller, Alcaraz and Johannsen (2005) and IRIS (2005a and 2005b). The
procedure here diverges from naïve stepwise in that expert judgment and non-statistical
criteria were used to select from among the most-predictive indicators. This improves
robustness and, more importantly, helps ensure that the indicators are simple and
the share of poor and non-poor households versus all households ranked by score.
Finally, “c” can also be seen as the share of all possible pairs of poor and non-poor
households in which the poor household has a lower score. The more often the poor
household has the lower score, the better the ranking by poverty status.
4
4. Scorecard use
appropriately. When scoring projects fail, the culprit is usually not inaccuracy but
rather the failure of users to accept scoring and to use it properly (Schreiner, 2002). The
challenge is not technical but human and organizational, not statistics but change
The scorecard here was designed to help users to understand and trust it (and
thus use it properly). While accuracy matters, it must be balanced against simplicity,
ease-of-use, and “face validity”. In particular, programs are more likely to collect data,
compute scores, and pay attention to the results if, in their view, scoring avoids creating
“extra” work and if the whole process generally seems to make sense.
allows field workers to score households by hand in real time because it features:
• Only 10 indicators
determining (in a day) who in a village qualifies for, say, work-for-food, or ration cards.
5
The scorecard in Figure 4 can be photocopied for immediate use. It can also
serve as a template for data-entry screens with database software that records
A score is not a poverty likelihood (that is, the probability of being poor), but
each score is associated with an estimated poverty likelihood via a simple table (Figure
5). For example, scores of 25–29 correspond to a poverty likelihood of 76.8 percent.
6
Scores (sums of weights) are associated with estimated poverty likelihoods
(probabilities of being poor) via the “bootstrap” (Efron and Tibshirani, 1993):
• From the first one-fourth hold-out sample, draw a new sample of the same size with
replacement
• For people in a given score range, compute the share who are poor
• For a given score range, define the poverty likelihood as the average of the shares of
people who are poor in that score range across the 10,000 samples
These resulting poverty likelihoods are objective, that is, based on data. This
process would produce objective poverty likelihoods even if the scorecards themselves
were constructed without data. In fact, scorecards of objective, proven accuracy are
often constructed only with qualitative judgment (Fuller, 2006; Caire, 2004; Schreiner et
al., 2004). Of course, the scorecard here uses data. While its construction—like any
acknowledgment of this fact is irrelevant for the objectivity of the poverty likelihoods.
After all, objectively depends on using data to associate scores with poverty likelihoods,
with 90-, 95-, and 99-percent confidence intervals. This is the standard way to measure
accuracy, and it is widely understood by lay people. The confidence intervals here were
derived empirically from the 10,000 bootstrap samples described above. For a given
7
score, the lower (upper) bound on the x-percent confidence interval is the value less
For example, the average poverty rate across bootstrap samples for people with
scores of 25–29 is 76.8 percent (this is the poverty likelihood in Figure 5). In 90 percent
of samples, the poverty rate is between 73.1–80.4 percent (Figure 6). In 95 percent of
For estimated and true poverty likelihoods, Figure 7 depicts mean absolute
differences and confidence intervals from bootstrapping the second one-fourth hold-out
sample from the 2002 APIS. The mean absolute difference is 3.6 percentage points.
This discussion so far looks at whether estimated poverty likelihoods are close to
true poverty likelihoods (and indeed they are). There is another aspect of accuracy, one
associated with targeting: how well the poor are concentrated in low scores. A perfect
scorecard would assign all the lowest scores to poor people (and all the highest scores to
non-poor people). In reality, no scorecard is perfect, so some poor people have high
ROC curves are standard tools for showing how well the poor are concentrated
in lower scores (Baulch, 2003; Wodon, 1997). They plot the share of poor and non-poor
What does the ROC curve in Figure 8 mean? Suppose a program sets a cut-off
so as to target the lowest-scoring x percent of people. The ROC curve then shows the
share of the poor (northwest curve) and non-poor (southwest curve) targeted. Greater
8
ability to rank-order—with less leakage and less undercoverage—is shown by curves
that are closer to the northwest and southeast corners of the graph.
In Figure 8, the northwest (southeast) curve depicts accuracy among the poor
hypothetical perfect scorecard that assigns all of the lowest scores to poor people. The
The curves for the scorecard show, for example, that targeting the 20 percent of
households with the lowest scores would target 51 percent of all the poor and 6 percent
of all the non-poor. In contrast, randomly targeting 20 percent of cases would target 20
Figure 8 also reports two other common measures of rank-ordering. The first is
the Kolmogorov-Smirnov (KS) statistic, defined as the maximum distance between the
poor and non-poor curves (here 59.2). Higher KS implies better rank-ordering.
The second measure is the ratio of the area inside the ROC curves to the area
inside the trapezoid of a hypothetical perfect scorecard (here 75.5). Again, greater area
inaccuracy are probably small relative to errors due to other sources (such as mistakes
in data collection or fraud) and relative to the accuracy of other feasible targeting tools.
All in all, Figures 6–8 suggest that the estimated likelihoods of being poor are estimated
9
4.2 Estimates of overall poverty rates
The estimated overall poverty rate is the average of the estimated poverty
likelihoods of individuals.
For example, suppose a program has 3,000 participants on Jan. 1, 2006 and that
1,000 have scores of 20, 1,000 have scores of 30, and 1,000 have scores of 40. The
poverty likelihoods that correspond to these scores are 77.6, 77.7 and 48.3 percent
(Figure 5). The overall poverty rate is the participants’ average poverty likelihood, that
To test accuracy and precision, the scorecard was applied to 10,000 bootstrap
replicates from the second one-fourth hold-out sample, comparing the estimated overall
poverty rates with the true values. The mean difference was 0.1 percentage points, with
a standard deviation of 0.37. The 90-percent confidence interval around the mean was
+/–0.6 percentage points, the 95-percent interval was +/–0.7 percentage points, and
the 99-percent interval was +/–1.0 percentage points. The estimated overall poverty
For a given group, progress out of poverty over time is estimated as the change
Continuing the previous example, suppose that on Jan. 1, 2007, the same 3,000
people (some of whom may no longer be participants) are now in groups of 500 with
10
scores of 20, 25, 30, 35, 40, and 45 (by Figure 5, poverty likelihoods of 77.6, 76.8, 77.7,
48.6, 48.3, and 33.6 percent). Their average poverty likelihood is now 60.4 percent, an
improvement of 67.9 – 60.4 = 7.5 percentage points. In other words, 7.5 of every 100 in
this group left poverty. Among those who were poor to start with, one in nine (7.5 ÷
Of course, the scorecard does not indicate what caused progress; it just measures
How would the poverty scorecard be used for targeting? Potential participants
with scores at or below a targeting cut-off are labeled targeted and treated—for
program purposes—as if they were poor. Those with higher scores are non-targeted and
Poverty status (expenditure below a poverty line) is distinct from targeting status
requires a cut-off and an inexpensive estimate of poverty likelihood. Indeed, the purpose
of scoring is to infer poverty status without incurring the cost of direct measurement.
No scorecard is perfect, so some of the truly poor will not be targeted, and some
of the truly non-poor will be targeted. Targeting is accurate to the extent that poverty
status matches targeting status. In turn, this depends on the selection of a targeting
11
cut-offs and how it balances accuracy for the poor versus non-poor. The standard
approach uses a classification matrix and a net-benefit matrix (SPSS, 2003; Adams and
Hand, 2000; Salford Systems, 2000; Hoadley and Oliver, 1998; Greene, 1993).
9). Accuracy improves as there are more cases in A and D and fewer in B and C.
second one-fourth hold-out sample. For example, with a cut-off of 25–29, there are:
12
Targeting accuracy (and errors of undercoverage and leakage) depends on the
cut-off. For example, if the cut-off were increased to 39–34, more poor (but less non-
Each of the four classification results is associated with a net benefit (Figure 11):
β. Cost (negative net benefit) per truly poor person mistakenly non-targeted
γ. Cost (negative net benefit) per truly non-poor person mistakenly targeted
Each net benefit α, β, γ, and δ corresponds to one of the quadrants in the general
classification matrix in Figure 9. For example, α is the net benefit associated with each
truly poor person who is correctly targeted (quadrant A), and β is the cost (negative net
benefit) associated with each truly poor person incorrectly targeted (quadrant B).
13
Given a net-benefit matrix and a classification matrix, total net benefit is the
sum of the net benefit per person in each quadrant multiplied by the number of people
• Compute total net benefits for each cut-off with the net-benefit matrix and Figure 10
The only non-trivial step is selecting a net-benefit matrix. Some common net-
benefit matrices are discussed below. In general, however, each program should
thoughtfully decide for itself how much it values successful targeting versus errors of
undercoverage and leakage. Of course, any program that targets already uses (if only
the poor, even at the cost of accidentally targeting more non-poor. It could reflect this
valuation by increasing the weight on quadrant A (by increasing its net benefit α),
and/or by decreasing the weight on quadrant B (by decreasing its net benefit β). The
14
5.2.1 “Total Accuracy”
corresponds to the “Total Accuracy” criterion (Figure 12, IRIS, 2005b). Then total net
= A + D.
This values correct classifications of the poor and non-poor equally. Grootaert
and Braithwaite (1998) and Zeller, Alcaraz, y Johannsen (2005) use “Total Accuracy”
Figure 13 shows “Total Accuracy” for all cut-offs. Total net benefit is greatest
(81.1) for a cut-off of 30–34; at that point, poverty segment matches poverty status for
“Total Accuracy” weighs the poor and non-poor the same. If most people are
non-poor and/or if a scorecard is more accurate for the non-poor, then “Total Accuracy”
might look good even if few poor people are correctly classified. Development programs,
however, probably value correct targeting more for the poor than for the non-poor.
A simple, transparent way to reflect this valuation is to increase the relative net
benefit α of correctly classifying the poor. For example, if a program values correctly
targeting the poor twice as much as correctly not targeting the non-poor, then α should
be set twice as high as δ in the net-benefit matrix. Then the new optimal cut-off is 50–
15
5.2.2 “Poverty Accuracy”
A criterion that values only correctly classifying the poor is “Poverty Accuracy”
= A.
Of course, correctly targeting the poor is rarely the sole criteria. In fact, Figure
13 shows that “Poverty Accuracy” is greatest with a cut-off of 95–100. While targeting
everyone does ensure that all poor people are targeted and so minimizes undercoverage
of the poor (second-to-last column of Figure 13), it also targets all the non-poor and so
net benefit is D). This is maximized by setting a cut-off of 0–4 and thus not targeting
5.2.4 “BPAC”
IRIS (2005b) proposes a new measure of accuracy called the “Balanced Poverty
• “Poverty Accuracy”
16
then BPAC’s net-benefit matrix is Figure 15. In essence, BPAC maximizes A while
= A + (B – C).
BPAC was invented because IRIS does not estimate poverty likelihoods. Instead,
IRIS estimates expenditure and then labels as poor those households with estimated
expenditure less than the poverty line. In this set-up, the overall poverty rate is
estimated as the share of people targeted, and this estimate is most accurate (that is,
For a scorecard (like the one here) that estimates poverty likelihoods, however,
BPAC is not meaningful. This is because the estimated overall poverty rate is the
of whatever targeting cut-off a program might set. In contrast, the targeting errors of
undercoverage B and leakage C depend directly on the cut-off. Thus, for scorecards that
accuracy of the estimated overall poverty rate and so is not related to BPAC’s goals.
17
6. Training, quality-control, and MIS
The technical aspects of scorecard construction and accuracy just discussed are
important, but gaining the trust and acceptance of managers and field workers is even
In particular, the field workers who collect indicators must be trained. If they put
garbage in, the scorecard will put garbage out. To prevent abuse, on-going quality
Programs should record in their MIS at least the poverty likelihood along with
an identifier for each client. Ideally, they would also record the score, the indicators,
and the values of the indicators. This will allow quick computation of average poverty
likelihoods (as well as other analyses), both for a point in time and for changes through
The simple poverty scorecard in Figure 4 can be used to track outreach not only
to the poor but also to the very poor, that is, the poorest half of the poor below the
national poverty line. This is the relevant group for USAID certification.
18
7.1 Poverty likelihoods
As before, scores are associated with the probability of being very poor by
bootstrapping 10,000 samples from first one-fourth hold-out sample from the 2002
APIS. The poverty likelihood for a given score is then taken as the average of the
shares of people with that score who are very poor across the 10,000 samples.
Columns 2–4 in Figure 16 are the poverty likelihoods for the three classes for all
scores. For example, if a potential participant has a score of 25–29, the probability of
being very poor is 42.2 percent, the probability of being poor is 34.4 percent, and the
status and by cut-off. For example, for a cut-off of 25–92, 58.3 percent of those targeted
would be very poor, 26.4 percent would be poor, and 15.2 percent would be non-poor.
Each person is associated with three poverty likelihoods. For example, a person
with a score of 25 may be targeted as very poor, but the likelihood of truly being very
poor is not 100 percent but rather 42.4 percent (from Figure 16). The same person has a
34.4-percent likelihood of being truly poor, and a 23.2-percent likelihood of being truly
non-poor. Each person has one targeting status (for program purposes), one true
poverty status (in reality), and three estimated poverty likelihoods (one for each
As before, these poverty likelihoods are objective, that is, based on data. They
are valid even though the scorecard was not constructed originally to predict the
19
likelihood of being very poor. It works because the likelihood of being very poor is
highly correlated with having a low score (high likelihood of being poor). A scorecard
could be built specifically for the very poor, but it would add cost and complexity.
Figure 17 shows the precision of estimated poverty likelihoods for being very
poor as point estimates with 90-, 95-, and 99-percent confidence intervals. For example,
the average poverty rate (the poverty likelihood) across bootstrap samples for people
with scores of 25–29 was 42.4 percent. In 90 percent of 10,000 bootstraps from the
second one-fourth hold-out sample, the share was between 38.2–46.7 percent. In 95
percent of samples, the share was between 37.3–47.7, and in 99 percent of samples, the
For estimated and true poverty likelihoods, Figure 18 depicts mean absolute
differences and confidence intervals from 10,000 bootstraps on the second one-fourth
hold-out sample. Weighting by the people in a score range, the mean absolute difference
The other aspect of accuracy is how well the very poor are concentrated in low
Figure 19 plots the share of the very poor against the share of the not very poor,
ranked by score. For example, targeting the 30 percent of cases with the lowest scores
would target 77 percent of all the very poor and 21 percent of all the not very poor.
20
In terms of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic, the maximum distance between
the curves is 56.0. In terms of the ratio of the area inside the scorecard curves to the
area inside the trapezoid of a hypothetical perfect scorecard, the value is 73.4.
All in all, Figures 17–19 suggest that the likelihoods of being very poor are
overall (very poor) poverty rate. To measure the accuracy and precision of this
estimate, the scorecard was applied to 10,000 bootstrap replicates from the second one-
fourth hold-out samples from the 2002 APIS, and then the estimated overall poverty
rates were compared with the true values. The mean difference was 0.8 percentage
points, with a standard deviation of 0.32. The 90-percent confidence interval around the
mean was +/–0.5 percentage points, the 95-percent interval was +/–0.6 percentage
would produce an unbiased estimate that, in 99 of 100 cases, would be within +/–0.8
percentage points of the true overall (very poor) poverty rate. This estimate is both
21
7.3 Targeting the very poor
matrix to select a cut-off. The wrinkle is that there are now three poverty statuses:
• Very poor: Poorest half of those with expenditure at or below the poverty line
22
There are two cut-offs (very poor/poor and poor/non-poor) and 9 classification
The general classification matrix (Figure 20) and the net-benefit matrix (Figure
Total net benefit = α·A + β·B + γ·C + δ·D + ε·E + ζ·F + η·G + θ·H + ι·I.
Figure 22 shows classification results for all possible pairs of cut-off scores in the
• Very poor/poor cut-off of 20–24 (so scores of 0–24 are targeted as very poor)
• Poor/non-poor cut-off of 30–34 (so scores of 25–34 are targeted as poor, and scores
23
As with any scorecard and cut-offs, there is both successful targeting and errors.
For the example cut-offs of 20–24 and 30–34, targeting would be correct for 65 percent
of the very poor, 39 percent of the poor, and 81 percent of the non-poor (Figure 23).
example, suppose the net-benefit matrix is Figure 24, representing one way to reflect:
• Greater cost of gross errors such as targeting the truly very poor as non-poor
Given the classification results in Figure 23 and net benefits in Figure 24, total
net benefit for the cut-off pair of 20–24 and 30–34 is +404 (Figure 25).
Is this the best pair of cut-offs? The answer requires applying the net-benefit
matrix to the classification results for all 190 possible pairs (Figure 22). It turns out
that total net benefit is highest for cut-offs 30–34 and 50–54, giving a net benefit of 764.
The simple poverty scorecard in Figure 4 can be used to track outreach not only
to the poor (the upper half of those under the national poverty line) and the very poor
(the lower half of those under the national poverty line) but also the $4PPP/day poor,
that is, those with incomes above the national poverty line but below the
24
describes the derivation of a $4PPP poverty line that accounts for differences in cost-of-
living across Filipino provinces and across rural and urban areas.
Scores are associated with the probability of being very poor by bootstrapping
1,000 samples from the first one-fourth hold-out sample from the 2002 APIS. The
poverty likelihood for a given score is then taken as the average of the shares of people
with that score who are $4/day-or-less poor across the 1,000 bootstrapped samples.
Columns 2–5 in Figure 26 are the poverty likelihoods for the four classes for all
scores. For example, if a potential participant has a score of 25–29, the probability of
being very poor is 42.2 percent, the probability of being poor is 34.4 percent, the
probability of being $4/day poor is 14.4 percent, and the probability of being non-poor
is 8.8 percent. The sum of the four poverty likelihoods is, of course, 100 percent.
status and by cut-off. For example, for a cut-off of 25–29, 58.3 percent of those targeted
would be very poor, 26.4 percent would be poor, 9.5 percent would be $4/day poor, and
Each person’s score is associated with four poverty likelihoods. For example, a
person with a score of 25 may be targeted as very poor, but the likelihood of truly being
very poor in this case is not 100 percent but rather 42.4 percent (from Figure 26). The
same person has a 34.4-percent likelihood of being truly poor, a 14.4-percent likelihood
of being $4/day poor, and an 8.8-percent likelihood of being truly non-poor. Each
25
person has one targeting status (for program purposes), one true poverty status (in
reality), and four estimated poverty likelihoods (one for each possible poverty status).
Figure 27 shows the precision of estimated poverty likelihoods for being $4/day-
or-less poor as point estimates with 90-, 95-, and 99-percent confidence intervals. For
example, the average $4/day-or-less poverty rate (the poverty likelihood) across
bootstrap samples for people with scores of 25–29 was 91.2 percent. In 90 percent of
1,000 bootstraps from the second one-fourth hold-out sample, the share was between
88.7–93.6 percent. In 95 percent of samples, the share was between 88.1–94.0, and in 99
For estimated and true poverty likelihoods, Figure 28 depicts mean absolute
differences and confidence intervals from 1,000 bootstraps on the second one-fourth
hold-out sample. Weighting by the people in a score range, the mean absolute difference
The other aspect of accuracy is how well the $4/day-or-less poor are
concentrated in low scores. Once again, an ROC curve is a useful way to look at this.
Figure 29 plots the share of the $4/day-or-less poor against the share of the non-
poor, ranked by score. For example, targeting the 20 percent of cases with the lowest
scores would target 44 percent of all the $4/day-or-less poor and 4 percent of all the
non-poor.
26
In terms of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic, the maximum distance between
the curves is 58.0. In terms of the ratio of the area inside the scorecard curves to the
area inside the trapezoid of a hypothetical perfect scorecard, the value is 74.3.
overall ($4/day-or-less) poverty rate. To measure the accuracy and precision of this
estimate, the scorecard was applied to 1,000 bootstrap replicates from the second one-
fourth hold-out samples from the 2002 APIS, and then the estimated overall poverty
rates were compared with the true values. The mean difference was 0.6 percentage
points, with a standard deviation of 0.39. The 90-percent confidence interval around the
mean was +/–0.6 percentage points, the 95-percent interval was +/–0.7 percentage
would produce an unbiased estimate that, in 99 of 100 cases, would be within +/–1.0
percentage points of the true overall ($4/day-or-less) poverty rate. This estimate is both
27
9. Conclusion
One in three Filipinos is poor. An easy-to-use, inexpensive tool for identifying the
poor could improve targeting and speed progress out of poverty. This paper presents a
The scorecard is built and tested using data on 38,014 households from the 2002
APIS. The scorecard is calibrated to estimate the likelihood of being poor (income
below the official line), very poor (poorest half of the poor), $4/day poor (income above
the official line but below the $4/day international benchmark), or non-poor.
Out-of-sample bootstrap tests show that the estimates are both accurate and
precise. For individual poverty likelihoods (whether poor or very poor), estimates are
within 6 percentage points of the true value with 90-percent confidence. For a group’s
overall poverty rate (again, whether poor or very poor), estimates are within 1
For targeting, programs can use the classification results reported here to select
accurate scorecard is worthless if programs feel daunted by its complexity and so never
even try to use it. For this reason, the scorecard here is kept simple, using 10 indicators
that are inexpensive to collect and that are straightforward to observe and verify.
Indicator weights are either zeros or positive integers, and scores range from 0 (most
likely poor) to 100 (least likely poor). Scores are related to poverty likelihoods via a
28
simple look-up table, and targeting cut-offs are also simple to apply. Thus, users can
not only understand the scorecard, but they can also use it to compute scores in the
Overall, the poverty scorecard can help development programs to target services
to the poor, track participants’ progress out of poverty through time, and report on
29
Appendix:
Adjusting the $4PPP Poverty Line for Cost-of-Living Differences
The population-weighted average of rural and urban $4PPP lines should match the all-
Philippines $4PPP line:
Furthermore, the ratio of the two lines should match the ratio of the official lines:
To account for cost-of-living across provinces, the official lines for 2002 are then
adjusted by their ratio with the rural or urban $4PPP line. For both rural and urban
areas, the adjustment factor is 1.337. That is, the $4PPP poverty line is 33.7 percent
higher than the national poverty line.
$2/day is about equal to the “very poor” line that defines the poorest half below the
national poverty line, and $3/day is almost exactly the same as the national line.
30
References
Adams, N.M.; and D.J. Hand. (2000) “Improving the Practice of Classifier Performance
Assessment”, Neural Computation, Vol. 12, pp. 305–311.
Baulch, Bob. (2003) “Poverty Monitoring and Targeting Using ROC Curves: Examples
from Vietnam”, IDS Working Paper No. 161,
http://www.ids.ac.uk/ids/bookshop/wp/wp161.pdf.
Caire, Dean. (2004) “Building Credit Scorecards for Small Business Lending in
Developing Markets”, Bannock Consulting,
http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/Scoring_SMEs_Hybrid.pdf.
Efron, Bradley; and Robert J. Tibshirani. (1993) An Introduction to the Bootstrap, New
York: Chapman and Hall, ISBN 0–412–04231–2.
Goodman, L.A. and Kruskal, W.H. (1979) Measures of Association for Cross
Classification, New York, NY: Springer-Verlag, ISBN 0–38–790443–3.
Greene, William H. (1993) Econometric Analysis: Second Edition, New York, NY:
MacMillan, ISBN 0–02–346391–0.
Hoadley, Bruce; and Robert M. Oliver. (1998) “Business measures of scorecard benefit”,
IMA Journal of Mathematics Applied in Business and Industry, Vol. 9, pp. 55–
64.
IRIS Center. (2005a) “Accuracy Results for 12 Poverty Assessment Tool Countries”,
http://www.povertytools.org/documents/Accuracy%20Results%20for%2012%
20Countries.pdf.
31
IRIS Center. (2005b) “Notes on Assessment and Improvement of Tool Accuracy”,
http://www.povertytools.org/documents/Assessing%20and%20Improving%20
Accuracy.pdf.
Matul, Michal; and Sean Kline. (2003) “Scoring Change: Prizma’s Approach to
Assessing Poverty”, MFC Spotlight Note No. 4, Warsaw, Poland: Microfinance
Centre for Central and Eastern Europe and the New Independent States,
http://www.mfc.org.pl/doc/Research/ImpAct/SN/MFC_SN04_eng.pdf.
Salford Systems. (2000) CART for Windows User’s Guide, San Diego, CA.
Schreiner, Mark. (2006) “Is One Simple Poverty Scorecard Enough for India?”, memo
for Grameen Foundation U.S.A.,
http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/Scoring_Poverty_India_Seg
ments.pdf.
Schreiner, Mark (2005a) “Un Indice de Pobreza para México”, memo for Grameen
Foundation U.S.A.,
http://www.microfinance.com/Castellano/Documentos/Scoring_Pobreza_Me
xico.pdf.
Schreiner, Mark. (2005b) “IRIS questions on poverty scorecards”, memo for Grameen
Foundation U.S.A.,
http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/Scoring_Poverty_Response_
to_IRIS.pdf.
Schreiner, Mark; Matul, Michal; Pawlak, Ewa; and Sean Kline. (2004) “Poverty
Scorecards: Lessons from a Microlender in Bosnia-Herzegovina”, Microfinance
Risk Management,
http://www.microfinance.com/English/Papers/Scoring_Poverty_in_BiH_Sh
ort.pdf.
SPSS, Inc. (2003) Clementine 8.0 User’s Guide, Chicago, IL, ISBN 1–56827–333–9.
Wodon, Quentin T. (1997) “Targeting the Poor Using ROC Curves”, World
Development, Vol. 25, No. 12, pp. 2083–2092.
32
Zeller, Manfred. (2004) “Review of Poverty Assessment Tools”, Accelerated
Microenterprise Advancement Project,
http://www.povertytools.org/documents/Review%20of%20Poverty%20Assess
ment%20Tools.pdf.
Zeller, Manfred; Alcaraz V., Gabriela; and Julia Johannsen. (2005) “Developing and
Testing Poverty-Assessment Tools: Results from Accuracy Tests in Peru”,
Accelerated Microenterprise Advancement Project,
http://www.povertytools.org/documents/Peru%20Accuracy%20Report.pdf.
33
Figure 1: Households surveyed, people represented,
and overall poverty rates
Sub-sample Households People % poor
Constructing scorecards 18,846 39,459,467 32.0
Associating scores with likelihoods 9,665 20,407,790 31.4
Testing accuracy 9,503 19,760,021 31.9
Source: 2002 APIS. 38,014 79,627,278 31.8
34
Figure 2: Official poverty lines and “half” poverty lines, pesos/person/year
Official line "Half" line Official line "Half" line Official line "Half" line Official line "Half" line
Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Province Urban Rural Urban Rural Province Urban Rural Urban Rural
NCR Region IV Region VIII Region XII
1st District 16,496 N/A 13,353 N/A Batangas 15,993 15,002 11,410 11,230 Eastern Samar 10,617 9,690 6,658 6,461 Lanao del Norte 12,393 11,630 8,014 6,336
2nd District 16,007 N/A 12,875 N/A Cavite 14,851 16,240 11,992 12,480 Leyte 10,639 10,460 7,978 6,473 North Cotabato 11,172 9,761 7,680 6,185
3rd District 15,256 N/A 12,739 N/A Laguna 14,147 12,312 11,480 9,941 Northern Samar 9,726 9,503 6,751 6,045 Sultan Kudarat 11,940 10,565 7,444 6,893
4th District 16,654 N/A 13,828 N/A Marinduque 12,301 11,639 8,726 8,001 Western Samar 10,868 10,523 8,320 6,799
Occidental Mindoro 12,271 12,327 8,409 7,420 Southern Leyte 11,033 9,921 8,515 6,795
Oriental Mindoro 15,095 13,938 10,368 8,859 Biliran 10,218 10,644 6,816 7,375
Palawan 13,541 10,729 9,017 7,520
Quezon 13,430 12,605 9,478 8,318
Rizal 14,264 13,561 10,870 10,192
Romblon 12,770 11,234 7,267 7,006
Aurora 12,121 11,469 7,304 7,379
35
Figure 3: Poverty indicators ranked by uncertainty coefficient
Uncertainty
coefficient Indicator (Value for those most likely “poor”; Value for those least likely “poor”)
1. 247 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per month on fuel, light, and water (charcoal,
firewood, LPG, kerosene/gas, electricity, candles, oils, water, etc.) (<P83/person; ≥P83/person)
2. 214 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per week on meat and meat preparations (fresh
chicken, beef, pork, carabeef, goat’s meat, corned beef, luncheon meat, meatloaf, Vienna sausage, longaniza, chorizo, hot
dogs, tocino, tapa, etc.) (<P19/person; ≥P19/person)
3. 214 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per month on personal care and effects (cleansing
cream, body deodorant, lotion, baby oil, toilet/bath soap, tissue paper, toothpaste, sanitary napkins, shampoo, jewelry,
handbags, wallets, wristwatches, haircuts, manicure or pedicure, etc.) (<P30/person; ≥P30/person)
4. 195 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per month on transportation and communication
(bus, jeepney, tricycle, air or water transport fare, gasoline/diesel, driver’s salary, telephone bills, postage stamps,
telegrams, driving lessons, feeds for animals used for transport, etc.) (<P38/person; ≥P38/person)
5. 190 Does the family own a gas stove or gas range? (No; Yes)
6. 183 Does the family own a refrigerator? (No; Yes)
7. 181 How many television sets does the family own? (0; 1; 2 or more)
8. 162 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per week on non-alcoholic beverages (soft drinks,
pineapple juice, orange juice, ice candy, ice drop, ice buko, etc.) (<P3/person; ≥P3/person)
9. 152 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per week on dairy products and eggs (milk, ice cream,
butter, cheese, fresh eggs, balut, salted eggs) (<P6/person; ≥P6/person)
10. 145 How many telephones and/or cell phones does the family own? (0; 1; 2 or more)
11. 140 During the past six months, how much on average did the household spend per week on food regularly consumed outside the
home (meals at school, place of work, restaurants, merienda or snacks, etc.) (<P11/person; ≥P11/person)
12. 136 Does the family own a sala set? (No; Yes)
13. 127 Does the family own a washing machine? (No; Yes)
14. 126 Is there any electricity in the building/house? (No; Yes)
15. 123 Does the family own a dining set? (No; Yes)
16. 121 During the past six months, how much did the household spend on clothing, footwear, and other wear (clothing and ready-made
apparel, footwear, sewing materials, accessories, service fees, etc.) (<P200/person; ≥P200/person)
17. 113 What is the highest grade completed by a household member? (Graduated secondary or less; 1 or more years of post-secondary)
18. 105 What is the primary occupation of the male head/spouse? (Farmers and laborers; Clerks, trades, special occupations, and
occupations not elsewhere classified; Clerks, and plant and machine operators; Technicians, and officials of government
and special-interest organizations; Professionals)
36
Figure 3 (cont.): Poverty indicators ranked by uncertainty coefficient
Uncertainty
coefficient Indicator (Value for those most likely “poor”; Value for those least likely “poor”)
19. 104 What is the house’s main source of water supply? (Spring, river, stream, dug well, or rain; Peddler or others; Own-use or shared-
use from a tubed/piped well or a community water system)
20. 102 Does the family have health insurance from Philhealth, a Health Maintenance Organization, a private health-insurance company,
or a community or cooperative? (No; Yes)
21. 98 Does the family have health insurance with Philhealth? (No; Yes)
22. 95 On a ladder with 10 steps going from lowest/poorest to highest/richest, on which step would you be? (1; 2; 3; 4; 5; 6 or more)
23. 94 How many people in the family are aged 0 to 17? (5 or more; 4; 2 or 3; 0 or 1)
24. 89 What are the house’s outer walls made of? (Salvaged or makeshift materials or all light or predominantly light materials such as
cogon, nipa, or sawali, bamboo, or anahaw; All strong or predominantly strong materials such as iron, aluminum, tile,
concrete, brick, stone, wood, or asbestos)
25. 86 What kind of toilet facility does the family have in the house? (None, open pit, or others; Closed pit; Water sealed)
26. 80 How many radios does the family own? (0; 1; 2 or more)
27. 78 What type of construction materials is the house’s roof made of? (Salvaged or makeshift materials or all light or predominantly
light materials such as cogon, nipa, or anahaw; All strong or predominantly strong materials such as galvanized iron,
aluminum tile, concrete, brick, stone, or asbestos)
28. 77 What is the highest grade completed by the male head/spouse? (Grades I to V of elementary; Did not complete any grade; Grade
VI of elementary to graduate of secondary; 1 or more years of post-secondary)
29. 77 How many people are there in the family from ages 0 to 17? (3 or more; 2; 1; 0)
30. 77 What is the highest grade completed by the female head/spouse? (I to V of elementary; None; VI of elementary to graduate of
secondary; 1 or more years of post-secondary)
31. 69 What is the primary occupation of the female head/spouse? (Farmers and laborers; Clerks, trades, special occupations, and
occupations not elsewhere classified; Clerks, and plant and machine operators; Technicians, and officials of government
and special-interest organizations; Professionals)
32. 61 Does the family live in an urban area? (No; Yes)
33. 58 How many children are there aged 17 or younger per adult aged 18 or older? (1 or more; <1)
34. 58 Does the family engage in crop farming or gardening? (Yes; No)
35. 53 Does the family own a vehicle? (No; Yes)
36. 48 What is the floor area of house in square meters? (50 or less; ≥50)
37. 47 Does the household have some type of health insurance? (No; Yes)
38. 41 During the past six months, did the household regularly consume food outside the home (meals at school, place of work,
restaurants, merienda or snacks, etc.)? (No; Yes)
37
Figure 3 (cont.): Poverty indicators ranked by uncertainty coefficient
Uncertainty
coefficient Indicator (Value for those most likely “poor”; Value for those least likely “poor”)
39. 40 During the past six months, did the household buy non-alcoholic beverages (soft drinks, pineapple juice, orange juice, ice
candy, ice drop, ice buko, etc.)? (No; Yes)
40. 39 How many children are there aged 11 or younger per adult aged 18 or older? (0.5 or more; <0.5)
41. 38 During the past six months, did the household make any deposits in banks? (No; Yes)
42. 35 During the past six months, did anyone in the family receive cash, gifts, support, or relief from abroad (including pensions
retirement, workmen’s compensation, dividends from investments, etc.)? (No; Yes)
43. 31 Is the male head/spouse self-employed? (No; Yes)
44. 22 During the past six months, did the household buy dairy products and eggs (milk, ice cream, butter, cheese, fresh eggs, balut,
salted eggs)? (No; Yes)
45. 22 Do all children in the family of ages 6 to 11 go to school? (No; Yes)
46. 22 Do any family members assist in the family business? (No; Yes)
47. 21 During the past six months, did anyone in the family make a deposit in a bank, receive interest on savings, or make a
withdrawal from a savings account? (No; Yes)
48. 21 Do any family members have salaried employment? (No; Yes)
49. 18 In the next 12 months, do you expect your household’s economic conditions to worsen, stay the same, or improve? (Worsen;
Stay the Same; Improve)
50. 17 Does the family have any income from entrepreneurial activities? (Yes; No)
51. 16 Is your household’s situation at present compared with the last 12 months worse, about the same, or better? (Worse, About the
same, Better)
52. 16 Are any household members involved with self-employment? (No; Yes)
Source: Based on 2002 APIS.
38
Figure 4: A simple poverty scorecard for the Philippines
Indicator Values Points
1. How many people in the family are aged 0 to 5 or more 3 or 4 1 or 2 Zero
17? 0 7 16 27
2. Does the family own a gas stove or gas range? No Yes
0 13
3. How many television sets does the family own? Zero 1 2 or more
0 9 18
4. What are the house's outer walls made of? Light (cogon , nipa , or sawali , bamboo, Strong (iron, aluminum,
anahaw ) tile, concrete, brick, stone,
wood, asbestos)
0 4
5. How many radios does the family own? Zero 1 2 or more
0 3 10
6. Does the family own a sala set? No Yes
0 9
7. What is the house's roof made of? Light (Salvaged, makeshift, cogon , nipa , or Strong (Galvanized iron,
anahaw ) aluminum tile, concrete,
brick, stone, or asbestos)
0 2
8. What kind of toilet facility does the family have? None, open pit, closed pit, or other Water sealed
0 3
9. Do all children in the family of ages 6 to 11 No Yes No children ages 6-11
go to school? 0 4 6
10. Do any family members have salaried employment? No Yes
0 6
Source: Calculations based on the 2002 APIS. Total:
39
Figure 5: Scores and poverty likelihoods
Poverty likelihood % of people % of people
for people with <=score >score
Score score in range (%) who are poor who are non-poor
0-4 99.3 99.3 68.4
5-9 92.5 94.6 69.4
10-14 91.9 93.2 70.9
15-19 93.4 93.3 72.5
20-24 77.6 88.3 74.3
25-29 76.8 84.8 77.0
30-34 77.7 82.9 80.6
35-39 48.6 74.0 83.4
40-44 48.3 68.7 86.8
45-49 33.6 63.0 89.1
50-54 34.4 58.4 92.7
55-59 22.6 55.5 94.0
60-64 10.1 49.0 94.9
65-69 10.2 43.7 96.6
70-74 6.9 40.1 97.9
75-79 3.8 37.1 98.8
80-84 2.1 34.1 100.0
85-89 0.0 32.9 100.0
90-94 0.0 32.5 100.0
95-100 0.0 32.1 100.0
Surveyed cases weighted to represent the Filipino population.
Source: Based on the 2002 APIS.
40
Figure 6: Confidence intervals for estimated poverty likelihoods associated
100
95 Upper 99% bound
Poverty likelihood (mean, 90-, 95-, 99-percent two-sided
41
Figure 7: Differences between estimated and true poverty likelihoods
20
18 Upper 99% bound
Upper 95% bound
Difference between predicted and estimated
16
Upper 90% bound
14
Mean
12
Lower 90% bound
10
Lower 95% bound
8
poverty likelihood
42
Figure 8: ROC curve of ability to rank-order households by poverty status
1.00
Proportion of poor and non-poor with scores <=
0.95 "Poor"
0.90
0.85 Targeting the
a given score when ordered by score
43
Figure 9: General classification matrix
Targeting segment
Targeted Non-targeted
A. B.
True poverty status
44
Figure 10: People by targeting classification and score
A. B. C. D.
Truly poor Truly poor Truly non-poor Truly non-poor
correctly mistakenly mistakenly correctly
Score targeted non-targeted targeted non-targeted
0-4 0.7 31.4 0.0 67.9
5-9 2.1 30.0 0.1 67.8
10-14 4.3 27.8 0.3 67.6
15-19 6.4 25.6 0.5 67.5
20-24 9.0 23.1 1.2 66.7
25-29 12.4 19.7 2.2 65.7
30-34 16.6 15.5 3.4 64.5
35-39 20.0 12.1 7.0 60.9
40-44 23.4 8.7 10.6 57.3
45-49 25.6 6.5 15.0 52.9
50-54 28.3 3.8 20.2 47.8
55-59 29.2 2.8 23.4 44.5
60-64 30.1 2.0 31.3 36.7
65-69 31.1 1.0 40.1 27.8
70-74 31.6 0.4 47.2 20.7
75-79 31.9 0.2 54.0 14.0
80-84 32.1 0.0 62.0 5.9
85-89 32.1 0.0 65.5 2.5
90-94 32.1 0.0 66.6 1.3
95-100 32.1 0.0 67.9 0.0
Figures normalized to sum to 100.
Source: Based on the 2002 APIS.
45
Figure 11: General net-benefit matrix
Targeting segment
Targeted Non-targeted
True poverty status
Poor α β
Non-poor γ δ
46
Figure 12: “Total Accuracy” net-benefit matrix
Targeting segment
Targeted Non-targeted
True poverty status
Poor 1 0
Non-poor 0 1
47
Figure 13: Total net benefit for some common net-benefit matrices
Non-poverty
Total Accuracy Poverty Accuracy Accuracy Undercoverage Leakage
(A + B) 100*A / (A+B) 100*D / (C+D) 100*B / (A+B) 100*C / (A+C)
1 0 1 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0
Score 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 -1 0
0-4 68.6 2.2 100.0 97.8 0.8
5-9 69.9 6.6 99.8 93.4 5.4
10-14 71.9 13.4 99.5 86.6 6.8
15-19 73.9 20.1 99.3 79.9 6.7
20-24 75.7 27.9 98.3 72.1 11.7
25-29 78.1 38.6 96.7 61.4 15.2
30-34 81.1 51.7 95.0 48.3 17.1
35-39 80.9 62.3 89.7 37.7 26.0
40-44 80.7 72.8 84.3 27.2 31.3
45-49 78.5 79.7 77.9 20.3 37.0
50-54 76.0 88.2 70.3 11.8 41.6
55-59 73.7 91.1 65.5 8.9 44.5
60-64 66.8 93.9 54.0 6.1 51.0
65-69 58.9 97.0 41.0 3.0 56.3
70-74 52.3 98.6 30.5 1.4 59.9
75-79 45.9 99.5 20.5 0.5 62.9
80-84 38.0 100.0 8.7 0.0 65.9
85-89 34.5 100.0 3.6 0.0 67.1
90-94 33.4 100.0 1.9 0.0 67.5
95-100 32.1 100.0 0.0 0.0 67.9
All figures in percentage units.
48
Figure 14: “Poverty Accuracy” net-benefit matrix
Targeting segment
Targeted Non-targeted
True poverty status
Poor 1 0
Non-poor 0 0
49
Figure 15: Net-benefit matrix for BPAC
Targeting segment
Targeted Non-targeted
True poverty status
Poor 1 1
Non-poor -1 0
50
Figure 16: Poverty likelihoods for the very poor, poor, and non-poor
by score
Poverty likelihood in score range Share of cases <= score
Score Very Poor Poor Non-poor Very Poor Poor Non-poor
0-4 85.0 14.3 0.7 85.0 14.3 0.7
5-9 79.7 12.8 7.6 81.3 13.3 5.4
10-14 61.9 30.0 8.1 71.3 21.9 6.8
15-19 70.5 22.9 6.6 71.0 22.3 6.7
20-24 53.2 24.4 22.4 65.4 22.9 11.7
25-29 42.4 34.4 23.2 58.3 26.4 15.2
30-34 35.2 42.6 22.3 52.1 30.8 17.1
35-39 23.8 24.8 51.4 44.8 29.2 26.0
40-44 22.2 26.1 51.7 40.1 28.6 31.3
45-49 16.5 17.1 66.4 36.3 26.7 37.0
50-54 12.6 21.8 65.6 32.4 25.9 41.6
55-59 8.4 14.2 77.4 30.5 25.0 44.5
60-64 4.7 5.4 90.0 26.8 22.2 51.0
65-69 2.5 7.6 89.9 23.5 20.2 56.3
70-74 1.7 5.2 93.1 21.4 18.7 59.9
75-79 1.6 2.2 96.3 19.8 17.4 62.9
80-84 0.7 1.4 97.9 18.1 16.0 65.9
85-89 0.0 0.0 100.0 17.5 15.4 67.1
90-94 0.0 0.0 100.0 17.3 15.2 67.5
95-100 0.0 0.0 100.0 17.0 15.0 67.9
Total: 17.0 15.0 67.9
51
Figure 17: Confidence intervals for estimated poverty likelihoods for
being very poor associated with scores
100
Upper 99% bound
Difference between predicted and estimated
90
Upper 95% bound
Upper 90% bound
80
Mean
poverty likelihood (% pts.)
50
40
Average confidence intervals 90: 2.2
30 across scores, weighted by 95: 2.8
persons (+/- percentage points): 99: 3.6
20
10
0
0-4 5-9 10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85-89 90-94 95-
Range of score 100
52
Figure 18: Differences between estimated and true poverty likelihoods
for the very poor
20
Upper 99% bound
Upper 95% bound
Difference between predicted and estimated
-5
-20
0-4 5-9 10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85-89 90-94 95-
Range of score 100
53
Figure 19: ROC curve of ability to rank-order households by very poor
versus not very poor poverty status
1.00
"Very poor"
Proportion of poor and non-poor with scores <=
0.95
0.90
0.85
a given score when ordered by score
0.80
0.75 Targeting the lowest-scoring
0.70 30% of households targets
0.65 21% of the not very poor and
0.60 77% of the very poor
0.55
0.50
0.45
0.40
0.35 Area KS
0.30 Random 0.0 0.0
0.25 Scorecard 73.4 56.0
0.20 Perfect 100 100
0.15
0.10
0.05 "Non-poor"
0.00
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Percentage of all cases, ordered by score
54
Figure 20: Classification matrix, three segments
Targeting segment
Very Poor Poor Non-poor
A. B. C.
Truly very poor Truly very poor Truly very poor
Very Poor correctly incorrectly incorrectly
True poverty status
55
Figure 21: Net-benefit matrix, three segments
Targeting segment
Very Poor Poor Non-poor
α β γ
Very Poor
True poverty status
δ ε ζ
Poor
η θ ι
Non-poor
56
Figure 22: Classification results, very poor/poor cut-offs from 0 to 44 and
poor/non-poor cut-offs from 5 to 49
Upper bound, poor segment
5-9 10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44
Upper bound, very poor segment
12 24 301 12 53 272 12 85 239 12 119 205 12 157 168 12 194 130 12 227 98 12 258 67
0-4 2 4 291 2 18 277 2 28 267 2 44 251 2 74 221 2 120 175 2 154 141 2 190 105
0 2 1,340 0 6 1,336 0 9 1,333 0 23 1,319 0 44 1,298 0 68 1,275 0 139 1,204 0 210 1,132
36 29 272 36 61 239 36 95 205 36 133 168 36 170 130 36 203 98 36 234 67
5-9 6 14 277 6 25 267 6 40 251 6 71 221 6 116 175 6 150 141 6 186 105
2 4 1,336 2 7 1,333 2 21 1,319 2 42 1,298 2 65 1,275 2 136 1,204 2 208 1,132
65 32 239 65 66 205 65 104 168 65 141 130 65 174 98 65 204 67
10-14 20 10 267 20 26 251 20 56 221 20 102 175 20 136 141 20 172 105
6 3 1,333 6 17 1,319 6 38 1,298 6 62 1,275 6 133 1,204 6 204 1,132
97 34 205 97 71 168 97 109 130 97 142 98 97 172 67
15-19 30 16 251 30 46 221 30 91 175 30 126 141 30 162 105
9 14 1,319 9 35 1,298 9 59 1,275 9 130 1,204 9 201 1,132
131 37 168 131 75 130 131 108 98 131 138 67
20-24 46 30 221 46 76 175 46 110 141 46 146 105
23 21 1,298 23 44 1,275 23 115 1,204 23 187 1,132
168 38 130 168 70 98 168 101 67
25-29 76 45 175 76 80 141 76 116 105
44 24 1,275 44 95 1,204 44 166 1,132
206 33 98 206 63 67
30-34 122 34 141 122 70 105
68 71 1,204 68 142 1,132
239 31 67
35-39 156 36 105
139 71 1,132
40-44
45-49
57
Figure 22 (cont.): Classification results, very poor/poor cut-offs from 0 to 49
and poor/non-poor cut-offs from 50 to 100
Upper bound, poor segment
50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85-89
12 299 26 12 306 19 12 314 11 12 319 6 12 321 3 12 324 1 12 325 0 12 325 0 12
0-4 2 246 49 2 258 37 2 267 28 2 282 13 2 290 5 2 293 2 2 295 0 2 295 0 2
0 399 944 0 463 880 0 618 724 0 793 550 0 933 409 0 1,066 276 0 1,226 117 0 1,293 49 0
36 275 26 36 282 19 36 290 11 36 295 6 36 297 3 36 300 1 36 301 0 36 301 0 36
5-9 6 243 49 6 254 37 6 263 28 6 278 13 6 286 5 6 289 2 6 291 0 6 291 0 6
2 396 944 2 460 880 2 616 724 2 790 550 2 931 409 2 1,064 276 2 1,223 117 2 1,291 49 2
65 246 26 65 253 19 65 261 11 65 266 6 65 268 3 65 270 1 65 272 0 65 272 0 65
10-14 20 228 49 20 240 37 20 249 28 20 264 13 20 272 5 20 275 2 20 277 0 20 277 0 20
6 393 944 6 456 880 6 612 724 6 786 550 6 927 409 6 1,060 276 6 1,220 117 6 1,287 49 6
97 214 26 97 220 19 97 229 11 97 233 6 97 236 3 97 238 1 97 239 0 97 239 0 97
15-19 30 218 49 30 230 37 30 239 28 30 254 13 30 262 5 30 265 2 30 267 0 30 267 0 30
9 390 944 9 453 880 9 609 724 9 783 550 9 924 409 9 1,057 276 9 1,217 117 9 1,284 49 9
131 180 26 131 186 19 131 195 11 131 199 6 131 202 3 131 204 1 131 205 0 131 205 0 131
20-24 46 202 49 46 214 37 46 223 28 46 238 13 46 246 5 46 249 2 46 251 0 46 251 0 46
23 375 944 23 439 880 23 594 724 23 769 550 23 910 409 23 1,043 276 23 1,202 117 23 1,270 49 23
168 142 26 168 149 19 168 157 11 168 162 6 168 165 3 168 167 1 168 168 0 168 168 0 168
25-29 76 172 49 76 184 37 76 193 28 76 208 13 76 216 5 76 219 2 76 221 0 76 221 0 76
44 355 944 44 419 880 44 574 724 44 749 550 44 890 409 44 1,022 276 44 1,182 117 44 1,250 49 44
206 105 26 206 111 19 206 120 11 206 124 6 206 127 3 206 129 1 206 130 0 206 130 0 206
30-34 122 127 49 122 138 37 122 147 28 122 162 13 122 170 5 122 173 2 122 175 0 122 175 0 122
68 331 944 68 395 880 68 550 724 68 725 550 68 866 409 68 999 276 68 1,158 117 68 1,226 49 68
239 72 26 239 79 19 239 87 11 239 92 6 239 94 3 239 97 1 239 98 0 239 98 0 239
35-39 156 92 49 156 104 37 156 113 28 156 128 13 156 136 5 156 139 2 156 141 0 156 141 0 156
139 260 944 139 324 880 139 479 724 139 654 550 139 795 409 139 928 276 139 1,087 117 139 1,155 49 139
269 41 26 269 48 19 269 56 11 269 61 6 269 64 3 269 66 1 269 67 0 269 67 0 269
40-44 192 56 49 192 68 37 192 77 28 192 92 13 192 100 5 192 103 2 192 105 0 192 105 0 192
210 189 944 210 253 880 210 408 724 210 583 550 210 723 409 210 856 276 210 1,016 117 210 1,083 49 210
291 20 26 291 27 19 291 35 11 291 40 6 291 42 3 291 45 1 291 46 0 291 46 0 291
45-49 214 34 49 214 46 37 214 55 28 214 70 13 214 78 5 214 81 2 214 83 0 214 83 0 214
296 103 944 296 166 880 296 322 724 296 496 550 296 637 409 296 770 276 296 930 117 296 997 49 296
Figures in units of 10,000 people.
58
Figure 22 (cont.): Classification results, very poor/poor cut-offs from 50 to 94
and poor/non-poor cut-offs from 55 to 100
55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85-89
311 7 19 311 15 11 311 20 6 311 23 3 311 25 1 311 26 0 311 26 0
Upper bound, very poor segment
85-89
90-94
59
Figure 23: Classification results, very poor 0–24,
poor 25–34, and non-poor 35–100
People with score in range
Segment Score Very Poor Poor Non-poor
0-4 12 2 0
5-9 24 4 2
Very poor 10-14 131 29 46 14 23 4
0-24 15-19 65% 32 23% 10 12% 3
20-24 34 16 14
Poor 25-29 75 37 76 30 44 21
25-34 30-34 38% 38 39% 45 23% 24
35-39 33 34 71
40-44 31 36 71
45-49 21 22 86
50-54 20 34 103
55-59 7 12 64
Non-poor 60-64 130 8 175 9 1,275 155
35-100 65-69 8% 5 11% 15 81% 175
70-74 3 8 141
75-79 2 3 133
80-84 1 2 159
85-89 0 0 68
90-94 0 0 23
95-100 0 0 26
Total: 336 297 1,342
Counts of people are in units of 10,000.
60
Figure 24: An example net-benefit matrix
reflecting common values
Targeting segment
Very Poor Poor Non-poor
+3 -2 -6
Very Poor
True poverty status
-1 +2 -2
Poor
-2 -1 +1
Non-poor
Note: This is an example. Each program should define its own net-benefit matrix.
61
Figure 25: Computation of total net benefit for a
cut-off pair of 20–24 and 30–34
Cell Persons Net benefit/person Net benefit
A. Truly very poor as very poor 131 +3 +393
B. Truly very poor as poor 75 –2 –150
C. Truly very poor as non-poor 130 –6 –780
D. Truly poor as very poor 46 –1 –46
E. Truly poor as poor 76 +2 +152
F. Truly poor as non-poor 175 –2 –350
G. Truly non-poor as very poor 23 –2 –46
H. Truly non-poor as poor 44 –1 –44
I. Truly non-poor as non-poor 1,275 +1 +1,275
Total net benefit: +404
Note: Persons are counted in units of 10,000.
62
Figure 26: Poverty likelihoods for the very poor, poor, $4/day poor,
and non-poor by score
Poverty likelihood in score range Share of cases <= score
Score Very Poor Poor Poor $4/day Non-poor Very Poor Poor Poor $4/day Non-poor
0-4 85.0 14.3 0.4 0.4 85.0 14.3 0.4 0.4
5-9 79.7 12.8 4.4 3.2 81.3 13.3 3.1 2.3
10-14 61.9 30.0 6.3 1.8 71.3 21.9 4.8 2.0
15-19 70.5 22.9 4.5 2.1 71.0 22.3 4.7 2.0
20-24 53.2 24.4 12.8 9.5 65.4 22.9 7.3 4.4
25-29 42.4 34.4 14.4 8.8 58.3 26.4 9.5 5.8
30-34 35.2 42.6 13.1 9.2 52.1 30.8 10.4 6.7
35-39 23.8 24.8 23.1 28.3 44.8 29.2 13.7 12.3
40-44 22.2 26.1 22.6 29.1 40.1 28.6 15.5 15.7
45-49 16.5 17.1 27.0 39.4 36.3 26.7 17.4 19.6
50-54 12.6 21.8 18.6 47.0 32.4 25.9 17.6 24.1
55-59 8.4 14.2 19.8 57.7 30.5 25.0 17.8 26.7
60-64 4.7 5.4 20.6 69.4 26.8 22.2 18.2 32.8
65-69 2.5 7.6 14.5 75.4 23.5 20.2 17.6 38.7
70-74 1.7 5.2 11.8 81.2 21.4 18.7 17.1 42.8
75-79 1.6 2.2 4.5 91.7 19.8 17.4 16.1 46.8
80-84 0.7 1.4 2.4 95.5 18.1 16.0 14.9 51.1
85-89 0.0 0.0 0.8 99.2 17.5 15.4 14.4 52.7
90-94 0.0 0.0 0.2 99.8 17.3 15.2 14.2 53.3
95-100 0.0 0.0 0.7 99.3 17.0 15.0 14.0 53.9
Total: 17.0 15.0 14.0 53.9
63
Figure 27: Confidence intervals for estimated poverty likelihoods for
being $4/day-or-less poor associated with scores
100
95 Upper 99% bound
Poverty likelihood (mean, 90-, 95-, 99-percent
64
Figure 28: Differences between estimated and true poverty likelihoods
for the $4/day-or-less poor
18
16
Difference between predicted and estimated
14
12
10
8
poverty likelihood
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
-16
0-4 5-9 10-14 15-19 20-24 25-29 30-34 35-39 40-44 45-49 50-54 55-59 60-64 65-69 70-74 75-79 80-84 85-89 90-94 95-
Range of score 100
65
Figure 29: ROC curve of ability to rank-order households by
$4/day-or-less poverty status
1.00
Proportion of poor and non-poor with scores <=
0.95
0.90
0.85 Targeting the
a given score when ordered by score
0.80 lowest-scoring
0.75 20% of households
0.70 targets 3% of the
0.65 non-poor and 44%
0.60 of the $4/day poor
0.55
0.50
0.45
0.40 Area KS
0.35 Random 0.0 0.0
0.30 Scorecard 74.3 58.0
0.25 Perfect 100 100
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100
Percentage of all cases, ordered by score
66